International Handbooks on Information Systems
Series Editors Peter Bernus, Jacek Błażewicz, Günter J. Schmidt, Michael J. Shaw
For further volumes: http://www.springer.com/series/3795
Titles in the Series M. Shaw, R. Blanning, T. Strader and A. Whinston (Eds.) Handbook on Electronic Commerce ISBN 978-3-540-65882-1
P. Bernus, K. Merlins and G. Schmidt (Eds.) Handbook on Architectures of Information Systems ISBN 978-3-540-25472-0, 2nd Edition
J. Błaz˙ewicz, K. Ecker, B. Plateau and D. Trystram (Eds.) Handbook on Parallel and Distributed Processing ISBN 978-3-540-66441-3
S. Kirn, O. Herzog, P. Lockemann and O. Spaniol (Eds.) Multiagent Engineering ISBN 978-3-540-31406-6
H.H. Adelsberger, Kinshuk, J.M. Pawlowski and D. Sampson (Eds.) Handbook on Information Technologies for Education and Training ISBN 978-3-540-74154-1, 2nd Edition C.W. Holsapple (Ed.) Handbook on Knowledge Management 1 Knowledge Matters ISBN 978-3-540-43527-3 Handbook on Knowledge Management 2 Knowledge Directions ISBN 978-3-540-43848-9 J. Błaz˙ewicz, W. Kubiak, I. Morzy and M. Rusinkiewicz (Eds.) Handbook on Data Management in Information Systems ISBN 978-3-540-43893-9 P. Bernus, P. Nemes and G. Schmidt (Eds.) Handbook on Enterprise Architecture ISBN 978-3-540-00343-4 S. Staab and R. Studer (Eds.) Handbook on Ontologies ISBN 978-3-540-70999-2, 2nd Edition S.O. Kimbrough and D.J. Wu (Eds.) Formal Modelling in Electronic Commerce ISBN 978-3-540-21431-1
J. Błaz˙ewicz, K. Ecker, E. Pesch, G. Schmidt and J. Weglarz (Eds.) Handbook on Scheduling ISBN 978-3-540-28046-0 F. Burstein and C.W. Holsapple (Eds.) Handbook on Decision Support Systems 1 ISBN 978-3-540-48712-8 F. Burstein and C.W. Holsapple (Eds.) Handbook on Decision Support Systems 2 ISBN 978-3-540-48715-9 D. Seese, Ch. Weinhardt and F. Schlottmann (Eds.) Handbook on Information Technology in Finance ISBN 978-3-540-49486-7 T.C. Edwin Cheng and Tsan-Ming Choi (Eds.) Innovative Quick Response Programs in Logistics and Supply Chain Management ISBN 978-3-642-04312-3 J. vom Brocke and M. Rosemann (Eds.) Handbook on Business Process Management 1 ISBN 978-3-642-00415-5 Handbook on Business Process Management 2 ISBN 978-3-642-01981-4 T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty ISBN 978-3-642-19256-2
Tsan-Ming Choi
l
T.C. Edwin Cheng
Editors
Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty
Editors Tsan-Ming Choi The Hong Kong Polytechnic University Business Division, Institute of Textiles and Clothing Hung Hom, Kowloon Hong Kong SAR
[email protected]
T.C. Edwin Cheng The Hong Kong Polytechnic University Department of Logistics and Maritime Studies Hung Hom, Kowloon Hong Kong SAR
[email protected]
ISBN 978-3-642-19256-2 e-ISBN 978-3-642-19257-9 DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9 Springer Heidelberg Dordrecht London New York Library of Congress Control Number: 2011935633 # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011 This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved, whether the whole or part of the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse of illustrations, recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilm or in any other way, and storage in data banks. Duplication of this publication or parts thereof is permitted only under the provisions of the German Copyright Law of September 9, 1965, in its current version, and permission for use must always be obtained from Springer. Violations are liable to prosecution under the German Copyright Law. The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, etc. in this publication does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such names are exempt from the relevant protective laws and regulations and therefore free for general use. Printed on acid-free paper Springer is part of Springer Science+Business Media (www.springer.com)
Preface
Channel coordination is a core subject of supply chain management. It is well-known that a stochastic multi-echelon supply chain system usually fails to be optimal owing to the presence of the bullwhip effect and the double marginalization issue. Motivated by the importance of the topic, over the past decade, much research effort has been devoted to exploring the detailed mechanisms (such as incentive alignment schemes) for achieving supply chain coordination under uncertainty and has generated many fruitful analytical and empirical results. Despite the abundance of research results, there is an absence of a comprehensive reference source that provides state-of-the-art findings on both theoretical and applied research on the subject “under one roof”. In addition, many new topics and innovative measures for supply chain coordination under uncertainty have appeared in recent years and many new challenges have emerged. As a result, we believe it is significant to put together all these interesting works and the respective insights into an edited volume. In view of the above, we co-edit this Springer handbook. The handbook contains five parts, covering (1) introductory materials and review of supply chain coordination; (2) analytical models for innovative coordination under uncertainty; (3) channel power, bargaining, and coordination; (4) technological advancements and applications in coordination; and (5) empirical analysis and case studies. The specific topics covered include the following: – Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents – A Timely Review on Supply Chain Coordination – A Review of Control Policies for Multi-Echelon Inventory Systems with Stochastic Demand – Supply Chain Models with Active Acquisition and Remanufacturing – Facilitating Demand Risk-sharing with the Innovative Percent Deviation Contract – Value-added Retailer in a Mixed Channel under Asymmetric Information – Capacity Management and Price Discrimination under Demand Uncertainty using Options – Dynamic Procurement and Quantity Discounts in Supply Chains – Coordination in a Multi-period Setting: The Additional Ordering Cost Contract
v
vi
Preface
– Use of Supply Chain Contract to Motivate Selling Effort – Price and Warranty Competition in a Duopoly Supply Chain – Supply Chain Coordination for Newsvendor-type Products with Two Ordering Opportunities – Bargaining in a Two-Stage Supply Chain through Revenue-Sharing Contract – Should a Stackelberg-dominated Supply-chain Player Help her Dominant Opponent to Obtain Better Information – Supply Chain Coordination under Demand Uncertainty using Credit Option – Supply Chain Coordination under Consignment Contract – A Heuristic Approach for Collaborative Planning in Detailed Scheduling – RFID Technology Adoption and Supply Chain Coordination – Possibilistic Mixed Integer Programming Approach for Supply Chain Network Problems – Coordination of Converging Material Flows in Supply Chains under Uncertainty – Bioenergy Systems and Supply Chains in Europe: Conditions, Capacity, and Coordination – Benefits of Involving Contract Manufacturers in Collaborative Planning for Three-Echelon Supply Networks – A Capability-Based Approach for Managing IT Suppliers – Methodology for Assessing Collaboration Strategies and Incentives in the Pulp and Paper Industry We are very pleased to see that this research handbook has generated a lot of new analytical and empirical results with precious insights, which will not only help supply chain agents to understand more about the latest measures for supply chain coordination under uncertainty, but also help practitioners and researchers to know how to improve supply chain performance based on innovative methods. This will be especially meaningful to industries such as fashion apparel and consumer electronics, in which effective supply chain management has been known to be the key to success. We would like to take this opportunity to show our gratitude to Werner A. Mueller and Christian Rauscher for their kind support and advice along the course of carrying out this project. We sincerely thank all the authors who have contributed their decent research to this handbook. We are grateful to the professional reviewers who reviewed the submitted papers and provided us with timely comments and constructive recommendations. We are indebted to our student Pui-Sze Chow for her editorial assistance. We also acknowledge the funding support of the Research Grants Council of Hong Kong under grant number PolyU 5143/07E (General Research Fund) and The Hong Kong Polytechnic University under grant number J-BB6U. Last but not least, we are grateful to our families, colleagues, friends, and students, who have been supporting us during the development of this important research handbook. Tsan-Ming Choi, T.C.E. Cheng The Hong Kong Polytechnic University
Contents
Part I
Introduction and Review
Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3 Xianghua Gan, Suresh P. Sethi, and Houmin Yan Addendum to “Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents” by Gan, Sethi, and Yan (2004) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33 Xianghua Gan, Suresh P. Sethi, and Houmin Yan A Review on Supply Chain Coordination: Coordination Mechanisms, Managing Uncertainty and Research Directions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39 Kaur Arshinder, Arun Kanda, and S.G. Deshmukh Control Policies for Multi-echelon Inventory Systems with Stochastic Demand . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83 Qinan Wang Supply Chain Models with Active Acquisition and Remanufacturing . . . 109 Xiang Li and Yongjian Li Part II
Analytical Models for Innovative Coordination under Uncertainty
Facilitating Demand Risk-Sharing with the Percent Deviation Contract . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131 Matthew J. Drake and Julie L. Swann
vii
viii
Contents
Value-Added Retailer in a Mixed Channel: Asymmetric Information and Contract Design . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 165 Samar K. Mukhopadhyay, Xiaowei Zhu, and Xiaohang Yue Capacity Management and Price Discrimination under Demand Uncertainty Using Option Contracts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 189 Fang Fang and Andrew Whinston Dynamic Procurement, Quantity Discounts, and Supply Chain Efficiency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 219 Feryal Erhun, Pinar Keskinocak, and Sridhar Tayur Coordination of the Supplier–Retailer Relationship in a Multi-period Setting: The Additional Ordering Cost Contract . . . . . 235 Nicola Bellantuono, Ilaria Giannoccaro, and Pierpaolo Pontrandolfo Use of Supply Chain Contract to Motivate Selling Effort . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 255 Samar K. Mukhopadhyay and Xuemei Su Price and Warranty Competition in a Duopoly Supply Chain . . . . . . . . . . . 281 Santanu Sinha and S.P. Sarmah Supply Chain Coordination for Newsvendor-Type Products with Two Ordering Opportunities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 315 Yong-Wu Zhou and Sheng-Dong Wang Part III
Channel Power, Bargaining and Coordination
Bargaining in a Two-Stage Supply Chain Through Revenue-Sharing Contract . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 347 Jing Hou and Amy Z. Zeng Should a Stackelberg-Dominated Supply-Chain Player Help Her Dominant Opponent to Obtain Better System-Parameter Knowledge? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 379 Jian-Cai Wang, Amy Hing-Ling Lau, and Hon-Shiang Lau Supply Chain Coordination Under Demand Uncertainty Using Credit Option . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 403 S. Kamal Chaharsooghi and Jafar Heydari Supply Chain Coordination Under Consignment Contract with Revenue Sharing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 427 Sijie Li, Jia Shu, and Lindu Zhao
Contents
Part IV
ix
Technological Advancements and Applications in Supply Chain Coordination
DEAL: A Heuristic Approach for Collaborative Planning in Detailed Scheduling . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 457 J. Benedikt Scheckenbach Inventory Record Inaccuracy, RFID Technology Adoption and Supply Chain Coordination . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 483 H. Sebastian Heese Possibilistic Mixed Integer Linear Programming Approach for Production Allocation and Distribution Supply Chain Network Problem in the Consumer Goods Industry . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 505 Bilge Bilgen Coordination of Converging Material Flows Under Conditions of Uncertainty in Supply Chains . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 525 Liesje De Boeck and Nico Vandaele Part V
Empirical Analysis and Case Studies
Bioenergy Systems and Supply Chains in Europe: Conditions, Capacity and Coordination . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 545 Kes McCormick Three Is a Crowd? On the Benefits of Involving Contract Manufacturers in Collaborative Planning for Three-Echelon Supply Networks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 563 Henk Akkermans, Kim van Oorschot, and Winfried Peeters Managing IT Suppliers: A Capability-Based Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 599 Carlos Brito and Mafalda Nogueira Methodology for Assessing Collaboration Strategies and Incentives in the Pulp and Paper Industry . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 625 Nadia Lehoux, Sophie D’Amours, and Andre´ Langevin Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 651
.
Contributors
Henk Akkermans Supply Network Dynamics, Department of Information Management, Tilburg University, Warandelaan 2, P.O. Box 90153, 5000 LE, Tilburg, The Netherlands,
[email protected] Nicola Bellantuono Dipartimento di Ingegneria dell’Ambiente e per lo Sviluppo Sostenibile, Politecnico di Bari, via De Gasperi s.n, 74100 Taranto, Italy,
[email protected] Bilge Bilgen Department of Industrial Engineering, Dokuz Eylul University, 35160 Izmir, Turkey,
[email protected] Carlos Brito Faculty of Economics, University of Porto, Rua Roberto Frias, 4200-464 Porto, Portugal,
[email protected] S. Kamal Chaharsooghi Industrial Engineering Department, Tarbiat Modares University, Tehran, Iran,
[email protected] Sophie D’Amours FORAC, Department of Mechanical Engineering, Pavillon Adrien-Pouliot, Universite´ Laval, Que´bec, Canada, G1V 0A6, sophie.
[email protected] Liesje De Boeck Centre for Modeling and Simulation, HUBrussel, Stormstraat 2, 1000 Brussels, Belgium; Research Centre for Operations Management, K.U.Leuven, Naamsestraat 69, 3000 Leuven, Belgium,
[email protected] S.G. Deshmukh Department of Mechanical Engineering, Indian Institute of Technology Delhi, New Delhi, 110016, India,
[email protected] Matthew J. Drake Palumbo-Donahue Schools of Business, Duquesne University, Pittsburgh, PA 15282, USA,
[email protected]
xi
xii
Contributors
Feryal Erhun Department of Management Science and Engineering, Stanford University, Stanford, CA, USA,
[email protected] Fang Fang Department of ISOM, College of Business Administration, California State University at San Marcos, 333 S. Twin Oaks Valley Road, San Marcos, CA 92096, USA,
[email protected] Xianghua Gan Department of Logistics and Maritime Studies, The Hong Kong Polytechnic University, Hung Hom, Kowloon, Hong Kong, China, lgtxgan@polyu. edu.hk Ilaria Giannoccaro Dipartimento di Ingegneria Meccanica e Gestionale, Politecnico di Bari, viale Japigia 182, 70125 Bari, Italy,
[email protected] H. Sebastian Heese Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, 1309 East Tenth Street, Bloomington, IN 47405, USA,
[email protected] Jafar Heydari Industrial Engineering Department, Shiraz University of Technology, Shiraz, Iran,
[email protected] Jing Hou Business School, Hohai University, Nanjing, Jiangsu 211100, China, hjbgwin0702@ hotmail.com Arun Kanda Department of Mechanical Engineering, Indian Institute of Technology Delhi, New Delhi 110016, India,
[email protected] Arshinder Kaur Department of Management Studies, Indian Institute of Technology Madras, Chennai 600036, India,
[email protected] Pinar Keskinocak School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, GA, USA,
[email protected] Andre´ Langevin CIRRELT, Department of Mathematics and Industrial Engineering, E´cole Polytechnique de Montre´al, C.P. 6079, succ. Centre-ville, Montre´al, Canada, H3C 3A,
[email protected] Amy Hing Ling Lau School of Business, University of Hong Kong, Pokfulam, Hong Kong,
[email protected] Hon-Shiang Lau Department of Management Sciences, City University of Hong Kong, Kowloon Tong, Hong Kong,
[email protected] Nadia Lehoux FORAC, Department of Mechanical Engineering, Pavillon AdrienPouliot, Universite´ Laval, Que´bec, Canada, G1V 0A6,
[email protected]
Contributors
xiii
Sijie Li Institute of Systems and Engineering, Southeast University, Nanjing, Jiangsu People’s Republic of China,
[email protected] Xiang Li Research Centre of Logistics, College of Economic and Social Development, Nankai University, Tianjian 300071, P.R. China,
[email protected] Yongjian Li Business School, Nankai University, Tianjin 300071, P.R. China,
[email protected] Kes McCormick International Institute for Industrial Environmental Economics (IIIEE), Lund University, Lund, Sweden,
[email protected] Samar K. Mukhopadhyay Graduate School of Business, Sungkyunkwan University, Jongno-Gu, Seoul 110–745, South Korea,
[email protected] Mafalda Nogueira Management School, Lancaster University, Lancaster, LA1-4YX, UK,
[email protected] Winfried Peeters BU HPMS, NXP Semiconductors, High Tech Campus 60, 5656 AG Eindhoven, The Netherlands,
[email protected] Pierpaolo Pontrandolfo Dipartimento di Ingegneria dell’Ambiente e per lo Sviluppo Sostenibile, Politecnico di Bari, via De Gasperi s.n, 74100 Taranto, Italy,
[email protected] S.P. Sarmah Department of Industrial Engineering and Management, Indian Institute of Technology, Kharagpur 721302, India,
[email protected] J. Benedikt Scheckenbach
[email protected]
Cranachstr. 16, 50733 Koeln, Germany, benedikt.
Suresh P. Sethi School of Management, SM30, The University of Texas at Dallas, 800W Campbell Road, Richardson, TX 75080-3021, USA,
[email protected] Jia Shu Department of Management Science and Engineering, School of Economics and Management, Southeast University, Nanjing, Jiangsu P.R. China,
[email protected] Santanu Sinha Complex Decision Support Systems, Tata Consultancy Services, Akruti Trade Centre, MIDC, Andheri (E), Mumbai 400093, India, santanu_snh@ yahoo.com Xuemei Su College of Business Administration, California State University Long Beach, 1250 Bellflower Blvd, Long Beach, CA 90840, USA,
[email protected]
xiv
Contributors
Julie L. Swann H. Milton Stewart School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, GA 30332-0205, USA, jswann@isye. gatech.edu Sridhar Tayur Tepper School of Business, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA, USA,
[email protected] Kim van Oorschot Department of Leadership and Organizational Behaviour, BI Norwegian School of Business, NO-0442 Oslo, Norway,
[email protected] Nico Vandaele Research Centre for Operations Management, K.U.Leuven, Naamsestraat 69, 3000 Leuven, Belgium; Faculty of Business and Economics, K.U. Leuven-Campus Kortrijk, Etienne Sabbelaan 53-bus 0000, 8500 Kortrijk, Belgium,
[email protected] Jian-Cai Wang School of Business, University of Hong Kong, Pokfulam, Hong Kong; School of Management and Economics, Beijing Institute of Technology, Beijing, China,
[email protected] Qinan Wang Nanyang Business School, Nanyang Technological University, Singapore, Singapore 639798,
[email protected] Sheng-Dong Wang Department of Mathematics, Hefei Electronic Engineering Institute, Hefei, Anhui, P.R. China,
[email protected] Andrew B. Whinston Department of IROM, McCombs School of Business, The University of Texas at Austin, 1 University Station B6000, Austin, TX 78712, USA,
[email protected] Houmin Yan Department of Systems Engineering and Engineering Management, The Chinese University of Hong Kong, Shatin, NT, Hong Kong,
[email protected] Xiaohang Yue Sheldon B. Lubar School of Business, University of WisconsinMilwaukee, P.O. Box 742, Milwaukee, WI 53201, USA,
[email protected] Amy Z. Zeng School of Business, Worcester Polytechnic Institute, Worcester, MA 01609, USA,
[email protected] Lindu Zhao Institute of Systems and Engineering, Southeast University, Nanjing, Jiangsu People’s Republic of China,
[email protected] Yong-Wu Zhou School of Business Administration, South China University of Technology, Guangzhou, Guangdong, P.R. China,
[email protected] Xiaowei Zhu College of Business and Public Affairs, West Chester University of Pennsylvania, West Chester, PA 19383, USA,
[email protected]
.
Part I
Introduction and Review
.
Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents Xianghua Gan, Suresh P. Sethi, and Houmin Yan
Abstract The extant supply chain management literature has not addressed the issue of coordination in supply chains involving risk-averse agents. We take up this issue and begin with defining a coordinating contract as one that results in a Paretooptimal solution acceptable to each agent. Our definition generalizes the standard one in the risk-neutral case. We then develop coordinating contracts in three specific cases (1) the supplier is risk neutral and the retailer maximizes his expected profit subject to a downside risk constraint, (2) the supplier and the retailer each maximizes his own mean-variance trade-off, and (3) the supplier and the retailer each maximizes his own expected utility. Moreover, in case (3) we show that our contract yields the Nash Bargaining solution. In each case, we show how we can find the set of Pareto-optimal solutions, and then design a contract to achieve the solutions. We also exhibit a case in which we obtain Pareto-optimal sharing rules explicitly, and outline a procedure to obtain Pareto-optimal solutions. Keywords Capacity • Coordination • Nash bargaining • Pareto-optimality • Risk averse • Supply chain management
X. Gan (*) Department of Logistics and Maritime Studies, The Hong Kong Polytechnic University, Hung Hom, Kowloon, Hong Kong e-mail:
[email protected] S.P. Sethi School of Management, SM30, The University of Texas at Dallas, 800W. Campbell Road, Richardson, TX 75080-3021, USA e-mail:
[email protected] H. Yan Department of Systems Engineering and Engineering Management, The Chinese University of Hong Kong, Shatin, NT, Hong Kong e-mail:
[email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_1, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
3
4
X. Gan et al.
1 Introduction Much of the research on decision making in a supply chain has assumed that the agents in the supply chain are risk neutral, i.e., they maximize their respective expected profits. An important focus of this research has been the design of supply contracts that coordinate the supply chain. When each of the agents maximizes his expected profit, the objective of the supply chain considered as a single entity is unambiguously to maximize its total expected profit. This fact alone makes it natural to define a supply chain to be coordinated if the chain’s expected profit is maximized and each agent’s reservation profit is met. A similar argument holds if each agent’s objective is to minimize his expected cost. In this paper we consider supply chains with risk-averse agents. Simply put, an agent is risk averse if the agent prefers a certain profit p to a risky profit, whose expected value equals p. In the literature, there are many measures of risk aversion; see Szeg€o (2004) for examples. Regardless of the measure used, when one or more agents in the supply chain are risk averse, it is no longer obvious as to what the objective function of the supply chain entity should be. Not surprisingly, the issue of coordination of supply chain consisting of risk-averse agents has not been studied in the supply chain management literature. That is not to say that the literature does not realize the importance of the risk-averse criteria. Indeed, there are a number of papers devoted to the study of inventory decisions of a single riskaverse agent. These include Lau (1980), Bouakiz and Sobel (1992), Eeckhoudt et al. (1995), Chen and Federgruen (2000), Agrawal and Seshadri (2000a), Buzacott et al. (2002), Chen et al. (2007), and Gaur and Seshadri (2005). There also have been a few studies of supply chains consisting of one or more risk-averse agents. Lau and Lau (1999) and Tsay (2002) consider decision making by a risk-averse supplier and a risk-averse retailer constituting a supply chain. Agrawal and Seshadri (2000b) introduce a risk-neutral intermediary to make ordering decisions for risk-averse retailers, whose respective profits are side payments from the intermediary. Van Mieghem (2003) has reviewed the literature that incorporates risk aversion in capacity investment decisions. While these papers consider risk-averse decision makers by themselves or as agents in a supply chain, they do not deal with the issue of the supply chain coordination involving risk-averse agents. It is this issue of coordination of supply chains consisting of one or more riskaverse agents that is the focus of this paper. That many decision makers are riskaverse has been amply documented in the finance and economics literature; see, for example, Van Neumann and Morgenstern (1944), Markowitz (1959), Jorion (2006), and Szeg€o (2004). We shall therefore develop the concept of what we mean by coordination of a supply chain, and then design explicit contracts that achieve the defined coordination. For this purpose we use the Pareto-optimality criterion, used widely in the group decision theory, to evaluate a supply chain’s performance. We define each agent’s payoff to be a real-valued function of a random variable representing his profit, and propose that a supply chain can be treated as coordinated if no agent’s payoff can be
Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents
5
improved without impairing someone else’s payoff and each agent receives at least his reservation payoff. We consider three specific cases of a supply chain (1) the supplier is risk neutral and the retailer maximizes his expected profit subject to a downside risk constraint, (2) the supplier and the retailer each maximizes his own mean-variance trade-off, and (3) the supplier and the retailer each maximizes his own expected utility. We show how we can coordinate the supply chain in each case according to our definition. In each case we do this by finding the set of Paretooptimal solutions acceptable to each agent, and then constructing a flexible contract that can attain any of these solutions. Moreover, the concept we develop and the contracts we obtain generalize the same known for supply chains involving risk-neutral agents. The remainder of the paper is organized as the follows. In Sect. 2 we review the related literature in supply chain management and group decision theory. In Sect. 3 we introduce a definition of coordination of a supply chain consisting of risk-averse agents. In Sect. 4 we characterize the Pareto-optimal solutions and find coordinating contracts for the supply chains listed as the first two cases. In Sect. 5 we first take up the third case using exponential utility functions for the agents, and design coordinating contracts as well as obtain the Nash Bargaining solution. Then we examine a case in which the supplier has an exponential utility followed by a linear utility. Section 6 provides a discussion of our results. The paper concludes in Sect. 7 with suggestions for future research.
2 Literature Review There is a considerable literature devoted to contracts that coordinate a supply chain involving risk-neutral agents. This literature has been surveyed by Cachon (2003). In addition, the book by Tayur et al. (1999) contains a number of chapters addressing supply contracts. In light of these, we limit ourselves to reviewing papers studying inventory and supply chain decisions by risk-averse agents. First we review papers dealing with a single risk-averse agent’s optimal inventory decision. Then we review articles dealing with decision making by risk-averse agents in a supply chain. Chen and Federgruen (2000) re-visit a number of basic inventory models using a mean-variance approach. They exhibit how a systematic mean-variance trade-off analysis can be carried out efficiently, and how the resulting strategies differ from those obtained in the standard analyses. Agrawal and Seshadri (2000a) consider how a risk-averse retailer, whose utility function is increasing and concave in wealth, chooses the order quantity and the selling price in a single-period inventory model. They consider two different ways in which the price affects the distribution of demand. In the first model, they assume that a change in the price affects the scale of the distribution. In the second model, a change in the price only affects the location of the distribution. They show that in comparison to a risk-neutral retailer, a risk-averse retailer will charge a higher price
6
X. Gan et al.
and order less in the first model, whereas he will charge a lower price in the second model. Buzacott et al. (2002) model a commitment and option contract for a risk-averse newsvendor with a mean-variance objective. The contract, also known as a takeor-pay contract, belongs to a class of volume flexible contracts, where the newsvendor reserves a capacity with initial information and adjusts the purchase at a later stage when some new information becomes available. They compare the performance of strategies developed for risk-averse and risk-neutral objectives. They conclude that the risk-averse objective can be an effective approach when the quality of information revision is not high. Their study indicates that it is possible to reduce the risk (measured by the variance of the profit) by six- to eightfold, while the loss in the expected profit is almost invisible. On the other hand, the strategy developed for the expected profit objective can only be considered when the quality of information revision is high. They show furthermore that these findings continue to hold in the expected utility framework. The paper points out a need for modeling approaches that deal with downside risk considerations. Lau and Lau (1999) study a supply chain consisting of a monopolistic supplier and a retailer. The supplier and the retailer employ a return policy, and each of them has a mean-variance objective function. Lau and Lau obtain the optimal wholesale price and return credit for the supplier to maximize his utility. However, they do not consider the issue of improving the supply chain’s performance, i.e., improving both players’ utilities. Agrawal and Seshadri (2000b) consider a single-period model in which multiple risk-averse retailers purchase a single product from a common supplier. They introduce a risk neutral intermediary into the channel, who purchases goods from the vendor and sells them to the retailers. They demonstrate that the intermediary, referred to as the distributor, orders the optimal newsvendor quantity from the supplier and offers a menu of mutually beneficial contracts to the retailers. In every contract in the menu, the retailer receives a fixed side payment, while the distributor is responsible for the ordering decisions of the retailers and receives all their revenues. The menu of contracts simultaneously (1) induces every risk-averse agent to select a unique contract from it; (2) maximizes the distributor’s profit; and (3) raises the order quantities of the retailers to the expected value maximizing (newsvendor) quantities. Tsay (2002) studies how risk aversion affects both sides of the supplier–retailer relationship under various scenario of relative strategic power, and how these dynamics are altered by the introduction of a return policy. The sequence of play is as follows: first the supplier announces a return policy, and then the retailer chooses order quantity without knowing the demand. After observing the demand, the retailer chooses the price and executes on any relevant terms of the distribution policy as appropriate (e.g., returning any overstock as allowed). Tsay shows that the behavior under risk aversion is qualitatively different from that under risk neutrality. He also show that the penalty for errors in estimating a channel partner’s risk aversion can be substantial.
Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents
7
In a companion paper (Gan et al. 2005), we examine coordinating contracts for a supply chain consisting of one risk-neutral supplier and one risk-averse retailer. There we design an easy-to-implement risk-sharing contract that accomplishes the coordination as defined in this paper. Among these supply chain papers, Lau and Lau (1999) and Tsay (2002) consider the situation in which both the retailer and the supplier in the channel are risk averse. However, neither considers the issue of the Pareto-optimality of the actions of the agents. The aim of Agrawal and Seshadri (2000b) is to design a contract that increases the channel’s order quantity to the optimal level in the risk-neutral case by having the risk-neutral agent assume all the risk. Once again, they do not mention the Pareto-optimality aspect of the decision they obtain. Finally since our definition of coordination is based on the concepts used in the group decision theory, we briefly review this stream of literature. From the early fifties to the early eighties, a number of papers and books appeared that deal with situations in which a group faces intertwined external and internal problems. The external problem involves the choice of an action to be taken by the group, and the internal problem involves the distribution of the group payoff among the members. Arrow (1951) conducted one of the earliest studies on the group decision theory, and showed that given an ordering of consequences by a number of individuals, no group ordering of these consequences exists that satisfies a set of seemingly reasonable behavioral assumptions. Harsanyi (1955) presented conditions under which the total group utility can be expressed as a linear combination of individuals’ cardinal utilities. Wilson (1968) used Pareto-optimality as the decision criterion and constructed a group utility function to find Pareto-optimal solutions. Raiffa (1970) illustrates the criterion of Pareto-optimality quite lucidly, and discusses how to choose a Pareto-optimal solution in bargaining and arbitration problems. LaValle (1978) uses an allocation function to define Pareto-optimality. Eliashberg and Winkler (1981) investigate properties of sharing rules and the group utility functions in additive and multilinear cases.
3 Definition of Coordination of a Supply Chain with Risk-Neutral or Risk-Averse Agents In this section we define coordination of a supply chain consisting of agents that are risk neutral or risk averse. We use concepts developed in group decision theory that deals with situations in which a group faces intertwined external and internal problems. The external problem involves the choice of an action to be taken by the group, and the internal problem involves the distribution of the group payoff among the members. In group decision problems, a joint action of the group members is said to be Pareto-optimal if there does not exist an alternative action that is at least as acceptable to all and definitely preferred by some. In other words, a joint action is Pareto-optimal if it is not possible to make one agent better off without making
8
X. Gan et al.
another one worse off. We call the collection of all Pareto-optimal actions as the Pareto-optimal set. It would not be reasonable for the group of agents to choose a joint action that is not Pareto-optimal. Raiffa (1970) and LaValle (1978) illustrate this idea quite lucidly with a series of examples. A supply chain problem is obviously a group decision problem. The channel faces an external problem and an internal problem. External problems include decisions regarding order/production quantities, item prices, etc. The internal problem is to allocate profit by setting the wholesale price, deciding the amount of a side payment if any, refund on the returned units, etc. Naturally, we can adopt the Pareto-optimality criterion of the group decision theory for making decisions in a supply chain. Indeed, in the risk-neutral case, the optimal action under a coordinating contract is clearly Pareto-optimal. In general, since the agents in the channel would not choose an action that is not in the Pareto-optimal set, the first step to coordinate a channel is to characterize the set. Following the ideas of Raiffa (1970) and LaValle (1978), we formalize below the definition of Pareto-optimality. Let (O; F ; P) denote the probability space and N denote the number of agents in the supply chain, N r2. Let Si be the external action space of agent i; i ¼ 1; . . . ; N, and S ¼ S1 SN . For any given external joint action s ¼ ðs1 ; . . . ; sN Þ 2 S, the channel’s total profit is a random variable Pðs; oÞ; o 2 O. Let E and V denote the expectation and variance defined on (O; F ; P), respectively. Now we define a sharing rule that governs the splitting of the channel profit among the agents. Let Y be the set of all functions from S O to RN . P Definition 1. A function uðs; vÞ 2 Q is called a sharing rule if i ui ðs; vÞ ¼ 1 almost surely. Under the sharing rule uðs; oÞ, agent i’s profit is represented by Pi ðs; v; uðs; vÞÞ ¼ ui ðs; vÞPðs; vÞ; i ¼ 1; . . . ; N: Often, when there is no confusion, we write Pðs; vÞ simply as PðsÞ, uðs; vÞ as uðsÞ, and Pi ðs; v; uðs; vÞÞ as Pi ðs; uðsÞÞ. A supply chain’s external problem is to choose an s 2 S and its internal problem is to choose a function uðsÞ 2 Y. Thus the channel’s total problem is to choose a pair ðs; uðsÞÞ 2 S Y. Now we define the preferences of the agents over their random profits. Let G denote the space of all random variables defined on ðO; F ;PÞ. For X; X0 2 G, the agent i’s preference will be denoted by a real-valued payoff function ui ðÞ defined on G. The relation ui ðXÞ>ui ðX0 Þ, ui ðXÞ
0. Example 2. Assume that agent i maximizes his expected profit under the constraint that the probability of his profit being less than his target profit level a does not exceed a given level b; 0
Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents
ui ðXÞ ¼
9
EðXÞ; if PðXbaÞbb; 1; if PðXbaÞ>b:
Example 3. Suppose agent i has a concave increasing utility function gi : R1 ! R1 of wealth and wants to maximize his expected utility. Then the agent’s payoff function is ui ðXÞ ¼ E½gi ðXÞ; X 2 G. Remark 1. In Raiffa (1970) and LaValle (1978), each agent is assumed to have a cardinal utility function of profit, and his objective is to maximize his expected utility. However, some preferences, such as the one in Example 2, cannot be represented by a cardinal utility function. A point a 2 RN is said to be Pareto-inferior to or Pareto-dominated by another point b 2 RN , if each component of a is no greater than the corresponding component of b and at least one component of a is less than the corresponding component of b. In other words, we say b is Pareto-superior to a or b Pareto-dominates a. A point is said to be a Pareto-optimal point of a subset of RN , if it is not Paretoinferior to any other point in the subset. With these concepts, we can now define Pareto-optimality of a sharing rule uðsÞ and an action pair ðs; uðsÞÞ. Definition 2. Given an external action s of the supply chain, u ðsÞ is a Paretooptimal sharing rule, if ðu1 ðP1 ðs; u ðsÞÞÞ; ; uN ðPN ðs; u ðsÞÞÞÞ is a Pareto-optimal point of the set fðu1 ðP1 ðs; uðsÞÞÞ; ; uN ðPN ðs; uðsÞÞÞÞ; u 2 Yg; where ui ðPi ðs; uðsÞÞÞ is the payoff of the ith agent. Definition 3. ðs ; u ðs ÞÞ is a Pareto-optimal action pair if the agents’ payoffs ðu1 ðP1 ðs ; u ðs ÞÞÞ; ; uN ðPN ðs ; u ðs ÞÞÞÞ is a Pareto-optimal point of the set fðu1 ðP1 ðs; uðsÞÞÞ; ; uN ðPN ðs; uðsÞÞÞÞ; ðs; uðsÞÞ 2 S Yg: Clearly if ðs ; u ðs ÞÞ is a Pareto-optimal action pair, then u ðs Þ is a Paretooptimal sharing rule given s . We begin now with an examination of the Pareto-optimal set in a supply chain consisting of risk-neutral agents. If an external action maximizes the supply chain’s expected profit, then it is not possible to make one agent get more expected profit without making another agent get less. More specifically, we have the following proposition.
10
X. Gan et al.
Proposition 1. If the agents in a supply chain are all risk neutral, then an action pair ðs; uðsÞÞ is Pareto-optimal if and only if the channel’s external action s maximizes the channel’s expected profit. Proof. The proof follows from the fact that in the risk-neutral case, for each s, X
ui ðPi ðs; uðsÞÞÞ ¼
X
EPi ðs; uðsÞÞ ¼ E
X
Pi ðs; uðsÞÞ ¼ EPðsÞ:
Thus, every ðs ; uðs ÞÞ 2 S Y is Pareto-optimal provided s maximizes EPðs Þ. □ Since agents in a supply chain maximize their respective objectives, the agents’ payoffs might not be Pareto-optimal if their objectives are not aligned properly. In this case, it is possible to improve the chain’s performance, i.e., achieve Paretosuperior payoffs. The agents can enter into an appropriately designed contract, under which their respective optimizing actions leads to a Pareto-superior payoff. In the supply chain management literature, a contract is defined to coordinate a supply chain consisting of risk-neutral agents if their respective optimizing external actions under the contract maximize the chain’s expected profit. Then, according to Proposition 1, a coordinating contract is equivalent to a Pareto-optimal action in the riskneutral case. It is therefore reasonable to use the notion of Pareto-optimality to define supply chain coordination in the general case. Definition 4. Supply Chain Coordination. A contract agreed upon by the agents of a supply chain is said to coordinate the supply chain if the optimizing actions of the agents under the contract 1. Satisfy each agent’s reservation payoff constraint. 2. Lead to an action pair ðs ; u ðs ÞÞ that is Pareto-optimal. Besides Pareto-optimality of a contract, we have introduced the individualrationality or the participation constraints as part of the definition of coordination. The constraints ensure that each agent is willing to participate in the contract by requiring that each gets at least his reservation payoff. It is clear that each agent’s reservation payoff will not be less than his status-quo payoff, which is defined to be his best payoff in the absence of the contract. Thus, we need consider only the subset of Pareto-optimal actions that satisfy these participating constraints. The reservation payoff of an agent plays an important role in bargaining, as we shall see in the next section. Now we illustrate the introduced concept of coordination by an example. Example 4. Consider a supply chain consisting of one supplier and one retailer who faces a newsvendor problem. Before the demand realizes, the supplier decides on his capacity first, and the retailer then prices the product and chooses an order quantity. The supplier and the retailer may enter into a contract that specifies the retailer’s committed order quantity and the supplier’s refund policy for returned items. In this channel, the external actions are the supplier’s capacity selection and the retailer’s pricing and ordering decisions. These are denoted as s. The internal
Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents
11
actions include decision on the quantity of commitment, the refundable quantity, and the refund credit per item. These internal actions together lead to a sharing rule denoted by uðsÞ. Once the contract parameters are determined, the agents in the supply chain choose their respective external actions that maximize their respective payoffs. If ðs; uðsÞÞ satisfies the agents’ reservation payoffs and is Pareto-optimal, then the channel is coordinated by the contract. The definition of coordination proposed here allows agents to have any kind of preference that can be represented by a payoff function satisfying the complete and transitive axioms specified earlier. For example, all of the seven kinds of preferences listed in Schweitzer and Cachon (2000), including risk-seeking preferences, are allowed. Since often in practice, an agent is either risk neutral or risk averse, we restrict our attention to only these two types. Remark 2. Our definition applies also to a T-period case. For this, we define the payoff function of player i as ui ðP1i ðs ; u ðs ÞÞ; P2i ðs ; u ðs ÞÞ; ; PTi ðs ; u ðs ÞÞÞ : GT ! R1 ; where Pti ðs ; u ðs ÞÞ is agent i’s profit in period t.
4 Coordinating Supply Chains Each Pareto-optimal action pair ðs; uðsÞÞ results in a vector of payoffs ðu1 ðP1 ðs; uðsÞÞÞ; ; uN ðPN ðs; uðsÞÞÞÞ; where ui ðPi ðs; uðsÞÞÞ is the payoff of the ith agent. Let C ¼ fðu1 ðP1 ðs; uðsÞÞÞ; ; uN ðPN ðs; uðsÞÞÞÞjðs; uðsÞÞ is Pareto - optimal; ðs; uðsÞÞ 2 S Yg; denote the set of all Pareto-optimal payoffs, and let F C be the subset of Paretooptimal payoffs that satisfy all of the participation constraints. We shall refer to F as Pareto-optimal frontier. We will assume that F is not empty. To coordinate a supply chain, the first step is to obtain the Pareto-optimal frontier F. If F is not a singleton, then agents bargain to arrive at an element in F to which they agree. A coordinating contract is one with a specific set of parameters that achieves the selected solution. A contract is appealing if it has sufficient flexibility. In Cachon (2003), a coordinating contract is said to be flexible if the contract, by adjustment of some parameters, allows for any division of the supply chain’s expected profit among the risk-neutral agents. This concept can be extended to the general case as follows.
12
X. Gan et al.
Definition 5. A coordinating contract is flexible if, by adjustment of some parameters, the contract can lead to any point in F: We shall now develop coordinating contracts in supply chains consisting of two agents: a supplier and a retailer. We shall consider three different cases. In each of these cases, we assume that agents have complete information. In Case 1, the supplier is risk neutral and the retailer has a payoff function in Example 2, i.e., the retailer maximizes his expected profit subject to a downside constraint. In Case 2, the supplier and the retailer are both risk averse and each maximizes his own meanvariance trade-off. In Case 3, the supplier and the retailer are both risk averse and each maximizes his own expected concave utility. We consider the first two cases in this section and the third case in Sect. 5. In each case, let us denote the retailer’s and the supplier’s reservation payoffs as pr r0 and ps r0, respectively. We first obtain F and then design a flexible contract that can lead to any point in F by adjusting the parameters of the contract.
4.1
Case 1: Risk Neutral Supplier and Retailer Averse to Downside Risk
We consider the supplier to be risk neutral and the retailer to maximize his expected profit subject to a downside risk constraint. This downside risk constraint requires that the probability of the retailer’s profit to be higher than a specified level is not too small. The risk neutrality assumption on the part of the supplier is reasonable when he is able to diversify his risk by serving a number of independent retailers, which is quite often the case in practice. When the retailers are independent, the supply chain can be divided into a number of sub-chains, each consisting of one supplier and one retailer. This situation, therefore, could be studied as a supply chain consisting of one risk-neutral supplier and one risk-averse retailer. We say that an action pair ðs; uðsÞÞ is feasible if the pair satisfies the retailer’s downside risk constraint. We do not need to consider a pair ðs; uðsÞÞ that is not feasible since under the pair the retailer’s payoff is 1 and he would not enter the contract. We denote PðsÞ, Pr ðs; uðsÞÞ, and Ps ðs; uðsÞÞ as the profits of the supply chain, the retailer, and the supplier, respectively. Other quantities of interest will be subscripted in the same way throughout the chapter, i.e., subscript r will denote the retailer and subscript s will denote the supplier. Then we have the following result. Theorem 1. If the supplier is risk neutral and the retailer maximizes his expected profit subject to a downside risk constraint, then a feasible action pair ðs; uðsÞÞ is Pareto-optimal if and only if the supply chain’s expected profit is maximized over the feasible set. Proof. ONLY IF: It is sufficient to show that if EPðsÞ is not maximal over the feasible set, then ðs; uðsÞÞ is not Pareto-optimal.
Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents
13
If EPðsÞ is not the maximal channel profit, then there exists an s0 such that EPðs0 Þ>EPðsÞ. Consider the pair ðs0 ; u0 ðs0 ÞÞ in which Pr ðs0 ; u0 ðs0 ÞÞ ¼ Pr ðs; uðsÞÞ and Ps ðs0 ; u0 ðs0 ÞÞ ¼ Pðs0 Þ Pr ðs; uðsÞÞ, we then get ur ðPr ðs0 ; u0 ðs0 ÞÞÞ ¼ EPr ðs; uðsÞ) and us ðPs ðs0 ; u0 ðs0 ÞÞÞ ¼ EPðs0 Þ EPr ðs; uðsÞÞ: We can see that ur ðPr ðs0 ; u0 ðs0 ÞÞÞ ¼ ur ðPr ðs; uðsÞÞ) and us ðPs ðs0 ; u0 ðs0 ÞÞÞ>us ðPs ðs; uðsÞÞÞ: This means that ðs; uðsÞÞ is Pareto-inferior to ðs0 ; u0 ðs0 ÞÞ, which contradicts with the Pareto-optimality of ðs; uðsÞÞ. IF: Suppose the supply chain’s expected profit is maximized. If ðs; uðsÞÞ is not Pareto-optimal, then according to the definition of a Pareto-optimal action pair, there exists a feasible pair ðs00 ; u0 ðs00 ÞÞ that is Pareto-superior to ðs; uÞ. Since it is Paretosuperior to ðs; uðsÞÞ, it is also feasible. Thus, us ðPs ðs00 ; u00 ðs00 ÞÞÞ þ ur ðPr ðs00 ; u0 ðs00 ÞÞÞ ¼ EPðs00 Þ>EPðsÞ ¼ ur ðPr ðs; uðsÞÞÞ þ us ðPs ðs; uðsÞÞÞ; which contradicts the fact that EPðsÞ is the maximal expected channel profit. □ Let s be an action of the channel that maximizes the channel’s expected profit, and let EPr ðs Þ be the retailer’s payoff. Since the retailer’s and the supplier’s reservation payoffs are pr and ps , respectively, we must impose the participating constraints of the agents on the solutions in C. Thus, EPr ðs Þrpr and EPðs Þ EPr ðs Þrps :
(1)
Together with Theorem 1, we get F ¼ fðEPr ðs Þ; EPðs Þ EPr ðs ÞÞjEPðs Þ ps rEPr ðs Þrpr g: Clearly, if EPðs Þ ps rpr , then F is not empty. In Gan et al. (2005), we show that a retailer, who is subject to a downside risk constraint, may order a lower quantity from a supplier than that desired by the channel under a wholesale, buy-back or revenue-sharing contract. Based on an initial contract, a risk-sharing contract is designed, which stipulates the supplier to offer a full refund on unsold items up to a limited quantity. The contract coordinates the supply chain, and requires that both the supplier and the retailer share the risk. Another coordinating contract is possible when EPr ðs Þ exceeds the retailer’s target profit a, where s is the channel’s optimal action. In this case, a contract that provides a payoff of EPr ðs Þ to the retailer and remainder to the supplier coordinates the supply chain. This contract is of two-part tariffs type as defined, for example, in Chopra and Meindl (2001, p. 160). However, if EPr ðs Þ is less than the retailer’s target profit a, then the contract does not work since the downside risk constraint of the retailer is not satisfied. But the risk-sharing contract in
14
X. Gan et al.
Gan et al. (2005) still works, since the retailer’s downside risk constraint P ðXbaÞbb is always satisfied under that contract.
4.2
Case 2: Mean-Variance Suppliers and Retailers
In this case, both the supplier and the retailer maximize their respective meanvariance trade-offs. First we consider a two-agent scenario and then extend it to the case of N agents. Let the retailer’s payoff function be EPr ðs; uðsÞÞ lr VðPr ðs; uðsÞÞÞ;
(2)
and the supplier’s payoff function be EPs ðs; uðsÞÞ ls VðPs ðs; uðsÞÞÞ:
(3)
We first find all Pareto-optimal sharing rules for any given channel’s external action s. We show that regardless of the selected external action s, the optimal sharing rule has the same specific form. Under this form of a sharing rule, we obtain optimal external actions. This procedure results in a Pareto-optimal ðs; uðsÞÞ. We now solve for the Pareto-optimal set for a supply chain consisting of N agents, and then specialize it for supply chains with two agents. We assume that the ith agent’s payoff function is EPi ðs; uðsÞÞ li VðPi ðs; uðsÞÞÞ:
(4)
To obtain Pareto-optimal sharing rules, we solve max u2Y
s.t: X
X
EPi ðs; uðsÞÞ
i
X
li VðPi ðs; uðsÞÞÞ;
(5)
i
Pi ðs; uðsÞÞ ¼ PðsÞ:
(6)
i
The solution of this problem is given in the following proposition. Proposition 2. A sharing rule u is a solution of the problem (5)–(6) if and only if 1=li PðsÞ þ pi ; i ¼ 1; . . . N; Pi ðs; uðsÞÞ ¼ P j 1==lj almost surely, where
P i
pi ¼ 0.
(7)
Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents
Proof. Because
P i
15
EPi ðs; uðsÞÞ ¼ EPðsÞ, the problem is equivalent to X
min u2Y
s.t: X
li VðPi ðs; uðsÞÞÞ;
(8)
i
Pi ðs; uðsÞÞ ¼ PðsÞ:
(9)
i
It is easy to see that X
li VðPi ðs; uðsÞÞÞ
i
¼
X
h i X 2 E PðsÞ PðsÞ P ðs; uðsÞÞ i i j 1=lj
li VðPi ðs; uðsÞÞÞ þ P
i
" # X 1 1=li ¼P VðPðs; uðsÞÞÞ þ li V Pi ðs; uðsÞÞ P PðsÞ : j 1=lj j 1=lj i
(10)
Since the second term on the RHS of (10) is nonnegative, we have shown that X
1 VðPðs; uðsÞÞÞ j 1=lj
li VðPi ðs; uðsÞÞÞr P
i
(11)
for any feasible Pi ðs; uðsÞÞ; i ¼ 1; . . . N. Thus, P 11=l VðPðs; uðsÞÞÞ provides a j
j
lower bound for the objective function (8). Note that a u satisfies (7) if and only if 1=li PðsÞ ¼ 0; i ¼ 1; . . . N: Pi ðs; uðsÞÞ P j 1=lj This means that X
li VðPi ðs; uðsÞÞÞ ¼ P
i
1 VðPðsÞÞ j 1=lj
(12)
and X
1 VðPðsÞÞ j 1=lj
li VðPi ðs; uðsÞÞÞ> P
i
for any u not satisfying (7).
□
16
X. Gan et al.
For any optimal sharing rule u given in Proposition 2, the sum of the agents’ payoffs equals 1 VðPðsÞÞ: j 1=lj
EPðsÞ P
By adjusting p0 , the sharing rule u allows for any division of the total payoff among the agents. Therefore, an optimal external action, given u , has to maximize the total payoff, i.e., it must be an action pair of "
# 1 VðPðsÞÞ : max EPðsÞ P s2S j 1=lj
(13)
Next we characterize the set of Pareto-optimal actions by summarizing the results we have got. Theorem 2. An action pair ðs ; u Þ is Pareto-optimal if and only if "
#
1 VðPðsÞÞ s ¼ arg max EPðsÞ P s2S j 1=lj
(14)
1=li PðsÞ þ pi ; i ¼ 1; . . . N; Pi ðs; u ðsÞÞ ¼ P j 1=lj
(15)
and
almost surely. Clearly, if a contract can allocate the channel profit among the N agents proportionally, then the contract along with a side payment scheme can coordinate the supply chain. Moreover, this contract is flexible by adjusting the amounts of side payment. Theorem 3, as a special result of Theorem 2, characterizes the set of Paretooptimal actions for supply chains consisting of one supplier and one retailer. Theorem 3. An action pair ðs ; u ðs ÞÞ is Pareto-optimal if and only if lr ls s ¼ arg max EPðsÞ VðPðsÞÞ s2S lr þ ls
(16)
and Pr ðs ; u ðs ÞÞ ¼
ls Pðs Þ þ p0 ; lr þ ls
(17)
Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents
Ps ðs ; u ðs ÞÞ ¼
lr Pðs Þ p0 ; lr þ ls
17
(18)
almost surely. It follows from Theorem 3 that under any Pareto-optimal solution, the retailer gets a fixed proportion ls =ðlr þ ls Þ of the channel profit plus p0 and the supplier gets the remaining profit, i.e., lr =ðlr þ ls Þ of the channel profit minus p0 . If lr >ls , i.e., the retailer is more risk-averse than the supplier, then the supplier takes a greater proportion of the channel profit. In other words, the agent with a lower risk aversion takes a higher proportion of the total channel profit than the other one does. The side payment, which is determined by the respective bargaining powers of the agents, determines the agents’ final payoffs. According to Theorem 3, C¼
ls lr 1 uðs Þ þ p0 ; uðs Þ p0 jp0 2 R ; lr þ l s lr þ l s
where uðs Þ represents EPðs Þ lVðPðs ÞÞ: Since the retailer’s and the supplier’s reservation payoffs are pr and ps , respectively, p0 has to satisfy the participating constraints of the agents. Thus, ls lr uðs Þ þ p0 rpr and uðs Þ p0 rps : lr þ ls lr þ l s Then F can be represented by
lr ls lr ls uðs Þ þ p0 ; uðs Þ p0
uðs Þ ps rp0 rpr uðs Þ : l r þ ls lr þ l s lr þ l s l r þ ls
Furthermore, if lr ls uðs Þ ps rpr uðs Þ; lr þ ls lr þ l s i.e., if pr þ ps buðs Þ; then F is not empty. The problem considered thus far is quite general, in the sense that the external action s is rather an abstract one that can include such decisions as order quantity, item price, etc. We next consider a special case. Here the retailer faces a newsvendor problem and makes a single purchase order of a product from the supplier at the beginning of a period, who in turn produces and delivers the order to the retailer before the selling season commences. Let p denote the price per unit,
18
X. Gan et al.
c the supplier’s production cost, v the salvage value, and q the retailer’s order quantity. In this problem, the supply chain’s external action is the retailer’s order quantity q. According to Theorem 3, the coordinating contract should allocate the profit in the same proportion for every realization of the channel profit in the absence of any side payment. We shall call such a sharing rule a proportional sharing rule. Here we only examine buy-back and revenue-sharing contracts. With a buy-back contract, the supplier charges the retailer a wholesale price per unit, but he pays the retailer a credit for every unsold unit at the end of the season. With a revenuesharing contract, the supplier charges a wholesale price per unit purchased, and the retailer gives the supplier a percentage of his revenue. See Pasternack (1985) and Cachon and Lariviere (2005) for details on these contracts. In the following, we see that both buy-back and revenue-sharing contracts allocate the channel profit proportionally. Proposition 3. A revenue-sharing contract allocates the channel profit (a random variable) proportionally. If w ¼ fc;
(19)
the retailer’s share is f and the supplier’s share is 1 f. Proof. Let D denote the demand faced by the retailer. Then the supply chain’s profit is
pD þ ðq DÞv cq pq cq;
if Dbq; if D>q:
(20)
On the other hand, the retailer’s profit is
fpD þ fðq DÞv wq if Dbq; fpq wq; if D>q:
(21)
By using w ¼ fc into (21), we can see that the retailer gets the proportion f of the supply chain’s profit for every realization of the demand. □ Cachon and Lariviere (2005) prove that for each coordinating revenue-sharing contract, there exists a unique buy-back contract that provides the same profit as in the revenue-sharing contract for every demand realization. They show that the buyback contract’s parameters have the form b ¼ ð1 fÞðp vÞ;
(22)
w ¼ pð1 fÞ þ fc;
(23)
where b is the refund to the retailer for each unsold unit, and f is the retailer’s share of the channel profit in the revenue-sharing contract. It is easy to see that the same result holds here as well.
Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents
19
Proposition 4. A buy-back contract allocates the channel profit (a random variable) proportionally. If the contract parameters satisfy (22) and (23), then the retailer’s fractional share is f and the supplier’s is 1 f under this contract. Nagarajan and Bassok (2008) obtain the Nash Bargaining solution in the riskneutral case. According to their results, if both the retailer and the supplier are risk neutral, the retailer’s share of profit is fPðsÞ ¼ ½PðsÞ ps þ pr =2:
(24)
Under a buy-back or a revenue-sharing contract, the retailer’s problem is max p0 þ s2S
ls ½EPðsÞ lV ðPðsÞÞ: lr þ l s
(25)
For a given p0 , the retailer’s problem (25) becomes max EPðsÞ lVðPðsÞÞ; s2S
(26)
which has been solved by Lau (1980) and Chen and Federgruen (2000). Since the solution is s , the retailer would choose the optimal external action voluntarily. So we can state the following two theorems. Theorem 4. If the parameters of a revenue-sharing contract satisfy w¼
ls c; lr þ l s
(27)
then the revenue-sharing contract along with a side payment p0 to the retailer coordinates the supply chain. The profit allocation is given in (17)–(18). Theorem 5. If the parameters of a buy-back contract satisfy b¼ w¼p
lr ðp vÞ; lr þ ls
lr ls þ c; lr þ ls lr þ ls
(28)
(29)
then the buy-back contract along with a side payment p0 to the retailer coordinates the supply chain. The profit allocation is given in (17)–(18). Note that by adjusting the side payment p0 , the revenue-sharing as well as the buy-back contract can lead to any point in F. Thus, both contracts are flexible. The contracts obtained in Theorems 5 and 4, when lr ¼ ls ¼ 0, reduce to the standard contracts obtained in the risk-neutral case, because the fraction lr =ðlr þ ls Þ can take any value in ½0; 1. In particular, if the supplier is risk neutral and the retailer is risk averse, i.e., ls ¼ 0, the fraction lr =ðlr þ ls Þ ¼ 1, which
20
X. Gan et al.
means that the supplier takes the entire channel profit and gives a side payment to the retailer. In this case, it is Pareto-optimal for the supplier to bear all of the risk. Since the retailer’s profit is a side payment from the supplier, the supplier’s expected profit is the channel’s profit minus that payment. Therefore, the supplier’s payoff is maximized when the channel’s expected profit is maximized. Thus, we have a coordinating contract under which the supplier and the retailer execute s , the retailer gets a constant profit p0 , and the supplier gets the remaining profit. In the following example, we design a coordinating contract according to Theorem 5. We also obtain the optimal ordering quantity and determine the required side payment. Example 5. Consider a supply chain consisting of one retailer and one supplier. The retailer faces a newsvendor problem and makes a single purchase order of a product from the supplier at the beginning of a period, who in turn produces and delivers the order to the retailer before the selling season. Suppose that the demand D is uniformly distributed on some interval, which without loss of generality, can be taken as interval [0,1]. Thus, the distribution function FðxÞ ¼ x for 0bxb1 and FðxÞ ¼ 1 for xr1. We confine the ordering quantity q to be in [0,1]. Let the unit price p be 100, the supplier’s production cost c be 60, and the salvage value v be 20. Let the retailer’s and the supplier’s payoff functions be, respectively, EPr lr VðPr Þ and EPs ls VðPs Þ;
(30)
where lr ¼ 0:05 and ls ¼ 0:01. We assume that the agents have equal bargaining powers in the sense that their payoffs are equal. According to Theorem 3, the retailer’s payoff is ls lr ls EPðqÞ VðPðqÞÞ þ p0 ; lr þ ls lr þ ls
(31)
where PðqÞ is the channel’s profit when the retailer’s ordering quantity is q, 0bqb1. Thus, the retailer’s optimal order quantity is a q that maximizes (31). From Chen and Federgruen (2000), we have EPðqÞ ¼ 40q 80q2 and VðPðqÞÞ ¼ 6400ðq3 =3 q4 =4Þ:
(32)
With this, the retailer’s problem is 160 3 40 4 q þ q ; max 40q 80q2 0b qb 1 9 3
(33)
and q ¼ 0:236. According to Theorem 5, the retailer’s and the supplier’s payoffs are 0:799 þ p0 and 3:99 p0 , respectively. It is easy to see that p0 ¼ 1:598 equalizes their payoffs, as has been assumed.
Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents
21
5 Coordinating a Supply Chain Consisting of Agents with Concave Utility Functions In this case, we assume that agent i has an increasing concave utility function gi ðÞ of his profit, and wants to maximize his expected utility, i ¼ r; s. Then his payoff function is E½gi ðÞ . To compute the set of Pareto-optimal actions, we first find the Pareto-optimal sharing rules given an external action s. According to the group decision theory literature (Wilson 1968; Raiffa 1970), the problem can be formulated as follows: max ar Egr ðPr ðs; uðsÞÞÞ þ as Egs ðPs ðs; uðsÞÞÞ;
(34)
s.t: Pr ðs; uðsÞÞ þ Ps ðs; uðsÞÞ ¼ PðsÞ;
(35)
u2Y
where ar ; as >0, ar þ as ¼ 1. The specification of ðar ; as Þ is derived from their respective bargaining powers. By varying ar and as , we can get all possible Pareto-optimal sharing rules Cs , denoted as fður ðPr ðs; uðsÞÞÞ; us ðPs ðs; uðsÞÞÞÞju is Pareto - optimal; u 2 Yg:
(36)
Clearly, each point in Cs represents, given s, the agents’ payoffs under a Paretooptimal sharing rule. Then we can get C, which is the set of Pareto-optimal points S of the set s2S Cs . According to Definition 3, any action pair that leads to a point in C is Pareto-optimal. It is well known that the problem of maximizing the expected quadratic utility can be reduced to one of maximizing a mean-variance trade-off. Therefore, when both agents’ utility functions are quadratic, we can coordinate the channel with the contracts developed in Sect. 4.2. Levi and Markowitz (1979) show that a utility function exhibiting constant risk aversion, particularly of the form log x or xa ; 0
5.1
Characterizing the Pareto-Optimal Set
Let the retailer’s and the supplier’s utility functions be, respectively,
22
X. Gan et al.
gr ðxÞ ¼ 1 elr x and gs ðxÞ ¼ 1 els x :
(37)
Then the absolute risk aversion measure for the retailer and the supplier are lr and ls , respectively; see Pratt (1964). We want to find a Pareto-optimal sharing rule for any given channel’s external action s. Raiffa (1970) solves the problem (34)–(35), which implies the following result. Proposition 5. For a given external action s for the channel under consideration, a sharing rule u ðsÞ is a Pareto-optimal sharing rule if and only if Pr ðs; u ðsÞÞ ¼
ls as ls PðsÞ l ln ; lr þ ls ar lr
(38)
Ps ðs; u ðsÞÞ ¼
lr as ls PðsÞ þ l ln ; lr þ ls ar lr
(39)
1 almost surely, where ar ; as >0, ar þ as ¼ 1, and l ¼ lr þl . s Thus we can get
Cs ¼ fður ðPr ðs; u ðsÞÞÞ; us ðPs ðs; u ðsÞÞÞÞjar ; as >0; ar þ as ¼ 1g; where lr as ls lr ls PðsÞ E exp ; ln ur ðPr ðs; u ðsÞÞÞ ¼ 1 exp lr þ ls ar lr lr þ ls
ls ar ls lr ls PðsÞ us ðPs ðs; u ðsÞÞÞ ¼ 1 exp ln E exp : lr þ ls as lr lr þ ls
(40)
(41)
Since both the retailer and the supplier’s payoff functions decrease with lr ls PðsÞ ; E exp lr þ ls it is easy to check that C ¼ fður ðPr ðs ; u ÞÞ; us ðPs ðs; u ÞÞÞjar ; as >0; ar þ as ¼ 1g;
(42)
where s is the solution of the problem lr ls PðsÞ : min E exp s2S l r þ ls
(43)
Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents
23
Now the supply chain’s external problem has been transformed to problem (43). This problem has been studied in the literature in some special situations. Bouakiz and Sobel (1992) have shown that a base-stock policy is optimal in a multi-period newsvendor problem, when the newsvendor has an exponential utility function. Eeckhoudt et al. (1995) discuss the situation in which the entity faces a newsvendor problem, and they prove that the newsvendor orders less than that in the risk-neutral case. Agrawal and Seshadri (2000a) consider the entity’s price and inventory decision jointly in a newsvendor framework. Remark 3. Although we have got proportional sharing rules for the above case and the second case in Sect. 4, the Pareto-optimal sharing rules usually are not proportional for any two utility functions (Raiffa 1970). Moreover, the Pareto-sharing rules may depend on the channel’s external action. See Wilson (1968), Raiffa (1970), and LaValle (1978) for further details on Pareto-optimal sharing rules. Now we summarize the results in the following theorem. Theorem 6. An action pair ðs ; u ðs ÞÞ is Pareto-optimal if and only if lr ls PðsÞ ; s ¼ arg minE exp s2S lr þ ls
(44)
Pr ðs ; u ðs ÞÞ ¼
ls as ls Pðs Þ l ln ; lr þ ls ar lr
(45)
Ps ðs ; u ðs ÞÞ ¼
lr as ls Pðs Þ þ l ln ; lr þ ls ar lr
(46)
almost surely, where ar ; as >0, ar þ as ¼ 1. It follows from Theorem 6 that under any Pareto-optimal solution, the retailer and the supplier get fixed proportions of channel profit minus/plus a side payment. If lr >ls , i.e., if the retailer is more risk averse than the supplier, then the supplier takes a greater proportion of the channel profit if we ignore the side payment.
5.2
Bargaining Issue
We have got Pareto-optimal payoffs set C in (42). Since ur <1 and us <1 from (40) and (41), we assume that pr <1 and ps <1. Participating constraints of the agents are ur ðPr ðs ; u ðs ÞÞÞrpr and us ðPr ðs ; u ðs ÞÞÞrps :
(47)
Conditions (47) are equivalent to
lr lr ls Pðs Þ as ls lr þls l l Pðs Þ ð1 pr Þ=E exp =ð1 ps Þ: r rE exp r s ar lr lr þ ls lr þ ls (48)
24
X. Gan et al.
Then F can be represented by fður ðPr ðs ;u ðs ÞÞÞ;us ðPs ðs ;u ðs ÞÞÞÞjar ;as >0;ar þ as ¼ 1; and ð48Þ is satisfied:g: (49)
Pðs Þ If ð1 pr Þ=E exp lrllrsþl s
Pðs Þ =ð1 ps Þ, i.e., if rE exp lrllrsþl s
ð1 pr Þð1 ps Þr
lr ls Pðs Þ 2 E exp ; lr þ ls
then F is not empty. Nagarajan and Bassok (2008) use Nash Bargaining concept to deal with bargaining issue in the risk-neutral case. Here we use the same concept to deal with the bargaining issue in a risk-averse case. The approach of Nash (1950) requires that a bargaining solution satisfy the following eight axioms. 1. An agent offered two possible anticipations can decide which is preferable or that they are equally desirable. 2. The ordering thus produced is transitive; if A is better than B and B is better than C then A is better than C. 3. Any probability combination of equally desirable states is just as desirable as either. 4. If A, B, and C, are as in Axiom 2, then there is a probability combination of A and C which is just as desirable as B. This amounts to an assumption of continuity. 5. If 0bpb1 and A and B are equally desirable, then pA þ ð1 pÞC and pB þ ð1 pÞC are equally desirable. Also, A may be substituted for B in any desirability ordering relationship satisfied by B. 6. Let S, which is compact and convex, be the agents’ payoffs set and let cðSÞ denote the bargaining solution point in this set. If a is a point in S such that there exists another point b in S with the property ur ðbÞ>ur ðaÞ and us ðbÞ>us ðaÞ, then a2 = cðSÞ. 7. If the set T contains the set S and cðTÞ is in S, then cðTÞ ¼ cðSÞ: 8. If S is symmetrical with respect to the line ur ¼ us , and ur and us display this, then cðSÞ is a point on the line ur ¼ us . Clearly, exponential utilities in (37) satisfy the first five axioms. The agents’ payoff set S is fður ðPr ðs; uðsÞÞÞ; us ðPs ðs; uðsÞÞÞÞjðs; uðsÞÞ 2 S Yg: We assume that PðsÞ be continuous in s, so that S is compact. Now we prove the convexity of S by showing that its frontier is a concave curve. The Pareto-frontier of this set is given in (49), where
Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents
25
lr as ls lr ls Pðs Þ E exp ; ur ðPr ðs ; u ðs ÞÞÞ ¼ 1 exp ln lr þ ls ar lr lr þ ls
us ðPs ðs ; u ðs ÞÞÞ ¼ 1 exp
ls ar lr lr ls Pðs Þ E exp : ln lr þ ls as ls lr þ ls
(50)
(51)
From (50) and (51), lr þls lr
ð1 u r Þ
ð1 us Þ
lr þls ls
¼
lr ls Pðs Þ E exp lr þ ls
ðlr þls Þ2 =ðlr ls Þ3
:
(52)
Clearly, the curve represented by (52) is concave since the right side is a constant. Axiom 6 assures that the solution is Pareto-optimal, Axiom 8 expresses the equality of bargaining skills. Nash (1950) shows that the solution point is the point that is the solution of the problem max ður pr Þðus ps Þ:
(53)
ður ;us Þ2S
Since the solution has to be Pareto-optimal, (53) is equivalent to max ður pr Þðus ps Þ:
(54)
ður ;us Þ2F
Pðs Þ : Then, Now we solve the problem (54). Let EðuÞ represent E exp lrllrsþl s ður pr Þðus ps Þ ¼ ð1 pr Þð1 ps Þ þ ½EðuÞ2 " # ls lr as ls lr þls as ls lr þls ð 1 pr Þ EðuÞ þ ð1 ps Þ EðuÞ : ar lr ar l r Thus, problem (54) is equivalent to min ð1 pr Þ a1 ;a2
as ls ar lr
llþls r
s
EðuÞ þ ð1 ps Þ
as ls ar lr
l lþlr r
s
EðuÞ:
(55)
Thus, when as ls ð1 pr Þls ¼ ; ar lr ð1 ps Þlr
(56)
26
X. Gan et al.
ður pr Þðus ps Þ is maximized. Therefore, the Nash Bargaining solution is represented by the payoffs given in (50) and (51) with parameters ar; as that satisfy ar >0; as >0, ar þ as ¼ 1; and (56). From (56), we can see that as ls =ar lr decreases in the retailer’s reservation payoff pr and increases in the supplier’s reservation payoff ps . Thus, the retailer’s payoff increases in pr and decreases in ps . The same property holds for the supplier. These properties imply that in the Nash Bargaining solution, each agent’s payoff increases with his own reservation payoff and decreases with the other agent’s reservation payoff. When pr ¼ ps , l lnðas ls =ar lr Þ ¼ 0, the side payment disappears. Finally, we can see that the Nash bargaining solution assigns a player a higher payoff when the other player becomes more risk averse.
5.3
Designing a Coordinating Contract
For the special supply chain considered in Sect. 4.2, we can use either a buy-back or a revenue-sharing contract to allocate the channel profit. Under either of these contracts, the retailer’s problem is: lr ls PðsÞ max 1 E exp : s2S lr þ ls This problem is equivalent to problem (43), which implies that the retailer would voluntarily choose the optimal external action s . So we have the following two results. Theorem 7. If the parameters of a buy-back contract satisfy b¼ w¼p
lr ðp vÞ; lr þ ls
lr ls þ c; lr þ ls lr þ ls
then the buy-back contract along with the side payment l lnðas ls =ar lr Þ to the supplier coordinates the supply chain. The profit allocation is given in (45)–(46). Theorem 8. If the parameters of a revenue-sharing contract satisfy w¼
ls c; lr þ l s
then the revenue-sharing contract along with the side payment l lnðas ls =ar lr Þ to the supplier coordinates the supply chain. The profit allocation is given in (45)–(46).
Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents
27
Note that if ar and as satisfy condition (56), then both the revenue-sharing and the buy-back contracts achieve the Nash Bargaining solution. By adjusting the bargaining coefficients ar and as , one can attain any point in F. Thus, both these contracts are flexible. We should note that in general, Pareto-optimal sharing rules are not proportional as in the case with exponential utility functions. Wilson (1968) provides a necessary and sufficient condition for Pareto-optimality of a sharing rule in a channel with N agents. The condition is stated in the following theorem. Theorem 9. Given an external action s, a necessary and sufficient condition for Pareto-optimality of a sharing rule is that there exists nonnegative weights a ¼ ða1 ; a2 ; . . . ; aN Þ and a function m : R1 ! R1 ; such that X
Pi ðs; uðsÞÞ ¼ PðsÞ;
(57)
i
almost surely, and for each i ai g0i ðPi ðs; uðsÞÞÞ ¼ mðPðsÞÞ;
(58)
almost surely. In what follows, we give an example in which the sharing rule is not of the form of (45)–(46). Here we see that the Pareto-optimal sharing rule depends on the realized channel profit, i.e., it depends on the chosen external action as well as the realized random event. Example 6. Let gr ðxÞ ¼ 1 elr x ; gs ðxÞ ¼
1 els x ; xbx0 ; 1 ex0 ls þ l1s ex0 ls ðx x0 Þ; x>x0 :
(59) (60)
In this example, the retailer’s utility function is the same as in (37), but the supplier’s utility is changed in a way that his risk attitude is the same as in (37) at low profit levels and he is risk neutral at higher profit levels. Proposition 6. For a given external action s for the channel under consideration, a sharing rule u is a Pareto-optimal sharing rule if and only if as ls s PðsÞ l ln aars llsr ; PðsÞb lrlþl x l ln 0 ar lr r ; Pr ðs; u ðsÞÞ ¼ lr þls as ls : ls x0 l ln as ls ; PðsÞ> x l ln 0 lr ar lr lr ar lr 8 <
Ps ðs; u ðsÞÞ ¼
8 <
ls lr þls
lr lr þls PðsÞ
þ l ln aars llsr ;
: PðsÞ ls x0 þ l ln as ls ; lr
ar lr
as ls s PðsÞb lrlþl x l ln 0 ar lr r ; lr þls PðsÞ> lr x0 l ln aars llsr
(61)
(62)
28
X. Gan et al.
Fig. 1 Example of a Paretooptimal frontier
u2 Pareto-optimal Frontier
Ψs5 Ψs4
Ψs3
r2
Ψs1
Ψs2
r1
u1
1 almost surely, where ar ; as >0, ar þ as ¼ 1, and l ¼ lr þl . s Proof. Let
8 lr þls as ls < ðar lr Þlls ðas ls Þllr exp lr ls t ; t b x l ln 0 lr ar lr ; h lr þl s i mðtÞ ¼ : ðar lr Þlls ðas ls Þllr exp ls x0 l ln as ls ; t> lr þls x0 l ln as ls : ar lr lr ar lr Then, according to Theorem 9, (61) and (62) are Pareto-optimal since conditions (57) and (58) are satisfied. □ We can see that under the Pareto-optimal sharing rule, the retailer’s profit increases linearly with the channel’s realized profit when the latter is below a certain level, and remains unchanged thereafter. This is not a proportional sharing rule, and consequently, neither a buy-back nor a revenue-sharing contract along with side payments would coordinate the channel. It appears that new contract forms need to be designed to achieve coordination in such cases. In order to obtain s , we outline the following procedure. First, we compute Cs for each S s 2 S according to (36), and then we find the Pareto-optimal frontier of the set s2S Cs . Any action pair ðs ; u ðs ÞÞ that leads to a point on this frontier is Pareto-optimal. Note that s may not be unique. To illustrate this procedure, let us assume S ¼ fs1 ; s2 ; s3 ; s4 ; s5 g for convenience in exposition. Suppose that the sets Cs for s 2 S are as shown in Fig. 1. Then the frontier consisting of Pareto-optimal solutions is shown as the bold-faced boundary in the figure. Construction of such a frontier in general would require development of numerical procedures. This is not the focus of this chapter, and it is a topic for future research.
6 Discussion One of our main findings is that in any Pareto-optimal joint action, the retailer and the supplier must share the risk appropriately. Specifically, the less risk averse an agent is, the more risk he assumes by taking a larger portion of the channel’s
Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents
29
random profit. The agents’ final payoffs can be adjusted by a side payment depending on their respective bargaining powers. In the extreme case when one of the agents is risk neutral, then that agent may assume all of the risk. Owing to the risk-sharing effect, the supply chain, when considered as a single entity, is less risk averse than either the risk-averse retailer or the risk-averse supplier if considered as the single owner of the whole channel. For example, in Case 2, the channel’s problem according to (25) is equivalent to solving the problem max ½EðPðsÞÞ lVðPðsÞÞ: s2S
If the retailer or the supplier were to own the channel, he would solve the problem max ½EPðsÞ lr VðPðsÞÞ or max ½EPðsÞ ls VðPðsÞÞ: s2S
s2S
Since l
N X i¼1
ai ui ðPðsÞÞ; ai 2 ½0; 1;
N X
ai ¼ 1;
i¼1
where the agent i’s utility function is denoted as ui ðPðsÞÞ; i ¼ 1; 2; . . . N. In this case, each agent’s identity is not preserved and the critical issue is how to determine the weights ai ; i ¼ 1; 2; . . . N. Once the optimal action for the supply chain is obtained by maximizing uðPðsÞÞ; the profit could be allocated according to some weighting scheme, possibly different from ai ; i ¼ 1; 2; . . . N: It is clear that this method generalizes the risk-neutral case. However, we do not follow this method because it does not guarantee Pareto-optimality of the final outcome.
30
X. Gan et al.
7 Conclusion and Further Research We have proposed a definition of coordination of a supply chain consisting of riskaverse agents. We show that to coordinate such a chain, the first step is to characterize the set of Pareto-optimal solutions and select a solution from this set based on the agents’ respective bargaining powers. The second step is to design a contract to achieve the selected solution. In the risk-neutral case, it is easy to see that an action pair is Pareto-optimal if and only if the supply chain’s expected profit is maximized. But in the risk-averse case, it is more difficult to find Pareto-optimal actions. We characterize Paretooptimal solutions in three specific cases of a supply chain involving one supplier and one retailer, and in each case we design a flexible contract to coordinate the channel. Furthermore, we discuss the bargaining issue in one of the cases. We provide answers to the following questions: What is the optimal external action of the supply chain and what is the optimal sharing rule? In the specific cases that we have considered, we are able to obtain Paretooptimal actions by first obtaining a Pareto-optimal sharing rule that can be used with any external action. This property allows us to obtain an objective function for the supply chain, whose optimization yields an external action, which together with the sharing rule provides us with Pareto-optimal solutions. In more general cases, however, we do not have the above property, and therefore, the sequential procedure used in the special cases does not work. In such cases, we show by a specially constructed example, that obtaining Paretooptimal solutions requires finding first the Pareto-optimal sets corresponding to external actions, and then identifying the Pareto-optimal frontier of the union of these sets. Moreover, the standard contract forms that work for risk-neutral cases do no longer coordinate, and research is required to find new coordinating contract forms.
References Agrawal V, Seshadri S (2000a) Impact of uncertainty and risk aversion on price and order quantity in the newsvendor problem. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 4:410–423 Agrawal V, Seshadri S (2000b) Risk intermediation in supply chains. IIE Trans 32:819–831 Arrow KJ (1951) Social choice and individual values. Wiley, New York Bouakiz M, Sobel MJ (1992) Inventory control with an expected utility criterion. Oper Res 40:603–608 Buzacott J, Yan H, Zhang H (2002) Optimality criteria and risk analysis in inventory models with demand forecast updating. Working paper, The Chinese University of Hong Kong, Shatin Cachon GP (2003) Supply coordination with contracts. In: Kok T, Graves S (eds) Handbooks in operations research and management science. North-Holland, Amsterdam Cachon GP, Lariviere M (2005) Supply chain coordination with revenue-sharing contracts: strengths and limitations. Manage Sci 51:30–44
Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents
31
Chen F, Federgruen A (2000) Mean-variance analysis of basic inventory models. Working paper, Columbia University, New York Chen X, Sim M, Simchi-Levi D, Sun P (2007) Risk aversion in inventory management. Oper Res 55:828–842 Chopra S, Meindl P (2001) Supply chain management. Prentice-Hall, New Jersey, NJ Eeckhoudt L, Gollier C, Schlesinger H (1995) The risk averse (and prudent) newsboy. Manage Sci 41:786–794 Eliashberg J, Winkler RL (1981) Risk sharing and group decision making. Manage Sci 27:1221–1535 Gan X, Sethi SP, Yan H (2005) Coordination of a supply chain with a risk-averse retailer and a risk-neutral supplier. Prod Oper Manage 14:80–89 Gaur V, Seshadri S (2005) Hedging inventory risk through market instruments. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 7(2):103–120 Harsanyi JC (1955) Cardinal welfare, individualistic ethics, and interpersonal comparisons of utility. J Polit Econ 63:309–321 Jorion P (2006) Value at risk. McGraw-Hill, New York, NY Lau HS (1980) The newsboy problem under alternative optimization objectives. J Oper Res Soc 31:393–403 Lau HS, Lau AHL (1999) Manufacturer’s pricing strategy and return policy for a single-period commodity. Eur J Oper Res 116:291–304 Lavalle IH (1978) Fundamentals of decision analysis. Holt, Rinehart, and Winston, New York Levi H, Markowitz H (1979) Approximating expected utility by a function of mean and variance. Am Econ Rev 69:308–317 Markowitz H (1959) Portfolio selection: efficient diversification of investment. Cowles foundation monograph 16, Yale University Press, New Haven, CT Nagarajan M, Bassok Y (2008) A bargaining framework in supply chains: the assembly problem. Manage Sci 54:1482–1496 Nash JF (1950) The bargaining problem. Econometrica 18:155–162 Pasternack BA (1985) Optimal pricing and returns policies for perishable commodities. Mark Sci 4:166–176 Pratt WJ (1964) Risk aversion in the small and in the large. Econometrica 32:122–136 Raiffa H (1970) Decision analysis. Addison-Wesley, Reading, MA Schweitzer ME, Cachon GP (2000) Decision bias in the newsvendor problem with a known demand distribution: experimental evidence. Manage Sci 46:404–420 Szeg€o G (ed) (2004) New risk measures for the 21st century. Wiley, West Sussex Tayur S, Ganeshan R, Magazine M (eds) (1999) Quantitative models for supply chain management. Kluwer, Boston, MA Tsay A (2002) Risk sensitivity in distribution channel partnerships: implications for manufacturer return policies. J Retailing 78:147–160 Van Mieghem JA (2003) Capacity management, investment, and hedging: review and recent developments. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 5:269–302 Van Neumann J, Morgenstern O (1944) Theory of games and economic behavior. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ Wilson R (1968) The theory of syndicates. Econometrica 18:155–162
.
Addendum to “Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents” by Gan, Sethi, and Yan (2004) Xianghua Gan, Suresh P. Sethi, and Houmin Yan
Abstract In “Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents” (POMS, Volume 13, 2004), we study the issue of coordination in supply chains involving risk-averse agents, and define a coordinating contract as one that results in a Paretooptimal solution acceptable to each agent. We then develop coordinating contracts in various cases. In the case where the supplier and the retailer each maximizes his own expected utility, we also show that our contract yields the Nash Bargaining solution. In this addendum, we first review some related works that have appeared since the publication of the paper, and then discuss directions for future research. Keywords Supply chain management • Risk aversion • Pareto-optimality • Coordination • Nash bargaining
1 Introduction In Gan et al. (2004), we study the issue of coordination in supply chains involving risk-averse agents, and define a coordinating contract as one that results in a Paretooptimal solution acceptable to each agent. We develop coordinating contracts in three specific cases (1) the supplier is risk neutral and the retailer maximizes his expected profit subject to a downside risk constraint, (2) the supplier and the retailer
X. Gan (*) Department of Logistics and Maritime Studies, The Hong Kong Polytechnic University, Hung Hom, Kowloon, Hong Kong S.P. Sethi School of Management, SM30, The University of Texas at Dallas, 800W. Campbell Road, Richardson, TX 75080-3021, USA H. Yan Department of Systems Engineering and Engineering Management, The Chinese University of Hong Kong, Shatin, N.T., Hong Kong T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_2, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
33
34
X. Gan et al.
each maximizes his own mean-variance trade-off, and (3) the supplier and the retailer each maximizes his own expected utility. Moreover, in case (3) we show that our contract yields the Nash Bargaining solution. In each case, we demonstrate how to find the set of Pareto-optimal solutions, and then design a contract to achieve the solutions. We also exhibit a case in which we obtain Pareto-optimal sharing rules explicitly, and outline a procedure to obtain Pareto-optimal solutions. Gan et al. (2004) was published in Productions and Operations Management and won the Wickham-Skinner Best Paper Award at the Production and Operations Management Society Cancun meeting in 2004. This paper and Gan et al. (2005) are identified as part of a knowledge cluster by means of factor analysis in the paper entitled “The evolution of the intellectual structure of operations management1980–2006: A citation/co-citation analysis” by Pilkington and Meredith (2009). Specifically, the clusters in the general knowledge structure in the 2000s appear on Fig 7 on p.196 of their paper.
2 Related Literature since the Publication of Gan et al. (2004) Since the publication of Gan et al. (2004), there has been a considerable amount of literature devoted to contracts that coordinate supply chains involving risk-averse agents. Some papers study coordination of supply chains with agents who maximize their own mean-variance objectives, for example, Choi et al. (2008) and Wei and Choi (2010). Some papers study management of disruption risk faced by supply chains, for example, Tomlin (2006) and Bakshi and Kleindorfer (2009). Chen and Seshadri (2006) use optimal control theory to show that the contract menu proposed in Agrawal and Seshadri (2000) is optimal. Shi and Chen (2007) focus on Pareto€ u et al. (2007) study optimal contracts for supply chains with risk-averse agents. Ulk€ the optimal allocation of risk between two agents in a supply chain. Sobel and Turcic (2008) employ the Nash bargaining solution to determine the value of an opportunity to negotiate a contract in an archetypal supply chain game. Another stream of literature focuses on inventory management for risk-averse agents. Some papers incorporate financial instruments into inventory management, for example, Gaur and Seshadri (2005), Martı´nez-de-Albe´niz and Simchi-Levi (2005), and Chen et al. (2008). Choi et al. (2009) study a multi-product newsvendor under lawinvariant coherent risk measures. In the following, we limit our review to papers that focus on supply chain coordination. Gan et al. (2005) examine coordinating contracts for a supply chain consisting of one risk-neutral supplier and one risk-averse retailer. They design an easy-toimplement risk-sharing contract that accomplishes the coordination as defined in Gan et al. (2004). Martı´nez-de-Albe´niz and Simchi-Levi (2005) develop a framework that provides buyers with the ability to select multiple contracts at the same time in order to optimize their expected profit. For this purpose, they define a new type of contract, called a portfolio contract, which is in fact a combination of many
Addendum to “Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents”
35
traditional contracts, such as long-term, option, and flexibility contracts. Then they specialize the model to the case of a portfolio consisting of option contracts, and show that a modified base-stock policy is optimal. Chen and Seshadri (2006) revisit the problem in Agrawal and Seshadri (2000), and use optimal control theory to prove that the contract menu proposed in that paper is optimal. They also show that the menu is optimal among nearly all contracts. Shi and Chen (2007) study a supply chain with two agents, each maximizing his own probability of achieving a predetermined target profit. They investigate two types of contracts: linear tariff contracts and buy-back contracts. They first identify the Pareto-optimal contract(s) for each type, and then evaluate the performance of those contracts. They also show that in some cases, a wholesale price contract can coordinate the supply chain whereas a buy-back contract cannot. € u et al. (2007) consider a supply chain with a contract manufacturer (CM) Ulk€ and a number of original equipment manufacturers (OEMs). Since investment into productive resources is made before demand realization, the supply chain faces the € u et al. (2007) investigate two scenarios in risk of under- or over-investment. Ulk€ which this risk is borne by the OEM and CM, respectively. They show that premium-based schemes are effective in inducing the best party to bear the risk, and conclude that they function well despite information asymmetry when double marginalization is not very high. Note that premium-based schemes are similar to the side payment scheme in Gan et al. (2004). Choi et al. (2008) study channel coordination in a supply chain consisting of a retailer and a supplier, each maximizing his mean-variance trade-off. They find that incorporation of risk aversion substantially affects the achievability of channel coordination. They also show that channel coordination depends on the difference between the risk preferences of the retailer and the supplier. Sobel and Turcic (2008) study a supply chain that faces a newsvendor problem. They characterize the Nash-optimal contracts, and contrast the risk-neutral case with the risk-averse one. They show that risk aversion has a significant impact on the contract terms and one firm’s risk aversion may be advantageous to the other. They suggest that a firm should consider its own and its prospective partner’s sensitivities to risk when it looks for a supply chain partner. Bakshi and Kleindorfer (2009) consider disruption risk management in a global supply chain with two participants who face interdependent losses resulting from supply chain disruptions. They use the Harsanyi-Selten-Nash Bargaining framework to model the supply chain participants’ choice of risk mitigation investments. The bargaining approach allows a framing of both joint financing of mitigation activities before a disruption and loss-sharing after the disruption. Wei and Choi (2010) study coordination of a supply chain with a wholesale pricing and a profit sharing scheme (WPPS) under the mean-variance decision framework. They show that there exists a unique equilibrium of the Stackelberg game with WPPS in the decentralized case. They also show that the manufacturer may benefit from pretending to be more risk-averse than he actually is. Finally, they propose a method to prevent this from happening.
36
X. Gan et al.
3 Future Research The issue of supply chain coordination with risk-averse agents has drawn much attention in recent years and has been studied in a number of research papers. Future research on this issue might be conducted in the following directions. First, optimization problems for a single firm can be revisited from the supply chain’s point of view. In the literature, numerous papers study a single risk-averse firm’s optimal decisions regarding order/production quantities, item prices, etc. Usually, those papers assume that the wholesale price, the amount of a side payment if any, refund on the returned units, etc., are exogenously given. More often than not, the single firm’s optimal decisions do not lead to a Pareto-optimal solution for the whole supply chain. In this case, it is worthwhile to study those problems from a system-wide view. As suggested in Gan et al. (2004), all of the agents in a supply chain can negotiate wholesale price, side payment, and refund policy, and come up with Pareto-optimal decisions on order/production quantities, item prices, etc. Recently, asymmetric information problems have been widely studied in the OR/MS literature. In these studies, the agents are usually assumed to be riskneutral. When those agents are risk-averse, the results in risk-neutral case may not apply and future research is warranted. For example, when the production cost of the supplier is asymmetric, C¸akanyldrm et al. (2010) show that a Pareto-optimal solution is achievable. However, when the agents in a supply chain are risk-averse, the achievability of a Pareto-optimal solution is not clear. The decisions of the agents in a supply chain depend crucially on customer demand. However, in the OR/MS literature, customer demand is usually assumed, for simplification, to be a function of the selling price, and the issue of customers’ risk-aversion is ignored. When the customer demand depends on risk attitudes of the customers, it might be interesting to investigate how the agents in supply chain share risk with customers.
References Agrawal V, Seshadri S (2000) Risk intermediation in supply chains. IIE Trans 32:819–831 Bakshi N, Kleindorfer P (2009) Co-opetition and investment for supply-chain resilience. Prod Oper Manage 2009:583–603 C¸akanyldrm M, Feng Q, Gan X, Sethi SP (2010) Contracting and coordination under asymmetric production cost information. Working paper, University of Texas at Dallas, TX Chen YJ, Seshadri S (2006) Supply chain structure and demand risk. Automatica 2006:1291–1299 Chen F, Gao F, Chao X (2008) Joint optimal ordering and weather hedging decisions: a newsvendor model. Working paper, Chinese University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong Choi S, Ruszczynski AR, Zhao Y (2009) A multi-product risk-averse newsvendor with law invariant coherent measures of risk. Working paper, Rutgers University, New Jersey Choi TM, Li D, Yan H, Chiu CH (2008) Channel coordination in supply chains with agents having mean-variance objectives. Omega 36:565–576
Addendum to “Coordination of Supply Chains with Risk-Averse Agents”
37
Gan X, Sethi SP, Yan H (2004) Coordination of supply chains with risk-averse agents. Prod Oper Manage 13:135–149 Gan X, Sethi SP, Yan H (2005) Coordination of a supply chain with a risk-averse retailer and a risk-neutral supplier. Prod Oper Manage 14:80–89 Gaur V, Seshadri S (2005) Hedging inventory risk through market instruments. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 7:103–120 Martı´nez-de-Albe´niz V, Simchi-Levi D (2005) A portfolio approach to procurement contracts. Prod Oper Manage 14:90–114 Pilkington A, Meredith J (2009) The evolution of the intellectual structure of operations management-1980–2006: a citation/co-citation analysis. J Oper Manage 27:185–202 Shi C, Chen B (2007) Pareto-optimal contracts for a supply chain with satisfying objectives. J Oper Res 58:751–759 Sobel M, Turcic D (2008) Risk aversion and supply chain contract negotiation. Working paper, Case Western Reserve University, Cleveland, OH Tomlin B (2006) On the value of mitigation and contingency strategies for managing supply chain disruption risks. Manage Sci 52:637–659 € u S, Toktay LB, Y€ Ulk€ ucesan E (2007) Risk ownership in contract manufacturing. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 9:225–241 Wei Y, Choi TM (2010) Mean-variance analysis of supply chains under wholesale pricing and profit sharing schemes. Eur J Oper Res 204:255–262
.
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination: Coordination Mechanisms, Managing Uncertainty and Research Directions Kaur Arshinder, Arun Kanda, and S.G. Deshmukh
Abstract The Supply Chain (SC) members are dependent on each other for resources and information, and this dependency has been increasing in recent times due to outsourcing, globalization and rapid innovations in information technologies. This increase in dependency brings some extent of risk and uncertainty too along with benefits. To meet these challenges, SC members must work towards a unified system and coordinate with each other. There is a need to identify the coordination mechanisms which helps in addressing the uncertainty in supply chain and achieving supply chain coordination. A systematic literature review is presented in this paper to throw light on the importance of SC coordination. The objectives of this paper are to: Report and review various perspectives on SC coordination issues, understand and appreciate various mechanisms available for coordination and managing SC uncertainty and identify the gaps existing in the literature. Perspectives on various surrogate measures of supply chain coordination have been discussed followed by the scope for further research. Keywords Coordination mechanisms • Supply chain coordination • Supply chain coordination index • Supply chain uncertainty
This paper is based on earlier version of the following paper: Arshinder K, Kanda A, Deshmukh SG (2008) Supply chain coordination: perspectives, empirical studies and research directions. Int J Prod Econ 115(2):316–335. This paper is also based on the doctoral research work done by Arshinder (2008) at Indian Institute of Technology Delhi, India. K. Arshinder (*) Department of Management Studies, Indian Institute of Technology Madras, Chennai 600036, India e-mail: [email protected] A. Kanda • S.G. Deshmukh Department of Mechanical Engineering, Indian Institute of Technology Delhi, New Delhi 110016, India e-mail: [email protected]; [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_3, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
39
40
K. Arshinder et al.
1 Introduction Supply chain has evolved very rapidly since 1990s showing an exponential growth in papers in different journals of interest to academics and practitioners (Burgess et al. 2006). The rise in papers on supply chain (SC) as well as the case studies in different areas in different industries motivates to study SC issues further. Supply chains are generally complex with numerous activities (logistics, inventory, purchasing and procurement, production planning, intra-and inter-organizational relationships and performance measures) usually spread over multiple functions or organizations and sometimes over lengthy time horizons. Supply chains tend to increase in complexity and the involvement of numerous suppliers, service providers, and end consumers in a network of relationships causes risks and vulnerability for everyone (Pfohl et al. 2010). The continuous evolving dynamic structure of the supply chain poses many interesting challenges for effective system coordination. Supply chain members cannot compete as independent members. The product used by the end customer passes through a number of entities contributed in the value addition of the product before its consumption. Also, the practices like globalization, outsourcing and reduction in supply base have exacerbated the uncertainty and risk exposure as well as more prone to supply chain disruption. Earlier literature considers risks in relation to supply lead time reliability, price uncertainty, and demand volatility which lead to the need for safety stock, inventory pooling strategy, order split to suppliers, and various contract and hedging strategies (Tang 2006). But today’s supply networks have become very complex and vulnerable to various supply chain risks hence these issues have pulled attention of various academics and practitioners for the last few years (Oke and Gopalakrishnan 2009). Uncertainty relates to the situation in which there is a total absence of information or awareness of a potential event occurrence, irrespective of whether the outcome is positive or negative. The terms risk and uncertainty are frequently used interchangeably (Ritchie and Brindley 2007). As firms move to leaner operating models and increasingly leverage global sourcing models, uncertainty in both supply and demand is growing along with supply chain complexity. To improve the overall performance of supply chain, the members of supply chain may behave as a part of a unified system and coordinate with each other. Thus “coordination” comes into focus. There seems to be a general lack of managerial ability to integrate and coordinate the intricate network of business relationships among supply chain members (Lambert and Cooper 2000). Stank et al. (1999) studied inter-firm coordination processes characterized by effective communication, information exchange, partnering, and performance monitoring. Lee (2000) proposes supply chain coordination as a vehicle to redesign decision rights, workflow, and resources between chain members to leverage better performance such as higher profit margins, improved customer service performance, and faster response time.
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination
41
Though, there are efforts in literature regarding coordination of different functions of the supply chain, the study of coordinating functions in isolation may not help to coordinate the whole supply chain. It appears that the study of supply chain coordination (SCC) is still in its infancy. Though, the need for coordination is realized, a little effort has been reported in the literature to develop a holistic view of coordination. It is interesting to note the following perspectives on supply chain coordination as reported in the literature: • Collaborative working for joint planning, joint product development, mutual exchange information and integrated information systems, cross coordination on several levels in the companies on the network, long term cooperation and fair sharing of risks and benefits (Larsen 2000). • A collaborative supply chain simply means that two or more independent companies work jointly to plan to execute supply chain operations with greater success than when acting in isolation (Simatupang and Sridharan 2002). • Kleindorfer and Saad (2005) asserted that continuous coordination, cooperation, and coordination among supply chain partners are imperative for risk avoidance, reduction, management and mitigation such that the value and benefits created are maximized and shared fairly. • Supply chain coordination is a strategic response to the challenges that arise from the dependencies supply chain members (Xu and Beamon 2006). • Supply chain coordination can be defined as identifying interdependent supply chain activities between supply chain members and devise mechanisms for manage those interdependencies. It is the measure of extent of implementation of such aggregated coordination mechanisms, which helps in improving the performance of supply chain in the best interests of participating members (Arshinder 2008). Various perspectives have been presented in the literature for coordinating supply chain (discussed in Sect. 2). These perspectives and classification of coordination literature has been adopted from the review paper by Arshinder et al. (2008a), however, the authors are motivated to revise the paper with view of incorporating uncertainty in SCC and up gradation of coordination mechanisms. The following developments have motivated the authors to upgrade the current review paper. • Growth in reporting of coordination mechanisms in supply chain. • Managing uncertainty has become more and more challenging, which can be tackled with SCC. • Information technology has been evolving and playing an important role in making global supply chain seamless. To develop a better understanding of the coordination issues in supply chain, a systematic literature review is required to throw light on the importance of SCC and specifically to address the objectives as: to understand and appreciate SCC in different processes of supply chain, to explore various coordination mechanisms to coordinate the supply chain, to understand the role of SCC in managing SC uncertainty and to relate surrogate measures of SCC with supply
42
K. Arshinder et al.
chain performance. The last objective is to identify the gaps existing in the literature followed by few research directions. The terms like integration, collaboration, cooperation and coordination are at times complementary and at times contradictory to each other and when used in the context of supply chain can easily be considered as a part of SCC. This assumption can be followed without loss of generality as the elements like integration (combining to an integral whole); collaboration (working jointly) and cooperation (joint operation) are the elements of coordination.
2 Supply Chain Coordination Literature Classification and Observations The papers related to supply chain coordination were searched using library databases covering a broad range of journals (Appendix). The papers were selected based on the issues addressed by these papers: How to define supply chain coordination and the imperatives of SCC? How to achieve supply chain coordination? Will coordinated supply chain be beneficial to all the individual members of the supply chain? What is the impact of SCC on the performance of various activities and processes of a supply chain? How SCC can help in mitigating supply chain uncertainties? The papers in response to the above mentioned questions were gathered and classified in categories presented in the following sections. To capture each and every aspect of SCC an attempt has been made to classify the literature on SCC as follows: • Perspectives and conceptual models on supply chain coordination. • Joint consideration of functions or processes by supply chain members at different levels to coordinate the supply chain. • Various supply chain coordination mechanisms adopted in the supply chain. • Supply chain coordination to manage uncertainties in the supply chain. • Empirical case studies in supply chain coordination. A schematic overview of hierarchical classification of literature is shown in Fig. 1 which shows that how the different categories of coordination will help in understanding the importance of SCC, utility of coordination mechanisms and the application of SCC on real life problems.
2.1
2.1.1
Perspectives and Conceptual Models on Supply Chain Coordination Challenges in Coordinating the Supply Chain
In any system, the smooth functioning of entities is the result of well-coordinated entities. It may be very difficult to define “coordination” precisely, but the lack of
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination
43
Supply Chain Coordination
Perspectives and conceptual models on SCC
Joint consideration of functions/ processes by various SC members
Coordination across functions of the supply chain
Supply chain coordination mechanisms
Integrated ProcurementProductionDistribution processes
Contracts
Supply uncertainty
Information technology and Information sharing
Supply chain coordination to manage uncertainty
Production disruptions
Demand uncertainty
Other collaborative initiatives
Fig. 1 Overview of the literature classification scheme
coordination can be easily articulated through a variety of surrogate measures. The supply chain members have conflicting goals or objectives and disagreements over domain of supply chain decisions and actions. It must be noted that a typical supply chain also deals with human systems, and hence, which may pose following challenges and difficulties in coordinating supply chain members. • The individual interest, local perspective and opportunistic behavior of supply chain members results in mismatch of supply and demand (Fisher et al. 1994). • The traditional performance measures based on the individual performance may be irrelevant to the maximization of supply chain profit in a coordinated manner. Similarly, the traditional policies, particularly rules and procedures, may not be relevant to the new conditions of inter organizational relationship. There has been over reliance on technology in trying to implement IT (Lee et al. 1997; McCarthy and Golocic 2002). • According to Piplani and Fu (2005), supply chain “plug and play” misalignment is associated with the difficulties involved in dynamically interchanging products (with short life cycle) and partners in the fast changing business environment. • The organizations want to reach to the best suppliers regardless their location globally, which brings many risks and uncertainties in managing cross border supply chains.
44
K. Arshinder et al.
• The benefits accrued by the whole supply chain after joint determination of supply chain performance indicators by supply chain members has no value in the absence of fair share mechanisms. There are multiple benefits accruing from effective SCC. Some of these include: elimination of excess inventory, reduction of lead times, increased sales, improved customer service, efficient product developments efforts, low manufacturing costs, increased flexibility to cope with high demand uncertainty, increased customer retention, and revenue enhancements (Fisher et al. 1994; Lee et al. 1997). 2.1.2
Various Perspectives and Conceptual Models on SCC
The literature reviewed by Burgess et al. (2006) showed that there is relative paucity of strong multi-theoretic approaches in supply chain. By looking at the problems of managing relationships between supply chain members, a need arises to tackle this problem using coordination theory. The most commonly accepted definition of coordination in the literature is “the act of managing dependencies between entities and the joint effort of entities working together towards mutually defined goals” (Malone and Crowston 1994). Coordination is perceived as a prerequisite to integrate operations of supply chain entities to achieve common goals. Various perspectives are reported in the literature regarding SCC. The researchers have described SCC either in the context of the application of coordination in different activities of supply chain or they are derived from other disciplines, summarized in Table 1. Several coordination strategies have been developed to align supply chain processes and activities to ensure better supply chain performance. The papers addressing various forms of coordination are Buyer–Vendor coordination by coordinating Procurement–Inventory–Production–Distribution processes (Goyal and Deshmukh 1992; Thomas and Griffin 1996; Sarmiento and Nagi 1999; Sarmah et al. 2006). Hoyt and Huq (2000) presented a literature review on the buyer-supplier relationship from the perspective of transaction cost theory, strategy structure theory and resource-based theory of the firm. There is abundant literature on conceptual based supply chain partnership but the testing of these concepts is required by utilization of operations research in supply chain (Maloni and Benton 1997). Various models have been discussed presenting various form of coordination such as price changes, quantity discounts (Sharafali and Co 2000), and partial deliveries and establishing their joint policies in context of manufacturing firms (Sarmah et al. 2007), information sharing and decision-making coordination (Sahin and Robinson 2002). Some of the coordination forms can be seen in Table 2. Power (2005) reviewed three principal elements of supply chain integration: information systems, inventory management and supply chain relationships aiming at reducing costs and improving customer service levels. The emerging area of supply chain coordination is outsourcing practices in case of insufficient production capacity of suppliers (Sinha and Sarmah 2007).
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination Table 1 Various perspectives on supply chain coordination Author (year) Perspective Narus and Anderson Cooperation among independent but (1995) related firms to share resources and capabilities to meet their customers’ most extraordinary needs Lambert et al. (1999) A particular degree of relationship among chain members as a means to share risks and rewards that result in higher business performance than would be achieved by the firms individually Larsen (2000) Collaborative working for joint planning, joint product development, mutual exchange information and integrated information systems, cross coordination on several levels in the companies on the network, long term cooperation and fair sharing of risks and benefits Lee (2000) Supply chain coordination as vehicle for redesigning decision rights, workflow, and resources between chain members to leverage better performance Simatupang et al. Given the nature of the interdependencies (2002) between units, coordination is necessary prerequisite to integrate their operations to achieve the mutual goal of the supply chain as a whole as well as those of these units Larsen et al. (2003) Where two or more parties in the supply chain jointly plan a number of promotional activities and work out synchronized forecasts, on the basis of which the production and replenishment processes are determined Hill and Omar Coordination can be achieved when the (2006) supply chain members jointly minimize the operating costs and share the benefits after jointly planning the production and scheduling policies Arshinder (2008) Identifying interdependent supply chain activities between SC members and devise mechanisms for manage those interdependencies. It is the measure of extent of implementation of such aggregated coordination mechanisms, which helps in improving the performance of supply chain in the best interests of participating members
45
Context Resource sharing
Risk and reward sharing
Holistic view of coordination
Workflow/resource dependency
Mutuality
Joint promotional activities, forecasting
Joint decision-making, benefit sharing
Linking coordination mechanisms with SC performance
46
K. Arshinder et al.
Table 2 Different forms of coordination viewed in supply chain S. No. Coordination Author (year) perspectives 1 Coordination of Goyal and Deshmukh (1992), functions or process Thomas and Griffin across SC members (1996) Sarmiento and Nagi (1999) 2 Coordination by Hoyt and Huq (2000), Sahin information sharing and Robinson (2002), Huang et al. (2003), Simatupang et al. (2002) 3 Supply chain Power (2005) partnerships 4
5
Coordination mechanisms and performance Problems in coordinating SC
6
Coordination by IT
7
Implementation issues in coordination
Issues in coordination Integrated procurement, production, distribution and inventory systems Value of information sharing and sharing modes, incentive alignment
Communication, Inventory management and supply chain partnerships Lee et al. (1997) Channel coordination, operational efficiency and information sharing Fawcett and Magnan (2002), Lack of information transparency, incentive Simatupang and Sridharan misalignment (2002) Li et al. (2002), Mc Laren Internet based integration of et al. (2002) complex supply chain processes, cost and benefits of different information systems coordinating supply chain Barratt (2004) Cultural, strategic and implementation elements of supply chain coordination
The other pragmatic initiatives such as Collaborative Planning, Forecasting and Replenishment (CPFR) (Larsen et al. 2003) and Supply Chain Operations Reference (SCOR) (Huan et al. 2004) may have relevance from practitioner’s point of view. Even though coordination improves the performance of the supply chain, it may not always be beneficial to coordinate the supply chain members. The high adoption costs of joining inter-organizational information systems and information sharing under different operational conditions of organizations may hurt some supply chain members (Zhao and Wang 2002). Therefore, it is essential to investigate the conditions under which supply chain coordination is beneficial, so that it should not result in higher supply chain costs and imprecise information. Observations and Gaps Regarding Various Perspectives and Conceptual Models on SCC (a) There seems to be no standard definition of SCC. Various perspectives on SCC as reported in the literature are testimony to this. The differences in perceptions
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination
47
are there because of the different expectations of the various stakeholders and the respective problem domain. Some of these perspectives present the inherent capability or intangibles required to coordinate like responsibility, mutuality, cooperation and trust. The other perspectives can be visualized, based on the coordination effort required in achieving common goals in different activities of supply chain. Since the activities are different, the coordination requirements also vary with the complexity of the activity. The most challenging coordination perspective is to extend the concept of coordination from within an organization to coordination between organizations. (b) By looking at these different perspectives, the SCC can be viewed as a set of following steps: 1. Identify why supply chain members want to coordinate and for which activity/process they are interdependent? Different interdependencies among supply chain members can be: ordering, procurement, inventory management, production, design and development, replenishment, forecasting and distribution. 2. Identify which activity or a set of activities needs to be coordinated, complexities in the activity (activities) and degree of coordination required. 3. Identify the reason to coordinate. Is it the demand uncertainty and/or supply uncertainty, double marginalization or other external risk in the supply chain, which can be addressed by coordination? 4. Identify whether a single or a combination of coordination mechanism are required to tackle the complexities in managing the interdependencies like resource sharing, knowledge sharing, information sharing, joint working, joint decision making, joint design and development of product, joint promotions, implementing information systems, designing risk sharing contracts. (c) Though there are attempts to focus on coordinating the different processes of supply chain, most of the papers reviewed have discussed the work done on analytical models with joint decision making of different process. The literature seems to be lacking in developing empirical relationship between coordination means and mechanisms (Information sharing, trust and IT) and SCC. (d) There is a need to embrace a variety of perspectives on supply chain coordination, various coordination issues and the means and mechanisms to achieve coordination in a holistic manner. (e) Various coordination mechanisms suggested in these models help in improving the various performance measures of the supply chain. These mechanisms include: joint decision-making, information sharing, resource sharing, implementing information technology, joint promotional activities, etc. The other motivation seems to be the ability of supply chain members to share the risks and subsequently share the benefits. (f) There is a need to monitor coordination in supply chain because of the adverse effects of lack of coordination on supply chain performance. There seems to be no measure to quantify coordination. Some models can be proposed to
48
K. Arshinder et al.
quantify and assess the strength of coordination on the basis of coordination mechanisms. (g) More empirical studies are required regarding the proper implementation of coordination mechanisms, so that combinations of different feasible coordination mechanisms can capture the impact of coordination on various supply chain performance measures. The above conceptual models on supply chain coordination have been presented in a fragmented manner. It is important to understand various SC functions to be coordinated. The complexity in coordinating various SC members may also depend on the interface to which two supply chain members belong. The following section presents the importance of SC coordination in various SC functions as well as in different SC processes at various supply chain interfaces.
3 Joint Consideration of Functions or Processes by Supply Chain Members at Different Levels to Coordinate Supply Chain Coordination can be visualized in different functions such as logistics, inventory management, forecasting, transportation, etc. Similarly, various interface such as supplier-manufacturer; manufacturer-retailer, etc. can be effectively managed using coordination.
3.1
Coordinating Functions Across Supply Chain Members
The supply chain members perform different functions or activities like logistics, inventory management, ordering, forecasting and product design involved in management of flow of goods, information and money. In traditional supply chain individual members of supply chain have been performing these activities independently. The supply chain members may earn benefits by coordinating various activities as discussed in following subsections. Logistics has traditionally been defined as the process of planning, implementing, and controlling the efficient flow and storage of goods, services, and related information as they travel from point of origin to point of consumption. The uncertainty and complexity of decision making regarding logistics operations: diversified customers and their different requirements, different resources required, increasing rate of unanticipated change and level of goal difficulty among logistics provider and the customer (supplier, manufacturer, distributor and retailer), geographically dispersed networks of multiple manufacturing sites lead to the need of coordination in this process (Huiskonen and Pirttila 2002). The challenges lie in managing the network complexities to collectively create value to the end customer
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination
49
(Stank et al. 1999; Stock et al. 2000) and integrating the logistics with whole supply chain with the help of electronic communication. The major decisions regarding inventory management include: determination of the order quantity, the timing of order, reorder point and the replenishment of inventory. The factors which are considered while deciding the inventory policy are customer demand (deterministic and random), number of members in supply chain, replenishment lead time, number of different products stored, length of the planning horizon, service level requirements and costs comprised of cost of production, transportation, taxes and insurance, maintenance, obsolescence opportunity cost, stock out, etc. The changes even in one of the above factors affect the decisions regarding inventory policy. The factors related to inventory policy are highly dynamic because of changing market condition, supply uncertainty; different and conflicting inventory policies among supply chain members, and unavailability of inventory information of other members. To face the dynamic situation, the members of supply chain have realized the importance of coordination in inventory management. The supply chain members may coordinate by joint consideration of the system wide costs (Huq et al. 2006; Wu and Ouyang 2003; Gurnani 2001; Barron 2007), sharing cost and price information (Boyaci and Gallego 2002; Piplani and Fu 2005), synchronizing order processing time (Zou et al. 2004; Lu 1995; Yao and Chiou 2004; Barron 2007) and networked inventory management information systems (Verwijmeren et al. 1996). These policies may sometime hurt one of the supply chain members. To compensate losses, different mechanisms have been proposed as quantity discounts, revenue sharing contracts and incentive alignment policies (Li et al. 1996; Moses and Seshadri 2000; Chen and Chen 2005). The different models results in reduction in ordering cost, holding cost, purchasing cost, and supply chain system wide costs and improvement in customer service level and product availability and product variety. The organization has perceived the need of reviving the traditional purchasing function in view of degree of participation and expertise of suppliers to a new evolving function called “strategic sourcing”(Gottfredson et al. 2005). The suppliers can form strategic partnerships by having common goals and sharing forecast information to have updated single forecasting process, which results in substantial cost reduction in whole supply chain (Zsidisin and Ellram 2001; Aviv 2001). The increasing rate of changing technologies, innovation, customer expectations, competition, and risk involved with new product entry and at the same time keeping the product design process cost efficient, is a challenging job. Kim and Oh (2005) presented systems dynamics approach to coordinate supplier and manufacturer decisions regarding improvement in quality and the new product development. Petersen et al. (2005) presented the findings from an empirical survey about the capabilities of suppliers required in coordinating the product design process with supplier. The coordination at design stage may result in better design and improved financial performance if the supplier has sufficient knowledge required to design the product.
50
3.2
K. Arshinder et al.
Coordinating Different Processes of the Supply Chain
A supply chain process consists of a set of activities taken together. Various processes in supply chain are procurement, production and distribution. These processes can be accomplished when some activities are performed like procurement process comprised supplier management, ordering, acquisition, replenishment, inspection activities, etc. Integration of different processes into a single optimization model to simultaneously optimize decision variables of different processes that have traditionally been optimized sequentially helps in improving the performance of SC (Park 2005). These processes sometimes face conflicting issues which are presented in Table 3. Isolated decision making in functionally related supply chain processes might weaken the supply chain system wide competitiveness. The different supply chain processes can be coordinated by implementing joint production delivery policies, common cycle approach, identical replenishment cycle (Yang and Wee 2002) and joint lot scheduling models (Kim et al. 2006). The coordination problems and the related issues at the interfaces of supply chain are presented in Table 4.
3.2.1
Production and Distribution Coordination
Integration of production and distribution processes may lead to a substantial saving in global costs and to an improvement in relevant service by exploiting scale economies of production and transportation, balancing production lots and vehicle loads, and reducing total inventory and stockout. Chikan (2001) gave a theoretical background of integrated production/logistics systems on the basis Table 3 Conflicting issues in supply chain processes SC processes Conflicting issues in supply chain processes Production and distribution The difference in performance metrics such as improvement in coordination quality of production, reduction in cost and improvement in service levels for distribution may also give rise to conflict Production sub functions are usually concentrated in the organization, while distribution sub functions are spread over (Chikan 2001) Production function is obsessed with low cost production, with large batch sizes and efficient and smooth production schedules (Pyke and Cohen 1993) and the distribution function is concerned with customer service as first priority, small batch sizes and frequent changeovers (Pyke and Cohen 1993) Procurement and production Suppliers typically want manufacturers to commit themselves coordination to purchasing large quantities in stable volumes with flexible delivery dates Manufacturers require just-in-time (JIT) supply in small batches from their suppliers due to changing demand and their unwillingness to hold inventories
Information sharing and IT
Coordination mechanism
Logistics provider and clientsa
Structure of supply chain
Joint decision making and benefit sharing Quantity discounts
Manufacturer–retailer
Single-supplier–multibuyers
Joint system cost consideration, quantity discounts
Supply chain network
Single-supplier–multibuyer Seller–buyer
Joint decision making and quantity discounts
Need of system cooperation Independent management IT and mutual benefits of inventories
Different order intervals
Mismatch goals between Information sharing, aligning Logistics provider and shipper and goals, EDI, contracts clientsa transportation provider Lack of integration EDI Logistics provider and between logistics and clientsa supply chain Need of relation Information sharing, IT, Logistics provider and improvement integrating role manufacturer between logistics and client
Mismatch goals between shipper and transportation provider
Coordination problem
Moses and Seshadri (2000) Need of risk sharing, mismatch in stock level and review period Gurnani (2001) Mismatch in timing of order
Verwijmeren et al. (1996)
Inventory Lu (1995) and Yao and Chiou (2004) Li et al. (1996)
Huiskonen and Pirttila (2002)
Stock et al. (2000)
Stank and Goldsby (2000)
Logistics Stank et al. (1999)
Author
Table 4 Coordination in various activities and interfaces of supply chain
Analytical model
Optimization
Network solution
Game theoretic model
Analytical model
Conceptual survey
Empirical survey
Conceptual framework
Empirical survey
Methodology used
Minimize cost
(continued)
Improving customer service level, increasing product variety, and lower supply chain system wide costs Minimize cost
Minimize costs (ordering + holding + purchasing) Maximize profits
Good relationship
Operational performance and financial performance
Inventory level, transportation costs, warehousing costs, ordering costs, order cycle variance, on time deliveries and unacceptable deliveries Channel cycle time and inventory level
Performance measure
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination 51
Misaligned inventory decisions
Independent cost consideration Different cycle times
Piplani and Fu (2005)
Huq et al. (2006)
Inventory-distribution Haq and Kannan (2006)
Forecasting Aviv (2001)
Barron (2007)
Chen and Chen (2005)
Zou et al. (2004)
Wu and Ouyang (2003)
Potential lie in reducing costs by considering all costs jointly
Multi-supplier–singleassembler
Single-manufacturer– multi-retailer Vendor–buyer
Single-wholesaler– multi-retailer
Structure of supply chain
Joint decision making
Joint consideration of cost
Joint consideration of costs at Multi-echelon each level
Manufacturer–retailer
Multi-warehouse– multi-retailer Serial supply chain (multi-echelon)
Joint consideration of cost, Manufacturer–retailer savings sharing, quantity discounts Cost sharing and service level Multi-echelon contracts
Jointly plan pricing and inventory replenishment policies Order coordination, information sharing Joint cost consideration with shortages Information sharing and revenue sharing contracts
Coordination mechanism
Independent decision Joint decision making and making of forecasting demand information sharing
Lack of coordination in lot sizing decisions and pricing Mismatch in timing of order Independent cost calculation Different order processing times of suppliers and incentive conflicts Need of risk sharing
Boyaci and Gallego (2002)
Zhao et al. (2002)
Coordination problem
Author
Table 4 (continued) Performance measure
Pareto improvement
Maximize profits, minimize costs (holding + shortage)
Minimize cost and improve service level Minimize cost
Minimize cost
Fuzzy AHP and genetic Minimize costs (inventory algorithm carrying + production + transportation)
Analytical model
Multi agent technology Minimize inventory holding cost and genetic algorithm Mathematical model Minimize distribution cost and lead and simulation time Analytical model Minimize costs (ordering + holding)
Mathematical
Analytical model (extension to newsboy model)
Analytical model
Simulation
Analytical optimization Maximize channel profits (wholesale problem price-inventory related costs)
Methodology used
52 K. Arshinder et al.
a
Multi-echelon
Joint production distribution cost minimization Joint cost minimization with global BOM
Coordinate production scheduling and vehicle routing
Multi-echelon
Multi-echelon
Multi-echelon
Near optimal cost and service Single-manufacturer– level, plan jointly single-distributor– single-retailer
Joint production distribution cost minimization
Conflict in finding Joint decision making and Single-supplier–multinumber of deliveries quantity discounts buyer of an order by vendor and buyer Holding costs increases For different holding costs of Single-supplier–singleas goods move members, find order buyer downstream in supply quantity and share chain benefits Managing complexities Synchronizing production Multi-echelon (5 cycles and risk pooling levels) effects
Lack of integration in different processes of supply chain Conflict between large batch size (production) and small batch size (distribution) Costs of carrying inventory at multi location, results more inventory level in whole supply chain Lack of integration in different processes Need for coordinating production and distribution
Clients can be supplier, manufacturer, distributor and retailer
Hwarng et al. (2005)
Hill and Omar (2006)
Production-inventory Yang and Wee (2002)
Jang et al. (2002)
Ganeshan (1999)
Chandra and Fisher (1994)
Pyke and Cohen (1993)
Production-distribution Jayaraman and Pirkul (2001)
Simulation
Mathematical model
Mathematical model
Mathematical and simulation Lagrangian heuristics and genetic algorithm
Local improvement heuristics
Constrained optimization problem
Lagrangian relaxation scheme
Average stock level, average backlog and average total cost
Minimize costs (production + shipping + holding)
Minimize costs (holding + ordering)
Minimize costs (purchasing + production + distribution) Minimize costs (production + distribution)
Minimize costs (fixed cost of facilities + holding + distribution)
Production cost and service level
Minimize costs (purchasing + production + distribution)
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination 53
54
K. Arshinder et al.
of institutional economics, discussed business issues regarding integration of these two functions and how this connection is handled in education. Jayaraman and Pirkul (2001) developed an integrated production distribution model comprised fixed cost, purchasing cost, production cost and distribution cost, taken simultaneously. Pyke and Cohen (1993) presented an integrated production distribution model and examined its performance characteristics (production cost and service level). Hill (1997) determined the production and shipment schedule for an integrated system to minimize average total cost per unit time. Kim et al. (2006) developed a mathematical optimization problem in multiple plants in parallel and single retailer supply chain system. The joint optimization of costs was carried out to determine the production cycle length, ordering quantity and frequency, and production allocation ratios for multiple plants. Dotoli et al. (2005) proposed a three-level hierarchical methodology for a supply chain network design at the planning management level. The network is so designed where the members are selected based on the performance followed by optimizing the communication and transportation links of supply chain. The performance measures used were operating costs, cycle time, energy saving, product quality and environmental impact.
3.2.2
Procurement and Production Coordination
Goyal and Deshmukh (1992) reviewed the literature on Integrated ProcurementProduction (IPP) systems. The different models of IPP were classified into the categories based on number of products, planning horizon, solution method employed, joint replenishment orders, and algorithmic issues in their study. Munson and Rosenblatt (2001) presented a purchasing-production integrated model and compared the cases of centralized SC and decentralized SC. It was found that decentralized SC gives same results as that of centralized supply chain if quantity discounts are considered at both upstream and downstream interfaces.
3.2.3
Production and Inventory Coordination
Lu (1995) considered heuristics approach for single vendor multi-buyer problem based on equal sized shipments. With the coordination of the replenishments of different items, the vendor can reduce his total annual cost by 30%. The buyers also benefit from the multi-buyer model by reducing their costs. Hoque and Goyal (2000) developed an optimal solution procedure for optimal production quantity in single vendor single buyer production inventory system with unequal and equal sized shipments from the vendor to the buyer and under the capacity constraint of the transport equipment by using simple interval search approach. Arreola-Risa (1996) considered the situation of multi-item production–inventory system with stochastic demands and capacitated production under deterministic or exponentially distributed unit manufacturing times. The observed results are that variation
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination
55
in the production environment increases the optimal inventory levels. The impact of capacity utilization in optimal base stock level is non-linear function of demand rate. Grubbstrom and Wang (2003) developed a multi-level capacity constrained model with stochastic demand. The Laplace transform was used as tool to construct the model and dynamic programming was used to solve and to find out the net present value (NPV) as an objective function. It was observed that for higher levels of capacity, the stochastic solution continues to improve performance of the system, albeit at a very slow rate and then takes advantage of increasing availability of the capacity resources. Kim et al. (2006) considered common production cycle length, delivery frequency and quantity in three level supply chain in joint economic procurement, production and delivery policy.
3.2.4
Distribution and Inventory Coordination
Jayaraman (1998) developed an integrated mathematical programming mixedinteger model for minimization of the total distribution cost associated with all three decision components i.e. facility locations, inventory parameters and transportation alternative selection, all investigated jointly. The integrated model permits a more comprehensive evaluation of the different trade-off that exists among the three strategic issues. Yokoyama (2002) developed an integrated optimization model of inventory-distribution system in which any consumer point can be supplied by multiple distribution centers. The order-up-to-R, periodic review inventory policies and transportation problem are considered simultaneously. Simulation and linear programming was used to calculate the expected costs and a random local search method was developed to determine optimum target inventory, which was then compared with genetic algorithm. Haq et al. (1991) formulated a mixed integer programming for integrated production–inventory-distribution model. The objective of the model was to determine optimal production and distribution quantities through various channels, optimal levels of inventory at various production stages and at warehouses over 6-month planning periods considering set up time cost, lead time, production losses and recycling of losses with backlogging. Observations and Gaps in Different Activities and at the Interfaces of Supply Chain (a) In the literature, different problems in coordinating the activities with various approaches have been discussed. The main objective considered in coordinating different problems in some activity is either minimizing the costs or maximizing profits. The coordination of same activities at different levels of supply chain reduces the supply chain costs. (b) The common problems addressed in literature are the joint consideration of different costs in an activity. These costs are associated with the supply chain coordination problems of joint ordering by buyers to some supplier, jointly plan order quantity between supplier and buyer, jointly order delivery to the buyers and joint replenishment activities in terms of coordinated lead times.
56
K. Arshinder et al.
The coordination problems have also been extended for coordinating different processes to collectively consider the costs of different processes to minimize the overall cost of supply chain. (c) The methodologies adopted to tackle the problem include: analytical, mathematical and optimization tools. Most of the studies regarding SCC are conducted on a two-level dimension because of the simple supply chain structure (Ganeshan 1999; Hill 1997) and discussed production delivery policies and joint stocking with discounts (Weng and Parlar 1999) at two level supply chain. To effectively allocate the production requirement and capture supply chain dynamics, various models have been dealt with joint purchasing policies in multiple supplier environment (Zou et al. 2004) and considering total cost of logistics. The investigations are required in supply chain encompassing multiple levels that consider the complex interactions between the upstream and downstream sites and gives a more real picture of supply chain. (d) The following are some gaps, which if considered, may further enhance coordination and performance of supply chain: • The whole supply chain is required to coordinate, so models can be extended to consider more than one activity. • The only coordination mechanism used by most of the authors is joint consideration of costs. From the literature regarding coordination models it can be observed that a number of coordination mechanisms (information sharing, roles integration, information technology) are possible to solve the coordination problem. There can be situations where two mechanisms are required to reduce the supply chain costs for example information sharing and quantity discounts. • The consideration of one performance measure may not justify the value of coordination. So, a number of performance measures are required to capture the impact of coordination in a holistic manner. Along with the measures like costs and profits, the benefits of coordination may also be indicated with the help of performance measures like: improving responsiveness by timely information sharing in whole supply chain, reducing inventory delays and information lead time by implementing good information systems and evaluating risks and rewards due to coordination. • The analytical and mathematical approaches used to coordinate activities and processes of supply chain may not tackle the dynamics of supply chain. Hence, simulation approach may be a good choice to view the overall coordination scenario of the whole supply chain. • Most of the studies on coordination are done for two level supply chains. This assumption may restrict the usage of models, as these models may not handle the ever-changing variables of supply chain. • The assumption of integrated different functions and processes leads to cost reduction, but models are required to evaluate or measure the degree of coordination (which leads to improvement in the supply chain performance).
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination
57
• The recent trend of outsourcing the logistics operations to third party logistics provider (3PL) has reduced many discrepancies related to replenishment of goods (Jayaram and Tan 2010). The studies are required how to 3PLs can be an information source to coordinate suppliers and buyers. The knowledge and expertise of 3PLs on routes, fleet size and fleet type can be leveraged in optimizing the procurement-production-distribution problems and integrating with 3PLs. • To gain the advantage of common logistics provider and information systems, the supply chain members at same level may coordinate horizontally. Very few papers have discussed horizontal collaboration (Arshinder et al. 2006; Bahinipati et al. 2009) by using multi-criteria decision making models. Some quantitative models can be proposed to quantify such kind of coordination also. In this section we can observe that how supply chain coordination is required in each SC process. Various processes have been coordinated by adopting different means mechanisms of coordination. By looking at the need of coordination in SC, the researchers may like to know various existing coordination mechanisms, which can be adopted to coordinate supply chain across different industries. The next section presents various coordination mechanisms, which can be adopted as per the suitable supply chain environment.
4 Various Supply Chain Coordination Mechanisms Adopted in the Supply Chain The dependencies between supply chain members can be managed by some means and mechanisms of coordination. By utilizing coordination mechanisms, the performance of supply chain may improve. There are different types of coordination mechanisms as discussed in the following subsection.
4.1
Supply Chain Contracts
Supply chain members coordinate by using contracts for better management of supplier buyer relationship and risk management. The contracts specify the parameters (like quantity, price, time, and quality) within which a buyer places orders and a supplier fulfills them. The objectives of supply chain contracts are: to increase the total supply chain profit, to reduce overstock/understock costs and to share the risks among the supply chain partners (Tsay 1999). The contracts counter double marginalization that is by decreasing the costs of all supply chain members and total supply chain costs when they coordinate as against the costs incurred
58
K. Arshinder et al.
when the SC members act independently. The problem of double marginalization and risks like overstock and understock has been widely been observed single period inventory models with less shelf life of product. Most of the contracts have been proposed as single period models. Various contracts are defined in Table 5. Buyback contracts or returns policy has been widely used coordination contract in textile and fashion industry. In buyback contracts a manufacturer offers retailer either full credit for a partial return of goods a partial credit for all unsold goods. In case of retail competition the manufacturer will be benefited from the returns policy when the production costs are sufficiently low and demand uncertainty is not too great (Padmanabhan and Png 1997). Krishnan et al. (2004) have analyzed that Table 5 Definitions of supply chain contracts S. Supply chain Definition No. contract 1 Buy back The manufacturer (seller) agrees to buy back the unsold units from the retailer (buyer) for agreed upon prices at the end of the selling season 2 Revenue In a revenue sharing contract, the sharing buyer shares some of his revenues with the seller, in return for a discount on the whole sale price 3 Sales rebate The sales rebate provides a direct incentive to the retailer to increase sales by means of a rebate paid by the supplier for any item sold above a certain quantity 4 Quantity It couples the customer’s flexibility commitment to purchase no less than a certain percentage below the forecast with the supplier’s guarantee to deliver up to a certain percentage above 6 Trade policy This policy deals with how the total profit is shared among supply chain entities 7 Reservation This policy offers discounts to the policy products reserved and the products which are not reserved are sold at retail price After the selling season, the unsold 8 Markdown money units are sold at discounted price (price discount) 9 Quantity During the selling period, the seller discount offers discounts based on quantity of goods purchased
Author (year)
Remarks
Mantrala and Improves the coordination, Raman increases (1999), Hau and Li (2008) sales, risk sharing Yao et al. (2008), More flexible in terms in terms Zhou and of whole sale Wang (2009) price Wong et al. Provides direct (2009) incentives for retailers to increase sales Tsay (1999)
Gives more flexibility in order quantity
Ding and Chen (2008)
Offers better profit sharing
Chen and Chen (2009)
Reduces the uncertainty in demand
Lee (2001), Pan et al. (2009)
Improves profit of the channel
Weng (2004)
Improves the sales
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination
59
buyback contract coupled with promotional cost sharing agreements between manufacturer and retailer result in supply chain coordination. The other consideration in buyback contract is the case of information sharing and asymmetrical information between the supply chain members (Yao et al. 2005; Yue and Raghunathan 2007). Bose and Anand (2007) proposed that by assuming transfer price exogenous the buyback contract is Pareto efficient. Yao et al. (2008) proposed an analytical model to analyse the impact of stochastic and price dependent demand on returns policy between manufacturer and retailer. The other variants of buyback contracts discussed in literature are: stochastic salvage capacity in fashion industry (Lee and Rhee 2007); two period contract model in case of decentralized assembly system (Zou et al. 2008); in case of updating of information in supply chain (Chen et al. 2006) and by including the risk preferences of the SC members (He et al. 2006). In case of quantity flexibility contract, the buyer is allowed to modify the order within limits agreed to the supplier as demand visibility increases closer to the point of sale. The buyer modifies the order as he gains better idea of actual market demand over time. Tsay and Lovejoy (1999) proposed quantity flexibility contracts for two independent members of the supply chain model to design incentives for the two parties to determine system wide optimal outcome. The efficiency can be improved when buyer is ready to pay more to the supplier for increased flexibility. Tsay and Lovejoy (1999) proposed a framework for the design of quantity flexibility in three level supply chains, behavioural models in response to quantity flexibility contracts and the impact on the supply chain performance measures: inventory levels and order variability. More output flexibility comes at the expense of greater inventory cost, so inventory management has been viewed as the management of process flexibilities. It is observed that the quantity flexibility contracts can dampen the transmission of order variability throughout the supply chain. Milner and Rosenblatt (2002) analysed two period quantity flexibility contract in which the buyer is allowed to adjust second order paying a per unit order adjustment penalty. This contract can reduce the potentially negative effect of correlation of demand between two periods, but the order quantity flexibility reduces the profits of the buyer. Barnes-Schuster et al. (2002) proposed two period options contracts where buyer has flexibility to respond to market changes in second period and coordinate the supply chain channel. Sethi et al. (2004) developed a model to analyze a quantity flexibility contract involving multiple periods, rolling horizon demand and forecast updates including demand and price information updates. In revenue sharing contract, the supplier charges the buyer a low wholesale price and shares a fraction of the revenues generated by the buyer (Giannoccaro and Pontrandolfo 2004; Cachon and Lariviere 2005; Koulamas 2006). The SC members can design contracts based on discounts: lot size based or volume based. Yao et al. (2008) developed a revenue sharing model in the case of retail competition by considering price sensitivity. vander Rhee et al. (2010) has considered multi echelon (more than two) supply chain members and simultaneously installed revenue sharing contracts between all pairs of adjacent supply chain members to coordinate the supply chain.
60
K. Arshinder et al.
A discount is lot size based if the pricing schedule offers discounts based on the quantity ordered in a single lot. A discount is volume based if the discount is based on the total quantity purchased over a given period regardless of the number of lots purchased over that period (Rubin and Benton 2003; Weng 2004). Chauhan and Proth (2005) proposed a profit sharing model under price dependent demand proportional to their risks based on expected customer demand.
4.2
Role of Information Sharing and Information Technology
IT is used to improve inter-organizational coordination (McAfee 2002; Sanders 2008) and in turn, inter-organizational coordination has been shown to have a positive impact on select firm performance measures, such as customer service, lead-time, and production costs (Vickery et al. 2003). Information technology helps to link the point of production seamlessly with the point of delivery or purchase. It allows planning, tracking and estimating the lead times based on the real time data. Advances in Information Technology [e.g. internet, EDI (electronic data interchange), ERP (enterprise resource planning), e-business and many more] enable firms to rapidly exchange products, information, and funds and utilize collaborative methods to optimize supply chain operations. Internet and web can enhance effective communication, which helps members of supply chain review past performance, monitor current performance and predict when and how much of certain products need to be produced and to manage workflow system (Liu et al. 2005). Fin (2006) investigated the relation between EDI in apparel industry and three performance levels: operational, financial and strategic. This helped in reduction of lead time from several weeks to 3 days. According to Soliman and Youssef (2001), e-business strategy refers to the way internet tools are selected and used in relation to the needs of integration and coherent with other organizational and managerial tools: e-commerce (Swaminathan and Tayur 2003) can be used to support processes such as sales, distribution and customer service processes, support to sourcing, procurement, tendering, and order fulfillment processes, and e-manufacturing (Kehoe and Boughton 2001). Devaraj et al. (2007) analyzed the relationship between supplier integration and customer integration with supply chain performance when supported by e-business technologies. E-business capability supporting supply chain technologies such as customer orders, purchasing and collaboration between suppliers and customer enhances the production information integration intensity, which in turn improves the supply chain performance. Skipper et al. (2008) proposed a conceptual model to link level of interdependence among supply chain with supply chain performance moderated by different types of IT needed to achieve different levels of coordination. The framework is supported by interdependence theory and coordination theory. The coordination processes between globally dispersed and mobile supply chain members is becoming more and more information intensive. The recent trends in intelligent wireless
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination
61
web services have proved enhancement in the mobile real time supply chain coordination (Saroor et al. 2009). The various coordination problems handled by information systems are: little value to the supplier because of competitive bidding, forced implementation of IT, incompatible information system at different levels of supply chain, greater lead times, inefficient purchase order and misaligned e-business strategies and coordination mechanisms (Porter 2001). Stank et al. (1999) report that the food firms benefit from more accurate and timely information and IT or EDI improves inventory management and helps in comprehension of the order cycle. Yusuf et al. (2004) examined key dimensions of implementation of ERP system in Rolls Royce. The implementation of latest information system only may not be sufficient to integrate supply chain members, since at times; faulty implementation may result in the poor performance of supply chain. Li et al. (2009) carried out an empirical study to explore relationship between IT, supply chain integration and supply chain performance of Chinese manufacturing organization. Supply chain integration mediates the relationship between IT implementation and supply chain performance. Hence, IT can be a good enabler to integrate supply chain. But it is important to take into account the justification of IT in changing business environment. It must take into account the appropriate usage, investment justification and align with business environment to achieve competitive advantage (Gunasekaran et al. 2006). The supply chain members coordinate by sharing information regarding demand, orders, inventory, shipment quantity, POS data, etc. Timely demand information or advanced commitments from downstream customers helps in reducing the inventory costs by offering price discounts and this information can be a substitute for lead time and inventory (Reddy and Rajendran 2005). The value of information sharing increases as the service level at the supplier, supplier-holding costs, demand variability and offset time increase, and as the length of the order cycle decrease (Bourland et al. 1996; Chen et al. 2000). The higher the level of information sharing, the more important the effective supply chain practice is to achieve superior performance (Zhou and Benton 2007). Some comparative studies have done in which no information sharing policy is compared with full information sharing policy. Information sharing policy results in inventory reductions and cost savings (Yu et al. 2001). Cachon and Fisher (2000) presented a simulation-based comparative study, where the supply chain costs are 2.2% lower on average with full information sharing policy than with traditional information policy and the maximum difference is 12.1%. Also, this results in faster and cheaper order processing that leads to shorter lead times. The point of sales (POS) data helps the supplier to better anticipate future orders of the retailers and reduces the bullwhip effect (Dejonckheere et al. 2004). The supplier may take advantage of the retailers’ inventory information in allocating the stock to retailers optimally (Moinzadeh 2002). Ding et al. (2011) has investigated the mechanism of providing incentive to retailer by upstream partner for implementing demand information sharing in the context of three-echelon supply chain system. A cooperative game approach is
62
K. Arshinder et al.
proposed to address the problem of profit allotment between partners to effectively motivate the partners to be cooperative with each other.
4.3
Other Collaborative Initiatives
Joint consideration of replenishment (Yao and Chiou 2004; Chen and Chen 2005), inventory holding costs with dynamic demand (Boctor et al. 2004), collaborative planning (Aviv 2001), costs of different processes (Haq and Kannan 2006; Jayaraman and Pirkul 2001; Ganeshan 1999), frequency of orders (Yang and Wee 2002; Barron 2007), batch size (Pyke and Cohen 1993; Boyaci and Gallego 2002), product development (Kim and Oh 2005) to improve the performance of supply chain. A supply chain member may design a scheme to share profits at the end of period. The supply chain members share profit by determining optimal order quantity of single supplier and multi-buyer supply chain and achieve coordination (Jain et al. 2006). A coherent decision-making helps in resolving conflicts among supply chain members and in exceptions handling in case of any future uncertainty. There are many factors involved in achieving coordination like human, technology, strategies, relationship, rewards, sharing of knowledge, sharing benefits, aligning goals, scheduling of frequent meetings of stakeholders for conflict resolution, understanding of nature of intermediates and knowledge of supply chain concepts, status or power difference and resistance in following the instructions of other organizations (Lu 1995; Gittell and Weiss 2004). Simatupang et al. (2004) explored a fashion firm to see how coordination is driven by its responsibility interdependence, uncertainty, and inter-functional conflict. By properly identifying different points of coordination, the performance improvement was effected. Vendor Managed Inventory (VMI) is a supply chain initiative whereby a supplier assumes responsibility for maintaining inventory levels and determining order quantities for its customers. A number of benefits from VMI adoption have been reported in literature: reduction in inventories, shorter order intervals and more frequent deliveries. A VMI program typically involves the use of a software platform, the sharing of demand forecasts and/or cost information, timely communications, set liability levels, and risk-sharing parameters and common goal sharing between the buyer and the supplier. VMI can be particularly beneficial in the products with high demand variance and high outsourcing costs (Cheung and Lee 2002). Collaborative Planning, Forecasting and Replenishment (CPFR) is a collaboration initiative where two or more parties in the supply chain jointly plan a number of promotional activities and work out synchronized forecasts, on the basis of which the production and replenishment processes are determined (Larsen et al. 2003). Some of the benefits of CPFR are increased sales, higher service levels, faster order response time, lower product inventories, faster cycle times, reduced capacity requirements, reduced number of stocking points, improved forecast accuracy and lower system expenses. Danese et al. (2004) explored the relationship between the
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination
63
types of interdependencies (one way and two way communications) among the units involved in the CPFR processes and the activated coordination mechanisms (Liaison positions, meetings, task forces, standing committees and integrating managers) in three case studies for all the steps of implementation of CPFR. The case studies were considered from different industries: pharmaceutical, automotive and mechanical. This relationship may help managers in the decision making process to select the most appropriate action to perform to implement CPFR. Quick response (QR) is another inventory management initiative which can be undertaken to coordinate supply chain members by responding quickly to market changes with reduced lead time. The response time is reduced as a retailer sends POS data to its supplier. The supplier makes use of this information to improve the demand forecast and production/distribution schedules (Iyer and Bergen 1997; Simchi-Levi et al. 2007). Choi and Sethi (2010) have reviewed QR supply chains from both supply and demand perspectives and classified the literature as supply information management, demand information management and supporting technologies. It is concluded that there are challenges to implement QR in multiple decision points, which needs to be met by continuously innovating new technologies like Radio Frequency Identification Devices (RFID). The Supply Chain Operations Reference (SCOR) model helps in evaluating and improving enterprise wide supply chain performance and management. SCOR is structured on four levels: plan, source, make and deliver. It brings order to the diverse activities that make up the supply chain, and provides common terminology and standard process descriptions. The model allows companies to: evaluate their own processes effectively, compare their performance with other, companies both within and outside their industry segment, pursue specific competitive advantages, use benchmarking and best practice information to prioritize their activities, quantify the benefits of implementing change and identify software tools best suited to their specific process requirements (Huan et al. 2004). Observations and Gaps in Coordination Mechanisms (a) The supply chain contracts can be a useful mechanism to resolve the conflict and risk related problems. The use of information technology in handling transactions online between supply chain members reduces the response time. The members can plan their operational activities by sharing or retrieving the data from each other. It helps in streamlining the processes and reduces supply chain costs. (b) The members might have different technologies, skill and different type of knowledge about market. To handle any future exceptions or uncertainties, the members may jointly plan supply chain activities like ordering, replenishment, and forecasting and product design. (c) The following gaps regarding coordination mechanisms need attention to enhance coordination: • Since the role and utility of all coordination mechanisms is handling different phases of supply chain. To coordinate supply chain as a whole,
64
K. Arshinder et al.
the consideration of all coordination mechanisms may give very good performance. • Most of the models describing coordination mechanisms are dealt in two level supply chain, which can be extended to multi-level supply chain. The relation between different coordination mechanisms and the performance measures of supply chain need to be developed. The models handling the problems of coordination have emphasized on single performance measures. The supply chain dynamics may be captured by considering a number of performance measures of supply chain. • Supply chain contracts are designed to motivate the downstream member to order more than his/her optimal order quantity. The downstream member always faces uncertainty of overstock or under stock. The upstream member always faces uncertainty that whether the downstream member will send the order matching the upstream member’s capacity. The contracts like buyback and revenue sharing contracts can enhance expected sales and reduces stock outs. Quantity flexibility contracts can reduce the overstock problems of downstream members. These performance indicators are equally important, which needs more research attention. • The contract decision variables at different interfaces of the supply chain in multi echelon environment interact with each other. For example the contract adopted by supplier and manufacturer is sometimes dependent on the contract adopted by same manufacturer with his/her distributor in a same supply chain. There is a need to explore such relationship and to explore different combinations of contracts at different interfaces of supply chain. The major driver of SCC is the conflict or uncertainty, which needs to be addressed by selecting suitable coordination mechanism. But, it is important to understand at the same time, to what extent SCC can help in mitigating supply chain uncertainty (presented in the next section).
5 Supply Chain Coordination to Manage Uncertainty in the Supply Chain Supply chain uncertainty has been captured in various forms like supply uncertainty, production or operational uncertainty and demand uncertainty. In the supply chain coordination literature, various coordination mechanisms have been adopted to manage supply chain uncertainty like uncertainty in capacity, demand, lead time, quantity and production and supply disruptions (Tang and Musa 2011) as shown in Fig. 2. Many papers have emphasized on supply chain contracts and information exchange/sharing to manage supply chain uncertainties. Whereas, the other set of papers discussed the joint consideration of costs and profits of all supply chain members while taking decisions regarding ordering and replenishment. This joint
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination Supply side uncertainty
Supplier Production/ Operational uncertainty
65 Supply side uncertainty
Buyer Production/ Operational uncertainty
Buyer’s side uncertainty
Supplier
Coordination mechanisms
Demand uncertainty
Buyer
Coordinate as SC members are part of one system to manage uncertainty and to share risks and rewards
Supply Chain Performance Improvement Fig. 2 Managing supply chain uncertainty with supply chain coordination
consideration of costs or profits (centralized system) helps to improve the performance of supply chain over a decentralized case (independent decision making). Due to the increased technological innovations, the products’ lifecycle has largely shortened. Seasonal and perishable goods can be attributed to this kind. Such products have longer production and delivery lead time than their selling season (Mantrala and Raman 1999). So the orders should be placed before the selling season starts. Some of the important challenges in integrating the supply chain are tackling issues such as managing complex supply chain structures, demand uncertainty and leftover units after selling season. In a single period inventory model, better coordination can be achieved by inducing the retailer/ buyer to order more in order to avoid their risk of under stocking through some negotiations with the manufacturers/seller. The manufacturer offers integrated decision making policies like returns policy, sales rebate policy, price discount/ volume discount policy, etc. to raise the order quantity and improves sales (Yao et al. 2008). Past research has proved that introduction of various contracts improve the performance of the supply chain as well of each entity in supply chain.
66
K. Arshinder et al.
The contracts have been discussed for single period inventory models with either deterministic demand or uncertain demand or price dependent demand. Apart from contracts there can be some incentive function to achieve flexible cost allocation between supplier and buyer to coordinate the supply chain and to manage uncertainty in supply (Zimmer 2004). Hou et al. (2010) have proposed a model considering one manufacturer and two suppliers: the main supplier is cheaper but prone to disruption risk and backup supplier is more reliable but an expensive. The authors have developed a non-linear optimization model to determine the optimal values of buyer’s order quantity and optimal buyback price under both supply and demand uncertainty. Early supply involvement reduces the likelihood of supply disruptions and negative supply events (Zsidsin and Smith 2005). The contracts like advanced purchase commitments can help mitigating supply uncertainty, where unsatisfied demand can be backordered from risky supplier (Serel 2007). The other kind of uncertainty due to disruption can be observed as disruptions in the production process at manufacturer’s facility. Qi et al. (2004) proposed a model for short life cycle product with demand as decreasing function of retail price considering disruptions. The model considered the two periods wherein the second period demand change can lead to the disruption, which may affect the production plan of supplier. The wholesale quantity discounts may coordinate the supply chain in this scenario of disruption. The similar kind of disruption can be seen in terms of production costs. Xiao and Qi (2008) developed two-period model for onemanufacturer and two competing retailers supply chain under production costs disruption. The authors have analyzed two mechanisms; an all unit quantity discounts and incremental quantity discounts the under production disruptions for possible coordination scenarios. A risk sharing contract is proposed where at the end of period the retailer compensates manufacturer’s losses due to overproduction or manufacturer compensates retailer’s losses due to over stock in case of supply chain with two stage demand information updating (Chen et al. 2006). There can be several benefits of splitting the single period order into multiple ordering to update the demand information and revise the order in the subsequent orderings. It has impact on production costs of the manufacturer due to slow production and fast production as against the multiple different orders (Liu et al. 2004). The other effect of multiple ordering can be seen on holding cost, lead time, backorders, varying wholesale and retail price and consideration of demand for multiple periods. The methodology adopted for handling multiple ordering ranges from newsboy problem to analytical models with simulation to the dynamic programming. The decision variables have been the order quantities and/or the varying wholesale prices, retail prices and buyback prices in multi-period situation (Lee 2007; Zhou and Wang 2009; Pan et al. 2009). Other aspect of capturing demand uncertainty is by using fuzzy demand. The expected profits of coordinated supply chain outperform the expected profits in the case of no coordination under fuzzy demand (Xu and Zhai 2010). Barbarosoglu (2000) has proposed a decision support model for improving supplier–buyer coordination by using supply contracts where the buyer’s commitment is considered as a
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination
67
function of time at the contract renewal time to reduce the supply chain nervousness. A pricing model is formulated to address partnership expectations for a fair sharing of savings of the supply chain members. Observations and Gaps in Uncertainty and Supply Chain Coordination (a) Most of the studies are restricted to two level serial supply chains. In reality, supply chain can have divergent and convergent multi-echelon structures. The literature seems lacking to address the uncertainty concerns in such structures. (b) The literature has emphasized more on demand uncertainty, whereas, supply uncertainty can be of equal concern in the era of globalization and outsourcing. Moreover, the quantitative models can be proposed to explore the impact of supply uncertainty on supply chain performance. (c) There are very few studies on splitting the single period order into multiple orders. The supply chain members can take advantage of more accurate information over a period of selling season and hence resolve supply chain inefficiencies. (d) The buyback contract is the only contract which has been discussed in multi ordering models to manage the risk. There is a scope to explore combination of other contracts in multiple ordering over single season.
6 Discussion A number of difficulties in SCC are identified based on the literature. These difficulties have been identified from different activities, interfaces and the number of levels in the supply chain. It has been realized that the difficulties in SCC and independent working of supply chain members lead to poor performance. The coordination problems are solved by implementing some coordination mechanisms in supply chain activities, which may result in the improvement of some performance measures. The SC activities have been considered in isolation to solve their respective coordination problem. The coordination problems may not be same in all activities of supply chain. The requirements of coordinating whole SC may vary with SC activity, with some interface of SC, with number of echelons in SC and with process of SC. There are different activities and different coordination problems in whole supply chain. Coordinating one activity may not help to improve supply chain system wide performance.
6.1
Existing Models of Coordination and the Gaps in These Models
There are some initiatives and models (such as CPFR and SCOR) which may help in collaboration along the supply chain. These models consist of so many steps and
68
K. Arshinder et al.
the implementation of such processes takes time. Various guidelines are required to implement these models in practice. It is difficult to link the guidelines directly to the performance of supply chain. It may take a number of years to know the performance improvement by implementing these models, as there is no set measure to quantify coordination which can be linked with practice (or which may result due to implementation of these models) of these models. It is difficult to get a quantitative measure after implementing models like CPFR and SCOR, which may indicate about whether SC is coordinated or not. The coordination models discussed have different performance measures at single level and at interface of supply chain, which are not aligned with the whole supply chain. To monitor coordination in supply chain, same performance measures throughout will help in evaluating the value of coordination. There are different mechanisms, which when applied, result in different trade-offs of performance measures of coordinated supply chain because of different characteristics of performance measures. The complexity of considering whole supply chain and the performance trade-offs cannot be handled with the models discussed in the literature. These difficulties can be easily tackled by approaches like fuzzy logic (Ross 1997) and multi-objective genetic algorithms (Deb 2002). Fuzzy logic is applied in the situation where understanding is quite judgmental and the processes where human reasoning and human decision making is involved like the complexities in supply chain. The optimum values of decision variables in multi objective environment can be easily determined with the help of tools like Genetic Algorithm.
6.2
Proposed Framework to Quantify Coordination
The controlling parameter of achieving coordination is the impact of application of coordination mechanisms (CMs) on the performance measure. It can be observed from the Decision-coordination mechanism matrix given in Table 6 that how different coordination mechanisms can be used for various supply chain decisions. The proper implementation and usage of coordination mechanisms improve the performance of the supply chain (Arshinder 2008). It can be observed that the problems and conflicts in coordinating the supply chain members can be resolved through coordination mechanisms. The importance of coordination mechanism may help in determining the value of coordination in supply chain.
6.2.1
Framework Using Various Coordination Mechanisms
A framework has been proposed based on the usage of coordination mechanisms and their importance in managing uncertainty and resolving various kinds of conflicting problems in coordination. The coordination mechanisms can be classified as:
Coordination mechanism
Supply chain network Integrated procurementproduction
Integrated production-distribution Joint consideration of cost
X
X
Coordinated timing of the order
Coordinated timing of replenishment Inventory management in a network Forecasting
X
X
X
X
X
X
Supply Information chain technology contracts
Inventory Coordinated order quantity
Logistics Coordination issues in 3PL provider and customer Integrating the logistics activity geographically dispersed network/supply chain
Supply chain decision
Table 6 Decision-coordination mechanism matrix
X
X X
X
Jayaraman and Pirkul (2001), Pyke and Cohen (1993), Kim et al. (2006) Dotoli et al. (2005) Goyal and Deshmukh (1992), Munson and Rosenblatt (2001)
Aviv (2001)
X
X
Speed of delivery, status of order, accuracy of information, invoicing on delivery, cash-flow improvements, accurate invoicing, transportation costs, warehousing costs, inventory levels, ordering costs, stock-outs, order cycle time, order cycle variance, on time deliveries
Performance measures
Supply chain system wide cost
Supply chain system wide cost
Bullwhip effect, holding cost, system wide cost
Li et al. (1996), Boyaci and Gallego (2002), Inventory levels, ordering costs, customer Piplani and Fu (2005), Zou et al. (2004), service level, holding costs, product Wu and Ouyang (2003) variety, purchasing costs, product availability, unacceptable delivery, Lu (1995), Moses and Seshadri (2000), system wide costs Gurnani (2001), Zhao et al. (2002) Huq et al. (2006), Barron (2007)
Stock et al. (2000)
Huiskonen and Pirttila (2002)
Authors
Verwijmeren et al. (1996)
X
X
X
X
Joint decision making
X
X
X
X
Information sharing
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination 69
70
• • • •
K. Arshinder et al.
Supply chain contracts (M1) Information Technology (M2) Information sharing (M3) Joint decision making (M4)
This is not an exhaustive list of coordination mechanisms. These coordination mechanisms can be different in number as per the requirements of supply chain for example dependent on the type of industry and type of interdependencies between SC members. In the present framework four coordination mechanisms are considered because of their extensive discussion in literature. It can be assumed without any loss of generality, that if the coordination mechanism is applied properly, it will help in achieving SCC. Since, supply chain involves certain members who are human beings and the human system is the most complex system to be managed in organization study. There is bound to be conflicts and problems in the traditional supply chain, which call for an urgent need to implement coordination mechanisms in supply chain. The coordination mechanisms are from different domains, require different conditions and can operate in different situations. But, one thing common in all mechanisms is that all mechanisms are implemented to improve the performance of supply chain and to resolve confusion and uncertainty among SC members due to independent decision making. To know more about the importance of coordination mechanism, one way is to study all the activities in some process, identify the dependent activities in that process and select the coordination mechanism to coordinate all activities of a process (Arshinder et al. 2006). Since, whole supply chain needs to be coordinated; the usage of all four coordination mechanisms and performance improvement achieved by these mechanisms will help in evaluating SCC. A better way to find some quantitative index of supply chain coordination is by incorporating the strength of coordination mechanisms by following steps shown in Fig. 3. The quantitative index can be represented as Supply Chain Coordination Index (SCCI) can be viewed as a function of implementation of coordination mechanisms. SCCI for four coordination mechanisms can be represented as: SCCI ¼ f ðM1; M2; M3; M4Þ The above function is to be formulated in such a way that the combined impact of performance improvement by using all mechanisms is considered. This formulation poses two challenges: 1. It is required to represent all coordination mechanisms with a unique scale. 2. It is required to evaluate improvement in performance measures qualitatively or quantitatively by using coordination mechanisms. The methodologies like AHP and Fuzzy logic may help to represent coordination mechanisms with a unique scale. The performance improvement can be captured either empirically with the help of judgments given by managers or
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination
71
Define the structure of supply chain
Set performance measures for whole supply chain
Choose input variables
Run the simulation for The case when the members are working independently Observe the impact on performance measures and set as PM(w/c) (without coordination)
Select the coordination mechanisms and run the simulation
Supply chain contracts (M1) Buyback Revenue sharing Quantity flexibility Quantity discounts
Determine performance measure (PMM1C)
Information Technology (M2) Email Internet EDI ERP POS
Determine performance measure (PMM2C)
Information sharing (M3) Demand Inventory Lead time Production schedule Capacity Cost
Determine performance measure (PMM3C)
Joint decisionmaking (M4) Cost consideration Replenishment Forecasting Ordering
Determine performance measure (PMM4C)
Determine the percentage improvement in performance measures with respect to case of without coordination PMMi = (PMMiC – PMMi (w/c))/ PMMi (w/c) for i=1,2,3,4
Assign weights to different coordination mechanisms (WMi, for i= 1,2,3,4) based on relative improvement of percentage of all CMs by devising some scale (AHP).
WM1
WM2
WM3
WM4
SCCI = WM1PMM1+ WM2PMM2 + WM3 PMM3 + WM4 PMM4
Fig. 3 The proposed model to quantify supply chain coordination index (SCCI)
with the help of simulating the scenarios of using these coordination mechanisms to obtain same performance measures. The improvement in performance measures will motivate supply chain members to implement coordination mechanisms.
72
K. Arshinder et al.
One of the efforts has been proposed based on the implementation of all coordination mechanisms with the help of graph theoretic approach (Kaur et al. 2006). This methodology is based on allocation of relative importance of these coordination mechanisms given by the judgments of managers. These judgments are based on the implementation of mechanisms and the importance of mechanisms based on the performance improvement by these mechanisms.
6.2.2
Relation Between Coordination Mechanisms and Performance Measures with Simulation
A simulation approach can also be a useful tool in capturing the different scenarios of coordination mechanisms and their impact on selected performance measures. Certain assumptions can be considered regarding the levels of supply chain, one period or multiple period model and various operational variables like order quantity, holding and shortage costs, etc. The implementation of various coordination mechanisms can be simulated to analyze same performance measures with same assumptions. Some constraints can be included in the model which takes care of the fact that none of the supply chain member will face losses by implementing coordination mechanisms. The improvement in performance measures will give an idea about the capability of an organization to achieve coordination. The model proposed in Fig. 3, helps in evaluating SCCI. The first few steps can be used in simulation to determine the performance measures. Some input variables may be selected like different costs, price, inventory policies, lead time, capacity and type of coordination mechanisms at all levels of supply chain in a pre defined structure of supply chain. The assumptions for demand (uncertain and price dependent), lead time and time horizon can be set for the simulation and run the simulation to obtain certain performance measures. The performance measures are function of input variables. The problem may be multi objective based on the selected performance measures of supply chain. The results of simulation that is improvement in the performance measures by applying different coordination mechanisms can be combined using again some hybrid frameworks like: AHP, Fuzzy logic and/or Graph theoretic approach to determine SCCI.
6.2.3
Hybrid Framework Using Various Coordination Mechanisms and Simulation
The coordination mechanisms (M1, M2, M3 and M4) have different characteristics and their impact on the performance measures may also be different. The simulation can be carried out without implementing coordination mechanisms and then the results are compared with the situation with considering the coordination
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination
73
mechanisms as shown in Fig. 3. A framework is required which can capture and combine the values of performance improvements by coordination mechanisms and their relative importance. To make the results consistent, the performance improvements can be normalized in terms of percentages. This framework may have capability to find the relative importance of respective coordination mechanisms by using AHP and/or Fuzzy logic (Arshinder et al. 2007). A scale can be devised based on the difference in the percentage improvements by CMs. This scale may help in determining the relative importance or weights of CMs. The linear equation of SCCI can be derived from the proposed model to determine the value of SCCI.
6.3
Insights Gained from Proposed Framework
The proposed framework helps in defining and measuring SCC. Supply chain coordination can be used to enhance system wide performance enabled due to the implementation of coordination mechanisms selected based on the type of industry and the interdependencies between supply chain members keeping in view mutual interests of all SC members. Supply chains can be coordinated by identifying interdependent activities between supply chain members required to accomplish SC objectives. Once interdependencies are identified, some means of mechanism(s) are devised to manage the decision variables pertaining to interdependent activity. The independent evaluation of decision variables of interdependent activities by SC members represents the case of uncoordinated supply chains. Once, coordination mechanism is selected to manage interdependencies, SC members can simulate and compare the scenarios: one with using CM and other without coordination mechanisms. The expected values of improvement in certain performance measures may help to realize the value of coordination. Same steps can be used for all processes of supply chain. Various functions can be explored for SCCI depending on the number and implementation of CMs. Suitable techniques can be used such as Multi-CriteriaDecision-Making (MCDM) models to quantify SCCI as a function of various CMs.
6.4
Surrogate Measures of Supply Chain Coordination
To innovate continuously is the base line for all the organizations, which makes the supply chain more dynamic in nature. It is important to capture the performance of supply chain. The highly uncertain environment in supply chain brings in the challenges to have fix kind of performance measures. Gunasekaran et al. (2001) developed a framework for measuring supply chain performance for each activity
74
K. Arshinder et al.
of plan, source, make and deliver under strategic, tactical and operational decisions. The literature on supply chain performance measures is lacking in presenting standard performance metrics. The problem manifolds when the question comes to measure supply chain coordination. There is scarcity of studies to evaluate coordination in supply chain. The following performance measures can be good indicators of supply chain coordination. (a) Supply chain profitability. Joint consideration of order quantity, costs or profits may lead to improvement in supply chain performance. Regardless of the number of entities in supply chain, the joint consideration of order quantity in supply chain for single period model improves the profitability of whole supply chain (Arshinder et al. 2009a). Most of the contracts reported in literature have expected profits as a performance indicator too. (b) Supply chain flexibility. When the supply chain members coordinate with each other by using contracts, it gives more flexibility to supply chain members to change order quantity, price, cost and lead time. The lower and upper bound can be set for decision variables of contracts (coordination mechanisms) to ensure that the performance of each SC member in a centralized case (consideration of all SC members to be a part of one system) with appropriate coordination mechanism is better than decentralized case (individual supply chain member). Various supply chain contracts present different kinds of supply chain flexibility (Arshinder et al. 2008a). (c) Mitigating uncertainty or risk sharing. The recent issue in supply chain coordination is “How to allocate the total gain in the supply chain achieved due to coordination after mitigating risk?” Many studies have recently developed game theoretic models to fairly share the rewards among supply chain members. The risk mitigation in the form of gain in whole supply chain can be a surrogate measure of SCC. In similar way the extra share of profit allocated out of total gain in SC due to coordination can also reflect the coordinated supply chain. It has also been observed that as the demand variance is increased, the coordinated supply chain due to contracts outperform the independent case of supply chain (Arshinder et al. 2008b). The SC members can devise the contracts in which supplier gives assurance to the buyer to supply emergency orders in case of sudden surge in demand to share risk of losing a customer. Whereas, the buyer can share the extra cost incurred by the supplier in producing emergency orders in view of uncertainty in demand. How well such kind of contracts is designed can be a good indicator of coordination to share risks due to uncertainty in supply chain (Serel 2007). (d) Supply chain coordination index. As it has been discussed that various combination of coordination mechanisms can improve the performance of supply chain. Many situations in supply chain need more than one coordination mechanisms like VMI with quantity discounts, supply chain contracts with information sharing, supply chain contracts with joint decision making (joint consideration of costs). Such kind of index has been developed in Arshinder et al. (2009b) (also mentioned in the proposed framework).
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination
75
7 Major Challenges and Future Research Directions Coordinating the supply chain across organizational boundaries may be one of the most difficult aspects of supply chain management. Many firms simply are unaware of the fundamental dynamics of supply chains, but even those firms that are enlightened enough to understand these dynamics are often unable to realize inter-organizational coordination. Often the most effective supply chains have a dominating organization that sees the benefits of SCC and forces the rest of the supply chain to comply (i.e., global leader in retailing such as Wal-Mart). Many supply chains, however, either do not have a dominant organization, or the dominating organization is unenlightened. In these instances, coordinating the supply chain is most difficult. Typically, it is observed that the SCC problems could be due to the conflicting objectives that leads to a short time relationships with SC members, hence the environment and expectations changes frequently with dealing with new members. On this background, it is essential that the SC members need to appreciate the importance of coordination. This paper has attempted to deliberate on various theoretical perspectives on SCC. The objective to achieve coordination is limited only to the individual functions, to the single coordination mechanism at interfaces of supply chain and to achieve restricted performance measures. A holistic approach towards coordination in whole supply chain is a big challenge, which motivated to propose the issues of SCC in this paper. The mechanisms for coordination need to be studied in detail. The coordination mechanisms can further be of different sub types. To coordinate the whole supply chain, the aggregation of the impact of all coordination mechanisms on the performance of supply chain is required. Various combinations may be explored with the help of simulation. Supply chain contracts have proved to coordinate single period supply chains. The research is required to explore the utility of contracts in multi-period cases. In multi period model, the supply chain members are more expose to the uncertainty as they are dealing with supply chain members frequently. How various coordination mechanisms can be allied in multi period problems as well as can we evaluate coordination in such case? Very few studies have been reported to quantify risk or uncertainty in supply chain. The Bullwhip effect has extensively been discussed in the literature. Actually, there can be many variations seen in supply chain like supply uncertainty, delay in delivery having cascading effect as we go downwards in the supply chain, which is similar to the order variation in Bullwhip effect. How SCC can help in mitigating such uncertainties is one of the important research issues? Acknowledgements The authors are grateful to the reviewers and the whole editorial team of International Journal of Production Economics, Elsevier for constructive suggestions and for considering our paper for publication. The authors are also thankful to the referees of Springer’s Research Handbook Series on “Innovative Schemes for Supply Chain Coordination and Uncertainty” for the comments and suggestions to improve the quality of our paper.
76
K. Arshinder et al.
Appendix List of Journals Refereed in Review Paper 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16.
Computers & Industrial Engineering Computers & Operations research European Journal of Operational Research IIE Transactions International Journal of Logistics and System Management International Journal of Logistics Management International Journal of Operations and Production Management International Journal of Physical Distribution & Logistics Management International Journal of Production Economics International Journal or Production Research Journal of Operations Management Management Science Omega Supply Chain Management: An International Journal Transportation Research (Part E) Other Journals from Emerald, Inderscience and Sciencedirect portal
References Arreola-Risa A (1996) Integrated multi-item production-inventory systems. Eur J Oper Res 89(2):326–340 Arshinder K (2008) An integrative framework for supply chain coordination. Unpublished doctoral thesis, Indian Institute of Technology Delhi, New Delhi, Arshinder K, Kanda A, Deshmukh SG (2006) A coordination based perspective on the procurement process in supply chain. Int J Value Chain Manage 1(2):117–138 Arshinder K, Kanda A, Deshmukh SG (2007) Coordination in supply chains: an evaluation using fuzzy logic. Prod Plann Control 18(5):420–435 Arshinder K, Kanda A, Deshmukh SG (2008a) Supply chain coordination: perspectives, empirical studies and research directions. Int J Prod Econ 115(2):316–335 Arshinder K, Kanda A, Deshmukh SG (2008b) Development of a decision support tool for supply chain coordination using contracts. J Adv Manage Res 5(2):20–41 Arshinder K, Kanda A, Deshmukh SG (2009a) A coordination theoretic model for three level supply chains using contracts. Sadhana Acad Proc Eng Sci 35(5):767–798 Arshinder K, Kanda A, Deshmukh SG (2009b) A framework for evaluation of coordination by contracts: a case of two-level supply chains. Comput Ind Eng 56:1177–1191 Aviv Y (2001) The effect of collaborative forecasting on supply chain performance. Manage Sci 47(10):1326–1343 Bahinipati BK, Kanda A, Deshmukh SG (2009) Horizontal collaboration in semiconductor manufacturing industry supply chain: an evaluation of collaboration intensity index. Comput Ind Eng 57(3):880–895
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination
77
Barbarosoglu G (2000) An integrated supplier-buyer model for improving supply chain coordination. Prod Plann Control 11(8):732–741 Barnes-Schuster D, Bassok Y, Anupindi R (2002) Coordination and flexibility in supply contracts with options. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 4(3):171–207 Barratt M (2004) Understanding the meaning of collaboration in the supply chain. Supply Chain Manage Int J 9(1):30–42 Barron CLE (2007) Optimizing inventory decisions in a multi stage multi customer supply chain: a note. Transp Res E 43(5):647–654 Boctor FF, Laporte G, Renand J (2004) Models and algorithms for the dynamic joint replenishment problem. Int J Prod Res 42(13):2667–2678 Bose I, Anand P (2007) On returns policies with exogenous price. Eur J Oper Res 178(3): 782–788 Bourland KE, Powell SG, Pyke DF (1996) Exploiting timely demand information to reduce inventories. Eur J Oper Res 92(2):239–253 Boyaci T, Gallego G (2002) Coordinating pricing and inventory replenishment policies for one wholesaler and one or more geographically dispersed retailers. Int J Prod Econ 77(2):95–111 Burgess K, Singh PJ, Koroglu R (2006) Supply chain management: a structured review and implications for future research. Int J Oper Prod Manage 26(7):703–729 Cachon GP, Fisher M (2000) Supply chain Inventory management and the value of shared information. Manage Sci 46(8):1032–1048 Cachon GP, Lariviere MA (2005) Supply chain coordination with revenue sharing contracts: strengths and limitations. Manage Sci 51(1):30–44 Chandra P, Fisher ML (1994) Coordination of production and distribution planning. Eur J Oper Res 72(3):503–517 Chauhan SS, Proth JM (2005) Analysis of a supply chain partnership with revenue sharing. Int J Prod Econ 97(1):44–51 Chen TH, Chen JM (2005) Optimizing supply chain collaboration based on joint replenishment and channel coordination. Transp Res E 41(4):261–285 Chen LH, Chen YC (2009) A newsboy problem with simple reservation arrangement. J Comput Ind Eng 56(1):157–160 Chen F, Drezner Z, Ryan JK, Levi DS (2000) Quantifying the bullwhip effect in a simple supply chain: the impact of forecasting, lead times, and information. Manage Sci 46(3):436–443 Chen H, Chen J, Chen YF (2006) A coordination mechanism for a supply chain with demand information updating. Int J Prod Econ 103(1):347–361 Cheung KL, Lee HL (2002) The inventory benefit of shipment coordination and stock rebalancing in a supply chain. Manage Sci 48(2):300–306 Chikan A (2001) Integration of production and logistics – in principle, in practice and in education. Int J Prod Econ 69(2):129–140 Choi TM, Sethi S (2010) Innovative quick response programs: a review. Int J Prod Econ 114:456–475 Danese P, Romano P, Vinelli A (2004) Managing business processes across supply networks: the role of coordination mechanisms. J Purch Supply Manage 10(5):165–177 Deb K (2002) Multi-objective optimization using evolutionary algorithms. Wiley, Chichester Dejonckheere J, Disney SM, Lambrecht MR, Towill DR (2004) The impact of information enrichment on the Bullwhip effect in supply chains: a control engineering perspective. Eur J Oper Res 153(3):727–750 Devaraj S, Krajewski L, Wei JC (2007) Impact of eBusiness technologies on operational performance: the role of production information integration in the supply chain. J Oper Manage 25(6):1199–1216 Ding D, Chen J (2008) Coordinating three level supply chain with flexible returns policies. Omega 36(4):865–876 Ding H, Guo B, Liu Z (2011) Information sharing and profit allotment based on supply chain coordination. Int J Prod Econ 133(1):70–79
78
K. Arshinder et al.
Dotoli M, Fanti MP, Meloni C, Zhou MC (2005) A multi-level approach for network design of integrated supply chain. Int J Prod Res 43(20):4267–4287 Fawcett SF, Magnan GM (2002) The rhetoric and reality of supply chain integration. Int J Phys Distrib Logistics Manage 32(5):339–361 Fin B (2006) Performance implications of information technology implementation in an apparel supply chain. Supply Chain Manage Int J 11(4):309–316 Fisher ML, Raman A, McClelland AS (1994) Rocket science retailing is almost here: are you ready? Harv Bus Rev 72(3):83–93 Ganeshan R (1999) Managing supply chain inventories: a multiple retailer, one warehouse, multiple supplier model. Int J Prod Econ 59(1–3):341–354 Giannoccaro I, Pontrandolfo P (2004) Supply chain coordination by revenue sharing contracts. Int J Prod Econ 89(2):131–139 Gittell JH, Weiss L (2004) Coordination networks within and across organizations: a multi-level framework. J Manage Stud 41(1):127–153 Gottfredson M, Puryear R, Phillips S (2005) Strategic sourcing: from periphery to the core. Harv Bus Rev 83(2):132–139 Goyal SK, Deshmukh SG (1992) Integrated procurement-production systems: a review. Eur J Oper Res 62(1):1–10 Grubbstrom RW, Wang Z (2003) A stochastic model of multi-level/multi-stage capacityconstrained production-inventory systems. Int J Prod Econ 81–82(1):483–494 Gunasekaran A, Patel C, Tirtiroglu E (2001) Performance measures and metrics in a supply chain environment. Int J Oper Prod Manage 21(1–2):71–87 Gunasekaran A, Ngai EWT, McGaughey RE (2006) Information technology and systems justification: a review for research and applications. Eur J Oper Res 173(3):957–983 Gurnani H (2001) A study of quantity discount pricing models with different ordering structures: order coordination, order consolidation, and multi-tier ordering hierarchy. Int J Prod Econ 72(3):203–225 Haq AN, Kannan G (2006) Design of an integrated supplier selection and multi echelon distribution inventory model in a built-to-order supply chain environment. Int J Prod Res 44(10):1963–1985 Haq AN, Vrat PA, Kanda A (1991) An integrated production-inventory-distribution model for manufacture of urea: a case. Int J Prod Econ 25(1–3):39–49 Hau Z, Li S (2008) Impacts of demand uncertainty on retailer’s dominance and manufacturerretailer supply chain coordination. Omega 36(5):697–714 He J, Chin KS, Yang JB, Zhu DL (2006) Return policy model of supply chain management for single-period products. J Optim Theory Appl 129(2):293–308 Hill RM (1997) The single-manufacturer single retailer integrated production-inventory model with a generalized policy. Eur J Oper Res 97(3):493–499 Hill RM, Omar M (2006) Another look at the single-vendor single-buyer integrated productioninventory problem. Int J Prod Res 44(4):791–800 Hoque MA, Goyal SK (2000) An optimal policy for a single-vendor single-buyer integrated production-inventory system with capacity constraint of the transport equipment. Int J Prod Econ 65(3):305–315 Hou J, Zeng AZ, Zhao L (2010) Coordination with a backup supplier through buy-back contract under supply disruption. Transp Res E 46:881–895 Hoyt J, Huq F (2000) From arms-length to collaborative relationships in the supply chain: an evolutionary process. Int J Phys Distrib Logistics Manage 30(9):750–764 Huan SH, Sheoran SK, Wang G (2004) A review and analysis of supply chain operations reference (SCOR) model. Supply Chain Manage Int J 9(1):23–29 Huang G, Lau J, Mak K (2003) The impacts of sharing production information on supply chain dynamics: a review of the literature. Int J Prod Res 41(7):1483–1517 Huiskonen J, Pirttila T (2002) Lateral coordination in a logistics outsourcing relationship. Int J Prod Econ 78(2):177–185 Huq F, Cutright K, Jones V, Hensler DA (2006) Simulation study of a two-level warehouse inventory replenishment system. Int J Phys Distrib Logistics Manage 36(1):51–65
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination
79
Hwarng HB, Chong CSP, Xie N, Burgess TF (2005) Modelling a complex supply chain: understanding the effect of simplified assumptions. Int J Prod Res 43(13):2829–2872 Iyer AV, Bergen ME (1997) Quick response in manufacturer-retailer channels. Manage Sci 43:559–570 Jain K, Nagar L, Srivastava V (2006) Benefit sharing in inter-organizational coordination. Supply Chain Manage Int J 11(5):400–406 Jang YJ, Jang SY, Chang BM, Park J (2002) A combined model of network design and production/ distribution planning for a supply network. Comput Ind Eng 43(1–2):263–281 Jayaram J, Tan K (2010) Supply chain integration with third-party logistics providers. Int J Prod Econ 125(2):262–271 Jayaraman V (1998) Transportation facility location and inventory issues in distribution network design. Int J Oper Prod Manage 18(5):471–494 Jayaraman V, Pirkul H (2001) Planning and coordination of production and distribution facilities for multiple commodities. Eur J Oper Res 133(2):394–408 Kaur A, Kanda A, Deshmukh SG (2006) A graph theoretic approach to evaluate supply chain coordination. Int J Logistics Syst Manage 2(4):329–341 Kehoe DF, Boughton NJ (2001) New paradigms in planning and control across manufacturing supply chains: the utilization of internet technologies. Int J Oper Prod Manage 21(5–6):582–593 Kim T, Hong Y, Lee J (2006) Joint economic production allocation and ordering policies in a supply chain consisting of multiple plants and a single retailer. Int J Prod Res 43(17): 3619–3632 Kim B, Oh H (2005) The impact of decision making sharing between supplier and manufacturer on their collaboration performance, Supply Chain Management: An International Journal 10 (3-4):223–236 Kleindorfer PR, Saad GH (2005) Managing disruptions risks in supply chains. Prod Oper Manage 14(1):53–68 Koulamas C (2006) A newsvendor problem with revenue sharing and channel coordination, Decision Sciences 37(1):91–100 Krishnan H, Kapuscinski R, Butz DA (2004) Coordinating contracts for decentralized supply chains with retailer promotional effort. Manage Sci 50(1):48–63 Lambert DM, Cooper MC (2000) Issues in supply chain management. Ind Mark Manage 29(1): 65–83 Lambert DM, Emmelhainz MA, Gardner JT (1999) Building successful partnerships, Journal of Business Logistics 20(1):165–181 Larsen ST (2000) European logistics beyond 2000. Int J Phys Distrib Logistics Manage 30(6): 377–387 Larsen TS, Thernoe C, Anderson C (2003) Supply chain collaboration theoretical perspective and empirical evidence. Int J Phys Distrib Logistics Manage 33(6):531–549 Lee HL (2000) Creating value through supply chain integration. Supply Chain Manage Rev 4(4): 30–36 Lee HC (2001) Coordinated stocking, clearance sales, and return policies for a supply chain. Eur J Oper Res 131(3):491–513 Lee HC (2007) Coordination on stocking and progressive pricing policies for a supply chain. Int J Prod Econ 106(1):307–319 Lee CH, Rhee BD (2007) Channel coordination using product returns for a supply chain with stochastic salvage capacity. Eur J Oper Res 177(1):214–238 Lee HL, Padmanabhan V, Whang S (1997) Information distortion in supply chain: the bullwhip effect. Manage Sci 43(4):546–558 Li SX, Huang Z, Ashley A (1996) Improving buyer-seller system cooperation through inventory control. Int J Prod Econ 43(1):37–46 Li Z, Kumar A, Lim YG (2002) Supply chain modeling: a coordination approach. Integr Manuf Syst 13(8):551–561 Li G, Yang H, Sun L, Sohal AS (2009) The impact of IT implementation on supply chain integration and performance. Int J Prod Econ 120(1):125–138
80
K. Arshinder et al.
Liu K, Li JA, Lai KK (2004) Single period, single product news vendor model with random supply shock. Eur J Oper Res 158(3):609–625 Liu J, Zhang S, Hu J (2005) A case study of an inter-enterprise workflow-supported supply chain management system. Inf Manage 42(3):441–454 Lu L (1995) A one-vendor multi-buyer integrated model. Eur J Oper Res 81(2):312–323 Malone T, Crowston K (1994) The interdisciplinary study of coordination. ACM Comput Surv 26(1):87–119 Maloni MJ, Benton WC (1997) Supply chain partnerships: opportunities for operations research. Eur J Oper Res 101(3):419–429 Mantrala MK, Raman K (1999) Demand uncertainty and supplier’s returns policies for a multistore style-good retailer. Eur J Oper Res 115(2):270–284 McAfee A (2002) The impact of enterprise information technology adoption on operational performance: an empirical investigation. Prod Oper Manage 11(1):33–53 McCarthy S, Golocic S (2002) Implementing collaborative planning to improve supply chain performance. Int J Phys Distrib Logistics Manage 32(6):431–454 Mc Laren T, Head M, Yuan Y (2002) Supply chain collaboration alternatives: understanding the expected costs and benefits, Internet Research 12(4):348–364 Milner JM, Rosenblatt MJ (2002) Flexible supply contracts for short life cycle goods: the buyer’s perspective. Nav Res Logist 49(1):25–45 Moinzadeh K (2002) A multi-echelon inventory system with information exchange. Manage Sci 48(3):414–426 Moses M, Seshadri S (2000) Policy mechanisms for supply chain coordination. IIE Trans 32(3):254–262 Munson CL, Rosenblatt MJ (2001) Coordinating a three-level supply chain with quantity discounts. IIE Trans 33(5):371–384 Narus JA, Anderson JC (1995) Rethinking distribution: adaptive channels. Harv Bus Rev 74(4):112–120 Oke A, Gopalakrishnan M (2009) Managing disruptions in supply chains: a case study of a retail supply chain. Int J Prod Econ 118(1):168–174 Padmanabhan V, Png IPL (1997) Manufacturer’s returns policies and retailer’s competition. Mark Sci 16(1):81–94 Pan K, Lai KK, Liang L, Leung SCH (2009) Two period pricing and ordering policy for the dominant retailer in a two echelon supply chain with demand uncertainty. Omega 37(4):919–929 Park YB (2005) An integrated approach for production and distribution planning in supply chain management. Int J Prod Res 43(6):1205–1224 Petersen KJ, Handfield RB, Ragatz GL (2005) Supplier integration into new product development: coordinating product, process and supply chain design. J Oper Manage 23(3–4):371–388 Pfohl H, Kohler H, Thomas D (2010) State of the art in supply chain risk management research: empirical and conceptual findings and a roadmap for the implementation in practice. Logistics Res 2(1):33–44 Piplani R, Fu Y (2005) A coordination framework for supply chain inventory alignment. J Manuf Technol Manage 16(6):598–614 Porter ME (2001) Strategy and the internet. Harv Bus Rev 79(2):63–78 Power D (2005) Supply chain management integration and implementation: a literature review. Supply Chain Manage Int J 10(4):252–263 Pyke DF, Cohen MA (1993) Performance characteristics of stochastic integrated production distribution systems. Eur J Oper Res 68(1):23–48 Qi X, Bard JF, Yu G (2004) Supply chain coordination with demand disruptions. Omega 32:301–312 Reddy AM, Rajendran C (2005) A simulation study of dynamic order-up-to policies in a supply chain with non-stationary customer demand and information sharing. Int J Adv Manuf Technol 25(9–10):1029–1045 Ritchie B, Brindley C (2007) Supply chain risk management and performance: a guiding framework for future development. Int J Oper Prod Manage 27(3):303–322 Ross TJ (1997) Fuzzy logic with engineering applications. McGraw Hill, Singapore
A Review on Supply Chain Coordination
81
Rubin PA, Benton WC (2003) A generalized framework for quantity discount pricing schedules. Decis Sci 34(1):173–188 Sahin F, Robinson P (2002) Flow coordination and information sharing in supply chains: review, implications and directions for future research. Decis Sci 33(4):505–536 Sanders NR (2008) Pattern of information technology use: the impact on buyer–suppler coordination and performance. J Oper Manage 26(3):349–367 Sarmah SP, Acharya D, Goyal SK (2006) Buyer–vendor coordination models in supply chain management. Eur J Oper Res 175(1):1–15 Sarmah SP, Acharya D, Goyal SK (2007) Coordination and profit sharing between a manufacturer and a buyer with target profit under credit option. Eur J Oper Res 182(3):1469–1478 Sarmiento AM, Nagi R (1999) A review of integrated analysis of production–distribution systems. IIE Trans 31(11):1061–1074 Saroor J, Tarokh MJ, Shemshadi A (2009) Initiating a state of the art system for real-time supply chain coordination. Eur J Oper Res 196(2):635–650 Serel DA (2007) Capacity reservation under supply uncertainty. Comput Oper Res 34(4): 1192–1220 Sethi SP, Yan H, Zhang H (2004) Quantity flexibility contracts: optimal decisions with information updates. Decis Sci 35(4):691–712 Sharafali M, Co HC (2000) Some models for understanding the cooperation between supplier and the buyer. Int J Prod Res 38(15):3425–3449 Simatupang TM, Sridharan R (2002) The collaborative supply chain. Int J Logistics Manage 13(1):15–30 Simatupang TM, Wright AC, Sridharan R (2002) The knowledge of coordination for supply chain integration. Bus Process Manage J 8(3):289–308 Simatupang TM, Sandroto IV, Lubis SBH (2004) Supply chain coordination in a fashion firm. Supply Chain Manage Int J 9(3):256–268 Simchi-Levi D, Kaminsky P, Simchi-Levi E (2007) Designing and managing the supply chain, 3rd edn. McGraw Hill, New York Sinha S, Sarmah SP (2007) Supply chain coordination model with insufficient production capacity and option for outsourcing. Math Comput Modell 46:1442–1452 Skipper JB, Craighead CW, Byrd TA, Rainer RK (2008) Towards a theoretical foundation of supply network interdependence and technology-enabled coordination strategies. Int J Phys Distrib Logistics Manage 38(1):39–56 Soliman F, Youssef M (2001) The impact of some recent developments in e-business on the management of next generation manufacturing. Int J Oper Prod Manage 21(5–6):538–564 Stank TP, Crum MR, Arango M (1999) Benefits of interfirm coordination in food industry in supply chains. J Bus Logistics 20(2):21–41 Stank TP and Goldsby TJ (2000) A framework for transportation decision making in an integrated supply chain, Supply Chain Management: An International Journal 5(2):71–77 Stock GN, Greis NP, Kasarda JD (2000) Enterprise logistics and supply chain structure: the role of fit. J Oper Manage 18(5):531–547 Swaminathan JM, Tayur SR (2003) Models for supply chains in E-business. Manage Sci 49(10):1387–1406 Tang CS (2006) Perspectives in supply chain risk management. Int J Prod Econ 103(2):451–488 Tang O, Musa SN (2011) Identifying risk issues and research advancements in supply chain risk management, International Journal of Production Economics 133(1):25–34 Thomas DJ, Griffin PM (1996) Coordinated supply chain management. Eur J Oper Res 94(1): 1–15 Tsay A (1999) The quantity flexibility contract and supplier–customer incentives. Manage Sci 45 (10):1339–1358 Tsay AA, Lovejoy WS (1999) Quantity flexibility contracts and supply chain performance. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 1:89–111 vander Rhee B, vander Veen JAA, Venugopal V, Nall VN (2010) A new revenue sharing mechanism for coordinating multi-echelon supply chains. Oper Res Lett 38(4):296–301
82
K. Arshinder et al.
Verwijmeren M, Vlist PV, Donelaar KV (1996) Networked inventory management information systems: materializing supply chain management. Int J Phys Distrib Logistics Manage 26(6):16–31 Vickery SK, Jayaram J, Droge C, Calantone R (2003) The effects of an integrative supply chain strategy on customer service and financial performance: an analysis of direct versus indirect relationships. J Oper Manage 21(5):523–539 Weng ZK (2004) Coordinating order quantities between the manufacturer and the buyer: a generalized newsvendor model. Eur J Oper Res 156(1):148–161 Weng ZK, Parlar M (1999) Integrating early sales with production decisions: analysis and insights, IIE Transactions, 31(11): 1051–1060 Wong WK, Qi J, Leung SYS (2009) Coordinating supply chains with sales rebate contracts and vendor-managed inventory. Int J Prod Econ 120(1):151–161 Wu K, Ouyang L (2003) An integrated single-vendor single-buyer inventory system with shortage derived algebraically. Prod Plann Control 14(6):555–561 Xiao T, Qi X (2008) Price competition, cost and demand disruptions and coordination of a supply chain with one manufacturer and two competing retailers. Omega 36:741–753 Xu L and Beamon B (2006) Supply Chain Coordination and Cooperation Mechanisms: An Attribute-Based Approach, The Journal of Supply Chain Management 42(1):4–12 Xu R, Zhai X (2010) Analysis of supply chain coordination under fuzzy demand in a two-stage supply chain. Appl Math Model 34:129–139 Yang PC, Wee HM (2002) A single-vendor and multiple buyers production-inventory policy for deteriorating item. Eur J Oper Res 143(3):570–581 Yao MJ, Chiou CC (2004) On a replenishment coordination model in an integrated supply chain with one vendor and multiple buyers. Eur J Oper Res 159(2):406–419 Yao D, Yue X, Wang X, Liu JJ (2005) The impact of information sharing on a returns policy with the addition of a direct channel. Int J Prod Econ 97(2):196–209 Yao Z, Leung SCH, Lai KK (2008) Analysis of the impact of price sensitivity factors on the returns policy in coordinating supply chain. Eur J Oper Res 187(1):275–282 Yokoyama M (2002) Integrated optimisation of inventory-distribution systems by random local search and a genetic algorithm. Comput Ind Eng 42(2–4):175–188 Yu Z, Yan H and Cheng TCE (2001) Benefits of information sharing with supply chain partnerships, Industrial Management and Data Systems 101(3):114–119 Yue X, Raghunathan S (2007) The impacts of the full returns policy on a supply chain with information asymmetry. Eur J Oper Res 180(2):630–647 Yusuf Y, Gunasekaran A, Abthorpe MS (2004) Enterprise information systems project implementation: a case study of ERP in Rolls-Royce. Int J Prod Econ 87(3):251–266 Zhao W, Wang Y (2002) Coordination of joint pricing-production decisions in a supply chain. IIE Trans 34(8):701–715 Zhao X, Xie J, Zhang WJ (2002) The impact of information sharing and ordering coordination on supply chain performance. Supply Chain Manage Int J 7(1):24–40 Zhou H, Benton WC Jr (2007) Supply chain practice and information sharing. J Oper Manage 25(6):1348–1365 Zhou YW, Wang SD (2009) Manufacturer-buyer coordination for newsvendor products with two ordering opportunities and partial backorders. Eur J Oper Res 198(3):958–974 Zimmer K (2004) Supply chain coordination with uncertain just-in-time delivery. Int J Prod Econ 77:1–15 Zou X, Pokharel S, Piplani R (2004) Channel coordination in an assembly system facing uncertain demand with synchronized processing time and delivery quantity. Int J Prod Res 42(22):4673–4689 Zou X, Pokharel S, Piplani R (2008) A two-period supply contract model for a decentralized assembly system. Eur J Oper Res 187(1):257–274 Zsidisin GA, Ellram LM (2001) Activities related to purchasing and supply management involvement in supplier alliances. Int J Phys Distrib Logistics Manage 31(9):629–646 Zsidsin GA, Smith ME (2005) Managing supply risk with early supplier involvement: a case study and research propositions. J Supply Chain Manage 41(4):44–57
Control Policies for Multi-echelon Inventory Systems with Stochastic Demand Qinan Wang
Abstract Although supply chain management has become an important management paradigm, the optimal control of a stochastic multi-echelon supply chain inventory system is still largely an open issue. An inventory control policy for such a system has to consider at least three aspects: order coordination, information sharing, and stock or risk pooling. Each aspect can generate significant benefits. Nevertheless, an inventory control policy that can fully optimize system performance on all dimensions, even if it exists, would be very difficult to determine. In this paper, we provide a literature review of inventory control policies for multiechelon supply chain systems with uncertain demand. We first review generic policies developed by extending the basic inventory control policies at a single location. Subsequently, we discuss the themes of coordinated replenishment and information sharing for multi-echelon inventory systems and review the relevant literature. This framework highlights the key factors that drive the performance of multi-echelon inventory systems and shed lights on directions of future research in this area. Keywords Multi-echelon inventory control policy • Review • Supply chain management
1 Introduction A supply chain consists of all organizations involved directly or indirectly in the provision of a product and/or service required by end customers. Inventory management in a supply chain spans all movement and storage of raw materials, work-in-process inventory, and finished goods from point of origin to point of consumption. Traditionally, inventory decisions are made locally at each stocking Q. Wang (*) Nanyang Business School, Nanyang Technological University, Singapore, Singapore 639798 e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_4, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
83
84
Q. Wang
point. However, companies have long realized that they can achieve tremendous benefits by integrating their inventory operations with their business partners. Contemporary supply chain management calls for the application of a total systems approach to supply chain inventory management (Jacobs et al. 2009). There has been a great deal written on the control and management of supply chain inventory systems. The literature on supply chain inventory systems has been reviewed from different perspectives (see, e.g., Clark 1972; Federgruen 1993; Axs€ater 1993a, 2003b; Tsay et al. 1998; Ganeshan et al. 1998; Tan 2001; Sahin and Robinson 2002; Li and Wang 2007). In particular, Federgruen (1993) discussed discrete-time centralized planning models, and Axs€ater (1993a, 2003b) discussed continuous-review centralized planning models for multi-level inventory systems with stochastic demand. Tan (2001) reviewed the evolution of the supply chain management philosophy. More recently, Li and Wang (2007) reviewed the literature on coordination mechanisms of supply chain systems. We review the recent developments on centralized control policies for multiechelon inventory systems with stochastic demand in this paper. Except for some special cases, the optimal control of a supply chain inventory system with stochastic demand is still largely an open problem. We attempt to review the literature to highlight the deficiencies of existing multi-echelon inventory control policies in their capacity to optimize system performance. For this purpose, we adopt a framework to review the literature based on the basic inventory control policies at a single facility. As multi-echelon inventory systems are comprised of individual facilities, their control has been treated as an extension of the inventory control problem at a single facility. Consequently, the multi-echelon inventory control literature has been built based on inventory control policies at a single facility. We first review generic inventory control models for multi-echelon inventory systems that are developed by applying inventory control policies at a single facility. This approach helps us understand the evolution, and highlights the fundamental issues and methodologies for the control of multi-echelon inventory systems. However, a multi-echelon inventory control system is not a simple and straightforward extension of inventory control at individual facilities. The control and management of a multi-echelon inventory system brings about completely new issues and challenges. We subsequently discuss these challenges and review the relevant literature. This discussion highlights the deficiencies of the current literature and enhances our understanding about the key factors that drive the performance of multi-echelon inventory systems. The review also points out new challenges and directions for future research on multi-echelon inventory control systems. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Sect. 2, we discuss three basic inventory control policies at a single location, and the structures and issues of multiechelon inventory control systems. Subsequently, in Sects. 3–5, we review multiechelon inventory control systems that are built respectively on the three basic installation inventory control policies. In Sect. 6, we discuss the key factors that drive the performance of multi-echelon inventory systems and review the relevant
Control Policies for Multi-echelon Inventory Systems with Stochastic Demand
85
literature. Finally, in Sect. 7, we conclude the study and summarize possible directions for future research.
2 Multi-echelon Inventory Systems and Control Policies There are various supply chain network structures. The simplest is a serial system that has a single facility at each stage. The next simplest structure is an assembly system in which multiple parts are assembled into a single component and, therefore, a single facility can have multiple suppliers. A distribution system supplies a product to many customers and, therefore, can have multiple customers for a supplier. A tree system combines assembly systems and distribution systems, and a general system can include any of the above as part of the system (Zipkin 2000). A prototype network structure for previous studies on multi-echelon inventory systems is a two-level distribution system whereby a central warehouse supplies a product to a group of retailers. This structure includes a serial system as a special case. An assembly system can also be considered as a special case as it can be decomposed into multiple serial systems under certain conditions (Rosling 1989). More importantly, this structure includes all the fundamental issues for a multiechelon inventory control system and yet does not have the complexity of a general system. Unless otherwise stated, we use the distribution system that is depicted in Fig. 1 for the discussion. Furthermore, we assume that the warehouse obtains supply from a perfectly reliable external source that can fill an order without delay. As illustrated in Fig. 1, an installation is a single facility, and an echelon comprises the facility at the current stage and all facilities at the downstream stages. The following assumptions are typical (1) demand generates randomly and independently at the retailers, (2) all shortages are backordered, (3) all lead times are constant and deterministic, and (4) inventory holding costs and backorder costs are linear. In addition, demand processes are assumed to have stationary and independent increments. This condition holds true for the commonly used compound Poisson demand process and the normal demand model (Rao 2003).
2.1
Basic Inventory Control Policies for a Single Facility
Assume that the central warehouse has unlimited capacity and is perfectly reliable in fulfilling customer orders. Under this condition, inventory control decisions at a retailer can be made independently of inventory control decisions at other facilities in the system. An inventory control policy for the retailer in this case is referred to as an installation inventory control policy. Inventory management at a single facility or installation consists of two fundamental decisions: how much to order and when to order (Zipkin 2000). The objective is to minimize long-run expected inventory related costs including
86
Q. Wang
Echelon Inventory System
External Supplier
Warehouse
Retailer 1
Customer
. . .
Retailer N
Customer
Fig. 1 A two-echelon distribution system
ordering costs, inventory holding costs, and stockout costs. Fundamental trade-offs exist for safety stock and order quantity. Namely, a higher safety stock lowers stockout costs but raises inventory levels or inventory holding costs, and a smaller order quantity (or more frequent ordering) lowers inventory levels or inventory holding costs but increases ordering costs. We desire an inventory control policy that can balance the cost components and minimize their total. There are three basic installation inventory control policies. If inventory positions can be monitored continuously, there are two approaches to decide when to order. We can adopt a stock-based approach to place an order when the inventory position (inventory on hand plus outstanding orders minus backorders) reaches a reorder point or a time-based approach to order periodically in a fixed replenishment interval. The stock-based approach leads to the well-known continuous-review batch-ordering (R, Q) policy, and the time-based approach leads to the fixed-interval order-up-to (S, T) policy. On the other hand, if inventory positions can be monitored only periodically, a base-stock policy is adopted.
2.1.1
The Continuous-Review Batch-Ordering (R, Q) Policy
Under this policy, a batch of Q units is ordered from the supplier when the inventory position drops to a pre-determined reorder point R. The structural properties and optimization procedures for this policy have been well discussed (Silver and Peterson 1998; Zipkin 2000). The two decision variables of this policy, i.e. the reorder point R and order quantity Q, cannot be determined separately. According to Zheng (1992), if the order quantity is determined by the deterministic economic order quantity model,
Control Policies for Multi-echelon Inventory Systems with Stochastic Demand
87
and the reorder point is determined optimally given the order quantity, the maximum cost deviation as compared to the optimal (R, Q) policy is 12.5%.
2.1.2
The Fixed-Interval Order-up-to (S, T) Policy
Under this policy, the inventory position is reviewed in a fixed time interval of T and inventory is ordered, if necessary, at a review point to raise the inventory position to S. Similar to R and Q for the (R, Q) policy, S and T are decision variables for this policy. This policy provides a time-based alternative to the stockbased (R, Q) policy. Although time-based control that uses fixed replenishment schedules to coordinate production and inventory activities has long been a common practice (Graves 1996), the (S, T) policy has not been widely applied in the literature. One reason is that it is dominated by the (R, Q) policy. The structural properties of this policy have been analyzed recently by Rao (2003). It is shown that the long-run inventory related cost under this policy can be much higher than that under the (R, Q) policy. The worst case scenario identified by Rao (2003) is a 43% cost increase. The superiority of the (R, Q) policy comes from the use of continuous review or real time stock information to optimize replenishment decisions.
2.1.3
The Periodic-Review Base-Stock (s, S) Policy
If inventory positions can be monitored only periodically, for example, due to restrictions of physical conditions such as 1 day, 1 week, etc., time is typically modeled as a sequence of discrete time points. Time periods are defined as intervals between time points. Assume that all significant events occur at the time points. The decision problem is then to determine the order quantity at each review point. The problem was first formulated as a dynamic programming model under the assumption that demands at different time points (or equivalently in different time periods) are independent (Arrow et al. 1951; Dvoretzky et al. 1952). Since then, a massive literature on this topic has accumulated. Porteus (1990) provided a thorough review. Assume that the planning horizon is finite or otherwise demand and costs are stationary. The optimal inventory control policy can be fully characterized for this problem. Namely, if there are no economies of scale in ordering, the optimal inventory control policy is to order at each time point to raise the inventory position to a fixed base-stock level S. This policy is referred to as the base-stock policy. If there are economies of scale in ordering, the optimal inventory control policy is a generalization of the single-parameter base-stock policy: order to raise the inventory position to S if the current inventory is less than s (and order nothing otherwise). This modified base-stock policy is referred to as a (s, S) policy. Various algorithms have been developed to compute optimal (s, S) policies (see, e.g., Veinott and Wagner 1965; Zheng and Federgruen 1991).
88
2.2
Q. Wang
Multi-echelon Inventory Control Policies
Regardless of the source of supply, the central warehouse is usually not perfectly reliable and, even if it is, this may not be economically desirable. As such, an order from a retailer will be filled depending on availability of stock at the warehouse. Consequently, the inventory decisions at the retailers and the warehouse cannot be made independently. In other words, inventory control decisions at the warehouse and retailers should be considered together and integratively to optimize system performance. This leads to a multi-echelon inventory control problem. Obviously, each facility in a multi-echelon inventory control system faces the same fundamental decisions and issues for an installation inventory control problem. Therefore, a multi-echelon inventory control policy can be developed by applying an installation inventory control policy at each facility. Indeed most multi-echelon inventory control policies have been developed in this way. These policies are generic multi-echelon inventory control policies. This development provides a framework to review and discuss the multi-echelon inventory control literature. We will review the multi-echelon inventory control models that are developed based on the three basic installation inventory control policies separately in the next three sections. A multi-echelon inventory control system, however, is not a simple and straightforward addition of separate inventory control problems at individual facilities. The control of a multi-echelon inventory system brings about completely new issues and challenges. First, inventory decisions and activities at the warehouse and the retailers must be carefully planned and coordinated. Control policies as a result of local optimization are usually not able to optimize system performance. This issue is particularly important for decentralized supply chains in which inventory control decisions are usually made locally (Li and Wang 2007). Second, information sharing becomes a key driving factor for system performance. Accurate, timely and easily accessible information on demand and stock or advanced commitment from downstream customers can significantly improve system performance. Cachon and Fisher (2000) demonstrated that information sharing can lower system costs by an average of 2.2%, with a maximum of 12.1%. The benefits of demand information may be even higher (Lee et al. 2000). Finally, pooling lead time demand at retailers can also lead to significant reductions in system inventories and/or stockouts. Because of these issues, conventional relationships between installation inventory control policies may no longer be applicable. For example, although the basic (R, Q) policy dominates the basic (S, T) policy at a single facility, a fixed-interval order-up-to policy may perform significantly better than a stock-based batch-ordering policy for a distribution system with multiple retailers. As shown by Wang and Axs€ater (2010) and Wang (2010), although a stock-based batch-ordering policy still has the advantage of using real time stock information, a time-based base-stock policy can provide a better mechanism to coordinate replenishments and pool lead time demand for retailers. When the benefits of order coordination and stock pooling are more significant than the value of stock
Control Policies for Multi-echelon Inventory Systems with Stochastic Demand
89
information, the latter outperforms the former. We discuss these issues and review the relevant literature in Sect. 6. This discussion will highlight the key factors that drive the performance of a multi-echelon inventory control system.
3 Stock-Based Batch-Ordering Policies A typical stock-based batch-ordering policy for a multi-echelon inventory system is to apply a continuous-review ðR; QÞ policy at each facility. This means that a batch of size Q is ordered when the inventory position drops to or below the reorder point R. The batch size and reorder point may vary for different facilities. In addition, the reorder point can be determined based on installation stock or echelon stock. For convenience of discussion, we define the following conditions and parameters (1) there are N retailers, (2) the demand at retailer i follows a simple N P Poisson process with mean li and l ¼ li , and (3) the lead time is Li for retailer i¼1
i and L0 for the warehouse.
3.1
One-for-One Replenishments
Early applications of the (R, Q) policy started with one-for-one replenishments at all facilities. Under this assumption, facility i sets up an order-up-to level Si and orders one unit from the supplier when its inventory position drops to or below Si , or equivalently facility i adopts a continuous-review (R, Q) policy with R ¼ Si 1 and Q ¼ 1. Consider the operations at the warehouse when the warehouse and retailers all adopt one-for-one replenishments. A retailer order at time t is filled immediately if there is stock at the warehouse or otherwise until stock is available. The maximum delay occurs when an order has to be met with a unit ordered from the external supplier at time t. Consequently, all retailer orders placed prior to time t have been filled by time t þ L0 . Therefore, the outstanding orders at time t þ L0 , i.e. units ordered from the external supplier but not yet delivered to the warehouse, are the retailer orders or demands that have occurred between t and t þ L0 . When demand is Poisson, the number of outstanding orders at the warehouse follows a Poisson distribution with mean l L0 . Backorders occur at the warehouse as soon as the number of outstanding orders at the warehouse exceeds the inventory position S0 . Let y denote the number of outstanding orders and EðB0 Þ denote the average number of backorders. We have EðB0 Þ ¼ E½ðy S0 Þþ , where xþ ¼ maxf0; xg. By Little’s law, the average delay at
90
Q. Wang
the warehouse is then equal to EðB0 Þ= l0 . This result holds even if the lead time at the warehouse is stochastic (Axs€ater 1993a). The actual lead time at a retailer is equal to the constant lead time (i.e. Li ) plus a random delay at the warehouse. According to the discussion above, the delay at the warehouse is a random variable with an expected value of EðB0 Þ= l0 . The average lead time at retailer i, denoted by Li , is then equal to Li ¼ Li þ EðB0 Þ= l0 . Sherbrooke (1968) first developed the METRIC approximation by assuming that the lead time at retailer i is constant at Li . With this assumption, expected inventory levels and backorders at the retailers can be easily evaluated. However, this approximation often leads to significant errors. Various subsequent studies have attempted to improve and extend the METRIC approach to other situations (Muckstadt 1973, 1979; Graves 1985; Sherbrooke 1986; Lee and Moinzadeh 1987a). Shortly after the METRIC approximation was introduced, Simon (1971) developed an exact solution for the problem. Exact solution procedures that are more efficient and/or under more general conditions followed (Shanker 1981; Svoronos and Zipkin 1991). In particular, Axs€ater (1990a, 1993c) provided a very efficient recursive procedure to evaluate one-for-one replenishment policies when retailers are identical. Forsberg (1995) provided a solution when demand follows a compound Poisson process. The exact solution has also been extended to the case in which the warehouse adopts a general batch-ordering policy. Let CðSw ; Sr Þ denote the total inventory holding and shortage costs per time unit when applying one-for-one replenishments with inventory positions Sw and Sr at the warehouse and a retailer, respectively. When retailers use one-for-one replenishments and the warehouse adopts a general batch-ordering policy ðRw ; Qw Þ, the total inventory holding and þ Qw RwP shortage costs per time unit is given by ð1= Qw Þ Cðj; Sr Þ (Axs€ater 1993a). j¼Rw þ1
3.2
General Batch-Ordering Policies
Apparently, one-for-one replenishments are applicable only when there are no setup costs for orders. When there are economies of scale in ordering, a general batchordering policy is more appropriate. However, a general batch-ordering policy is usually more difficult to evaluate. Let Qi denote the order quantity of retailer i. Then retailer i places orders to the warehouse according to an Erlang renewal process with Qi stages. As a result, the demand process at the warehouse is a superposition of N such processes. The problem is still tractable for serial systems. For a two-level distribution system with a single retailer or N ¼ 1, let the retailer use a batch-ordering policy ðRr ; Qr Þ and the warehouse adopt a batch-ordering policy ðRw ; Qw Þ (both as batches of Qr ). Using the results for one-for-one replenishments, the total inventory holding and shortage costs per time unit is given by þ Qw RrP þ Qr RwP ð1= Qw Qr Þ Cðj Qr ; kÞ (Axs€ater 1993c). j¼Rw þ1 k¼Rr þ1
Control Policies for Multi-echelon Inventory Systems with Stochastic Demand
91
Many studies have developed batch-ordering inventory control policies for general serial systems. The following are a few notable examples. De Bodt and Graves (1985) developed an approximate solution using a nested policy in which an order is delivered to the retailer upon the arrival of a shipment from the external supplier at the warehouse. Badinelli (1992) put forward a model of the steady-state values of on-hand inventory and backorders at each facility when each member adopts an installation-stock (R, Q) policy. More recently, Chen and Zheng (1994a) first evaluated echelon-stock (R, nQ) policies and developed a recursive procedure to compute the steady-state inventory levels of the system when demand follows a simple Poisson process. Subsequently, they extended the analysis to situations in which demand follows a compound Poisson process and developed near-optimal echelon-stock (R, nQ) policies (Chen and Zheng 1998) and to situations in which materials flow in fixed batch sizes (Chen 2000). In particular, Chen (1999a) proved that, for a two-stage serial system with zero lead time at the warehouse, a nested stock-based batch-ordering policy can achieve at least 94% system optimality. This is probably the only performance evaluation for a multi-echelon batch-ordering policy. When there are multiple retailers, decisions at the retailers must be coordinated and integrated in order to optimize system performance. However, members in a supply chain traditionally have little communication about their demand and inventory activities. As a result, early developments of stock-based batch-ordering policies considered installation policies in which each member makes its inventory decision separately using only local stock and demand information. Deuermeyer and Schwarz (1981) considered a distribution system consisting of one supplier and multiple identical retailers, and developed an installation-stock policy. They approximated each facility as a single-location inventory system and used decomposition as an adaptation of the METRIC technique. The problem has been examined by many others and more accurate approximate solutions have been developed since then (Moinzadeh and Lee 1986; Lee and Moinzadeh 1987a, b; Svoronos and Zipkin 1988). Exact evaluations of on-hand inventories and backorders for the system have been developed by Axs€ater (1993c) when retailers are identical and face independent simple Poisson demand processes. Forsberg (1996) and Axs€ater (2000) then generalized the results to the case of non-identical retailers under simple and compound Poisson demand. Cheung and Hausman (2000) provided exact performance evaluations for the supplier when retailers order in batches of a basic quantity. Other approximate optimizations have been developed by Axs€ater et al. (2002), Axs€ater (2003a) and Gallego et al. (2007). Instead of using local or installation inventory position, a stock-based backordering policy can be developed based on echelon inventory position, or the sum of the local inventory position and the inventory positions at all its downstream members. Since an echelon-stock policy incorporates stock information at downstream facilities for inventory control, it is superior to an installation-stock policy. As shown by Axs€ater and Rosling (1993) and Axs€ater and Juntti (1996), although the relative performance of the two policies seldom deviates by more than 5%, it is
92
Q. Wang
clear that the echelon-stock policy outperforms the installation policy for serial and assembly systems. However, there are two barriers for the wide application of the echelon-stock policy. First, its implementation requires a centralized information system that enables a supply chain member to have access to the demand and inventory information at all its downstream members in order to continuously monitor its echelon stock. Second, echelon-stock policies are usually more difficult to evaluate than installation-stock policies. Axs€ater (1997) and Chen and Zheng (1997) provided exact evaluations of echelon-stock batch-ordering policies for twolevel distribution systems. When there are multiple retailers, neither an installation-stock policy nor an echelon-stock policy fully utilizes the inventory state of a multi-echelon inventory system to optimize system performance. This is obvious for an installation policy since the inventory control at the supplier utilizes no inventory information from the retailers. For an echelon-stock policy, the inventory control decision at the supplier utilizes the echelon-stock (i.e. the total inventory position at all retailers) information rather than the inventory status at the individual retailers. In this sense, neither policy may be able to optimize system performance. Stock-based batch-ordering policies have also been widely used to analyze multi-echelon inventory systems with multiple supply modes (see, e.g., Lee 1987; Moinzadeh and Nahmias 1988; Axs€ater 1990b; Moinzadeh and Schmidt 1991; Johansen and Thorstenson 1998) and information sharing (see, e.g., Bourland et al. 1996; Chen 1998; Gavieneni 2002; Gurbuz et al. 2007). The issue of information sharing will be discussed further in Sect. 6.
4 Fixed-Interval Order-up-to Policies When inventory position can be monitored continuously, most previous research work on multi-echelon inventory systems has been confined to stock-based batchordering policies. Applications of the fixed-interval order-up-to (S, T) policy to build multi-echelon inventory control systems are relatively limited. One reason is that the (S, T) policy is dominated by the (R, Q) policy for a single location. This dominance, however, does not extend to multi-echelon inventory systems. Wang and Axs€ater (2010) and Wang (2010) demonstrated recently that time-based control can perform significantly better than stock-based control under certain conditions for distribution systems with multiple retailers. Previous studies have considered control policies for multi-echelon inventory systems with fixed replenishment intervals. These studies assume that replenishment intervals are determined exogenously but allow the flexibility of coordinating replenishments. A notable feature is the concept of nesting (Graves 1996; van Houtum et al. 2007). This condition is achieved under two constraints: the integer-ratio constraint requires that the replenishment interval at a stage be an integer multiple of the replenishment interval at the next downstream stage; and the synchronization constraint requires that a shipment from an upstream can be
Control Policies for Multi-echelon Inventory Systems with Stochastic Demand
93
forwarded immediately to the next downstream stage if so desired. These policies can be considered as applications of the fixed-interval order-up-to (S, T) with a given interval T. On the other hand, for a given interval T, the decision problem is similar to a periodic-review inventory control problem with constraints on the replenishments at certain time points. Therefore, base-stock policies are adopted at replenishment points. Eppen and Schrage (1981) first considered a fixed replenishment interval policy for retailers to synchronize their replenishments. The retailers are identical, face independent stochastic demand, and order together periodically from an outside supplier through a depot. The replenishment interval is given, and stock is allocated to the retailers entirely and immediately upon its arrival at the depot. In this way, the depot does not carry inventory and acts only as a cross docking point. By assuming large incoming orders that will always result in an equal probability of stockout at each retailer, they derived approximately optimal base- stock policies at the depot. Subsequently, Schwarz (1989) and Kumar et al. (1995) adopted fixed replenishment interval policies to study the benefits of stock pooling. McGavin et al. (1993, 1997) used this structure to analyze warehouse inventory allocation policies to minimize system lost sales. Atkins and Iyogun (1988), Viswanathan (1997), and Eynan and Kropp (1998), among others, studied joint replenishment policies, and Cetinkaya and Lee (2000) analyzed time-based consolidation policies for vendor-managed inventory systems. In addition, a number of studies have been devoted to optimal control policies for multi-echelon inventory systems when replenishment intervals at all facilities are given (Yano and Carson 1988; Jackson 1988; Graves 1996; Axs€ater 1993b; van Houtum et al. 2007). A few studies have considered full decision models to optimize system performance on both replenishment interval and inventory control policies recently. Feng and Rao (2007) applied the ðS; TÞ policy to a two-stage serial system. They considered the “fixed reorder interval, T, order-up-to base-stock level, R” policy and refer to this policy as the echelon-stock (R, nT) policy. The decision problem is formulated as a mixed-integer nonlinear programming model, in which the cost under each decision alternative is obtained by simulation. They compared the (R, nT) policy to the (R, nQ) policy (Chen and Zheng 1994a, b) numerically and showed that, although the latter dominates the former, the cost differences are often not significant. More recently, Wang and Axs€ater (2010) developed a fixed-interval order-up-to policy for a distribution system with multiple retailers. Let the warehouse set up a basic replenishment period T. Retailers are required to replenish through the warehouse in intervals that are integer multiples of the basic replenishment period. No inventory is carried at the warehouse. They compared this policy to the stockstock batch-ordering policy (Axs€ater 1993c) and showed that the dominance of the latter at a single location does not extend to distribution systems with multiple retailers. The time-based policy can perform significantly better than the stockbased batch-ordering policy in certain situations. However, since the warehouse is restricted to a cross-docking point that does not carry inventory, the efficiency of this policy could be low if the cost of carrying inventory at the warehouse is low.
94
Q. Wang
Subsequently, Wang (2010) generalized this model to allow the warehouse to carry inventory and developed a general integer-ratio policy for a distribution system with multiple and identical retailers. Another motivation for this development is the remarkable achievements of the integer-ratio policy in deterministic settings (Roundy 1985, 1986). Let the warehouse set up a base replenishment interval to replenish inventories from the external supplier. Retailers are required to review their inventory positions and order in fixed time intervals that are integer or integer-ratio multiples of the base replenishment interval at the warehouse. The warehouse and retailers each adopt an echelon-stock order-up-to policy, i.e. order the needed inventories to raise the echelon inventory position to a fixed order-up-to level at each review point. It is shown numerically that, although the stock-based batch-ordering policy generates a lower system cost in many cases, the integer-ratio policy can perform significantly better in certain settings.
5 Periodic-Review Base-Stock Policies When time is discrete, the problem is usually formulated as a dynamic programming or Markov decision model. However, except for some special cases, the large dimension of the inventory state for the exact formulation usually precludes an exact solution. The focus is then shifted to approximate solutions.
5.1
Serial Systems
Clark and Scarf (1960) showed that, for a serial system with M stages, if the planning horizon is finite and there is no setup cost except at the highest installation, the inventory problem for the system can be decomposed into exactly M separate single location problems, one for each echelon. These problems can be specified and solved recursively starting from the highest echelon. The optimal solution at the highest echelon is a ðsM ; SM Þ policy: order the necessary stock from the external supplier to raise the system inventory position to an order-up-to level SM whenever the starting inventory position is at or below a reorder point sM ; the optimal solution at a lower echelon j < M is a modified base stock policy: set up a base stock level Sj for echelon j < M, and ship the necessary stock from the upper level if there is sufficient stock and otherwise whatever available to raise the inventory position at the echelon to Sj . The model and solution were originally suggested by Clark (1958). The seminal work by Clark (1958) and Clark and Scarf (1960, 1962) initiated the research on the optimal control of multi-echelon inventory systems. The basic model and solution have been generalized to various settings since then. Federgruen
Control Policies for Multi-echelon Inventory Systems with Stochastic Demand
95
and Zipkin (1984a) extended the basic model to the infinite-horizon case for both discounted and average costs, and showed that the computations required are much easier than for the finite-horizon case. They also considered the case with multiple locations at the lower echelon and showed that the problem can be approximated by a problem with a single location at the lower echelon. Subsequently, Zipkin (1986a, b) considered the problem with uncertain lead times. Chen (2000) considered optimal control policies for multi-stage serial or assembly inventory systems with batch ordering, and generalized several existing results for the basic model. Recently, van Houtum et al. (2007) generalized the results to serial inventory systems with fixed replenishment intervals. They proved the optimality of the (s, S) policy for a serial system under the integer and synchronization constraints when replenishments intervals are given. Chen and Song (2001) considered a serial system in which demand generates at stage one in each period according to a distribution that is determined by the current state of an exogenous Markov Chain, and showed that the optimal policy for the system is an echelon-stock base-stock policy with state-dependent order-up-to levels. Shang and Song (2003, 2007) and Gallego and Ozer (2003, 2005) developed simple heuristics and bounds and approximations for the optimal policy parameters. Recently, Chao and Zhou (2009) extended the results to serial systems with batch ordering and fixed replenishment schedules. The results for a serial system have been generalized to assembly systems. Schmidt and Nahmias (1985) considered a simple assembly system in which two components are purchased from outside and assembled into a single end item, and characterized the optimal policy. Subsequently, building on Schmidt and Nahmias (1985), Rosling (1989) showed that, when all order and assembly cost functions are linear, an assembly system can be transformed into an equivalent serial system. All carrying, outside order and assembly costs remain linear in the equivalent system. Therefore, an optimal control policy is to apply modified base stock policies in each period for all nodes. The result holds for both finite planning horizon and infinite planning horizon models. Song and Yao (2002) considered the performance and optimization of assembly systems with random lead times. By modeling an assembly system under a given base-stock policy as a M=G=1 queuing system, they derived easy-to-compute performance bounds. When there are setup costs at all stages, it is well known that the optimal control of the inventory system is difficult. Only heuristic solutions and approximations have been developed. Chen and Zheng (1994b) developed lower bounds for multi-echelon stochastic inventory systems including serial, assembly and distribution systems with multiple retailers in which economies of scale in ordering exist at all locations. Recently, Shang and Zhou (2010) considered (r, nQ, T) policies. Under such a policy, each stage reviews its inventory in every T periods and orders according to an echelon-stock (r, nQ) policy. There are two types of fixed costs: one for each order batch Q and another for each inventory review. They developed a method for obtaining heuristic and optimal policy parameters.
96
5.2
Q. Wang
General Systems
Similar to serial systems with setup costs at all stages, an optimal control policy that can fully optimize system performance for a distribution system with multiple retailers is unknown. Previous studies have focused on heuristic solutions and approximations under various restrictions. The reader is referred to Federgruen (1993) for a systematic and detailed discussion on such restrictions and approximations. A number of studies have considered control policies under the restriction that the warehouse does not hold inventory. Under this condition, the warehouse acts as only a cross docking point and a delivery at the warehouse is allocated immediately and entirely to retailers. Eppen and Schrage (1981) started the use of this restriction. Subsequently, Federgruen and Zipkin (1984b) showed that a distribution system with multiple retailers can be approximated by a single-location problem under this condition. Recently, Wang and Axs€ater (2010) adopted this setting to develop a fixedinterval order-up-to policy for a two-level distribution system with multiple retailers. When multiple retailers order from the warehouse at a common point in time, stock allocation becomes an important issue. Federgruen and Zipkin (1984c) provided a systematic and detailed discussion on this problem. They showed that, when stock is allocated based on the inventory positions at individual retailers, the state space of the dynamic programming problem has a very large dimension, which usually precludes an exact solution of the model. They developed a computationally tractable approximate solution with myopic stock allocation. Under a myopic stock allocation policy, an incoming order at the warehouse is allocated to retailers to minimize their expected costs in the very first period in which the allocation has an impact, i.e. in the period where the shipments arrive at their destinations. Since then, different allocation approaches have been considered. A cycle allocation policy allocates an incoming order at the warehouse to retailers to minimize their expected costs in an ordering cycle, i.e. the period from the arrival of the current shipments to the arrival of the shipments from the next order (Federgruen 1993). A general reservation policy reserves a unit of supply at the time of a demand event at a retailer, and ships the reserved supply together to a retailer according to a fixed schedule or when inventory becomes available. This allocation method was also called “virtual allocation” by Graves (1996) and Axs€ater (1993c). To maximize the benefits of stock pooling, stock at the warehouse should be allocated in the lastminute or at the time of shipment (Marklund 2006). Several studies also assumed that inventory positions can be balanced at an allocation point if necessary (see, e.g., Eppen and Schrage 1981; Federgruen and Zipkin 1984c; McGavin et al. 1993; Axs€ater et al. 2002; Sosic 2006). This balance condition means simply that transshipments among retailers or allocation of negative quantities are allowed, although this is not always possible in practice. According to Wang and Axs€ater (2010), allocation policies can have a significant impact on system costs. They showed that system costs may increase by more than 30% under certain conditions when stock at the warehouse is allocated according to a complete reservation allocation policy as compared to a last-minute allocation policy.
Control Policies for Multi-echelon Inventory Systems with Stochastic Demand
97
Despite these progresses, exact evaluations and solutions are rare. Cachon (2001) provided exact evaluations for average inventory, backorders and fill rates for a two-echelon distribution system with multiple retailers and batch-ordering. Chen and Zheng (1994b) established lower bounds for serial, assembly and distribution systems with setup costs at all stages. Although many studies have provided full or partial characterizations of optimal polices for some special cases (see, e.g., Chen 2004a, b; Fox et al. 2006; Chao and Zipkin 2008; Sheopuri et al. 2010), a general optimal solution is hard, if not impossible. The reader may refer to Glasserman and Tayur (1994, 1995), Kapuscinski and Tayur (1998), Gallego and Toktay (2004), Ozer and Wei (2004), Chao and Zipkin (2008), and the references herein for capacitated multi-echelon inventory systems; and Tagaras and Vlachos (2001), Feng et al. (2006), Sheopuri et al. (2010), and the references herein for multi-echelon inventory systems with multiple supply modes.
6 Coordinated Replenishment and Information Sharing Despite the great progresses over the years, we seem to know little about the key factors that drive the performance of a multi-echelon inventory control system (Gallego et al. 2007). This is particularly the case for systems with multiple facilities at a stage (e.g. a distribution system with multiple retailers). Many control policies for multi-echelon inventory systems have been developed by extending installation control policies. However, a multi-echelon inventory control system is more than a simple addition of inventory control problems at individual facilities. It brings about completely new issues and challenges. We discuss two such issues and review the relevant literature in this section.
6.1
Coordinated Replenishment
In general, coordinated replenishment centralizes and synchronizes the ordering decisions for retailers. There are two distinct potential benefits. First, when retailers order together, they may achieve economies of scale in ordering such as quantity discounts from the outside supplier, savings in transportation costs, etc. Second, the system can choose to allocate the stock among the retailers at the time of shipment rather than at the time of ordering. Postponing the allocation allows the system to observe the demands at the retailers in the warehouse lead time, and thus to make a better informed allocation. This can result in significant system cost reductions. Eppen and Schrage (1981) coined the term “statistical economies of scale” for these benefits. This effect is also commonly called the benefits of stock pooling in the literature. Coordinated replenishment for multiple products is commonly referred to as the joint replenishment problem and has been studied extensively (Federgruen et al. 1984;
98
Q. Wang
Khouja and Goyal 2008). The objective is to achieve economies of scale in ordering. Apparently, similar benefits can be achieved by coordinating replenishments for multiple retailers in a supply chain. Axs€ater and Zhang (1999) attempted to develop a joint replenishment policy for a distribution system, but did not find an appropriate policy to improve system performance. A more efficient policy was developed subsequently by Cheung and Lee (2002). They considered a supplier serving multiple retailers and developed the following joint replenishment policy. Let each retailer set up a target inventory position. As demands arrive at the retailers, the inventory positions at the retailers drop below their respective targets. When the cumulative demands over all retailers reach a batch size Q, the supplier orders the quantity from a warehouse to restore the inventory positions at the retailers to their respective target levels. The orders from the warehouse are transported from the external supplier directly to the retailers. The supplier does not carry inventory and acts as only a cross-docking point. They showed that the joint replenishment policy dominates the installation-stock batch-ordering policy (Axs€ater 1993c). The benefits of coordinated replenishments for multiple retailers in a supply chain, however, are beyond the traditional economies of scale in ordering. Cheung and Lee (2002) showed that, if orders from the warehouse are first transported to the supplier and then allocated and shipped to the retailers upon their arrival at the supplier, system costs can be further reduced significantly. This is due to the statistical economies of scale. Eppen and Schrage (1981) first studied this effect by synchronizing ordering decisions for a group of identical retailers. Subsequently, Jackson (1988) extended the basic model to allow the warehouse to carry inventory and demonstrated empirically the benefits of centralizing at least a portion of the total system stock. Schwarz (1989) assessed the value of stock pooling by comparing two systems. In system one, inventories are ordered and shipped directly from an outside supplier to each retailer separately. In system two, this is done through a warehouse, thereby inventories are ordered together and allocated and shipped to the retailers upon their arrival. The effect of stock pooling is measured by the overall reduction in variance of the retailer end-of-cycle net inventory. Kumar et al. (1995) studied this effect along a fixed delivery route using a dynamic inventory control policy. McGavin et al. (1993, 1997) analyzed warehouse inventory allocation policies to minimize system lost sales. Other studies have considered stock pooling in various situations (see, e.g., Eynan and Fouque 2003; Benjaafar et al. 2005; Ve´ricourt et al. 2002; Kukreja et al. 2001; Wee and Dada 2005). In particular, Wang and Axs€ater (2010) and Wang (2010) showed that fixedinterval order-up-to polices are able to provide a more efficient mechanism for supply chain members to coordinate replenishments than stock-based batch-ordering policies. Because of the benefits of coordinated replenishment, particularly the statistical economies of scale, time-based control policies can perform significantly better than stock-based control policies for distribution systems with multiple retailers.
Control Policies for Multi-echelon Inventory Systems with Stochastic Demand
6.2
99
Demand and Stock Information
Iglehart (1964) initiated the research on the use of demand information in inventory control. He considered the inventory control problem for a single location facing a demand distribution with unknown parameters, and developed a Bayesian estimation scheme to update the demand distribution with new information for inventory control. This problem has been studied subsequently by many others (Azoury 1985; Lovejoy 1990; Milner and Kouvelis 2002). Furthermore, Zheng and Zipkin (1990) started to quantify the value of information sharing among multiple products and/or facilities. They considered the scheduling problem for two items competing for a single production facility, and showed that information about outstanding orders of the two products could improve system performance. Zipkin (1995) extended the analysis to a multi-item production facility subsequently. Supply chain management brings about a new issue of sharing information across supply chain members. A massive literature has accumulated on the use of stock and demand information (Gunasekaran and Ngai 2004). Bourland et al. (1996) considered the use of stock information to improve inventory control decisions. They considered a two-level serial system with a supplier and a single retailer, and demonstrated that the supplier could improve its replenishment decision by making use of stock information at the retailer. In the meantime, a number of studies analyzed the use of information sharing to reduce the bullwhip effect in supply chain systems (Lee et al. 1997; Lee and Whang 1999; Chen et al. 2000). The recent interest has focused on the use of advance demand information to improve the efficiency of multi-echelon inventory control systems (see, e.g., Hariharan and Zipkin 1995; Gallego and Ozer 2001; Iyer and Ye 2000; Ozer 2003; Marklund 2006; Axs€ater and Marklund 2008; Wang and Toktay 2008). Many studies have evaluated the value of stock and demand information in supply chain management. The evaluations, however, varied for different studies. Chen (1998) studied the benefits of stock information by comparing the costs for a multi-echelon serial system when using an echelon-stock batch-ordering policy and an installation-stock batch-ordering policy. He observed that echelon-stock information could reduce system cost by an average cost of 1.75%, with a maximum of 9%. Gavieneni et al. (1999) and Gavieneni (2002) considered a similar setting with a capacitated manufacturer and a single retailer, and observed higher values for stock information, ranging from 1 to 35% of system inventory related cost with an average of 14%. In the meantime, Cachon and Fisher (2000) considered a setting with one supplier and N identical retailers. They contrasted the value of information sharing with faster and cheaper order processing, which led to shorter lead times and smaller batch sizes, respectively, and found that implementing information technology to accelerate and smooth the physical flow of goods through a supply chain was significantly more valuable than to expand the flow of information. Furthermore, Gurbuz et al. (2007) extended the joint replenishment policy developed by Cheung and Lee (2002) to use retailer stock information to trigger a joint replenishment order. Following Moinzadeh (2002), they proposed a second-order
100
Q. Wang
trigger rule based on a minimum inventory position at each retailer so that an order is placed to the outside supplier when any retailer’s inventory position drops to a minimum requirement level or the demand at all retailers accumulates to Q units, whichever is earlier. They showed numerically that stock information could improve the joint replenishment policy. However, the improvements were only moderate. Evaluations for the value of demand information varied even greater. Lee et al. (2000) considered a two-level supply chain that consists of a manufacturer and a single retailer who faces a non-stationary auto-correlated demand process, and showed that the manufacturer would experience great savings when demand information was shared by the downstream member. The analysis was subsequently extended by Aviv (2002) to a setting in which companies could observe early market signals to improve their forecasting performance. However, Raghunathan (2001, 2003) pointed out later that the finding of Lee et al. (2000) depends on the critical assumptions that the manufacturer uses only the most recent order information from the retailer to forecast its future orders and that the parameters of the demand process are only accessed by the retailer. If the parameters of the autocorrelated demand process are known to both parties, sharing of demand information is actually of limited value. As the manufacturer can forecast the demand by using the retailer’s order history and the accuracy of forecast increases monotonically with each subsequent time period, the value of information decreases monotonically with each time period and converges to zero. Since the entire retailer order history is available to the manufacturer, the manufacturer is in a position to use the data in its forecasting process. Graves (1999) made similar observations in a slightly different setting.
7 Conclusions and Discussions To summarize the literature review, let us consider the distribution system that is described in Sect. 2. Suppose time is continuous and there are multiple retailers. Several alternative policies have been developed for the inventory control system in the literature. We list these policies in Table 1 below. Previous studies have shown that, if everything else holds constant, (1) Policy 2 dominates Policy 1 because echelon stock provides more accurate information about the system inventory state, (2) the joint replenishment (JR) policies, i.e. Policies 3, 4, and 5, dominate Policy 1, also because joint replenishment utilizes more accurate system stock information, (3) Policy 4 dominates Policy 3 due to the effect of stock pooling, and (4) Policy 5 dominates Policy 3 because more accurate information about the inventory state at retailers is used. Policy 4, Policy 5, and Policy 6 do not dominate each other. These relationships reflect the state of the art for the developments of multiechelon inventory control systems. Optimal control of a multi-echelon inventory system is still largely an open problem. First of all, little is known about the format
Control Policies for Multi-echelon Inventory Systems with Stochastic Demand
101
Table 1 Policies for a distribution system with multiple retailers Policy Policy description References Installation-stock Apply the stock-based (R, Q) policy Axs€ater (1993c, 2000), Forsberg batch-ordering at each facility based on (1997), Cheung and Hausman policy installation stock (2000) Echelon-stock batchApply the stock-based (R, Q) policy Axs€ater (1997), Axs€ater and ordering policy at each facility based on echelon Rosling (1993), Chen and stock Zheng (1997) JR policy without stock Order for all retailers when their Axs€ater and Zhang (1999), pooling demands accumulate to a fixed Cheung and Lee (2002) batch size and ship stock to each retailer directly from the outside supplier JR policy with stock Order for all retailers when their Cheung and Lee (2002) pooling demands accumulate to a fixed batch size and ship stock to a depot where the stock is optimally allocated JR policy using retailer Order for all retailers when their Gurbuz et al. (2007) stock information demands accumulate to a fixed but no stock pooling batch size and/or the inventory position at a retailer reaches a trigger level, and ship stock to each retailer directly from the outside supplier Fixed-interval orderApply the time-based (S, T) policy at Eppen and Schrage (1981), up-to policy each facility based on echelon Jackson (1988), Schwarz stock (1989), Wang and Axs€ater (2010)
of an optimal control policy. Stock-based batch-ordering policies and time-based order-up-to policies have been developed based respectively on the basic (R, Q) policy and (S, T) policy for a single facility. These formats have been adopted mostly because of convenience rather than optimality. For a single facility, the stock-based (R, Q) policy can be optimal and dominates the time-based (S, T) policy. This dominance can carry over to serial systems but not to distribution systems with multiple retailers. Second, little seems to be known about the factors that drive the performance for a multi-echelon inventory system. Previous studies have shown that an optimal policy has to consider at least three aspects (a) careful planning and coordination of inventory activities at the warehouse and retailers, (b) use of accurate and timely stock and demand information, and (c) pooling of stocks. However, the evaluations of these benefits varied significantly for different studies. For example, evaluations for the value of information varied from almost zero to an average system cost reduction of more than 10%. Apparently, the significance of these benefits depends on the setting and the inventory control policy adopted for the study, among other possible confounding factors. Trade-off often exists. For example, a setting or a format of inventory control policy that can fully utilize stock information may not
102
Q. Wang
be able to maximize the benefits of order coordination and stock pooling. Consequently, an inventory control policy that can fully optimize system performance, even if it exists, would be extremely difficult to structure and determine. As a result, the research on multi-echelon inventory control systems has focused on the identification of close-to-optimal policies that have a relatively simple structure and are reasonably easy to determine and implement. While this trend will continue, the question on the efficiency of an inventory control policy to optimize system performance will always be a challenge. Current inventory control policies have focused on some but not all driving factors for system performance. For example, stock-based policies focus more on using stock information to optimize replenishment decisions. In contrast, time-based policies focus more on coordinating system replenishments for both the traditional and statistical economies of scale. In view of these developments, while performance evaluations on multi-echelon inventory control policies to optimize system performance are very desirable, we may develop more efficient multi-echelon inventory control policies by combining the features of different policy formats. Finally, we have focused exclusively on multi-echelon inventory systems where decisions can be centralized by a unique decision maker to optimize system performance. Although many studies have considered decentralized multi-echelon inventory control systems (see, e.g., Cachon and Zipkin 1999; Chen 1999b; Axs€ater 2001, 2005; Caldentey and Wein 2003), the literature on decentralized systems is still limited as compared to the literature on centralized systems. This is inadequate, given the fact that most supply chains consist of members who are separate and independent economic entities. One reason for this inadequacy is that, although a centralized solution can optimize system performance, it is not always in the best interest of every individual member. Therefore, the implementation of a centralized solution or the coordination of a decentralized supply chain that aims to optimize system performance must have a mechanism to align the objectives of individual supply chain members. While a lot of research has been done on this subject for deterministic supply chains (Li and Wang 2007), relatively little seems to have been done on the topic for stochastic supply chain systems. Consequently, the coordination of decentralized multi-echelon inventory systems with stochastic demand and/or lead time represents great opportunities and challenges for future research.
References Arrow K, Harris T, Marschak J (1951) Optimal inventory policy. Econometrica 19:250–272 Atkins D, Iyogun P (1988) Periodic versus ‘can-order’ policies for coordinated multi-item inventory systems. Manage Sci 34:791–796 Aviv Y (2002) Gaining benefits from joint forecasting and replenishment processes: the case of auto-correlated demand. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 4(1):55–74 Axs€ater S (1990a) Simple solution procedures for a class of two-echelon inventory problems. Oper Res 38:64–69 Axs€ater S (1990b) Modeling emergency lateral transshipments in inventory systems. Manage Sci 36:1329–1338
Control Policies for Multi-echelon Inventory Systems with Stochastic Demand
103
Axs€ater S (1993a) Continuous review policies for multi-level inventory systems with stochastic demand. In: Graves S, Rinnooy Kan A, Zipkin P (eds) Handbooks in operations research and management science, vol 4, Logistics of production and inventory. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 175–197 Axs€ater S (1993b) Optimization of order-up-to-S policies in two-echelon inventory systems with periodic-review. Nav Res Logist 40:245–253 Axs€ater S (1993c) Exact and approximate evaluation of batch-ordering policies for two-level inventory systems. Oper Res 41(4):777–785 Axs€ater S (1997) Simple evaluation of echelon stock (R, Q) policies for two-level inventory systems. IIE Trans 29:661–669 Axs€ater S (2000) Exact analysis of continuous review (R, Q) policies in two-echelon inventory systems with compound Poisson demand. Oper Res 48(5):686–696 Axs€ater S (2001) A framework for decentralized multi-echelon inventory control. IIE Trans 33:91–97 Axs€ater S (2003a) Approximate optimization of a two-level distribution inventory system. Int J Prod Econ 81–82:545–553 Axs€ater S (2003b) Supply chain operations: serial and distribution inventory systems. In: Graves SC, de Kok T (eds) Supply chain management: design, coordination, and operation. Handbooks in operations research and management science, vol 11, Chap. 10. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 525–559 Axs€ater S (2005) A simple decision rule for decentralized two-echelon inventory control. Int J Prod Econ 93–94:53–59 Axs€ater S, Juntti L (1996) Comparison of echelon stock and installation stock policies for twolevel inventory systems. Int J Prod Econ 45:303–310 Axs€ater S, Marklund J (2008) Optimal position-based warehouse ordering in divergent twoechelon inventory systems. Oper Res 56(4):976–991 Axs€ater S, Rosling K (1993) Installation vs. echelon stock policies for multilevel inventory control. Manage Sci 39(10):1274–1280 Axs€ater S, Zhang W (1999) A joint replenishment policy for multi-echelon inventory control. Int J Prod Econ 59:243–250 Axs€ater S, Marklund J, Silver EA (2002) Heuristic methods for centralized control of onewarehouse, N-retailer inventory systems. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 4(1):75–97 Azoury K (1985) Bayes solutions to dynamic inventory models under unknown demand distributions. Manage Sci 31(9):1150–1160 Badinelli R (1992) A model for continuous-review pull policies in serial inventory systems. Oper Res 40(1):142–156 Benjaafar S, Cooper W, Kim J (2005) On the benefits of pooling in production-inventory systems. Manage Sci 51(4):548–565 Bourland K, Powell S, Pyke D (1996) Exploiting timely demand information to reduce inventories. Eur J Oper Res 92:239–253 Cachon G (2001) Exact evaluation of batch-ordering inventory policies in two-echelon supply chains with periodic review. Oper Res 49(1):79–98 Cachon G, Fisher M (2000) Supply chain inventory management and the value of shared information. Manage Sci 46(8):1032–1048 Cachon G, Zipkin P (1999) Competitive and cooperative inventory policies in a two-stage supply chain. Manage Sci 45(7):936–953 Caldentey R, Wein L (2003) Analysis of a decentralized production-inventory system. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 5(1):1–17 Cetinkaya S, Lee C (2000) Stock replenishment and shipment scheduling for vendor managed inventory. Manage Sci 46(2):217–232 Chao X, Zhou S (2009) Optimal policy for a multiechelon inventory system with batch ordering and fixed replenishment intervals. Oper Res 57(2):377–391
104
Q. Wang
Chao X, Zipkin P (2008) Optimal policy for a periodic-review system under a supply capacity contract. Oper Res 56(1):59–70 Chen F (1998) Echelon reorder points, installation reorder points, and the value of centralized demand information. Manage Sci 44(12):S221–S234 Chen F (1999a) 94%-effective policies for a two-stage serial inventory system with stochastic demand. Manage Sci 45(12):1679–1696 Chen F (1999b) Decentralized supply chains subject to information delays. Manage Sci 45 (8):1076–1090 Chen F (2000) Optimal policies for multi-echelon inventory problems with batch ordering. Oper Res 48(3):376–389 Chen S (2004a) The optimality of hedging point policies for stochastic two-product flexible manufacturing systems. Oper Res 52(2):321–323 Chen S (2004b) The infinite horizon periodic review problem with setup costs and capacity constraints: a partial characterization of the optimal policy. Oper Res 52(3):409–421 Chen F, Song J (2001) Optimal policies for multi-echelon inventory problems with Markovmodulated demand. Oper Res 49(2):226–234 Chen F, Zheng Y (1994a) Evaluating echelon stock (R, nQ) policies in serial production/inventory systems with stochastic demand. Manage Sci 40(10):1262–1275 Chen F, Zheng Y (1994b) Lower bounds for multi-echelon stochastic inventory systems. Manage Sci 40(11):1426–1443 Chen F, Zheng Y (1997) One-warehouse multi-retailer systems with centralized stock information. Oper Res 45(2):275–287 Chen F, Zheng Y (1998) Near-optimal echelon-stock (R, nQ) policies in multistage serial system. Oper Res 46(4):592–602 Chen F, Drezner Z, Ryan J, Simchi-Levi D (2000) Quantifying the bullwhip effect in a simple supply chain: the impact of forecasting lead time and information. Manage Sci 46(3):436–443 Cheung K, Hausman W (2000) An exact performance evaluation for the supplier in a two-echelon inventory system. Oper Res 48(4):646–653 Cheung K, Lee H (2002) The inventory benefit of shipment coordination and stock rebalancing in a supply chain. Manage Sci 48(2):300–306 Clark A (1958) A dynamic, single-item, multi-echelon inventory model. Report. Rand Corporation, Santa Monica, CA Clark A (1972) An informal survey of multi-echelon inventory theory. Nav Res Logistics Q 19:621–650 Clark A, Scarf H (1960) Optimal policies for a multi-echelon inventory problem. Manage Sci 6 (4):475–490 Clark A, Scarf H (1962) Approximate solutions to a simple multi-echelon inventory problem. In: Arrow KJ, Karlin S, Scarf H (eds) Studies in applied probability and management science. Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA De Bodt M, Graves S (1985) Continuous review policies for a multi-echelon inventory problem with stochastic demand. Manage Sci 31(10):1286–1299 Deuermeyer B, Schwarz L (1981) A model for the analysis of system service level in warehouse/ retailer distribution systems: the identical retailer case. In: Schwarz LB (ed) Studies in the management sciences, vol 16, Multi-level production/inventory control systems. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 163–193 Dvoretzky A, Kiefer J, Wolfowitz J (1952) The inventory problem. Econometrica 20:187–222 Eppen G, Schrage L (1981) Centralized ordering policies in a multiwarehouse system with leadtimes and random demand. In: Schwarz LB (ed) Studies in the management sciences, vol 16, Multi-level production/inventory control systems. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 88–110 Eynan A, Fouque T (2003) Capturing the risk-pooling effect through demand reshape. Manage Sci 49(6):704–717
Control Policies for Multi-echelon Inventory Systems with Stochastic Demand
105
Eynan A, Kropp D (1998) Periodic review and joint replenishment in stochastic demand environment. IIE Trans 30:1025–1033 Federgruen A (1993) Centralized planning models for multi-echelon inventory systems under uncertainty. In: Graves S, Rinnooy Kan A, Zipkin P (eds) Handbooks in operations research and management science, vol 4, Logistics of production and inventory. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 133–173 Federgruen A, Zipkin P (1984a) Computational issues in an infinite-horizon, multi-echelon inventory model. Oper Res 32(4):818–836 Federgruen A, Zipkin P (1984b) Approximations of dynamic, multilocation production and inventory systems. Manage Sci 30(1):69–84 Federgruen A, Zipkin P (1984c) Allocation policies and cost approximation for multilocation inventory systems. Nav Res Logistics Q 31:97–131 Federgruen A, Groenevelt H, Tijms H (1984) Coordinated replenishments in a multi-item inventory system with compound Poisson demands and constant lead times. Manage Sci 30:344–357 Feng K, Rao U (2007) Echelon-stock (R, nT) control in two-stage serial stochastic inventory systems. Oper Res Lett 35:95–104 Feng Q, Sethi S, Yan H, Zhang H (2006) Are base-stock policies optimal in inventory problems with multi delivery modes? Oper Res 54(4):801–807 Forsberg R (1995) Optimization of order-up-to-S policies for two-level inventory systems with compound Poisson demand. Eur J Oper Res 81:143–153 Forsberg R (1997) Exact evaluation of (R, Q)-policies for two level inventory systems with Poisson demand. Eur J Oper Res 96:130–138 Fox E, Metters R, Semple J (2006) Optimal inventory policy with two suppliers. Oper Res 56 (4):696–707 Gallego G, Ozer O (2001) Integrating replenishment decisions with advance demand information. Manage Sci 47(10):1344–1360 Gallego G, Ozer O (2003) Optimal replenishment policies for multi-echelon inventory systems under advance demand information. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 5:157–175 Gallego G, Ozer O (2005) A new algorithm and a new heuristic for serial supply systems. Oper Res Lett 33:349–362 Gallego G, Toktay L (2004) All-or-nothing ordering under capacity constrain. Oper Res 52 (6):1001–1002 Gallego G, Ozer O, Zipkin P (2007) Bounds, heuristics, and approximations for distribution systems. Oper Res 55(3):503–517 Ganeshan R, Jack E, Magazine M, Stephens P (1998) A taxonomic review of supply chain management research. In: Tayur S, Magazine M, Ganeshan R (eds) Quantitative models for supply chain management, vol 17, International series in operations research and management science. Kluwer, Norwell, MA, pp 839–879 Gavieneni S (2002) Information flows in capacitated supply chains with fixed ordering cost. Manage Sci 48(5):644–651 Gavieneni S, Kapuscinski R, Tayur S (1999) Value of information in capacitated supply chains. Manage Sci 45(1):16–24 Glasserman P, Tayur S (1994) The stability of a capacitated, multi-echelon production-inventory system under a base-stock policy. Oper Res 42(5):913–925 Glasserman P, Tayur S (1995) Sensitivity analysis for base-stock levels in multi-echelon production-inventory systems. Manage Sci 41(2):263–281 Graves S (1985) A multi-echelon inventory model for repairable item with one-for-one replenishment. Manage Sci 31(10):1247–1256 Graves S (1996) A multi-echelon inventory model with fixed replenishment intervals. Manage Sci 42(1):1–18 Graves S (1999) A single-item inventory model for a nonstationary demand process. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 1(1):50–61
106
Q. Wang
Gunasekaran A, Ngai E (2004) Information systems in supply chain integration and management. Eur J Oper Res 159:269–295 Gurbuz M, Moinzadeh K, Zhou Y (2007) Coordinated replenishment strategies in inventory/ distribution systems. Manage Sci 53(2):293–308 Hariharan R, Zipkin P (1995) Customer-order information, leadtimes, and inventories. Manage Sci 41(10):1599–1607 Iglehart D (1964) The dynamic inventory problem with unknown demand distributions. Manage Sci 10(3):429–440 Iyer A, Ye J (2000) Assessing the value of information sharing in a promotional retail environment. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 2(2):128–143 Jackson P (1988) Stock allocation in a two-echelon distribution system or “what to do until your ship comes in”. Manage Sci 34(7):880–895 Jacobs F, Chase R, Aquilano N (2009) Operations and supply management, 12th edn. McGrawHill, New York Johansen S, Thorstenson A (1998) An inventory model with Poisson demands and emergency orders. Int J Prod Econ 56–57:275–289 Kapuscinski R, Tayur S (1998) A capacitated production-inventory model with period demand. Oper Res 46(6):899–911 Khouja M, Goyal S (2008) A review of the joint replenishment problem literature: 1989–2005. Eur J Oper Res 186:1–16 Kukreja A, Schmidt C, Miller D (2001) Stocking decisions for low-usage items in a multilocation inventory system. Manage Sci 47(10):1371–1383 Kumar A, Schwarz L, Ward J (1995) Risk-pooling along a fixed delivery route. Manage Sci 41:344–362 Lee H (1987) A multi-echelon inventory model for repairable items with emergency lateral transshipments. Manage Sci 33:1302–1316 Lee H, Moinzadeh K (1987a) Two-parameter approximations for multi-echelon repairable inventory models with batch ordering policy. IIE Trans 19:140–149 Lee H, Moinzadeh K (1987b) Operating characteristics of a two-echelon inventory system for repairable and consumable items under batch ordering and shipment policy. Nav Res Logistics Q 34:365–380 Lee H, Whang S (1999) Decentralized multi-echelon supply chains: incentives and information. Manage Sci 45(5):633–640 Lee H, Padmanabhan V, Whang S (1997) Information distortion in a supply chain: the bullwhip effect. Manage Sci 43(4):546–558 Lee H, So K, Tang C (2000) The value of information sharing in a two-level supply chain. Manage Sci 46(5):626–643 Li X, Wang Q (2007) Coordination mechanisms of supply chain systems. Eur J Oper Res 179:1–16 Lovejoy W (1990) Myopic policies for some inventory models with uncertain demand distributions. Manage Sci 36(6):724–738 Marklund J (2006) Controlling inventories in divergent supply chains with advance order information. Oper Res 54(5):988–1010 McGavin E, Schwarz L, Ward J (1993) Two-interval inventory-allocation policies in a onewarehouse N-identical retailer distribution system. Manage Sci 39(9):1092–1107 McGavin E, Ward J, Schwarz L (1997) Balancing retailer inventories. Oper Res 45(6):820–830 Milner J, Kouvelis P (2002) On the complementary value of accurate demand information and production and supplier flexibility. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 4(2):99–113 Moinzadeh K (2002) A multi-echelon inventory system with information exchange. Manage Sci 48(3):414–426 Moinzadeh K, Lee H (1986) Batch size and stocking levels in multi-echelon repairable systems. Manage Sci 32:1567–1581 Moinzadeh K, Nahmias S (1988) A continuous review model for an inventory system with two supply modes. Manage Sci 34:761–773
Control Policies for Multi-echelon Inventory Systems with Stochastic Demand
107
Moinzadeh K, Schmidt C (1991) An (S-1, S) inventory system with emergency orders. Oper Res 39:308–321 Muckstadt J (1973) A model for a multi-item, multi-echelon, multi-indenture inventory system. Manage Sci 20:472–481 Muckstadt J (1979) A three-person, multi-item model for recoverable items. Nav Res Logistics Q 26:199–221 Ozer O (2003) Replenishment strategies for distribution systems under advance demand information. Manage Sci 49(3):255–272 Ozer O, Wei W (2004) Inventory control with limited capacity and advance demand information. Oper Res 52(6):988–1001 Porteus E (1990) Stochastic inventory theory. In: Heyman D, Sobel M (eds) Stochastic models, handbooks in operations research and management science, vol 12. Elsevier (North-Holland), Amsterdam Raghunathan S (2001) Information sharing in a supply chain: a note on its value when demand is nonstationary. Manage Sci 47(4):605–610 Raghunathan S (2003) Impact of demand correlation on the value of and incentives for information sharing in a supply chain. Eur J Oper Res 146:634–649 Rao U (2003) Properties of the periodic-review (R, T) inventory control policy for stationary, stochastic demand. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 5(1):37–53 Rosling K (1989) Optimal inventory policies for assembly systems under random demands. Oper Res 37(4):565–579 Roundy R (1985) 98%-effective integer-ratio lot-sizing for one-warehouse multi-retailer systems. Manage Sci 31(11):1416–1429 Roundy R (1986) A 98%-effective lot sizing rule for a multi-product, multi-stage production/ distribution system. Math Oper Res 11(4):699–727 Sahin F, Robinson E (2002) Flow coordination and information sharing in supply chains: review, implications, and directions for future research. Decis Sci 33(4):505–535 Schmidt C, Nahmias S (1985) Optimal policy for a two-stage assembly system under random demand. Oper Res 33:1130–1145 Schwarz L (1989) A model for assessing the value of warehouse risk-pooling: risk-pooling over outside-supplier leadtimes. Manage Sci 35(7):828–842 Shang K, Song J (2003) Newsvendor bounds and heuristic for optimal policies in serial supply chains. Manage Sci 49(5):618–638 Shang K, Song J (2007) Serial supply chains with economies of scale: bounds and approximations. Oper Res 55(5):843–853 Shang K, Zhou S (2010) Optimal and heuristic echelon (r, nQ, T) policies in serial inventory systems with fixed costs. Oper Res 58(2):414–429 Shanker K (1981) Exact analysis of a two-echelon inventory system for recoverable items under batch inspection policy. Nav Res Logistics Q 28:579–601 Sheopuri A, Janakiraman G, Seshdri S (2010) New policies for the stochastic inventory control problem with two supply sources. Oper Res 58(3):734–747 Sherbrooke C (1968) METRIC: a multi-echelon technique for recoverable item control. Oper Res 16:122–141 Sherbrooke C (1986) VARI-METRIC: improved approximation for multi-indenture, multi-echelon availability models. Oper Res 34:311–319 Silver E, Peterson R (1998) Decision systems for inventory management and production. Wiley, New York Simon R (1971) Stationary properties of a two-echelon inventory model for low demand items. Oper Res 19:761–777 Song J, Yao D (2002) Performance analysis and optimization of assemble-to-order systems with random lead times. Oper Res 50(5):889–903 Sosic G (2006) Transshipment of inventories among retailers: myopic vs. farsighted stability. Manage Sci 52(10):1493–1508
108
Q. Wang
Svoronos A, Zipkin P (1988) Estimating the performance of multi-level inventory systems. Oper Res 36(1):57–72 Svoronos A, Zipkin P (1991) Evaluation of one-for-one replenishment policies for multiechelon inventory systems. Manage Sci 37:68–83 Tagaras G, Vlachos D (2001) A periodic review inventory system with emergency replenishments. Manage Sci 47(3):415–429 Tan K (2001) A framework of supply chain management literature. Eur J Purch Supply Manage 7:39–48 Tsay A, Nahmias S, Agrawa N (1998) Modeling supply chain contracts: a review. In: Tayur S, Magazine M, Ganeshan R (eds) Quantitative models for supply chain management, vol 17, International series in operations research and management science. Kluwer, Norwell, MA, pp 299–336 van Houtum G, Scheller-Wolf A, Ji X (2007) Optimal control of serial inventory systems with fixed replenishment intervals. Oper Res 55(4):674–687 Veinott A, Wagner H (1965) Computing optimal (s, S) inventory problems. Manage Sci 11:525–552 Ve´ricourt F, Karaesmen F, Dallery Y (2002) Optimal stock allocation for a capacitated supply system. Manage Sci 48(11):1486–1501 Viswanathan S (1997) Note. Periodic review (s, S) policies for joint replenishment inventory systems. Manage Sci 43:1447–1454 Wang Q (2010) Integer-ratio policies for distribution systems with multiple retailers and stochastic demand. Working paper, Nanyang Business School, Nanyang Technological University, Singapore Wang Q, Axs€ater S (2010) Fixed-interval order-up-to policies for distribution systems with multiple retailers and stochastic demand. Working paper, Nanyang Business School, Nanyang Technological University, Singapore Wang T, Toktay B (2008) Inventory management with advance demand information and flexible delivery. Manage Sci 54(4):716–732 Wee K, Dada M (2005) Optimal policies for transshipping inventory in a retailer network. Manage Sci 51(10):1519–1533 Yano C, Carson C (1988) Safety stocks for assembly systems with fixed production schedules. J Manuf Oper Manage 1:182–201 Zheng Y (1992) On properties of stochastic inventory systems. Manage Sci 38(1):87–103 Zheng Y, Federgruen A (1991) Finding optimal (s, S) policies is about as simple as evaluating a single policy. Oper Res 39(4):654–665 Zheng Y, Zipkin P (1990) A queuing model to analyze the value of centralized inventory information. Oper Res 38(2):296–307 Zipkin P (1986a) Stochastic leadtimes in continuous-time inventory models. Nav Res Logistics Q 33:763–774 Zipkin P (1986b) Inventory service level measures: convexity and approximation. Manage Sci 32 (8):975–981 Zipkin P (1995) Performance analysis of a multi-item production-inventory system under alternative policies. Manage Sci 41(4):690–703 Zipkin P (2000) Foundations of inventory management. McGraw-Hill, New York
Supply Chain Models with Active Acquisition and Remanufacturing Xiang Li and Yongjian Li
Abstract Nowadays economic, marketing, and environment legislation are increasingly driving firms to consider product reuse, thus active acquisition of used products is prevailing in industry. This chapter focuses on the problem regarding the active acquisition and remanufacturing within supply chain scope. We introduce some recent and important research developments, including the centralized system problem with price-sensitive acquisition and demand, the decentralized supply chain problem with vertical channels, and the decentralized supply chain problem with horizontal competition. For each problem, analytical models are presented and main results are elucidated. Finally, further research directions are also pointed out. Keywords Acquisition management • Closed-loop supply chain • Coordination • Remanufacturing
1 Introduction Supply chain management considering return flows has received substantial interests from both industrial and academic worlds. Product returns represent a growing financial concern for firms, with an estimation of $35 billion annually for the USA alone (Meyer 1999). From a traditional perspective, these returns fall into two categories: consumer returns to the retailer during the return period, and product overstocks returned to the upstream manufacturer, both incurring considerable reprocessing cost and revenue loss. This return flow is regarded as “a bad X. Li (*) Research Center of Logistics, College of Economic and Social Development, Nankai University, Tianjin 300071, P.R. China e-mail: [email protected] Y. Li Business School, Nankai University, Tianjin 300071, P.R. China e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_5, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
109
110
X. Li and Y. Li
thing”, and the associated costs are reduced by developing various return policies and incentive strategies (Ferguson et al. 2006). On the other hand, nowadays legislations usually encourage the reuse of product returns. Remanufacturing technology has been developed as an environmentally and economically sound way to deal with the returns after customer usage. As a result, a trend of active acquisition of used product is replacing the traditional passive return, and the remanufacturing industry is being boosted. The relevant activities, however, require effective coordination at multiple locations to retrieve the used product and recover its value, which is usually referred to as reverse supply chain management (Prahinski and Kocabasoglu 2006). The acquisition and remanufacturing management turns out to be a complicated problem, considering the uncertainty of the product returns, and the different, usually conflicting objectives of the supply chain members. This chapter focuses on the supply chain problem with active acquisition and remanufacturing, hoping to provide some recent research models and results. More specifically, there are three streams of researches drawing our attention: the centralized system problem with price-sensitive acquisition and demand, the decentralized supply chain problem with vertical channel, and the decentralized supply chain problem with horizontal competition. First of all, the used product can be actively collected in a market-driven channel by paying a price called acquisition price to end users or core dealers. The related problem is first proposed by Guide and Jayaraman (2000), which delineates the necessity of a careful coordination to balance the returns with the demand. Guide et al. (2003) builds up a quantitative model of a remanufacturing system in which the returns and demand could be controlled by the acquisition price and selling price, respectively, and Bakal and Akcali (2006) extends it into a random remanufacturing yield case. Ray et al. (2005) studies the optimal pricing/trade-in strategies for a durable, remanufacturable product, by characterizing some key factors of such product. Other related papers include Robotis et al. (2005), Qu and Williams (2008), Liang et al. (2009), etc. In sum, all the above papers focus on the centralized control of integrated acquisition and remanufacturing system. As for the decentralized supply chain, the acquisition and remanufacturing problems are usually linked up with game theory and contracting. One stream of the research is on the vertical channel, which is studied under Stackelberg leaderfollower game framework. Savaskan et al. (2004) considers the problem of choosing an appropriate reverse channel for the acquisition of used product. Three channel structures are analyzed and compared, involving the interaction among supply chain members such as the OEM, retailer, and 3PL collector. In the succeeding work, Savaskan and Van Wassenhove (2006) further explores the reverse channel choice problem with one upstream manufacturer and two competing retailers. The reverse supply chain model is also studied in Karakayali et al. (2006) without considering the forward distribution channel. As most papers focus on the policy of commercial returns, e.g., Pasternack(1985), Padmanabhan and Png (1997), Mukhopadhyay and Setoputro (2005), Yue and Raghunathan (2007) and so on, the research on vertical supply chain management with the active acquisition is rather limited.
Supply Chain Models with Active Acquisition and Remanufacturing
111
Furthermore, the study on the acquisition and remanufacturing competition at a horizontal supply chain level is being a hot topic recently. Majumder and Groenevelt (2001a) describes a two-period model under the assumption of indistinguishable quality between remanufactured and new product, but distinguishable brand between the competing OEM and remanufacturer. Majumder and Groenevelt (2001b) extends the model by allowing for competition in the acquisition of used product. Ferrer and Swaminathan (2006) extends Groenevelt and Majumder (2001a) into a multi-period setting where the brand competition is carried on in the second and subsequent periods. Ferguson and Toktay (2006) adopts a similar two-period model focusing on the strategic role of OEM remanufacturing as an entry deterrent to the local remanufacturer. The remanufacturing cost has a quadratic form and the competition is between the sales of new and remanufactured products. Atasu et al. (2008) also analyzes a two-period model to study the effect of timing of the remanufactured product introduction and the use of remanufacturing as a marketing strategy to compete with low-cost OEM competitors. Other related papers include Debo et al. (2005), Heese et al. (2005), Webster and Mitra (2007, 2008), etc. Most of the above models are under Nash game framework and two-period setting. In this chapter, we choose to present six models from the above three research streams, and provide an in-depth discussion on their managerial insights. The purpose is not to give an all-around review or survey on the numerous literature related to product returns, but to offer some connected and evolving works, hoping to reflect new research trends. Also, one of our main focuses is on the collection effort (and price) paid by supply chain members during the active acquisition of the used product, therefore some important researches outside this scope are not involved in the chapter. For example, some papers study the acquisition decision of the used product under a traditional newsvendor framework, where the used product acquisition can be simply regarded as a normal product order, e.g., Ferrer (2003), Vlachos and Dekker (2003), Galbreth and Blackburn (2006), Zikopoulos and Tagaras (2007), Kaya (2010), etc. Some other papers consider the acquisition problem with the location decision of acquisition centers, e.g., Wojanowski et al. (2007), Aras and Aksen (2008), Aras et al. (2008), etc. For a more comprehensive review on these subjects, we refer the reader to Dekker et al. (2004), Guide and Van Wassenhove (2009), Pokharel and Mutha (2009), and Ilgin and Gupta (2010).
2 Centralized System with Price-Sensitive Acquisition and Demand As stated in the last section, in the market-driven channel an acquisition price is paid to end users or core suppliers for the returned used product. This approach is widely adopted as it grants the firm a partial control on the used product returns. Guide and Van Wassenhove (2001) provides a detailed case study of the telephone remanufacturer, ReCellular Inc., buying used phones from a variety of sources and
112
X. Li and Y. Li
and selling remanufactured ones. Similar examples can also be found in the automotive industry, where automotive parts from the end-of-life vehicles are remanufactured and reused (Bakal and Akcali 2006). A common feature of the above cases is that the remanufacturing firm has full pricing power in both used product acquisition and remanufactured product demand, the quantities of which are sensitive to the acquisition price and the selling price, respectively. In this section, we investigate this pricing problem faced by the remanufacturing firm, with the objective of maximizing the profit from remanufacturing. The pricing decision is regarded as a lever to match the demand and supply, and both the deterministic and random yield models can be established.
2.1
Deterministic Model
A remanufacturing firm, ReCellular, collects used phones from the providers grading the phones and selling them in different quality classes. The used phones with quality classification differ in their condition, like the appearance, damage, and age, and the remanufacturing costs for different quality classes are different. On the other hand, all the remanufactured phones have the same quality and the same selling price. The acquisition quantities and demand are deterministic and dependent on the acquisition prices and selling price, respectively. This quantitative model is studied in Guide et al. (2003), and introduced in the following. Suppose that there are N quality classes, 1,2,. . .,N. The remanufacturing cost of class i is ci. The acquisition price of the used product of class i is denoted as fi, and the corresponding return quantity is ri( fi). It is assumed that ri( fi) is a continuous, increasing and twice differentiable function defined on [bi, g ci], where bi is the minimal acquisition price and g is the maximum price at which a remanufactured product can be sold. For convenience, the classes are ordered in such a way that b1 þ c1 < b2 þ c2 < < bN þ cN . On the demand side, let d(p) be the demand of the remanufactured product when the selling price is p, which is a continuous, decreasing and twice differentiable function defined on [b1 + c1, g]. The inverse function of d( p) is denoted by P(d), i.e., P(d(p)) ¼ p. And the inverse function of ri( fi) is denoted by Ai(ri), i.e., Ai(ri( fi)) ¼ fi, for all i. The objective is to determine the acquisition prices fi ; i ¼ 1; . . . ; N, and the selling price p to maximize the profit. The optimal acquisition price is denoted by fi and the resulting acquisition quantity is ri ; i ¼ 1; . . . ; N. As it is a deterministic model, the demand of the remanufactured product should be equal to the quantity of the used product returns to attain the profit maximization, i.e., the prices should satisfy dðpÞ ¼
N X i¼1
ri ðfi Þ:
(1)
Supply Chain Models with Active Acquisition and Remanufacturing
113
Thus, the optimization problem can be formulated as ðP1Þ
max P
f1 ;;fN
N X
! ri ðfi Þ
i¼1
N X
ri ðfi Þ
i¼1
N X
½ri ðfi Þðfi þ ci Þ;
(2)
i¼1
or equivalently, ðP2Þ
N X
max P
r1 ;...;rN
! ri
i¼1
N X i¼1
ri
N X
½ri ðAðri Þ þ ci Þ:
(3)
i¼1
It is natural to ask if the objective function (P1) or (P2) has joint concavity. Examples have shown that the function is not always concave and even not unimodal in some cases. Then the following two questions turn out to be essential: 1. On what conditions the objective function is concave (or unimodal) and in that case, is there any analytical property helpful to solve the problem? 2. Is there any algorithm/heuristic useful for the problem? Guide et al. (2003) provides the following answers. First, the objective (P2) is jointly concave if dP(d) is concave and riA(ri) is convex for any i. Second, under these conditions (called Condition C1 and C2, respectively), there is an M such that fi >bi for all i ¼ 1; . . . ; M and fi ¼ bi for all i ¼ M þ 1; ; N. This property indicates it is optimal to only acquire the used product in class i ¼ 1; ; M for some 1 M N. For the second question, define functions GðpÞ :¼ ddðpÞ and 0 ðpÞ þ p Fi ðfi Þ :¼ rr0iiðfðfiiÞÞ þ ðfi þ ci Þ. Then, the first-order optimality conditions for problem (P1) can be expressed by Fi ðfi Þ ¼ G P
N X
!! ri ðfi Þ
for i ¼ 1; ; M;
(4)
for i ¼ M þ 1; ; N:
(5)
i¼1
and Fi ðfi Þ G P
N X
!! ri ðfi Þ
i¼1
The above properties yield the following algorithm to calculate the optimal acquisition prices under Conditions C1 and C2. Step 1. M: ¼ 1. M ðaM Þ :¼ aM . If M 2, use the equation Fi(ai) ¼ FM(aM) to express ai as Step 2. HM a function of aM, denoted by HiM ðaM Þ, for i ¼ 1; 2; ; M 1.
114
X. Li and Y. Li
P M Step 3. Use the equation dðpÞ ¼ M i¼1 ri Hi ðaM ÞÞ to express p as a function of aM, denoted by KM(aM). Step 4. Obtain the value aM M for aM by equalizing FM(aM) to G(KM(aM)). Step 5. If either M ¼ N or FM ðaM M Þ FMþ1 ðbMþ1 Þ, output the optimal prices: fi ¼ M M M M Hi ðaM Þ for i ¼ 1; ; M, and fi ¼ bi for i ¼ M þ 1; ; N; And p ¼ K ðaM Þ. Otherwise, M :¼ M þ 1 and then go to Step 1. This algorithm shows the procedure to compute the exact optimal prices. However, Steps 4 and 5 have to be carried out numerically if the demand and return functions have complex shapes. Moreover, the algorithm can be only applied when both the conditions C1 and C2 are satisfied. In this regard, a heuristic is derived in Guide et al. (2003) based on the idea of making the prices such that the profit per product is fixed. It is set that fi ¼ max(bi, fnew ci), where fnew is the theoretical acquisition price that the firm is willing to pay for an as-good-as-new returned item, which doesn’t need the remanufacturing. The associated total return P quantity r 0 ðfnew Þ :¼ i;bi þci
2.2
Random Remanufacturing Yield Model
The uncertainty on product returns is regarded as an important characteristic of reverse logistics. In a market-driven collection channel, the quantity uncertainty of the returns is considerably controlled by acquisition price, while the quality uncertainty still exists. This quality uncertainty can be reflected by remanufacturing yield randomness and is considered in this subsection. The problem is motivated by the automotive remanufacturing industry. Typically, the automotive dismantling/remanufacturing firm buys end-of-life vehicles (ELVs) and sells remanufacturable parts, facing both the acquisition pricing and selling pricing problems. However, due to the uncertainty of the returned product quality, there is a random yield in the part remanufacturing process. That is to say, the quality requirement for remanufacturing is not satisfied by all returned parts, and the percentage of remanufacturable ones is uncertain. The random yield is a major concern in this remanufacturing system. Specifically, suppose that the supply of ELVs r(f) is a deterministic and linear function of the acquisition price f, i.e., r(f) ¼ a + bf, where a,b > 0. The demand for the remanufactured part d(p) is a deterministic and linear function of the selling price p, i.e., d(p) ¼ a bp. The random yield is also dependent on the acquisition price and modeled as the product of R and t(f). t(f) is a deterministic, concave and
Supply Chain Models with Active Acquisition and Remanufacturing
115
nondecreasing function of f which converges to 1 as f increases, and R is a random variable denoting the maximum attainable yield rate. The part not remanufacturable or not remanufactured has a salvage value s. It is also supposed that each ELV has a hulk that can be salvaged with a unit price h. The testing cost for each part is c and the remanufacturing cost for remanufacturable part is cr. The objective is to maximize the total expected profit from the remanufactured part sale and the hulk sale. Bakal and Akcali (2006) studies three different models to explore the acquisition pricing and selling pricing decisions of this problem. The first model is the deterministic yield case serving as a benchmark for the random yield cases. The pricing problem is formulated as follows: max f ; p Pðf ; pÞ ¼ ða bpÞðp s cr Þ þ ða þ bf Þðh þ s f cÞ s:t: ða bpÞ Rtðf Þða þ bf Þ
(6)
where the yield R now is a constant. Let K ¼ h + s c and r0 ¼ [a b(s + cr)]/ [t(K/s a/2b)(a + bK)]. It turns out that r0 is a threshold yield rate. If r0 1, then the profit is increasing in R until R ¼ r0 and remains constant thereafter. Otherwise, the profit is strictly increasing in R. The second model is called Postponed Pricing Model (PPM), in which the yield is random and the remanufacturer has the opportunity to set the selling price of the remanufactured part after the realization of random yield. Therefore, a two-step dynamic programme can be formulated for this model as follows. ðP3Þ
max p P1 ðpjr; f Þ ¼ ða bpÞðp s cr Þ þ ða þ bf Þðh þ s f cÞ s:t:ða bpÞ rtðf Þða þ bf Þ (7)
and ðP4Þ
max f Pðf Þ ¼ ER ½P1 ðp ðR; f ÞjR; f Þ
(8)
where p ðr; f Þ denotes the optimal selling price of Problem (P3) given the yield is realized as r and the acquisition price is f. It is generally difficult to explore the property of P(f) in (P3) for arbitrary t(f). Even in the simple case t(f) ¼ (f + m)/ (f + n), the unimodularity of P(f) is hard to prove analytically, though it could be validated by a thorough numerical experiment. In the third model, called Simultaneous Pricing Model (SPM), the acquisition price and selling price are determined simultaneously before the realization of random yield. Then the problem is equal to max f ; p Pðf ; pÞ ¼ ER fðp cr sÞ min½a bp; Rtðf Þða þ bf Þg ðc sÞða þ bf Þ þ hða þ bf Þ;
(9)
116
X. Li and Y. Li
in which v is the unit shortage penalty. The problem is also hard to analyze theoretically and it is conjectured that the objective function is pseudo-concave. The effect of the random yield on this active acquisition and remanufacturing system is explored by a comprehensive computational study. The threshold yield rate r0 turns out to be a critical indicator. The system is referred to as “high margin”/ “low margin” if r0 1/r0 1, which indicates the profit of used product acquisition h + s c f is high/low. In the high margin case, the expected supply always exceeds the demand in both the PPM and SPM scenarios, which indicates the firm creates a buffer inventory. This effect is especially prominent in SPM since the firm has no opportunity to adjust the selling price according to the realization of the yield and the buffer inventory helps to deal with this uncertainty more effectively. Moreover, when the deviation of the maximum attainable yield rate is moderate, both the models generate profits close to the benchmark DPM. In the low margin case, the performance of PPM is also close to DPM, whereas SPM generates lower profit and the firm does not hold buffer inventory any more since all the remanufacturable parts are used to satisfy the demand due to lower profit margin. It is shown that PPM always outperforms SPM by postponing the selling pricing decision after the realization of random yield. However, in the high margin case the difference is not prominent since the high hulk salvage value offsets the loss of delayed yield information to some extent. In fact, the benefit of postponing the selling pricing becomes more significant with lower profit margin, lower yield rate and higher variation. The value of perfect yield information is also studied by the comparison of deterministic maximum yield R ¼ 0.5 and uniformly distributed yield R ~ U(0,1). It can be concluded that the yield information is crucial for the operations of the firm, especially for the lower margin case.
3 Decentralized Supply Chain with Vertical Channels Outsourcing allows a firm to concentrate on its own core competency, reduce operational cost, and lower the financial risk. For these reasons, an original equipment manufacturer (OEM) usually outsources part of the reverse logistic activities, like used product acquisition or remanufacturing. In this section, we study the decentralized supply chain with vertical structure, in which the reverse logistics activities could be conducted by different supply chain members. The section starts from exploring a typical reverse supply chain consisting of a collector and a remanufacturer, engaged in the acquisition and remanufacturing of used products, respectively. The OEM can choose to outsource the collection or remanufacturing activity to a specific collector or remanufacturer, namely collectordriven or remanufacturer-driven channel, respectively. The decentralized decision problems within these channels are studied in Karakayali et al. (2006) and will be introduced in Sect. 3.1.
Supply Chain Models with Active Acquisition and Remanufacturing
117
Next we discuss the problem on closed-loop supply chain structure, which is regarded as the integration of the forward and reverse channels. The involved entities might be OEM, retailer, and 3PL collector, while the product returns could be through OEM-collection channel, retailer-collection channel or 3PLcollection channel. The related models are investigated in Savaskan et al. (2004) and will be presented in Sect. 3.2.
3.1
Reverse Supply Chain Channels
The reverse supply chain consists of a collector and a remanufacturer. The acquisition of used product and the demand of the remanufactured product are both deterministic and price-sensitive, denoted as r(f) ¼ a + bf and d(p) ¼ a bp, respectively. The collector and the remanufacturer incur unit transaction cost cl and cm, respectively. The salvage value per part is s and per hulk is h. The unit remanufacturing cost is cr. The above assumptions and notations are very similar to Sect. 2, with the difference that the collection and remanufacturing processes are operated by the collector and remanufacturer independently. However, the remanufacturing yield is not considered here. Karakayali et al. (2006) studies the problem on this reverse supply chain channel. Although the main focus is the decentralized interaction, the centralized problem serves as a benchmark for the decentralized one, which is formulated as follows: max f ; p Pðf ; pÞ ¼ ða bpÞðp s cr Þ þ ða þ bf Þðh þ s f cl cm Þ s:t: a bp a þ bf
(10)
It is easy to see this problem is a special case of Sect. 2.2 for R ¼ t(f) 1. For the decentralized scenario, two different channel settings are remanufacturerdriven channel and collector-driven channel. In the remanufacturer-driven/collector-driven channel, the OEM outsources the remanufacturing/collection activity, giving the remanufacturer/collector the leadership role in the channel. The analysis is based on the wholesale price contract under Stackelberg game framework. In the remanufacturer-driven channel, the remanufacturer acts as a leader and the other party responds as a follower. As a result, the collector’s problem is to choose the optimal acquisition price f*(w) for a given wholesale price w, maximizing the following objective: maxPc ¼ ðw f cl Þða þ bf Þ: f
(11)
The remanufacturer’s problem is max w ; p Pr ¼ ða bpÞðp s cr Þ þ ða þ bf ðwÞÞðh þ s w cm Þ s:t: a bp a þ bf ðwÞ:
(12)
118
X. Li and Y. Li
The remanufacturer’s problem can be solved by substituting the simple solution of the collector’s problem and then obtaining the optimal decision. In the collection-driven channel, the collector proposes the wholesale price w and the acquisition price f as the leader, and the remanufacturer correspondingly chooses the selling price of remanufactured product p*(w, f) and the quantity of used products that are not remanufactured t*(w, f). The remanufacturer’s problem is formulated as follows: max p ; t Pr ¼ ða bpÞðp cm cr w þ hÞ þ tðh þ s w cm Þ s:t:
t þ a bp a þ bf
(13)
t 0: The collector sets the wholesale price w and the collection price f accordingly, to maximize her profit function: max w ; f Pc ¼ ðw cl f Þða þ bf Þ s:t: tðw; f Þ þ a bpðw; f Þ a þ bf :
(14)
The solving procedure is similar to the remanufacturer-driven problem. The only delicate notion is that the collector should ensure the remanufacturer’s profit margin to be non-negative, or he is not willing to purchase any unit from the collector. As expected, the centralized channel is shown as the most effective strategy from both environmental and consumer’s perspectives. The acquisition price is highest paid and the selling price lowest charged, which yields the largest quantities of used products collected and remanufactured parts sold. It is also shown that a two-part tariff contract, characterized by a wholesale price and a fixed payment, can be used to coordinate the decentralized supply chain to achieve the collection efficiency attained in the centralized one. For the decentralized channels, a natural question is when the OEM would prefer the collection-driven or remanufacturer-driven channel. Numerical experiment shows that the parameters on both the supply and demand sides can influence such channel choice decision. As a decreases, and/or b increases, and a and/or b increases, it becomes more favorable for an OEM to outsource the collection activity. Otherwise the remanufacturer-driven is more preferable. On the other hand, the OEM can also consider altering the outsourcing decision due to a change in the cost and revenue parameters cr and h. For example, an OEM originally preferring a remanufacturer-driven channel for lower cr may choose a collectiondriven channel as cr increases and exceeds a threshold. Similar behavior could be observed for increasing h. Note that an implicit assumption in the above cases is the homogeneousness of the used product quality. If the used products are heterogeneous, the quality condition of the used product influences the acquisition and remanufacturing costs, and the hulk and part salvage values. Any remanufactured part, however, is
Supply Chain Models with Active Acquisition and Remanufacturing
119
of the same quality level and the same selling price. This setting is the same as in Sect. 2.1. For m quality classes, Karakayali et al. (2006) derives O(m2) iterative algorithms for the centralized and remanufacturer-driven channel problems, and an O(m22m) algorithm for the collector-driven channel problem. The supply chain can also be coordinated by two-part tariff contracts with a proper set of wholesale prices and fixed payments.
3.2
Closed-Loop Supply Chain Channels
We now consider a product in which there is no distinction between a remanufactured item and newly manufactured one, thus OEM could use a hybrid remanufacturing/manufacturing strategy to satisfy the market demand. The goal of this subsection is to present the model on a manufacturer’s reverse channel choice and to discuss its impact on the whole supply chain performance. Specifically, the manufacturer has three options to collect used products for remanufacturing (1) collect directly from customers, called Manufacturer Collection Channel; (2) delegate the downstream retailer to collect, called Retailer Collection Channel; and (3) subcontract the collection to a 3PL collector, like in Sect. 3.1, called 3PL Collection Channel. Suppose that remanufacturing is less costly than manufacturing new product for the manufacturer, i.e., cr < cm. The demand is linear decreasing in the selling price, i.e., d(p) ¼ a bp. The acquisition cost structure, on the other hand, is independent of the collection agent, i.e., the cost of collecting a certain amount of used units is the same for the manufacturer, retailer or 3PL. Let 0 t 1 denote the collection rate, which is the ratio of acquisition quantity of used units to the demand quantity. The total cost of collection C(t) is dependent on the collection rate of used products and given by C(t) ¼ CLt2 + Atd(p), where CL is a scaling parameter and A is the variable collection cost of each unit returned item. The problem is studied in a single-period setting. In the following we present three decentralized closed-loop supply chain channels, and the centralized scenario as well, which serves as a benchmark for the decentralized ones. The objective for the centralized system is to choose the selling price p and collection rate t to maximize max PC ¼ ða bpÞðp cm þ tDÞ CL t2 Atða bpÞ; p;t
(15)
where D ¼ cm cr denotes the economic attractiveness of remanufacturing compared to manufacturing. The analytical solution pC ; tC can be obtained by solving the first-order optimality condition of (15). In the decentralized systems, the manufacturer is assumed to have sufficient channel power over the other entities. She acts as a Stackelberg leader and uses her foresight about the retailer’s and 3PL’s reactions to maximize her own profit. In the
120
X. Li and Y. Li
Manufacturer Collection Channel, for a given wholesale price w, the retailer’s problem is maxp PM R ¼ ðp wÞða bpÞ. Substituting the best response pM ¼ ða þ bwÞ=ð2bÞ, we have the manufacturer’s problem as follows, maxPM M ¼ w;t
a bw a bw ðp cm þ tDÞ CL t2 At : 2 2
(16)
The optimal solutions wM and tM can be obtained by solving the first-order optimality condition. In the Retailer Collection Channel, the manufacturer delegates the retailer to collect used products and pays a transfer price b per unit acquired. Thus the retailer’s problem is maxp;t PRR ¼ ðabpÞðpwÞþbtðabpÞCL t2 AtðabpÞ, and the optimal pR and tR can be solved since the profit function is concave. Given the best response of the retailer, the manufacturer’s problem is R R R R max PM M ¼ ða bp Þðw cm þ t DÞ bt ða bp Þ; w;b
(17)
and the corresponding solution wR and bR can be obtained. An interesting observation is that the manufacturer’s profit is increasing in b, thus it is optimal to set bR ¼ D by the manufacturer. In the 3PL Collection Channel, the manufacturer outsources the collection to an independent 3PL collector and pays a transfer price b per unit collected. In this case, the retailer only engages in the product distribution and chooses the optimal selling price p , for a given wholesale price set by the manufacturer. The 3PL’s problem is R 2 R 3P maxt P3P 3P ¼ btða bp Þ CL t Atða bp Þ, and the optimal solution t can be obtained. As a Stackelberg leader, the manufacturer determines the optimal w3P and b3P by solving R 3P Þ: max P3P M ¼ ða bp Þðw cm þ ðD bÞt w;b
(18)
We have b3P ¼ ðD þ AÞ=2, indicating that b is a direct cost for the manufacturer and the closed-loop supply chain. Savaskan et al. (2004) compares the above cases and obtains the following results on the different closed-loop supply chain channels: 1. tC > tR > tM > t3P : 2. pC < pR < pM < p3P , and consequently dC > dR > d M > d3P . M 3P R M 3P C R M 3P 3. pR M > pM > pM , pR > pR > pR , and consequently p > pT > pT > pT . It shows that the collection rate increases with the 3PL, manufacturer, retailer as collecting agent, respectively, and reaches the highest value in the centralized system. Consequently, the acquisition of used product and sales of remanufactured product are highest in quantity in the centralized system. This result, which has been proved in Sect. 3.1, is validated again in the closed-loop supply chain setting.
Supply Chain Models with Active Acquisition and Remanufacturing
121
On the other hand, the selling price decreases in the same sequence. Moreover, both the profits of the retailer and manufacturer reach the highest values in the Retailer Collection Channel and lowest in the 3PL Collection Channel. In summary, the preferred collecting agent is the retailer, followed by the manufacturer, and then the third-party (3P), no matter from the perspective of the manufacturer, retailer, supply chain or the consumer welfare. Finally, Savaskan et al. (2004) indicates that a simple coordination mechanism can be designed for the Retailer-Collection Channel and thus the maximum of the supply chain profit can be attained.
4 Decentralized Supply Chain of Horizontal Competition Horizontal competition among supply chain members is a common phenomenon. Generally, retailers compete in sales performance, and manufacturers compete for market share. In the closed-loop supply chain area, the horizontal competition is more fierce between the OEM who manufactures the product originally and the small agents who only involve in the used product acquisition and remanufacturing. Such instances can be found in the industry of toner cartridge (Majumder and Groenevelt 2001a) or single-used camera (Ferrer and Swaminathan 2006). In this section, we introduce two models seizing the essential feature of horizontal competition between OEM and local remanufacturer. Both models capture the dynamic nature of the problem by a two-period setting, in which the OEM manufactures in the first period and faces competition with the remanufacturer in the second period. The main differences are that the first model assumes a linear remanufacturing cost and distinguishable product brands between the OEM and remanufacturer, while the second model assumes convex collection and remanufacturing costs and distinguishable product quality between the new product and remanufactured one. Nearly all papers in this field fall into the category of brand competition or quality competition, and this section incorporates typical problems of these two types.
4.1
Distinguishable Brand and Linear Remanufacturing Cost
We first consider a two-period model with two players, an OEM and a local remanufacturer. In the first period, the OEM manufactures and sells new product. A fraction of sold items after use is available for the OEM and remanufacturer to be acquired and remanufactured in the second period, and the OEM can also manufacture new units in addition to remanufacturing used ones. Therefore, the players compete in selling their products to consumers in the second period.
122
X. Li and Y. Li
Since the competition for used product acquisition is not the focus of this problem, the model is analyzed under given allocation mechanisms for returned units. Specifically, the OEM has access to a fraction of the products sold in the first period, namely g, and the remanufacturer has 1 g. Four allocation mechanisms are considered (1) OEM can acquire any used product left over by the remanufacturer, however the remanufacturer cannot do likewise; (2) the remanufacturer can acquire any used product left over by OEM, but OEM cannot do likewise; (3) neither can acquire used product left over by the other; (4) both can acquire used product left over by the other. An important feature is that the two players face a brand competition in selling their products. In other words, there is a perfect substitution between the OEM’s new and remanufactured items like in Sect. 3.2, but customers can distinguish between the remanufacturer and OEM’s products. The demand functions in the second period are of Bertrand-type: Do ðpo ; pl Þ ¼ ao bo po þ co pl ; Dl ðpo ; pl Þ ¼ al bl pl þ cl po ;
(19)
where the subscript o means the variables and parameters of the OEM, and the subscript l means those of the local remanufacturer. We suppose that the quantity of total used products available in the second period is equal to a fraction a of the production quantity in the first period. The problem is analyzed in two stages, starting with Nash game analyze in the second period. Given this equilibrium prediction, the OEM chooses the manufacturing quantity and selling price in the first period. Specifically, the remanufacturer’s problem in the second period is max ql ; pl Pl ¼ ql ðpl rl Þ s:t: ql r; ql Dl ql 0; pl 0
(20)
where ql and pl are the remanufacturer’s decision variables, denoting the remanufacturing quantity and selling price, respectively. rl is unit remanufacturing cost and r is the quantity of attainable used products according to specific allocation rule. Similarly, the OEM’s problem in the second period is max z ; qor ; po Pl ¼ zðpo cÞ þ ðc ro Þqor s:t: qor r; qor z Do qor 0; p0 0
(21)
where qor, z and po are the OEM’s decision variables, denoting the remanufacturing quantity, total selling quantity and the selling price, respectively. The unit
Supply Chain Models with Active Acquisition and Remanufacturing
123
remanufacturing cost is ro and manufacturing cost is c. Here, a crucial assumption is that the variable costs for remanufacturing each unit are constants (though they can be different for the OEM and local remanufacturer, i.e., rO 6¼ rl). Different remanufacturing cost structure will be discussed in the next subsection. Groenevelt and Majumder (2001a) proves that a unique pure strategy Nash Equilibrium exists in the second period game. The total produced quantity (of the newly manufactured and remanufactured units) and the newly manufactured quantity are both nondecreasing in the quantity of returned items R. In fact, as R increases, the remanufacturer no longer uses up all available used products to remanufacture, while the OEM first stops manufacturing new units and then no longer uses up all the used units available for him. In contrast, the first period problem for OEM is difficult to analyze theoretically, as the profit function doesn’t have a convenient structural property. Nevertheless, some important insights can be obtained through numerical experiments. For example, we can consider that OEM is a monopoly without or with remanufacturing option. These cases, called B1 (without remanufacturing) and B2 (with remanufacturing) serve as benchmarks to examine the competitive case. It is shown that a monopoly OEM in B2 produces most in the first period and earns the highest total profit among three cases. However, the comparison of B1 with the competitive case is inconclusive. Under some circumstances the OEM does have higher profit in the competitive case than in B1, indicating that the OEM might prefer to facilitate the remanufacturing even if it would incorporate the reverse channel competition. The effects of parameter changes are also examined. An interesting observation is that although competing with the OEM in remanufacturing, the remanufacturer is better off when the OEM’s remanufacturing cost r0 is reduced, which would induce the OEM to produce more in the first period and thus benefit the remanufacturer. The fraction a is another crucial parameter, the increase of which would enlarge the remanufacturing quantity. However, such an increase does not necessarily raise the OEM’s profit due to the competition effect. Note that the above observations are valid for all allocation mechanisms, indicating the allocation rule is not an essential factor as long as the quantity fraction between players is exogenously imposed.
4.2
Distinguishable Quality and Convex Remanufacturing Cost
Ferguson and Toktay (2006) studies the horizontal competition problem following Majumder and Groenevelt (2001a) in somewhat similar settings. The OEM manufactures new product in the first period, and in the second period faces the entry threat of a local remanufacturer that competes with the OEM by selling the remanufactured product. The quantity of available units to be remanufactured is a fraction g of the production quantity of the first period. Some other key assumptions, which are distinct from the last model, are stated as follows.
124
X. Li and Y. Li
First, the qualities of the new product and remanufactured one are differential for customers. More specifically, each consumer’s willingness-to-pay for a remanufactured product is only a fraction d (∈ (0, 1)) of that for the new one. It is further assumed that the consumer’s willing-to-pay is heterogeneous and uniformly distributed in interval [0,1]. This leads to the demand functions entirely different from Sect. 4.1. Second, the collection/remanufacturing cost is increasing and convex with respect to the collection/remanufacturing quantity, respectively. More specifically, the remanufacturing cost is a quadratic function hq2, for a given remanufacturing quantity q. Finally, instead of an exogenous allocation mechanism in Sect. 4.1, this model incorporates a costly collection and remanufacturing option. More specifically, the firm choosing to remanufacture incurs a fixed cost F ¼ Fc + Fr where Fc and Fr are the fixed costs for building up the collection operation and remanufacturing operation, respectively. Under the above assumptions, it is investigated that whether a monopoly OEM should process the collection and remanufacturing. For a monopoly OEM without remanufacturing, it turns out to be a simple optimization problem maxq(p c)q for each period. For the OEM with remanufacturing, a two-step dynamic programming model is formulated as follows: max q2n ;q2r P2 ðq2n ; q2r jq1 Þ ¼ ðp2n cÞq2n þ ðp2r hq2r Þq2r s:t:
q2r gq1
(22)
and max pðq1 Þ ¼ ðp1 cÞq1 þ p2 ðq1 Þ:
(23)
q1 0
Note that in the above formulation we suppose the fixed cost of remanufacturing F ¼ 0. In this case, remanufacturing is always more profitable than not remanufacturing. However, if F > 0, then there exists a threshold level on the remanufacturing cost factor h, above which the OEM would not remanufacture any unit in the second period. The closed-form solutions of the pricing and quantity decisions can be obtained. Another key issue of this problem is to explore the strategic role of the OEM remanufacturing as an entry deterrent to the local remanufacturer. Ferguson and Toktay (2006) studies the motivation for an OEM without remanufacturing to deter the remanufacturer’s entry into the reverse channel. In fact, an OEM might not remanufacture due to a too high remanufacturing cost factor h or fixed investment F. In this case, however, it is shown that remanufacturing could still be profitable for an external remanufacturer thus the OEM may suffer from it. Specifically, Nash Equilibrium can be obtained by simultaneously solving the following problems faced by the OEM and remanufacturer: q2r Þ ¼ ðp2n ðq2n ; qc max q2n P2 ðq2n jc 2r Þ cÞq2n ;
(24)
Supply Chain Models with Active Acquisition and Remanufacturing
125
and q2r jq2n ; q1 Þ ¼ ðc p2r ðq2n ; qc q2r Þc q2r F max qb P2 ðc 2r Þ hc 2r
s:t:
qc 2r gq1 :
(25)
In the first period, the OEM determines the production quantity q1 expecting the equilibrium result of the second period. By analyzing the above problem, Ferguson and Toktay (2006) characterizes the potential profit loss for the OEM due to the sales competition with the remanufacturer. As a result, the OEM could adopt two entry-deterrent strategies: remanufacturing, and preemptive collection. By the first strategy, the OEM chooses to remanufacture for the sole purpose of discouraging an external remanufacturer to do so, even if the remanufacturing would not be preferable in a monopoly setting. By the second strategy, the OEM would choose to collect returned units with the quantity large enough to deter the remanufacturer from collecting and remanufacturing. The collected used product, however, is never remanufactured by the OEM. They further investigate the impact of collection cost, unit manufacturing cost and consumer willing-to-pay on the choice of which deterrent strategy to use for the OEM. As the collection cost/unit manufacturing cost/willingness-to-pay increases, the profitability of the remanufacturing becomes more prominent. Moreover, if the collection cost increases linearly in the quantity, the collection strategy would also become less attractive, which indicates the significance of an accurate modeling for the collection cost curve.
5 Conclusion The importance of remanufacturing has been widely recognized in terms of environmental sustainability and economical benefit. The topic of this chapter relates to the supply chain models on active acquisition and remanufacturing, with a discussion of the following three classes of problems. The first class is on the centralized system with acquisition price and sale price decisions, faced by remanufacturing firms utilizing a market-driven acquisition channel. The used product supply can be controlled actively by the acquisition price, and the acquisition management is shown as a significant driver of remanufacturing profitability. In the deterministic model, the efficient strategies are developed to balance the supply and demand through the pricing level. In the random yield model, the effect of remanufacturing random yield is explored, and the benefit of delaying pricing decisions to mitigate the yield randomness is analyzed. Both models belong to the class of centralized optimization. It is also common for a dominant party in the supply chain, usually the manufacturer, to dictate terms to other supply chain members to process some activities,
126
X. Li and Y. Li
such as acquisition or remanufacturing. It is the objective of Sect. 3 to investigate this vertical channel design problem for the decentralized supply chain. In the pure reverse logistic setting, it is shown that the channel preference is conditional on some parameters, although an OEM might prefer to outsource the collection activity rather than the remanufacturing activity from a practical perspective. On the other hand, in a closed-loop supply chain setting, the OEM is most likely to assign the collection activity to the retailer and most reluctantly to the 3PL collector. The supply chain coordination issue is also considered in both the cases. Moreover, conflict between entities at the same supply chain level is also prevailing, which is the central issue of Sect. 4. Different settings of product distinction and cost structure lead to different results, while the effects of horizontal competition are explored by comparing with the monopoly OEM case. We believe there is still great potential on the study of supply chain with active acquisition and remanufacturing. Possible further directions include the problem with more random factors, e.g., the problem with random acquisition, random yield, and random demand, etc. In this case, both the centralized and decentralized issues are more complicated, yet more interesting. Another promising research opportunity might be information asymmetry. The information issue in the supply chain field has been a hot topic, but very scarce research has been done related to the product acquisition and remanufacturing. Finally, it is to be studied on negotiation problem between the manufacturer and other supply chain members, within the framework of bargaining theory or other cooperative game theories. Acknowledgment This work is partly supported by National Natural Science Foundation of China (NSFC) Nos. 70971069, 71002077 and 71002106, the Fok Ying-Tong Education Foundation of China (Grant No. 121078), and 2009 Humanities and Social Science Youth Foundation of Nankai University (Grant No. NKQ09027).
References Aras N, Aksen D (2008) Locating collection centers for distance and incentive dependent returns. Int J Prod Econ 111(2):316–333 Aras N, Aksen D, Tanugur AG (2008) Locating collection centers for incentive dependent returns under a pick-up policy with capacitated vehicles. Eur J Oper Res 191(3):1223–1240 Atasu A, Sarvary M, Van Wassenhove LN (2008) Remanufacturing as a marketing strategy. Manage Sci 54(10):1731–1746 Bakal IS, Akcali E (2006) Effects of random yield in reverse supply chains with price-sensitive supply and demand. Prod Oper Manage 15(3):407–420 Debo L, Toktay B, Van Wassenhove LN (2005) Market segmentation and product technology selection for remanufacturable products. Manage Sci 51(8):1193–1205 Dekker R, Fleischmann M, Inderfurth K, Van Wassenhove LN (2004) Reverse logistics: quantitative models for closed-loop supply chains. Springer, New York Ferguson M, Toktay B (2006) The effect of competition on recovery strategies. Prod Oper Manage 15(3):351–368 Ferguson M, Guide VDR Jr, Souza G (2006) Supply chain coordination for false failure returns. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 8(4):376–393
Supply Chain Models with Active Acquisition and Remanufacturing
127
Ferrer G (2003) Yield information and supplier responsiveness in remanufacturing operations. Eur J Oper Res 149:540–556 Ferrer G, Swaminathan J (2006) Managing new and remanufactured products. Manage Sci 52 (1):15–26 Galbreth MR, Blackburn JD (2006) Optimal acquisition and sorting policies for remanufacturing. Prod Oper Manage 15:384–392 Guide VDR Jr, Jayaraman V (2000) Product acquisition management: current industry practice and a proposed framework. Int J Prod Res 38(16):3779–3800 Guide VDR Jr, Van Wassenhove LN (2001) Managing product returns for remanufacturing. Prod Oper Manage 10(2):142–155 Guide VDR Jr, Van Wassenhove LN (2009) The evolution of closed-loop supply chain research. Oper Res 57(1):10–18 Guide VDR Jr, Teunter R, Van Wassenhove LN (2003) Matching supply and demand to maximize profits from remanufacturing. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 5:303–316 Heese HS, Cattani K, Ferrer G, Gilland W, Roth AV (2005) Competitive advantage through takeback of used products. Eur J Oper Res 164:143–157 Ilgin M, Gupta S (2010) Environmentally conscious manufacturing and product recovery (ECMPRO): a review of the state of the art. J Environ Manage 91(3):563–591 Karakayali I, Emir-Farinas H, Akcali E (2006) An analysis of decentralized collection and processing of end-of-life products. J Oper Manage 25(6):1161–1183 Kaya O (2010) Incentive and production decisions for remanufacturing operations. Eur J Oper Res 201:442–453 Liang Y, Pokharel P, Lim GH (2009) Pricing used products for remanufacturing. Eur J Oper Res 193(2):390–395 Majumder P, Groenevelt H (2001a) Competition in remanufacturing. Prod Oper Manage 10 (2):125–141 Majumder P, Groenevelt H (2001b) Procurement competition in remanufacturing. Working paper, Duke University School of Business, Durham, NC Meyer H (1999) Many happy returns. J Bus Strategy 80(7):27–31 Mukhopadhyay S, Setoputro R (2005) Optimal return policy and modular design for build-to-order products. J Oper Manage 23:496–506 Padmanabhan V, Png IPL (1997) Manufacturer’s returns policies and retail competition. Mark Sci 16(4):81–94 Pasternack BA (1985) Optimal pricing and return policies for perishable commodities. Mark Sci 4 (2):166–176 Pokharel S, Mutha A (2009) Perspectives in reverse logistics: a review. Resour Conserv Recycl 53 (4):175–182 Prahinski C, Kocabasoglu C (2006) Empirical research opportunities in reverse supply chains. Omega 34(6):519–532 Qu X, Williams JA (2008) An analytical model for reverse automotive production planning and pricing. Eur J Oper Res 190(3):756–767 Ray S, Boyaci T, Aras N (2005) Optimal prices and trade-in rebates for durable, remanufacturable products. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 7:208–228 Robotis A, Bhattacharya S, van Wassenhove LN (2005) The effect of remanufacturing on procurement decisions for resellers in secondary markets. Eur J Oper Res 16(3):688–705 Savaskan C, Van Wassenhove LN (2006) Reverse channel design: the case of competing retailers. Manage Sci 52(1):1–14 Savaskan C, Bhattacharya S, Van Wassenhove LN (2004) Closed-loop supply chain models with product remanufacturing. Manage Sci 50(2):239–252 Vlachos D, Dekker R (2003) Return handling options and order quantities for single period products. Eur J Oper Res 151:38–52 Webster S, Mitra S (2007) Competitive strategy in remanufacturing and the impact of take-back laws. J Oper Manage 25(6):1123–1140
128
X. Li and Y. Li
Webster S, Mitra S (2008) Competition in remanufacturing and the effects of government subsidies. Int J Prod Econ 111(2):287–298 Wojanowski R, Verter V, Boyaci T (2007) Retail-collection network design under deposit-refund. Comput Oper Res 34:324–345 Yue X, Raghunathan S (2007) The impacts of the full returns policy on a supply chain with information asymmetry. Eur J Oper Res 180:630–647 Zikopoulos C, Tagaras G (2007) Impact of uncertainty in the quality of returns on the profitability of a single-period refurbishing operation. Eur J Oper Res 182:205–225
Part II
Analytical Models for Innovative Coordination under Uncertainty
.
Facilitating Demand Risk-Sharing with the Percent Deviation Contract Matthew J. Drake and Julie L. Swann
Abstract Suppliers do not have much incentive to build capacity for supply chains with stochastic demand in which the buyer bears little or no inventory risk. This hinders the supply chain from satisfying the optimal amount of customer demand from a channel perspective. We describe and analyze the percent deviation contract as an innovative mechanism to improve the overall performance of this type of supply chain. This contract induces a dynamic game of perfect information, and we characterize the subgame-perfect Nash Equilibria under various contract scenarios. We establish ways to set the contract parameters to coordinate the supply chain under uncertainty and show that the percent deviation contract is able to achieve channel coordination in some cases where the quantity flexibility contract fails. In order to aid the implementation of the percent deviation contract in practice, we develop ways to set the parameters to satisfy the buyer’s individual-rationality constraint. Keywords Supply chain coordination • Contracting • Newsvendor • Model • Risksharing
1 Introduction The proliferation of computerized information systems in the 1990s facilitated the establishment of supply chain partnerships in which demand information is shared between firms. The upstream firms can use this information to reduce the traditional M.J. Drake (*) Palumbo-Donahue Schools of Business, Duquesne University, Pittsburgh, PA 15282, USA e-mail: [email protected] J.L. Swann H. Milton Stewart School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, GA 30332-0205, USA e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_6, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
131
132
M.J. Drake and J.L. Swann
demand distortion due to the bullwhip effect. Some firms have also incorporated this information into contracts that induce their supply chain partners to share demand risk, thereby improving supply chain efficiency. Many researchers and practitioners (e.g., Lee 2004; Finley and Srikanth 2005) have advocated demand risk-sharing as a necessary condition for supply chain collaboration efforts to be successful in practice. In this paper we analyze one such contracting mechanism, an innovative structure which we denote as the percent deviation contract. The percent deviation contract is most applicable to supply chains in which the buyer does not traditionally bear any inventory obsolescence risk in satisfying stochastic consumer demand. In these channels the buyer places orders with the supplier only when the consumer demand is known with certainty; that is, the buyer does not carry any excess inventory. This environment occurs in many service operations. One industry that stands to benefit from application of the percent deviation contract is truckload transportation. In fact, a large truckload carrier originally proposed the idea for this particular contract structure but did not know how to set the parameters or whether or not the contract would be beneficial. While these carriers generally have standing weekly orders for loads with their bigger customers, many shippers call dispatch requesting a pickup in a few hours. This limits the carrier’s ability to utilize its equipment effectively by allocating trailers in advance or coordinating backhauls from prior shipments. The percent deviation mechanism is applicable in many traditional manufacturer–retailer channels as well, such as home construction, equipment integrators, window replacement, or door-to-door sales. In all of these industries, the supplier bears most, if not all, of the consumer demand risk in many arrangements. We analyze the strategic properties of the percent deviation contract in which the buyer gives an initial order estimate and the supplier pre-acquires inventory at a low cost. Once the buyer’s consumer demand is realized, the buyer places the actual order, and the supplier fulfills all or a portion of the order, possibly by expediting, at a higher cost. The buyer pays a penalty if the final order is outside of an allowable range established around the initial order estimate. We characterize the subgameperfect Nash Equilibria (SPNE) decisions when the supplier has a fixed expediting capacity and discuss methods of channel coordination to optimize the performance of the entire system. Since the buyer assumes some consumer demand risk under the percent deviation contract, its expected profit may be less than that under a traditional contracting structure; therefore, we develop a method that the supplier can use to satisfy the buyer’s individual-rationality constraint. Our contribution to the existing literature on supply chain collaboration includes analysis of a risk-sharing contract where decisions made by the buyer and supplier explicitly depend on each other and are solvable in the framework of a dynamic, extensive form game. This necessarily results in a more complex contract, but we also show that this contract can be strictly Pareto-improving for both parties. Our contract has a structure similar to the quantity flexibility contract, but ours does not enforce limits on the buyer’s final behavior; thus, this contract can coordinate the supply chain in some cases where quantity flexibility cannot. Many models consider a supply chain with infinite capacity; whereas, the total capacity in our model is a function of the supplier’s decisions as well as an external constraint.
Facilitating Demand Risk-Sharing with the Percent Deviation Contract
133
2 Literature Review The breadth of supply chain contracting literature has grown significantly over the last two decades as researchers and practitioners have examined strategic relationships between supply chain partners. One stream of supply chain contracting literature has proposed and analyzed methods of coordinating decentralized decisions to attain the optimal supply chain profit. See Tsay et al. (1999) and Fugate et al. (2006) for extensive reviews of the supply chain contracting literature. We discuss below the most relevant contracting references, which model a system with multiple, sequential decisions. Tsay (1999) analyzes a quantity flexibility contract in which the retailer commits to purchasing no less than a certain percentage of the initial forecast while the supplier agrees to fulfill up to a certain percentage above the forecast. He also evaluates the sharing of demand risk that produces the coordinated channel. Tsay and Lovejoy (1999) extend these results to a rolling horizon decision environment. More recently, Lian and Deshmukh (2009) develop a finite-horizon dynamic programming model for a quantity flexibility contract where the buyer can adjust previously-determined order quantities in response to updated demand information for a higher price. Bassok and Anupindi (2008) discuss a similar model where the buyer must establish quantity commitments for multiple periods into the future and then can adjust them within a certain tolerance in a rolling horizon fashion. In contrast to quantity flexibility, the percent deviation contract places no limits on the buyer’s final order, although it adds complexity to the decision environment by including additional contract parameters. We show in Sect. 4.3 that this added complexity can be justified because the percent deviation contract succeeds in coordinating the supply chain in several cases where the quantity flexibility contract is known to be unable to coordinate the channel. Donohue (2000) and Cachon (2004) analyze contracts with two-tier pricing structure that induce early commitment from buyers. In both of these contracts the buyer is bound to its order in both periods, whereas in our contract the first order is only an estimate of demand and can be freely adjusted once demand is known. These two papers only consider the full compliance contract regime where the supplier must fulfill the entire order; whereas, we model the supplier’s compliance decision explicitly. Several contracts employ an options framework where the buyer makes a firm order commitment and purchases options for additional goods to be exercised if demand is high. Cachon and Lariviere (2001) consider a single period model with options and forecast sharing. Since the buyer has an incentive to provide a biased forecast, they develop conditions that facilitate the credible sharing of forecasts under both full and voluntary compliance. Barnes-Schuster et al. (2002) extend the options framework using a two-period model with correlated demand between periods. Wang and Liu (2007) develop some structural properties of coordinating options contracts in channels with powerful retailers, and Zhao et al. (2010) show that an options contract can coordinate the supply chain and can be
134
M.J. Drake and J.L. Swann
Pareto-improving compared with a traditional wholesale-price contract. In our model we have no firm commitment and no upper bound on the final order amount, so our contract cannot be reduced to an option-based model. An additional series of studies (see, for example, Erkoc and Wu 2005; Serel 2007) have analyzed reservation fee supply contracts in which the buyer pays a (usually) deductible fee to reserve capacity along with an exercise fee for the final order quantity. The manufacturer builds capacity based on the reservations made, but it can also build excess capacity to offer at a higher spot rate once demand is realized. The aforementioned studies only consider linear reservation fee contracts–where each unit ordered is charged the same prices. The percent deviation contract is a special case of a piecewise-linear reservation fee contract in which the reservation and exercise prices differ for various portions of the order. In addition to contracting, several papers (e.g., Lee et al. 2000; Cachon and Fisher 2000; Balakrishnan et al. 2004) have examined various ways of reducing the bullwhip effect through information sharing in decentralized supply chains. Kulp et al. (2004) study the benefits the manufacturer gains under different degrees of information sharing and collaboration. They find that most of the manufacturers’ benefit from information integration comes from collaborative activities such as vendor-managed inventory and collaborative forecasting instead of simply sharing information. On the contrary, our results suggest that the risk sharing induced by the percent deviation contract enables the supplier and the entire channel to attain higher profit. We develop a model in the next section for the general case where the supplier has an expediting capacity constraint as well as the special case of infinite capacity. In Sect. 4 we identify conditions on the contract parameters that satisfy each party’s participation constraints, detail ways to coordinate the channel in each decentralized scenario, and compare the percent deviation contract with the wellknown quantity flexibility contract. We demonstrate the use of the percent deviation contract on several numerical examples in Sect. 5, and we discuss the study’s conclusions and suggestions for future research in the final section of the chapter.
3 Models and Scenarios The percent deviation contract accommodates the following sequence of decisions. The buyer provides an initial estimate of its final-order demand that will be placed at a later date. The seller can then use this information to acquire goods in advance (e.g., a truckload carrier can preposition trucks or coordinate backhauls to optimize its transportation network) at a low cost in anticipation of this demand. When the buyer’s demand is known with certainty, the buyer places actual order with the supplier. Depending on the contract parameters, the seller can choose to satisfy additional demand by expediting or subcontracting at a high cost or can choose to fulfill only the demand equal to the number of previously-acquired goods. The percent deviation penalty is the mechanism that punishes the buyer for unrealistic
Facilitating Demand Risk-Sharing with the Percent Deviation Contract
135
estimates. If the buyer’s final order is within a certain percentage above or below the initial estimate, no penalty is charged. If the order exceeds the limits, the supplier charges a penalty on all goods ordered outside of the tolerable range.
3.1
Notation and Assumptions
We employ notation adapted from Donohue (2000). The buyer receives r dollars in revenue for each unit and pays a wholesale price, w, to the supplier. We assume that the buyer earns a positive gross margin from these transactions (i.e., r > w). Consumer demand for a period is given by the random variable X, which has a continuous, differentiable probability distribution function, f(x). If the buyer cannot satisfy the customers’ demand (due to lack of product availability), it incurs a customer penalty of b per unit.1 The seller faces a cost of c1 dollars to acquire a unit of inventory in anticipation of demand and must pay c2 dollars to satisfy demand after the firm order has been placed. We assume that c2 > c1, so the c2 can be thought of as an expediting or subcontracting cost. If the supplier has excess inventory at the end of the period, it receives a unit salvage value of v. It is natural to assume that w > v and c1 > v, which ensure that the supplier does not receive too much of a benefit from selling goods for salvage. Since the seller may choose not to satisfy the buyer’s entire order, it must pay the buyer a for each unit ordered but not delivered. We assume that a < b, which signifies that lost customers are more costly for the buyer. The per-unit penalty that the buyer must pay the supplier for orders outside of the allowable deviation range is denoted by p, while d ∈ [0,1] is the percentage that defines the range. For orders above the upper limit of the range, the buyer only pays the percent deviation penalty for the units that the supplier fulfills. The buyer’s initial forecast is given by q1, and the actual order is q2. The number of units the supplier acquires in advance of demand is t1, and the additional goods expedited or subcontracted are denoted by t2. The supplier has a maximum expediting capacity of M units. This particular way of modeling the supplier’s capacity bears further consideration. It is important to note that the capacity for the supplier’s pre-acquisition decision is infinite. By setting the t1 value, the supplier is de facto determining the capacity of the system as a whole, which is equal to t1 + M. This structure is appropriate for buyer–supplier transactions in which the supplier has a lot of capacity in its system but must make the allocation decisions across many customers before production occurs. Therefore, if the supplier knows in advance that demand will be high, it can allocate sufficient capacity to satisfy the large order; closer to the purchase date, however, it can only provide a limited amount of 1 This b could also be viewed as the higher cost from using an alternative supplier not under longterm contract.
136
M.J. Drake and J.L. Swann
excess capacity because the rest of the system is dedicated to fulfilling orders from other customers. We make the following assumptions that improve tractability but are not likely to impede the application of the results. The first assumption is that all costs are constant for each unit of demand for a single product line because we are interested in examining the structure of the incentives. Another assumption is the existence of complete, symmetric cost, capacity, and demand information between the two parties. When the buyer places the final order, it knows the exact demand as is usual in the other relevant service and manufacturer–retailer channels discussed in Sect. 1. If the actual demand exceeds the upper limit of the deviation range, the cost and penalty parameters determine whether or not the buyer’s order equals the full demand. In order for the buyer to order above the deviation threshold, the net cash flow must exceed the shortage penalty owed to the end consumer. r w p> b
(1)
If the inequality holds, then q2 ¼ X, or the actual customer demand. If this inequality is not satisfied (for instance, if the penalty for ordering outside of the deviation range is too high), q2 ¼ min{X,(1 þ d)q1}. The additional assumption w > p assures that if the actual demand is below the lower limit of the deviation range, (1 d)q1, the buyer orders the actual demand.
3.2
General Model with Finite Expediting Capacity
We begin our analysis with the decentralized structure in which each party makes decisions to optimize its individual expected profit. Even though the supplier has an expediting capacity of M units, the cost of expediting these units, c2, might be too high for the supplier to choose to do so. In order for the supplier to use any of this expediting capacity, the cash flow from expediting must be higher than the cost of failing to expedite. These flows are dependent on whether or not the supplier will receive the deviation penalty on some or all of these units. While the two buyer scenarios discussed above, which are dependent on whether or not the buyer is willing to place orders above the upper limit of the deviation range, generate different supplier responses, the derivation and form of these optimal decisions are the same in both cases. Thus, in this chapter we only examine the case in which the buyer is willing to order the entire demand even if it must pay the deviation penalty. (See Drake (2006) for the case in which the buyer will not order above the upper limit of the deviation range.) When the buyer is willing to order the actual demand, the supplier’s expediting decision can be determined a priori, without knowledge of how many units for which the buyer will pay the deviation penalty. If w c2 > a, then the supplier finds it beneficial to expedite whether or not the buyer will pay the deviation penalty
Facilitating Demand Risk-Sharing with the Percent Deviation Contract
137
on any units; consequently, t2 ¼ ðminfq2 t1 ; MgÞþ . We will denote this as Case A. Similarly, if w c2 þ p < a, the supplier would not choose to expedite any units even if the buyer paid the deviation penalty on all of the units; and thus, t2 ¼ 0. This will be Case B. We will use backward induction to solve for the subgame-perfect Nash Equilibria in each scenario. We now formulate the expected profit functions for the buyer and supplier in Case A, where q2 ¼ X and t2 ¼ ðminfq2 t1 ; 0gÞþ . The supplier chooses t1 to maximize the following expected profit function: Z t1 þM Z 1 S PA ¼ w xf ðxÞdx þ ðt1 þ MÞð1 Fðt1 þ MÞÞ a ðx t1 MÞf ðxÞdx Z
t1 þM
0
minft1 þM;ð1dÞq1 g
þp "Z0 þp
t1 þM
ð1þdÞq1
Z
t1
þv
ðminft1 þ M; ð1 dÞq1 g xÞf ðxÞdx # þ
ðx ð1 þ dÞq1 Þf ðxÞdx þ ðt1 þ M ð1 þ dÞq1 Þ ð1 Fðt1 þ MÞÞ Z
ðt1 xÞf ðxÞdx c1 t1 c2
0
t1 þM
ðx t1 Þf ðxÞdx þ Mð1 Fðt1 þ MÞÞ :
t1
(2) There are three separate functions that represent the realizations of the expected profit function in (2) based on the relationship between the total system capacity, t1 þ M, and the boundaries of the deviation range, (1 d)q1 and (1 þ d)q1. The expected profit regions are depicted in Fig. 1. In region S1 the supplier sets capacity so that it cannot even satisfy the lower limit of the deviation range. Region S2 prescribes that the total system capacity lies somewhere in the deviation range. In these first two regions, the buyer will never pay the deviation penalty for orders above the upper limit of the range because these units will never be fulfilled. Region S3 specifies that the system capacity exceeds the upper limit of the deviation range. In each region only one of the three separate expected profit realizations is feasible, regardless of which expected profit is higher in the region. The following observation establishes that the overall expected profit function is continuous. Observation 1 The individual expected profit function realizations that are active in two adjacent feasible regions are equal at the boundary (i.e., and PSA:II: ðð1 þ dÞq1 MÞ PSA:I: ðð1 dÞq1 MÞ ¼ PSA:II: ðð1 dÞq1 MÞ 2 S ¼ PA:III: ðð1 þ dÞq1 MÞ). Fig. 1 Regions of capacity defining the form of the supplier’s expected profit function
S1
S2 (1-d)q1
S3 (1+d)q1
t1+M
The three separate functions (PSA:I: , PSA:II: , and PSA:III: ) are defined in (24)–(26) in the Appendix.
2
138
M.J. Drake and J.L. Swann
Lemma 1. If w þ a > p þ c2, the supplier’s expected profit function in (2) is piecewise-concave, a continuous, piecewise function whose separate segments are individually concave. Each of the individual realizations of (2) has a corresponding maximizing value that is derived from the solution to the following equations, w þ a c1 ðc2 vÞFðtÞ (3) t1A:I: 2 t : Fðt þ MÞ ¼ w þ a c2 p w þ a c1 ðc2 vÞFðtÞ A:II: (4) t1 2 t : Fðt þ MÞ ¼ w þ a c2 t1A:III: 2
t : Fðt þ MÞ ¼
w þ a c1 þ p ðc2 vÞFðtÞ ; w þ a c2 þ p
(5)
which are all dependent on the supplier’s available expediting capacity. It is interesting to note that all of these values are independent of the buyer’s order quantity; they can easily be computed from the exogenous parameters. We can always solve these equations by applying the Intermediate Value Theorem since the left-hand sides are all bounded between 0 and 1. To understand the supplier’s best response to q1, we can consider the individual functional maximizers in (3)–(5) and their relationship to each other and the boundaries of the feasible regions. The following theorem characterizes the supplier’s best response, which is dependent on the specific value of the buyer’s decision, q1, via the feasible region boundary conditions. Theorem 1. The supplier’s best w þ a > p þ c2 is 8 A:I: t1 ; > > > > A:II: > ; t > > >1 > > > > > > > > tA:III: ; > >1 > > < ð1 dÞq1 M; t1 ðq1 Þ ¼ > > > > S > arg maxtA:I > ;t1A:III: PA ; > 1 > > > > arg maxð1dÞq1 M;t1A:III: PSA ; > > > > > > > > > : arg max A:II: A:III: PS ; t1 ;t1 A
response to a given value of q1 when if t1A:I: ð1 dÞq1 M & tA:III: ð1 þ dÞq1 M; 1 if ð1 dÞq1 M tA:II: ð1 þ dÞq1 M & 1 A:III: t1 ð1 þ dÞq1 M; if tA:II: ð1 þ dÞq1 M & tA:III: ð1 þ dÞq1 M; 1 1 if tA:II: ð1 dÞq1 M t1A:I: & 1 ð1 þ dÞq1 M; tA:III: 1 if t1A:I: ð1 dÞq1 M & tA:III: ð1 þ dÞq1 M; 1 if tA:II: ð1 dÞq1 M t1A:I: & 1 ð1 þ dÞq1 M; tA:III: 1 if ð1 dÞq1 M tA:II: ð1 þ dÞq1 M tA:III: : 1 1 (6)
The supplier’s best response function in (6) is admittedly complicated and difficult to interpret. To aid the reader’s understanding of this function, we provide
Facilitating Demand Risk-Sharing with the Percent Deviation Contract
Supplier I
t1 t1III
{S3}
{S1} t1I
{S1,S2} t1III
t1
argmax t1I, t1III
t1III
{S1,S2}
(1-d)q1-M
t1
{S2}
{S3}
t1II I
t1I
t1III t1II
{S1}
II
{S1}
{S1,S2}
argmax (1-d)q1-M, t1III
t1
{S2}
{S1,S2}
{S3}
{S1,S2} t1II
t1III
t1III
{S3}
argmax (1-d)q1-M, t1III t1III
III
II
{S3} t1III
{S 3}
{S3} t1
t1III
{S2} (1-d)q1-M
t1III
t1II
139
t1II
argmax t1II, t1III
argmax t1II, t1III
Fig. 2 Supplier’s best response depiction for Scenario A
a decision tree-type depiction of the supplier’s optimal decision for various problem parameters in Fig. 2. The buyer must choose the q1 that maximizes its expected profit while anticipating the supplier’s response to the chosen value. The buyer’s expected profit function is given by "Z # t1 ðq1 ÞþM B xf ðxÞdx þ t1 ðq1 Þ þ M 1 F t1 ðq1 Þ þ M PA ¼ ðr wÞ Z p "Z0 p
0
minfð1dÞq1 ;t1 ðq1 ÞþMg
t1 ðq1 ÞþM ð1þdÞq1
minfð1 dÞq1 ; t1 ðq1 Þ þ Mg x f ðxÞdx
ðx ð1 þ dÞq1 Þf ðxÞdx
(7)
i þ þ t1 ðq1 Þ þ M ð1 þ dÞq1 1 F t1 ðq1 Þ þ M Z 1 þ ða bÞ x t1 ðq1 Þ M f ðxÞdx: t1 ðq1 ÞþM
The supplier’s best response function in (6) is comprised of four explicit values as well as three situations where the supplier chooses the profit-maximizing quantity from a set of two of the explicit values. We first determine how the buyer should set q1 when the supplier will respond with each of the four possible t1 values. Each of these cases results in a different realization of the buyer’s expected profit function in (7). We apply the Karush–Kuhn–Tucker (KKT) conditions (c.f. Bazaraa et al. 1993: 151–155) over each realization’s feasible range of decisions to determine the constrained optimal values of q1.
140
M.J. Drake and J.L. Swann
Table 1 Possible SPNE pairs and feasibility conditions for Case A’s explicit t1(q1) decisions ðq1 ; t1 ðq1 ÞÞ Feasibility conditions n n A:I: oo A:III: þM t þM t ; t1A:I: Always feasible q1A:I: q : q max 11d ; 1 1þd
A:III: þM 1 maxftA:II: g 1 ;t1 ; t1A:II: Always feasible qA:II: max F1dð0Þ ; 1 1þd ðqA:III: fq : ð1 dÞFðð1 dÞqÞ ¼ 1
qA:III: 1
Þ dÞqÞÞg; tA:III: 1
ð1 þ dÞð1 Fðð1 þ q : Fðð1 dÞqÞ ¼
ðq1:A:IV:
rwaþb ; rwaþbþp
ð1 dÞq1A:IV: MÞ
A:III: þM minftA:II: g 1 ;t1 1þd
n A:II: o t þM tA:III: þM q1A:IV: max 1 1d ; 1 1þd qA:IV: 1
tA:I: 1 þM 1d
Theorem 2. The possible subgame-perfect Nash Equilibrium (SPNE) decision pairs for explicit t1 ðq1 Þ decisions are given in Table 1. We must also determine the buyer’s optimal decision over the regions where it knows that the supplier will be selecting the maximizing argument of a set of two values. From Theorem 1, we establish the following ranges of q1 under which each situation is possible. arg maxtA:I PSA : ;tA:III: 1 1 arg maxð1dÞq1 M;tA:III: PSA: : 1
t1A:I: þ M tA:III: þ M q1 1 (8) 1d 1þd A:I: tA:II: þM t1 þ M t1A:III: þ M 1 (9) q1 min ; 1d 1d 1þd
PSA : q1 arg maxtA:II: ;tA:III: 1 1
tA:II: þ M tA:II: þM tA:III: þ M 1 & 1 q1 1 1d 1þd 1þd
(10)
Since all three situations involve the possible decision t1A:III: , we define the difference function, DðtÞ PSA ðt1A:III: Þ PSA ðtÞ, where t is any other possible supplier pre-acquisition amount. While it is difficult to determine the exact feasible region for q1 that induces each of the possible t1(q1) values, we can use these difference functions to explain how a buyer would determine its optimal decision for a given set of problem parameters. Proposition 1. The structure of the three difference functions for the decisions in (8)–(10) enables us to determine the specific ranges of q1 that induce each of the two possible supplier values for t1. For each instance there are at most seven decision pairs from Table 1 and obtained from the procedure in Proposition 1, but some of these decisions may not be mutually feasible given a set of problem parameters. Since this set contains a maximum of seven elements, the buyer can evaluate its expected profit in (7) with respect to each of the feasible pairs and select the value of q1 that yields the highest
Facilitating Demand Risk-Sharing with the Percent Deviation Contract
141
expected profit to obtain the overall subgame-perfect Nash Equilibrium for this sequential supply chain game. Each of the formulas used in computing the potential decision pairs has an economic interpretation. The buyer always sets the initial order estimate with a goal of minimizing the expected deviation penalty that must be paid under each scenario. In the case where the supplier has system capacity larger than the upper limit of the deviation range, the optimal quantity balances the expected lower and upper deviation penalties. The supplier also seeks to balance the expected revenue from pre-acquiring inventory with the cost of doing so as well as the expected expediting and shortage costs. Even though the resulting formulas are more complicated, the supplier follows the same rationale as in a traditional newsvendor contract. We now consider Case B, where the supplier chooses not to expedite any units after the buyer places the final order because of a high expediting cost. This case is analogous to Case A when M ¼ 0 since the supplier can be viewed as having an effective expediting capacity of zero units if it chooses not to expedite. The maximizing values below correspond with the equations in (3)–(5) with M ¼ 0. t1B:I: 2
w þ a c1 t : FðtÞ ¼ wþavp
tB:II: 1
2
w þ a c1 t : FðtÞ ¼ wþav
t1B:III: 2
t : FðtÞ ¼
(11)
w þ a c1 þ p wþavþp
(12) (13)
Using the relationships in Lemma 4 (stated in the Appendix) to simplify the feasibility conditions, the supplier’s best response in this scenario is characterized by the following theorem. While it may not seem like it at first glance, the feasibility conditions for each of the decisions in (14) correspond to those in (6). Theorem 3. The supplier’s best response to a given value of q1 when w + a > p + v is 8 B:I: t1 ; > > > > tB:II: > 1 ; > > B:III: > t > 1 ; > > < ð1 dÞq1 ; t1 ðq1 Þ ¼ arg max B:I: B:III: PS ; t1 ;t1 B > > > S > B:III: arg max > ð1dÞq1 ;t1 PB ; > > > > > > : S B:III: P ; arg maxtB:II: B 1 ;t1
if t1B:I: ð1 dÞq1 & t1B:III: ð1 þ dÞq1 ; if ð1 dÞq1 tB:II: & t1B:III: ð1 þ dÞq1 ; 1 if tB:II: ð1 þ dÞq ; 1 1 if tB:II: ð1 dÞq1 t1B:I: & t1B:III: ð1 þ dÞq1 ; 1 if t1B:I: ð1 dÞq1 & t1B:III: ð1 þ dÞq1 ; if tB:II: ð1 dÞq1 t1B:I: & 1 t1B:III: ð1 þ dÞq1 ; if ð1 dÞq1 tB:II: ð1 þ dÞq1 t1B:III: : 1 (14)
142
M.J. Drake and J.L. Swann
The possible subgame-perfect Nash Equilibrium decision pairs in Case I.B. are the same as those for Case A (given in Table 1) except with the B supplier decision values replacing the A decisions. The buyer’s decisions are exactly the same as those in Case A since the actual q1 values are independent of M. The buyer can again apply the methods described in the proof of Proposition 1 to determine the optimal value of q1 in the cases in which the supplier’s best response is the value among a set of maximizing arguments for two of the expected profit realizations. Once the feasible set of possible decision pairs is determined, the buyer can again substitute each of them into its expected profit function to find the maximizing decision pair, which is the SPNE. If the contract’s parameters are such that neither of the above scenarios (A or B) apply, then the supplier’s expediting decision is dependent on the magnitude of the final order. The most interesting case is when the supplier will receive the deviation penalty for some of the expedited units and not for others, so we consider the case where q2 > (1 + d)q1 and t1 + M > (1 + d)q1. For it to be Pareto optimal for the supplier to fulfill the entire order, the cash flow from satisfying must be greater than the cash flow from not satisfying. When q2 t1 + M, which means that the supplier has enough capacity to satisfy the full order if it wants to, we must have (w c2) (q2 t1) + p(q2 (1 + d)q1) a(q2 t1). Solving for q2, the supplier satisfies the extra demand if q2
ðw c2 þ aÞt1 þ pð1 þ dÞq1 L1 : w c2 þ a þ p
Formally, the supplier’s expediting decision is ðq2 t1 Þþ ; if q2 L1 t2 ¼ 0; if q2 < L1 : When the actual order exceeds the supplier’s total capacity (i.e., q2 > t1 + M), the supplier can only satisfy an additional M units beyond t1. If the supplier chooses to supply the additional M units, it will have to pay the buyer the a penalty on each of the q2 t1 M that were ordered and not fulfilled. Thus, we must have (w c2)M + p(t1 + M (1 + d)q1) a(q2 t1 M) a(q2 t1) for the supplier to want to supply the extra M units. This condition simplifies to M
pðð1 þ dÞq1 t1 Þ L2 : w c2 þ a þ p
This means that the supplier’s decision to expedite the M additional units is M; if M L2 t2 ¼ 0; if 0
Facilitating Demand Risk-Sharing with the Percent Deviation Contract
143
added supply uncertainty. Knowing that the expediting decision rests with the magnitude of the order might induce the buyer to inflate the final order so that the supplier will fulfill the entire amount. The buyer’s strategic behavior in this case is detrimental for the supplier because it could be induced to expedite when it would not otherwise. To alleviate these difficulties, we recommend that the parties set the negotiated parameters–p and a–such that the contract assumes another case. This could be accomplished by letting a > c2 w, shifting the contract to the A case. Of course, shifts to other scenarios are possible through negotiations, depending on the relative market power of the parties. Since both parties have an incentive to set the contract parameters to move the contract to other cases, we omit this intermediate situation from further analysis and subsequently only consider Cases A and B.
3.3
Infinite Expediting Capacity
We conclude our presentation of the general models by considering a special case in which the supplier’s expediting capacity is infinite (or especially large for practical purposes). These uncapacitated models have an especially simple structure that enables us to develop (quasi) closed-form optimal decisions. Since this extension is based on the expediting capacity, we must only develop models for case analogous to A above, in which the supplier chooses to expedite. It does not matter how much extra capacity the supplier has if it chooses not to use it. Again we only consider the case where the buyer orders the actual demand in all cases (i.e., q2 ¼ X and t2 ¼ ðminfq2 t1 ; MgÞþ ) since (1) holds and w c2 > a. (It is straightforward to extend these models to the case in which the buyer does not order above the deviation range; see Drake (2006) for details.) We denote this scenario as A.1. The supplier’s expected profit function is again the same as in (2) with M ¼ 1, but this substitution results in the simpler function Z PSA:1
1
¼w
Z
0
þp þv
Z
ð1dÞq1
xf ðxÞdx þ p 1
ð1þdÞq1 Z t1
ðð1 dÞq1 xÞf ðxÞdx
0
ðx ð1 þ dÞq1 Þf ðxÞdx
(15) Z
1
ðt1 xÞf ðxÞdx c1 t1 c2
0
ðx t1 Þf ðxÞdx:
t1
The expected profit function in (15) is concave by Lemma 1, so we can solve for the optimal pre-acquisition amount using first order conditions. This yields c 2 c1 tA:1 ; (16) 2 t : FðtÞ ¼ 1 c2 v which is independent of the buyer’s initial order estimate because of the symmetric information assumption and the infinite total system capacity.
144
M.J. Drake and J.L. Swann
Similarly, the buyer’s expected profit function is the same as in (7), but infinite supplier capacity yields the following simplified form. Z PBA:1
¼ ðr wÞ Z 1 p
1
0
ð1þdÞq1
Z
ð1dÞq1
xf ðxÞdx p
ðð1 dÞq1 xÞf ðxÞdx
0
(17)
ðx ð1 þ dÞq1 Þf ðxÞdx
Because the supplier is willing to expedite to satisfy the buyer’s order regardless of its size, the buyer’s expected profit function is no longer dependent on the supplier’s t1 decision. In this case, the t1 decision only affects the supplier’s profitability and not its ability to fulfill the buyer’s order. The buyer’s optimal initial order estimate is given by qA:1 fq : ð1 dÞ 1 Fðð1 dÞqÞ ¼ ð1 þ dÞð1 Fðð1 þ dÞqÞÞg, which corresponds with the optimal decision in Case A.III in which the supplier has the capacity to satisfy orders is the value of q1 above the upper limit of the deviation range. The decision qA:1 1 that equates the marginal expected deviation penalty for demands below the lower limit of the range, p(1 d)F((1 d)q1), to the marginal expected penalty for orders above the upper limit, p(1 + d)(1 F((1 + d)q1)). Since the nominal deviation penalty, p, is the same regardless of whether the deviation was a lower deviation or an upper deviation, it is irrelevant to the buyer’s decision. Of course, if there were two deviation penalties, pl and pu, they would affect the buyer’s decision. A:1 Thus, the SPNE for the A.1 case is ðq1 ; t1 ðq1 ÞÞ ¼ ðqA:1 1 ; t1 Þ for all parameter sets such that w c2 > a. It applies in situations where the supplier always has enough extra capacity in its network to satisfy the buyer’s order. It would be most reasonable when the buyer’s requirements are small compared with the supplier’s capabilities. Consequently, the supplier would only need to utilize the more complicated capacitated contracts for customers who require a large portion of its capacity. Since these buyers are larger, they are presumably more important to the supplier, so it would have more incentive to utilize a more complicated contract for these customers.
4 Economic Analysis and Model Extensions 4.1
Individual Rationality Constraints
The practical implementation of the percent deviation contract is necessarily impacted by the competitive power of the parties. If the buyer has a powerful market presence, it will likely be able to negotiate favorable contract terms by threatening to use another supplier who offers a more traditional agreement. (We assume that the contract is used in a competitive industry, so the buyer can find
Facilitating Demand Risk-Sharing with the Percent Deviation Contract
145
another supplier with comparable service performance and quality.) The terms of the contract, therefore, must satisfy the buyer’s individual-rationality constraint, which says that under the percent deviation contract the buyer must be able to attain an expected profit at least as great as it could under a traditional mechanism. See Tirole (1988) for a detailed discussion of individual-rationality constraints. If this constraint is not satisfied, the buyer will switch to another supplier. In this section we compare our percent deviation contract to the status quo of a traditional wholesale-price contract. In the cases where the supplier’s expediting capacity is limited, the percent deviation mechanism can induce the supplier to preacquire significantly more inventory than it would under the traditional wholesaleprice contract. This additional ability to meet demand is beneficial for both parties, resulting in higher expected profits without further contract modifications. This is the situation demonstrated in the numerical example in Sect. 5.1. In situations where the supplier does not increase its pre-acquisition quantity significantly (i.e., the deviation penalty is not high enough to induce the supplier to pre-acquire much more inventory than under the traditional wholesale-price contract), it is clear that the buyer will earn less expected profit under the percent deviation contract because it now shares additional demand risk by paying the deviation penalty for orders outside of the allowable range. There are several ways in which the parties can adjust the terms of the percent deviation contract to satisfy the buyer’s individual-rationality constraint. The supplier can offer the buyer a fixed transfer payment to share some of its gain. In some cases the supplier can offer a discounted wholesale price, w0 , that gives the buyer the same expected profit as it would attain under the traditional wholesaleprice contract. The remainder of this section illustrates the methodology required to find the requisite discounted wholesale price. The A.1 infinite capacity model is comparable to the traditional newsvendor, wholesale-price (NV) contract, since the supplier chooses and has the capacity to satisfy the entire order. The Rbuyer’s expected profit function under the NV contract 1 is given by PBNV ¼ ðr wÞ 0 xf ðxÞdx. Notice that this function is not dependent on any decision by the supplier, because under a traditional contract in this setting the buyer places orders for exactly the number of units needed with no demand risk. Comparing this expected profit to that under the percent deviation contract in (15) with the qA:1 decision, the contracting parties wish to find w0 such that PBNV ðwÞ 1 PBA:1 ðw0 Þ, to ensure that the buyer earns at least as much expected profit under the percent deviation contract as it does under the original wholesale-price contract. We find that the discounted wholesale price given by 0
2R ð1dÞqA:1
w0 @wp4
1
0
31þ R1 ðð1dÞqA:1 xÞf ðxÞdxþ ð1þdÞqA:1 ðxð1þdÞqA:1 Þf ðxÞdx 1 1 1 5A R1 0 xf ðxÞdx (18)
satisfies the buyer’s participation constraint. The term in brackets represents the percentage of order periods in which the deviation penalty will be paid.
146
M.J. Drake and J.L. Swann
Consequently, the supplier must provide an allowance for this expected penalty if the buyer is to realize the same expected profit as in the newsvendor contract. If the right side of (18) assumes the value of zero, there is no discounted wholesale price mechanism that can satisfy the buyer’s rationality constraint with the given contract parameters. The supplier also has an individual-rationality constraint that should be considered. To induce the buyer to participate in the percent deviation contract in this case, the supplier must offer the discounted wholesale price discussed above. This reduces its expected profit from the high theoretical profit that could be earned under the percent deviation contract with the original newsvendor wholesale price. This is not a problem when we compare the supplier’s expected profit to that of the wholesale-price contract. The percent deviation contract induces the supplier to establish a higher system capacity (t1 + M) than the wholesale-price contract does. This increases the total expected profit of the entire supply chain because the supply chain is able to satisfy more of the consumer demand. If the supplier offers w0 equal to the right-hand side of (18), the buyer’s expected profit under percent deviation will be equal to its expected profit under the wholesale-price contract, and the supplier captures all of the additional supply chain profit. This makes the supplier better off than it was under the wholesale-price contract. Even if the supplier decides to make the buyer strictly better off by offering a slightly smaller value of w0 than the right-hand side of (18) requires, there is a range of values where both parties can improve their position by splitting the increased supply chain expected profit. This is the situation demonstrated in the numerical example in Sect. 5.2.
4.2
Channel Coordination
Supply chain research has shown that the total supply chain profit is maximized by a centralized firm making decisions that are best for the system as a whole. One main objective of supply chain contracts is to align each entity’s own incentives to induce decentralized decisions that attain the maximal centralized supply chain profit. This achievement is commonly referred to as “channel coordination.” We first examine the performance of the centralized channel and then develop mechanisms to coordinate the channel.
4.2.1
Centralized Channel Benchmark
In terms of a centralized channel, the buyer and the seller are viewed as a single entity trying to maximize its own expected profit. Hence, there is no wholesale price (w) paid from the sales department (the buyer) to the manufacturing department (the seller), and the penalties levied under the percent deviation contract (p and a) are not valid. The buyer’s decisions are not relevant either since the single company does not order from itself; the combined firm must only determine the number of units to acquire early and the number to expedite.
Facilitating Demand Risk-Sharing with the Percent Deviation Contract
147
If the cost structure for the centralized channel is such that r c2 > b, the firm will satisfy additional demand beyond the number of pre-acquired goods up to capacity M. In this case the number of units to be expedited is given by t2 ¼ (min {X t1, M})+. The channel’s expected profit function is Z
Z t1 xf ðxÞdx þ ðt1 þ MÞð1 Fðt1 þ MÞÞ þ v ðt1 xÞf ðxÞdx c1 t1 0 0 Z t1 þM c2 ðx t1 Þf ðxÞdx þ Mð1 Fðt1 þ MÞÞ t Z 11 ðx t1 MÞf ðxÞdx: (19) b
PC:I: ¼ r
t1 þM
t1 þM
This newsvendor-type profit function is concave, so first order optimality n C:I: conditions show that the optimal solution for t is t 2 t : Fðt þ MÞ ¼ 1 1 o rþbc1 ðc2 vÞFðtÞ . rþbc2 If r c2 < b the loss from expediting or subcontracting to meet the marginal demand is larger than the cash outlay from the penalty paid to the customer for not satisfying its demand. Accordingly, the centralized channel will not expedite at the higher cost c2 ; formally, we have t2 ¼ 0. The channel expected profit function now becomes Z
t1
PC:II: ¼ r 0
Z
Z xf ðxÞdx þ t1 ð1 Fðt1 ÞÞ þ v 1
b
t1
ðt1 xÞf ðxÞdx c1 t1
0
(20)
ðx t1 Þf ðxÞdx:
t1
The profit function in (20) is very similar to (19), except the expected revenue has been adjusted to reflect the fact that the centralized channel will not satisfy any demandnmore than t1. The o optimal number of units to acquire early is given by
1 tC:II: 2 t : Fðt1 Þ ¼ rþbc 1 rþbv .
4.2.2
Finite Expediting Capacity Channel Coordination
The subgame-perfect Nash Equilibria for the scenarios in which the supplier has finite expediting capacity have a complicated form. As a result, different mechanisms are required for each possible decision pair. Consequently, we consider one possible decision pair to show how the system can be coordinated given that particular decision. The procedure described below is applicable to all other possible decision pairs and case scenarios. We consider Case B, in which the buyer orders the entire demand but the supplier chooses not to expedite, where the corresponding decision pair is q1B:III: ; t1B:III: . The
148
M.J. Drake and J.L. Swann
following theorem contains the channel coordinating condition for this case, which also applies in Case A when the same decision pair is optimal. Theorem 4. The decentralized channel in scenario B (and A) in which the SPNE decision pair is q1B:III: ; t1B:III: will be coordinated if the contract parameters are set such that a þ p þ w ¼ r þ b:
(21)
The left-hand side of (21) comprises parameters that represent payments between the buyer and the supplier. These are set during contract negotiations as opposed to the right-hand side, which only contains parameters that we assumed were exogenous to the contract because they involve an outside party to the contract (the buyer’s customer). The parties can coordinate the channel by setting a, p, and w according to (21).
4.3
Comparison to Quantity Flexibility Contracts
Since the percent deviation contract provides the buyer with order flexibility around an initial order estimate, it is constructive to compare its channel performance with the quantity flexibility contract, which affords the buyer similar flexibility. Tsay (1999) establishes that the quantity flexibility contract cannot coordinate the supply chain when the buyer is not bound by a minimum purchase commitment. The percent deviation contract, on the other hand, does coordinate the channel without establishing a floor on the buyer’s order. Let us consider analysis for a particular case, e.g., the B scenario in which the SPNE is q1B:III: ; t1B:III: . Recall that this scenario can be coordinated by setting a + p + w ¼ r + b. To compare the quantity flexibility and percent deviation contracts, we need to analyze them in a similar framework. We apply the basic quantity flexibility contract structure but modify as follows to correspond to the percent deviation decision environment. We assume that the buyer’s actual order in the quantity flexibility contract is made after the customer demand has been realized, as in the percent deviation scenario. Consequently, the supplier commits to fulfilling a maximum of t1 units. The buyer establishes a minimum purchase commitment of (1 d)q1 units when it provides the initial order estimate, q1. If the buyer ends up being forced to order more units than are ultimately required to satisfy the realized demand (as a result of the minimum purchase quantity), these units generate u dollars per unit as a salvage value. We assume that leftover units of inventory are no more valuable to the buyer than they are to the supplier (i.e., u v). This is practical for several reasons. While it is true that goods generally appreciate in value as they move downstream in a supply chain, the buyer is not physically performing additional functions to add value to the product; consequently, the actual sale price of the salvaged product
Facilitating Demand Risk-Sharing with the Percent Deviation Contract
149
should be no higher than that which the supplier could receive if the good were sold it in the secondary market. Leftover product should be more valuable to the supplier in terms of expected revenue since the supplier could likely use the product to fulfill demand from another buyer while the buyer may have limited outlets to offload the extra product. This is especially true in the market for truckload transportation, which was an inspiration for the percent deviation contract. Carriers would obviously place more value on an unassigned truck than any one particular shipper might. Following the same backward-induction methodology we used in identifying the other equilibria, Theorem 5 provides the equilibrium decision for the quantity flexibility contract. Theorem 5. The SPNE decisions for the quantity flexibility contract are 80
1 rwþba > 1 >
F > > B rwþba C > rvþba > B C; if ðc1 vÞðrþbaÞ > ;F1 > 1d @ > rvþba A < > QF ¼ qQF 1 ;t1 þwvc1 u > > > > ðwþaÞðwuÞ > >
> > wþac > 1 > ; otherwise: : fqjFðð1dÞqÞ¼0g;F1 wþav (22) Suppose the parameter values are such that the quantity flexibility equilibrium decisions are the first pair in (22). We can write the expected total supply chain profit as the sum of the agents’ individual expected profit functions, which reduces to "Z QF # Z tQF t1 1 QF QF QF SC PQF ¼ r xf ðxÞdx þ t1 1 F t1 tQF þu 1 x f ðxÞdx c1 t1 0
Z
b
1 tQF 1
f ðxÞdx: x tQF 1
0
(23) SC Note that if u ¼ v, for any value of t1 we have PSC QF ðt1 Þ ¼ PC:II: ðt1 Þ, where is the centralized supply chain profit in (20).
PSC C:II: ðt1 Þ
Theorem 6. The percent deviation contract coordinates the supply chain in the following cases where the quantity flexibility contract fails to coordinate: 1. When the salvage value is higher at the supplier (u < v), there are cases in which the centralized supply chain profit under the percent deviation contract always exceeds that attainable from the quantity flexibility contract. 2. When the salvage values are equal for both parties (u ¼ v), channel coordination efforts for quantity flexibility require either setting a < 0 or w < c1 , both of which violate the underlying assumptions of the model.
150
M.J. Drake and J.L. Swann
In other supply chain contracting structures such as revenue-sharing agreements, it is possible for suppliers to benefit by selling goods for a wholesale price below their marginal cost of production as the second part of Theorem 6 requires. This strategy is successful because the supplier is receiving part of the buyer’s revenue in addition to the wholesale price. Looking at the supplier’s expected profit function under the quantity flexibility contract in (28), the supplier can either obtain w or v for each of the t1 pre-acquired units. If each of these values are less than c1, the supplier cannot earn positive expected profit by selling below the marginal cost. We have thus shown that there are cases in which the quantity flexibility contract cannot coordinate the supply chain, while the percent deviation contract is able to achieve coordinated performance. The main difficulty the quantity flexibility contract has in this decision environment is that it establishes a minimum purchase commitment for the buyer. The percent deviation contract provides buyers more flexibility by allowing them to choose to pay the penalties associated with ordering outside of the deviation range. Of course, in order to gain this flexibility, the contract must be more complex; therefore, the percent deviation contract would likely be more costly to manage in practice.
5 Numerical Analysis In this section we provide several numerical examples that illustrate the behavior of the percent deviation contract in various decision environments discussed above as well as how parameters can be set to satisfy individual-rationality constraints and to coordinate the channel. We estimated the demand distributions used below from weekly shipping data provided by a major US manufacturer. The demand random variable represents the number of shipments per week required from the supplier to a retailer on a particular origin-destination lane; we consider two such lanes. For one of the lanes, the exponential distribution gave the best fit, and for the other the uniform distribution was appropriate. We failed to reject chi-squared goodness of fit statistics at the 10% significance level for each of the two distributions. For the cost and contract parameters, we constructed values that make relative sense in this manufacturer’s business setting.
5.1
Exponential Demand Example (Case A.)
Consider weekly demand that follows an exponential distribution with l ¼ 0.17297 and the cost parameters listed in Table 2. These parameters define a contract in Case A., since r w + b > p and w + a > c2; all of the supplier’s expected profit function realizations are concave because w + a > c2 + p. Thus, the buyer orders the exact demand, and the supplier chooses to expedite units (up to the capacity of 5). Under a traditional wholesale-price contract with inventory pre-acquisition and
Facilitating Demand Risk-Sharing with the Percent Deviation Contract Table 2 Parameter declarations for numerical examples
Parameter r w c1 c2 a
Exp (.17297) 60 17 7 13 3
a
Unif (0,18) 30 18 6 22 1
151
Parameter b v d p M
Exp (.17297) 12 1 0.2 5 5
Unif (0,18) 4 1 0.2 13 5
b
225
50 25
200
0
175
−25
150
−50
125
−75 30 20 t
10
00
10
20 q
30
30
30
20
20 t
10 00
10 q
Fig. 3 Expected profit functions of (a) the supplier and (b) the buyer for the Exp(0.17297) example
n o 2 vÞFðtÞ , or expediting, the supplier pre-acquires tNV 2 t : Fðt þ MÞ ¼ wc1 ðc wc2 tNV ¼ 4.7667 units. This results in an expected profit of 189.89 for the buyer and 29.21 for the supplier; thus, the total supply chain profit for the wholesale-price contract is 219.10. The centralized-channel pre-acquisition quantity is 10.4930, yielding a maximal channel expected profit of 243.45. The main problem with the wholesale-price contract is that the supplier does not have an incentive to pre-acquire enough inventory because the buyer is not sharing any of the demand risk. This low pre-acquisition amount restricts the total system’s ability to satisfy realized customer demand, which dampens the system’s profit potential. For the same parameter set, the percent deviation contract with (p,d) ¼ (5,0.2) is Pareto-improving for both parties as compared with the wholesale-price contract. Figure 3a, b depict the expected profit functions for the supplier and the buyer, respectively, as a function of the two main decision variables, q1 and t1. Note the piecewise form of these expected profit functions, which reflects the different profit function realizations with their distinct optimal solutions. Applying solu the ; t ðq Þ ¼ tion procedure detailed in Sect. 3.2, the SPNE decision pair is q 1 1 1 A:III: A:III: ¼ ð5:1810; 6:0391Þ. These decisions yield an expected profit of q1 ; t1 192.55 for the buyer and 37.37 for the supplier and a total expected supply chain
152
M.J. Drake and J.L. Swann
profit of 229.92. While both parties are better off in relation to the wholesale-price contract, there are still more gains to be realized because there is a 6% efficiency loss with this solution compared with the centralized solution. We can design the percent deviation contract parameters to ensure that the channel coordination condition in (21) is met. Namely, we need a + w + p ¼ r + b, so we 3 can by setting satisfy this inequality p ¼ 52. This induces an equilibrium pair of A:III: A:III: C:I: ¼ t1 ¼ ð5:1810; 10:4930Þ, which gives channel-optiq1 ; t1 ðq1 Þ ¼ q1 ; t1 mal expected profits of 84.35 and 159.10 for the buyer and supplier, respectively, and a total expected supply chain profit of 243.45, as designed. To induce the supplier to pre-acquire the channel-optimal inventory amount, the buyer has had to relinquish a substantial amount of profit to the supplier. The buyer’s coordinated expected profit does not satisfy its individual-rationality constraint, which requires expected profit of at least 189.89, the buyer’s expected profit from the wholesale-price contract. If the buyer received a fixed transfer payment, then it would be willing to accept the percent deviation contract. In this case, the fixed transfer payment must be larger than 105.54.4 This payment, denoted F, should not be too high, though; or else the supplier would be better off under the original wholesale-price contract as well. Thus, for any fixed supplier-to-buyer transfer payment in the range F ∈ (105.54,129.89), the percent deviation contract is coordinated and strictly Pareto-improving for both parties as compared to the wholesale-price contract.
5.2
Uniform Demand Example (Case B.)
We now consider an example with uniform demand and parameters as defined in Table 2. Since r w + b > p and w + a < c2, a percent deviation contract in this case would fall in scenario B., where the buyer orders the full demand and the supplier chooses not to expedite because it is too expensive.5 Under a traditional wholesale-price contract, the supplier pre-acquires 12.7059 units of inventory. The buyer and supplier expected profits are 95.54 and 76.24, respectively, resulting in a total supply chain expected profit of 171.78. If the firms acted as a centralized
3 Since the deviation penalty is so large, the condition for concavity on the supplier’s first profit function realization is no longer satisfied. This does not matter, though, because the buyer would never choose an equilibrium in this realization, which requires that it pay the deviation penalty for every unit of demand satisfied. 4 Note that, in this case, the channel coordinating condition is a function of the wholesale price, so we do not attempt to satisfy the buyer’s individual-rationality constraint using a wholesale price discount as discussed in Sect. 4.1. 5 We see in Table 2 that the supplier has M ¼ 5 units of available expediting capacity. This number is irrelevant here because regardless of the amount of extra capacity available, the supplier will not use any of it because expediting is too costly.
Facilitating Demand Risk-Sharing with the Percent Deviation Contract
a
153
b
150
50
100
25
50
0
0
15 15
10 t
5 5
0
0
10 q
−25 15
10 t
5
00
5
10 q
15
Fig. 4 Expected profit functions of (a) the supplier and (b) the buyer for the Unif(0,18) example
channel, the pre-acquisition amount would be 15.2727 with a total expected profit of 177.82. Figures 4a, b depict the expected profit functions for the supplier and the buyer under a percent deviation contract in this example. We can apply the solution procedure B:III: B:III:for Case B. to determine the SPNE decision pair of q1 ; t1 ðq1 Þ ¼ q 1 ; t1 ¼ ð10:3846; 15:0968Þ, which results in expected profits of 71.53 and 106.26 for the buyer and the supplier, respectively, and a total supply chain expected profit of 177.79. Note that this decentralized percent deviation contract produces a supply chain profit very close to that of the centralized channel; this is due to the fact that the supplier’s t1 decision value is approximately equal to that of the centralized channel. While the above percent deviation contract is close to coordinated as currently constructed, it does not satisfy the buyer’s individual-rationality constraint when compared with the wholesale-price contract. Consequently, the percent deviation contract must be modified to give the buyer an incentive to accept it over the status quo. If the supplier offers a discounted wholesale price (as discussed in Sect. 4.1) of 15.2346, which represents an approximate discount of 15% off the original price of 18, the equilibrium decision pair becomes q1 ; t1 ðq1 Þ ¼ q1B:III: ; t1B:III: ¼ ð10:3846; 14:1812Þ. This contract results in expected profits of 95.54 and 82.08 for the buyer and the supplier, respectively, and a total supply chain expected profit of 177.62, which is still close to the centralized optimum of 177.82. This percent deviation contract with a discounted wholesale price satisfies the buyer’s participation constraint and provides a higher profit for the supplier in relation to the traditional wholesale-price contract. Thus, for this example the individual-rationality constraint and the Pareto-improving condition are more important than channel coordination since the decentralized percent deviation contracts are close to being coordinated without any additional consideration.
154
M.J. Drake and J.L. Swann
6 Conclusions and Further Research In this chapter we have characterized the subgame-perfect Nash Equilibria of a dynamic supply chain game induced by the percent deviation contract, an innovative mechanism that was motivated by our discussions with a major firm in the transportation industry. Due to the sequential extensive form of this supply chain game, many of the decisions are functions of those decisions made in earlier stages of the game. The main result we have shown is that the percent deviation contract is a viable, albeit somewhat complicated, mechanism whereby the supplier can transfer some of its demand risk to the buyer. The prospect of receiving a deviation penalty for large or small buyer orders induces the supplier to pre-acquire more inventory than it ordinarily would, which increases the total capacity of the system. This extra ability to satisfy end-user demand benefits the entire system, enabling Pareto improvements. Several trajectories exist for future research in this area. The first direction includes relaxing some of the assumptions that we made in these models. A natural extension would be adding some information asymmetry by including one party’s proprietary information on costs or capacity. One could also include nonlinear costs or another pricing policy such as quantity discounts. For completion, it would also be interesting to examine supply chain coordination mechanisms for the other possible decision pairs. More generally, future work incorporating dynamic decision environments could be useful, especially in multi-echelon supply chains. Comparison studies of various contracting mechanisms applied to the same scenario could lead to Pareto-improvements similar to the ones we found. Further analysis is also needed to incorporate the advanced demand information into operational production and transportation network models. Only then will the true value of the percent deviation contract be estimated for the entire system. Acknowledgements This research was funded, in part, by The Logistics Institute Leaders in Logistics Grant from Lucent Technologies and NSF Grants DMI-0223364 and DMI-0348532.
Appendix Proof of Lemma 1. We will define the three realizations of (2) as follows: Z
PSA:I:
Z t1 þM ¼w xf ðxÞdx þ ðt1 þ MÞð1 Fðt1 þ MÞÞ þ p ðt1 þ M xÞf ðxÞdx 0 0 Z t1 þM Z t1 ðt1 xÞf ðxÞdx c1 t1 c2 ðx t1 Þf ðxÞdx þ Mð1 Fðt1 þ MÞÞ þv 0 t1 Z 1 a ðx t1 MÞf ðxÞdx (24Þ t1 þM
t1 þM
Facilitating Demand Risk-Sharing with the Percent Deviation Contract
Z PSA:II: ¼ w
t1 þM
155
xf ðxÞdx þ ðt1 þ MÞð1 Fðt1 þ MÞÞ
0
Z
ð1dÞq1
þp
ðð1 dÞq1 xÞf ðxÞdx Z t1 þM Z t1 ðt1 xÞf ðxÞdx c1 t1 c2 ðx t1 Þf ðxÞdx þ Mð1 Fðt1 þ MÞÞ þv t1 0 Z 1 ðx t1 MÞf ðxÞdx (25Þ a 0
t1 þM
Z PSA:III: ¼ w Z
t1 þM
0 ð1dÞq1
þp "Z0 þp
t1 þM ð1þdÞq1
Z
t1
þv 0
Z a
xf ðxÞdx þ ðt1 þ MÞð1 Fðt1 þ MÞÞ ðð1 dÞq1 xÞf ðxÞdx # ðx ð1 þ dÞq1 Þf ðxÞdx þ ðt1 þ M ð1 þ dÞq1 Þð1 Fðt1 þ MÞÞ Z
t1 þM
ðt1 xÞf ðxÞdx c1 t1 c2
1
t1 þM
ðx t1 Þf ðxÞdx þ Mð1 Fðt1 þ MÞÞ
t1
ðx t1 MÞf ðxÞdx:
(26Þ
The second derivative of (24) taken with respect to t1 is (p + c2 w a)f(t1 + M) (c2 v)f(t1), which is negative for all values of t1 if w + a > p + c2 based on the parameter conditions of scenario A. The second derivative of (25) is (c2 w a)f(t1 + M) (c2 v)f(t1), and the second derivative of (26) is (c2 w a p)f(t1 + M) (c2 v)f(t1). Both of these expressions are negative for all values of t1 without the extra condition. □ Proof of Theorem 1. There are five possible values for the supplier’s best response. Each of the three realizations of the supplier’s expected profit function has an individual maximizer, shown in (3)–(5). In addition, the two points where the pieces of the profit function converge (t1 ¼ (1 d)q1 M and t1 ¼ (1 + d) q1 M) are possible solutions. These solutions would occur when the maximizing t1 values do not lie in their corresponding feasible regions. In order to establish the result in Theorem 1, we first make some observations about the expected profit function that will help us with the main proof. Observation 2 For all values of t1 less than the lower boundary ðð1 dÞq1 MÞ, PSA:II: ðt1 Þ>PSA:I: ðt1 Þ because the term representing the expected value of the lower deviation penalty paid is larger in PSA:II: . For values of t1 greater than the lower boundary, PSA:II: ðt1 Þ
156
M.J. Drake and J.L. Swann
Observation 3 For all values of t1 less than the upper boundary ðð1 þ dÞq1 MÞ, PSA:II: ðt1 Þ > PSA:III: ðt1 Þ because the term representing the expected value of the upper deviation penalty paid in PSA:III: is negative. For values of t1 greater than the upper boundary, PSA:II: ðt1 Þ < PSA:III: ðt1 Þ. The supplier’s best response function depends on the values of the three maximizers relative to the feasible boundaries. There are 27 possible cases because each of the three decisions can potentially lie in three regions; however, the following results show that several of these cases are not possible. Lemma 2. The following results hold in Case A. It is not possible to have t1A:I: < A:III: ð1 dÞq1 M < tA:II: <ð1 þ dÞq1 M < tA:II: 1 , and it is also not possible to have t1 1 . After using Lemma 2 to reduce the number of possible cases, we can determine the overall best response for each given the values of the individual maximizers by applying Observations 1–3. Summarizing all of the scenarios, we obtain the solutiongiven in (6). □ Proof of Proposition 1. We use the difference function to determine when the supplier chooses each t1 for given values of q1 in a range where its best response is known to be the maximizer of its expected profit from a set of two values. We then use this information to characterize explicitly the ranges of q1 that induce each value of t1. If the difference function is positive for a value of q1, then the supplier will choose t1A:III: ; it will select the other possible decision if the function is negative. The number of ranges for q1 is determined by the number of changes of sign in the difference function. The difference function related to the decision in (8) is given by D t1A:I: "Z A:III: # t1 þM A:III: A:III: A:I: A:I: xf ðxÞdxþ t1 þM 1F t1 þM t1 þM 1F t1 þM ¼w þM tA:I: 1
"Z
ð1dÞq1
þp "Z þp
t1A:III: 0
"Z a
t1A:III: þM
c2 Z
t1A:I: þM t1A:I:
Z f ðxÞdx
tA:I: 1
0
xt1A:III: M f ðxÞdx
tA:III: þM 1
tA:III: 1
# f ðxÞdx
ðxð1þdÞq1 Þf ðxÞdxþ t1A:III: þMð1þdÞq1 1F t1A:III: þM
t1A:III: x
1
"Z
t1A:I: þMx
0 t1A:III: þM
þv
t1A:I: þM
ðð1dÞq1 xÞf ðxÞdx
0
ð1þdÞq1
"Z
Z
t1A:I: x
Z
1
t1A:I: þM
#
f ðxÞdx c1 t1A:III: t1A:I:
xt1A:I: M
# f ðxÞdx
xt1A:III: f ðxÞdx
xt1A:I:
# A:I: A:III: f ðxÞdxM F t1 þM þF t1 þM :
#
Facilitating Demand Risk-Sharing with the Percent Deviation Contract
157
This difference function is convex in q1 since @@qD2 ¼ pð1 dÞ2 f ðð1 dÞq1 Þþ 1 difference function at the pð1 þ dÞ2 f ðð1 þ dÞq1 Þ>0. We can begin by evaluating the tA:I: þM tA:III: þM two endpoints of the region defined in (8); that is, q1 ¼ 11d and q1 ¼ 1 1þd . If the difference function is positive for one value and negative for the other, then convexity implies that there exists a single threshold value of q1 in the interval where the difference function changes sign. The buyer can use these supplier decision values to evaluate its best selection of q1 in this region with respect to its expected profit function. If the difference function is positive for both endpoint values of q1, then it is possible that there are zero, one, or two points where the function switches sign. If there are zero or one switching points, then the supplier will choose t1 ¼ t1A:III: for all values of q1 in the region. If there are two switching points, then for values of q1 between these two values, the supplier will choose t1 ¼ t1A:I: . It will choose t1 ¼ t1A:III: for all other values of q1. If the difference function is negative for both endpoint values, then convexity implies that it will be negative for all values of q1; thus, the supplier will always choose t1 ¼ t1A:I: . The difference function related to the decision in (10) is given by A:II: D t1 "Z A:III: t1 þM ¼w xf ðxÞdxþ t1A:III: þ M 1 F t1A:III: þ M 2
t1A:II: þM
þ M 1 F tA:II: þM tA:II: 1 1 "Z A:III: # t1 þM A:III: A:III: þp ðx ð1þ dÞq1 Þf ðxÞdxþ t1 þ M ð1þ dÞq1 1 F t1 þ M ð1þdÞq1
"Z
t1A:III:
þv 0
"Z a c2 Z
1
tA:III: þM 1
"Z
tA:III: 1
Z f ðxÞdx
tA:II: 1
0
x t1A:III: M f ðxÞdx
tA:III: þM 1
t1A:II: þM t1A:II:
t1A:III: x
tA:II: x 1
Z
1 tA:II: 1 þM
#
f ðxÞdx c1 t1A:III: tA:II: 1
x tA:II: M f ðxÞdx 1
#
x t1A:III: f ðxÞdx
# x tA:II: þ M þ F t1A:III: þ M : f ðxÞdx M F tA:II: 1 1
This difference function is convex in q1 since @@qD2 ¼ pð1 þ dÞ2 f ðð1 þ dÞq1 Þ > 0, 1 @D ¼ pð1 þ dÞð1 Fðð1 þ dÞq1 ÞÞ < 0. and it is also decreasing in q1 because @q 1 tA:II: þM This means that if the difference function is negative when q1 ¼ 1 1þd , which is the lower limit of the range defined in (10), then the supplier will always choose t1 ¼ tA:II: if the difference function is positive at the upper endpoint of 1 . Likewise, n A:II: o t þM tA:III: þM , then the supplier will always select the range q1 ¼ min 1 1d ; 1 1þd 2
158
M.J. Drake and J.L. Swann
t1 ¼ t1A:III: . If the difference function is positive for the lower endpoint and negative for the upper endpoint, then there exists exactly one point where the difference function changes sign, and we have two distinct ranges of q1 values where the two t1 decisions are chosen. The difference function related to the decision in (9) is given by Dðð1dÞq1 MÞ "Z A:III: t1 þM xf ðxÞdxþ t1A:III: þM 1F t1A:III: þM ¼w ð1dÞq1
ð1dÞq1 ð1Fðð1dÞq1 ÞÞ "Z A:III: # t1 þM A:III: A:III: þp ðxð1þdÞq1 Þf ðxÞdxþ t1 þM ð1þdÞq1 1F t1 þM "Z
ð1þdÞq1 tA:III: 1
þv
t1A:III: x
0
f ðxÞdx
Z
ð1dÞq1 M
tA:III: þM 1
c2 Z
t1A:III: þM t1A:III:
ðð1dÞq1 M xÞf ðxÞdx
0
c1 t1A:III: ð1dÞq1 þM "Z Z 1 A:III: a xt1 M f ðxÞdx "Z
#
#
1 ð1dÞq1
ðxð1dÞq1 Þf ðxÞdx
xt1A:III: f ðxÞdx
# A:III: ðxð1dÞq1 þMÞf ðxÞdxM Fðð1dÞq1 ÞþF t1 þM :
ð1dÞq1 ð1dÞq1 M
Here one of the potential supplier decisions is an explicit function of the buyer’s q1 decision, so the difference function is more complex. Specifically, the function is not necessarily convex or concave. For a given set of parameters, then the exact switching points can be determined by simple numerical search methods. In many realizations the difference function will be well-behaved; thus, a similar analysis to that performed for the previous two cases above would suffice for these situations. □ Proof of Theorem 4. This case can easily be compared with the centralized Case C.II. in which the centralized firm also does not expedite. The total expected supply chain profit for the voluntary compliance case is Z PSC B: ¼ r
t1
Z xf ðxÞdx þ t1 ð1 Fðt1 ÞÞ þ v
0
t1
ðt1 xÞf ðxÞdx c1 t1
0
Z
1
b t1
ðx t1 Þf ðxÞdx:
(27)
Facilitating Demand Risk-Sharing with the Percent Deviation Contract
159
Comparing (27) with the centralized supply chain profit in (20), it is easily seen that the two profits will be equal if the t1 decisions are equal, which is accomplished rþbc1 1 þp if wþac wþavþp ¼ rþbv . Simplifying this equality yields the channel coordinating condition. □ Proof of Theorem 5. We will solve for the subgame-perfect Nash equilibrium decisions under a quantity flexibility contract via backward induction. The parameters in the B. scenario are such that the buyer orders q2 ¼ maxfX; ð1 dÞq1 g, where X denotes the realized customer demand. The supplier’s expected profit can thus be written as "Z PSQF ¼ w
ð1dÞq1
Z ð1 dÞq1 f ðxÞdx þ
0
"Z
ð1dÞq1
þv Z
#
t1 ð1dÞq1
xf ðxÞdx þ t1 ð1 Fðt1 ÞÞ Z
ðt1 ð1 dÞq1 Þf ðxÞdx þ
0 1
a
#
t1 ð1dÞq1
ðt1 xÞf ðxÞdx c1 t1
ðx t1 Þf ðxÞdx:
(28)
t1
Since the supplier’s expected profit function is concave, first-order optimality wþac conditions imply that the supplier’s optimal decision is t1 ¼ F1 wþav1 . There is one additional consideration, though, since the buyer is guaranteed to order at least (1 d)q1. The supplier should pre-acquire at least the minimum purchase quantity because these n sales are guaranteed. o Thus, the supplier’s optimal decision is 1 tQF 1 ¼ max ð1 dÞq1 ; F
wþac1 wþav
.
The buyer’s expected profit function is given by "Z PBQF
tQF 1
¼r
# xf ðxÞdx þ
0
"Z
ð1dÞq1
w 0
Z
ð1dÞq1
þu 0
tQF 1 ð1
FðtQF 1 ÞÞ Z
ð1 dÞq1 f ðxÞdx þ
tQF 1 ð1dÞq1
# xf ðxÞdx þ
ðð1 dÞq1 xÞf ðxÞdx þ ða bÞ
Z
1 tQF 1
tQF 1 ð1
FðtQF 1 ÞÞ
ðx tQF 1 Þf ðxÞdx: (29)
We can solve for the buyer’s optimal decision, as before, by assuming that the supplier’s decision takes on each of the two possible values and then optimizing the buyer’s profit subject to the constraint the supplier’s decision valid. that makes F1 rwþba rvþba QF 1 rwþba ; t ; F is optimal if ¼ The decision pair qQF 1 1 1d rvþba
160
F1
M.J. Drake and J.L. Swann
F1
, which reduces to (c1 v)(r + b a) + wv c1u QF ¼ (w+ a)(w u). If this inequality is reversed, qQF 1 ; t1
F1 wþac1 wþav 1 . In this case the supplier’s decision is fixed regard; F1 wþac 1d wþav rwþba rvþba
wþac1 wþav
QF less of the value of qQF 1 , so the buyer can reduce its demand risk by offering q1 2 fqjFðð1 dÞqÞ ¼ 0g such that there is no probability of customer demand below the minimum quantity. □ SC Proof of Theorem 6. If u < v, then clearly PSC QF PC:II: for every value of t1, and there exist some values of t1 where the inequality is strict. Consequently, coordination is not possible in these cases because leftover goods are less valuable in the buyer’s possession, which is where they reside under quantity flexibility. SC SC C:II Now let u ¼ v. If tQF 1 ¼ t1 , then PQF ¼ PC:II: , and we would have a coordirþbc1 nated supply chain. Thus, we want to have rwþba rvþba ¼ rþbv . Since a(0), the penalty the supplier pays the buyer for not satisfying units ordered, is the one parameter over which the parties are assumed to have control under quantity flexibility, we solve for the coordinating condition
a¼
ðr þ b vÞðc1 wÞ : c1 v
(30)
Examining the components of (30) individually, we see that the first term in the numerator is greater than zero because r > v and b 0, as is the denominator. So if w > c1 by our initial assumption, then this would require a negative a. We could have a positive coordinating a if we allowed the supplier to sell the goods below cost. □ Proof of Lemma 2. The first result follows directly from Lemma 3. To establish the second result by contradiction, assume that this relationship is true. Since the piecewise functions are concave from Lemma 1, t1A:III: is the single maximum of PSA:III: , and PSA:III: ðt1 Þ is decreasing for values of t1 >t1A:III: . Consequently, S PSA:III: ðt1A:III: Þ>PSA:III: ðð1 þ dÞq1 MÞ>PSA:III: ðtA:II: 1 Þ. Since PA:II: ðð1 þ dÞq1 MÞ ¼ S PA:III: ðð1 þ dÞq1 MÞ from Observation 1, we have PSA:III: ðt1A:III: Þ> S A:II: PSA:II: ðð1 þ dÞq1 MÞ>PSA:III: ðtA:II: 1 Þ. Observation 3 states that PA:III: ðt1 Þ> S S S S A:II: A:III: PA:II: ðt1 Þ, which implies PA:III: ðt1 Þ>PA:II: ðð1 þ dÞq1 MÞ> PA:III: ðtA:II: 1 Þ> S S A:II: PSA:II: ðtA:II: Þ. The statement P ðð1 þ dÞq MÞ>P ðt Þ contradicts the 1 A:II: A:II: 1 1 S maximizes P . □ result that tA:II: A:II: 1 Lemma 3. If w + a > p + c2, then t1A:I: tA:II: 1 . A:I: Proof. Suppose, on the contrary, t1A:I: < tA:II: 1 , which implies that Fðt1 þ MÞb FðtA:II: þ MÞ. Substituting the values given in (3) and (4) and simplifying, we have 1
A:I: A:II: ðc2 vÞðw þ a c2 Þ FðtA:II: 1 Þ Fðt1 Þ p w þ a c1 ðc2 vÞFðt1 Þ : (31)
Facilitating Demand Risk-Sharing with the Percent Deviation Contract
161
The left side of (31) is positive, and the right side is negative since the numerator in (4) must be positive at tA:II: 1 . (The denominator is positive due to the parameter relationship defining Case A.) This leads to a contradiction. □ B:I: B:III: B:II: Lemma 4. If w + a > p + v, then t1 min t1 ; t1 . Proof. The proof follows the same contradiction procedure as in that of Lemma 3. □ Proof of Lemma 5. We will define the four functions resulting from (7) as follows: "Z PBA:I: ¼ ðr wÞ Z
# xf ðxÞdx þ t1 ðq1 Þ þ M 1 F t1 ðq1 Þ
t1 ðq1 ÞþM 0
t1 ðq1 Þ
p
t1 ðq1 Þ þ M x
0
Z f ðxÞdx þ ða bÞ
1
t1 ðq1 Þ
x t1 ðq1 Þ M f ðxÞdx (32)
"Z PBA:II: ¼ ðr wÞ Z
t1 ðq1 ÞþM 0
Z
ð1dÞq1
p
# xf ðxÞdx þ t1 ðq1 Þ þ M 1 F t1 ðq1 Þ
ðð1 dÞq1 xÞf ðxÞdx þ ða bÞ
0
1
t1 ðq1 Þ
x t1 ðq1 Þ M f ðxÞdx (33)
"Z PBA:III:
t1 ðq1 ÞþM
¼ ðr wÞ 0
Z
ð1dÞq1
p
# xf ðxÞdx þ t1 ðq1 Þ þ M 1 F t1 ðq1 Þ Z
ðð1 dÞq1 xÞf ðxÞdx þ ða bÞ
0
"Z p
t1 ðq1 ÞþM ð1þdÞq1
1
t1 ðq1 Þ
x t1 ðq1 Þ M f ðxÞdx
ðx ð1 þ dÞq1 Þf ðxÞdx
þ t1 ðq1 Þ þ M ð1 þ dÞq1 1 F t1 ðq1 Þ þ M : (34) "Z PBA:IV:
ð1dÞq1
¼ ðr wÞ Z p 0
# xf ðxÞdx þ ð1 dÞq1 ð1 Fðð1 dÞq1 ÞÞ
0 ð1dÞq1
Z ðð1 dÞq1 xÞf ðxÞdx þ ða bÞ
1 ð1dÞq1
ðx ð1 dÞq1 Þf ðxÞdx (35)
The concavity result follows the same logic as that used in Lemma 1.
□
162
M.J. Drake and J.L. Swann
Proof of Theorem 2. The following lemma establishes the piecewise-concavity of (7). □ Lemma 5. The buyer’s expected profit function realizations resulting from (7) are concave. Since the buyer’s four individual profit function realizations are concave from Lemma 5, we can use the KKT conditions to solve for the optimal q1 for each function over the region of q1 values where the function is valid, as defined in Theorem 1. t1A:I: þM We first maximize (32) n over theA:I:region o q1 1d . Since (32) is not dependent t þM on q1, any value q1A:I: q : q 11d is optimal. tA:II: þM T tA:II: þM T tA:III: þM We consider (33) over the region q1 1 1d q1 1 1þd q1 1 1þd . Taking the partial derivative and setting it equal to zero yields p(1 d)F((1 d) q1) ¼ 0. Since only the lower deviation penalty exists in this profit function realization, the buyer wants to make the initial order estimate as small as possible to avoid A:II: A:III: F1 ð0Þ maxft1 ;t1 gþM A:II: paying the penalty. Consequently, q1 ¼ q1 max 1d ; . 1þd A:II: A:III: T t þM t þM q1 1 1þd . First order We want to maximize (34) over the region q1 1 1þd A:III: fq : ð1 þ dÞ ¼ ð1 dÞFðð1 dÞqÞþ optimality conditions yield q1 ¼ q1 A:III: þM minftA:II: g 1 ;t1 ð1 þ dÞFðð1 þ dÞqÞg, which is feasible if it is smaller than 1þd A:II: . T t þM Finally, we maximize (35) over the region q1 1 1d q1 A:I: A:III: T t1 þM t1 þM A:IV: q1 1þd . The first order conditions give us q1 ¼ q1 n1d o n A:II: o t þM tA:III: þM rwaþb q : Fðð1 dÞq1 Þ ¼ rwaþbþp , which is feasible if max 1 1d ; 1 1þd qb1
t1A:I: þM 1d .
□
Proof of Theorem 3. The proof of this result follows the same logic as that of Theorem 1, utilizing the results from Lemma 4. □
References Balakrishnan A, Geunes J, Pangburn MF (2004) Coordinating supply chains by controlling upstream variability propagation. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 6(2):163–183 Barnes-Schuster D, Bassok Y, Anupindi R (2002) Coordination and flexibility in supply contracts with options. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 4(3):171–207 Bassok Y, Anupindi R (2008) Analysis of supply contracts with commitments and flexibility. Nav Res Logist 55:459–477 Bazaraa MS, Sherali HD, Shetty CM (1993) Nonlinear programming: theory and algorithms, 2nd edn. Wiley, New York Cachon GP (2004) The allocation of inventory risk in a supply chain: push, pull, and advancepurchase discount contracts. Manage Sci 50(2):222–238 Cachon GP, Fisher M (2000) Supply chain inventory management and the value of shared information. Manage Sci 46(8):1032–1048
Facilitating Demand Risk-Sharing with the Percent Deviation Contract
163
Cachon GP, Lariviere MA (2001) Contracting to assure supply: how to share demand forecasts in a supply chain. Manage Sci 47(5):629–646 Donohue KL (2000) Efficient supply contracts for fashion goods with forecast updating and two production modes. Manage Sci 46(11):1397–1411 Drake MJ (2006) The design of incentives for the management of supply and demand. PhD thesis, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, GA Erkoc M, Wu SD (2005) Managing high-tech capacity expansion via capacity reservation. Prod Oper Manage 14(2):232–251 Finley F, Srikanth S (2005) Seven imperatives for successful collaboration. Supply Chain Manage Rev 9(1):30–37 Fugate BS, Sahin F, Mentzer JT (2006) Supply chain management coordination mechanisms. J Bus Logistics 27(2):129–161 Kulp SC, Lee HL, Ofek E (2004) Manufacturer benefits from information integration with retail customers. Manage Sci 50(4):431–444 Lee HL (2004) The triple-A supply chain. Harv Bus Rev 82(10):102–112 Lee HL, So KC, Tang CS (2000) The value of information sharing in a two-level supply chain. Manage Sci 46(5):626–643 Lian Z, Deshmukh A (2009) Analysis of supply contracts with quantity flexibility. Eur J Oper Res 196:526–533 Serel DA (2007) Capacity reservation under supply uncertainty. Comput Oper Res 34:1192–1220 Tirole J (1988) Theory of industrial organization. MIT, Cambridge, MA Tsay AA (1999) The quantity flexibility contract and supplier–customer incentives. Manage Sci 45 (10):1339–1358 Tsay AA, Lovejoy WS (1999) Quantity flexibility contracts and supply chain performance. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 1(2):89–111 Tsay AA, Nahmias S, Agrawal N (1999) Modeling supply chain contracts: a review. In: Tayur S, Ganeshan R, Magazine M (eds) Quantitative methods for supply chain management. Kluwer, Norwell, MA Wang X, Liu L (2007) Coordination in a retailer-led supply chain through option contract. Int J Prod Econ 110:115–127 Zhao Y, Wang S, Cheng TCE, Yang X, Huang Z (2010) Coordination of supply chains by option contracts: a cooperative game theory approach. Eur J Oper Res 207:668–675
.
Value-Added Retailer in a Mixed Channel: Asymmetric Information and Contract Design Samar K. Mukhopadhyay, Xiaowei Zhu, and Xiaohang Yue
Abstract With increasing regularity, manufacturers are opening a direct selling channel using internet, keeping their traditional retail channel in place. This mixed channel is attractive to the manufacturers because they retain the advantage of the retailer’s traditional services while increasing their sales base to customers purchasing online. One disadvantage of this model is the potential for channel conflict because they are in direct competition with their own retailers. In this chapter, we propose an innovative way to mitigate this channel conflict, where the manufacturer allows the retailer to add value to the base product so that it is differentiated from their own offering through the direct channel. We model this supply chain where the retailer is also given the authority to price the value added product. Design of an optimal contract from the manufacturer’s point of view is complicated due to the fact that the manufacturer does not know the retailer’s cost of adding value. This chapter develops the closed form solution of the optimal contracts under this information asymmetry. Comparison with channel coordinating contracts is provided. This chapter develops a number of new managerial guidelines and identifies future research topics.
S.K. Mukhopadhyay Graduate School of Business, Sungkyunkwan University, Jongno-Gu, Seoul 110-745, South Korea e-mail: [email protected] X. Zhu (*) College of Business and Public Affairs, West Chester University of Pennsylvania, West Chester, PA 19383, USA e-mail: [email protected] X. Yue Sheldon B. Lubar School of Business, University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee, P.O. Box 742, Milwaukee, WI 53201, USA e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_7, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
165
166
S.K. Mukhopadhyay et al.
Keywords Channel conflict • Information asymmetry • Mixed channel • Valueadding retailer
1 Introduction In addition to their traditional retailer channel, firms are opening direct channels in increasing numbers. This is a new business model facilitated by emerging internet technology. The motivation is the increased control over product distribution and pricing, order capture and customer information. The traditional retail channel is also kept in place because it has important roles to play. These include creating and satisfying demand for the product, engaging in activities to build brand awareness, gathering market information, and providing customer support. The example of this type of mixed channel strategy includes Compaq starting it in 1998. Other firms that have adopted similar strategies include IBM (Nasiretti 1998), HP (Janah 1999), Mattel (Bannon 2000), Nike (Collinger 1998). Balasubramanian (1998) and Levary and Mathieu (2000) suggest that such a strategy could work well. The disadvantage of this model is that the manufacturer is now in direct competition with its channel partners. As Frazier (1999) showed, mixed channel would increase revenue, but would lead to decreased support from the channel partners. In fact, this led to some retailers actually taking action against the manufacturers who opened a direct channel in competition with them. Channel conflict is the biggest deterrent for the manufacturer to go ahead with the mixed channel business model. Because channel conflict is detrimental for the supply chain relationship, there needs to be ways to mitigate this conflict. Some of the ways are separating the brands sold directly and sold through retailers, taking orders over the Internet and then fulfilling the order through the retailers, and sharing a part of the profit from each direct sale with their retailers. They can also maintain the price at par with the retailer so as not to undercut them. Hann (1999) gives an example of Zurich, an insurance company. Another way would be to sell a basic version of the product direct, and let the retailer add further value to the product before selling to the final customer (Fay 1999). In this chapter, we address the mixed channel strategy where the channel conflict is eliminated by the use of a value-adding retailer. We study a business model where the retailer-manufacturer conflict is alleviated by a contract. We explore a number of cases in this scenario (1) a base case, for benchmarking purpose, where the channel is integrated and a joint profit function is maximized; (2) a case where the channel partners are separate but they share full information with each other; and (3) a more general case where there is information asymmetry in the channel. Under the information asymmetry, one partner offers a lump sum side payment to the other to alleviate channel conflict. In all cases we find the optimum price in each channel, the optimum value added by the retailer, and the optimum side payment. This book chapter is based on authors’ original work of Mukhopadhyay et al. (2008a).
Value-Added Retailer in a Mixed Channel
167
2 Literature Survey Supply chain coordination can be accomplished through appropriate contract design. Cachon and Lariviere (2005) study revenue-sharing contracts in a general supply chain model with revenues determined by each retailer’s purchase quantity and price. They compare revenue sharing to a number of other supply chain contracts, like buy-back contracts, price-discount contracts, quantity-flexibility contracts, sales-rebate contracts, franchise contracts, and quantity discounts. Plambeck and Taylor (2008) study how the potential for renegotiation influences the optimal structure of supply contracts. They show that renegotiation can greatly increase the firms’ investments and profits, provided that the contracts are designed correctly. Tsay et al. (1999) and Frazier (1999) survey channel structure and incentive design for performance enhancement. Cohen et al. (1995) study an intermediary who perform specific value-adding functions, and get compensated for this service by the manufacturer or distributors by a side payment. A mixed channel strategy in products that do not provide large value are studied by Chiang et al. (2003) who show that adding a direct channel can mitigate the profit loss. Yao and Liu (2003) study diffusion of customer between two channels and find that, under certain conditions, both channels would enjoy stable demand. Viswanathan (2000) study the mixed channel issue from the product differentiation point of view and conclude that the more different the product is in the two channels, the more the benefit for the channels. Khouja et al. (2010) indicates that the most critical factor in channel selection is the variable cost per unit of product sold using the direct versus the retail channels. There is an increased competition between the manufacturer and retailer (Agatz et al. 2008) as the manufacturer expands his channels to the customers. Though channel structures have been extensively researched in literature (i.e., Hua et al. 2010; Su et al. 2010; Chiang 2010) relatively few have studied mixed channel with value-adding retailer to decreasing the competition between channels. Mukhopadhyay et al. (2008b) find that the retailer would be willing to share information with the manufacturer if her cost of adding value is lower than a threshold value. One of contribution for our research is that we study the mixed channel under asymmetric information, not under full information like most of existing literature. Asymmetric information and supply chain coordination have been the subject of a number of recent studies. Desiraju and Moorthy (1997) study the case of information asymmetry about a price and service-sensitive demand curve. They show that coordination can be achieved by requirement of service performance. Cakanyildirim et al. (2010) find that information asymmetry about manufacturer’s production cost does not necessarily cause inefficiency in the supply chain. Value of information in a capacitated supply chain is derived by Gavirneni et al. (1999). Lee et al. (2000) show that, with a demand process correlated over time, it could be worthwhile to share information about the demand. Corbett and de Groote (2000) derive optimal discount policy for both full and incomplete information cases.
168
S.K. Mukhopadhyay et al.
Corbett et al. (2004) study different types of contracts to coordinate the supply chain for both complete information and asymmetric information. Ha (2001) finds that in case of private information, optimal order quantity is smaller and optimal selling price is higher than for the case with complete information. Mukhopadhyay et al. (2009) designed a contract for the manufacturer to motivate the retail’s marketing effort under asymmetric information of retailer’s sale effort. Section 3 of this chapter presents our mixed channel model. The optimal contracts for the complete information case and asymmetric information are shown in Sect. 4. We will also compare the two cases, and derive a number of managerial insights. In Sect. 5, we report the results of an extensive numerical experimentation to see how the changes in the parameters affect the contracts. Section 6 will conclude the chapter with some further research ideas.
3 The Model Our supply chain consists of a traditional manufacturer and a retailer. There is also a direct channel selling to the same customer pool (see Fig. 1). The retailer augments the basic product by adding value for the customer. Let p1 be the price of the basic product charged by the manufacturer in the direct channel. Let v be the value added to the basic product by the retailer who prices it as p2. The cost to the retailer for adding a value v is cv per unit. It can be assumed that p2 > p1. The effective price to the customer of the augmented product is p2 v because of the additional value compared to the basic product sold in the direct channel. Let the wholesale price charged by the manufacturer to the retailer be w. Customers evaluate both the products and compare their value with the respective prices. Let the equilibrium demands be d1 for the direct channel and d2 for the retailer channel. The decision variables in our model are p1 and w for the manufacturer and p2 and v for the retailer, each maximizing their own profit functions.
MANUFACTURER
(pM) w RETAILER
p1, d1
(pR) p2, cv, d2
Fig. 1 Mixed retail and direct channel distribution system
POTENTIAL CUSTOMERS
Value-Added Retailer in a Mixed Channel
3.1
169
Characterizing the Demands
The retail channel demand, in case of no direct channel is written as: d2 ¼ ða2 bp2 Þ þ bv where a2 is the base demand b is price sensitiveness, and b is the sensitivity of demand with respect to the value added, i.e., it is the increase in demand per unit value added. Similarly, in the absence of the retail channel, the demand from the direct channel is d1 ¼ ða1 bp1 Þ where a1 is the base demand for this channel. Literature in this area uses similar linear demand function (Cotterill and Putsis 2001) and we follow their lead here. We now consider the modified demand when both the channels are operating at the same time. Now, customers would make a purchase decision by considering the two prices p1 and p2, and also the value added v by the retailer. d1 and d2, therefore, would be functions of p1, p2 and v. As a result, there would be migration of customers from one channel to another. We assume that this migration is proportional to the price difference and the additional value. Then the demand of the two channels would be: The direct channel: d1 ¼ ða1 bp1 Þ rðp1 ðp2 vÞÞ ¼ a1 ðb þ rÞp1 þ rðp2 vÞ The retailer channel: d2 ¼ ða2 bp2 Þ þ bv rðp2 v p1 Þ ¼ a2 ðb þ rÞp2 þ ðb þ rÞv þ rp1 where r is the migration effectiveness. To maintain analytical tractability, we assume that a1 ¼ a2 ¼ a, b ¼ b and normalize (b + r) and (b + r) to 1. The demand function is thus simplified as follows. Direct channel: d1 ¼ a p1 þ rðp2 vÞ
(1)
d2 ¼ a ðp2 vÞ þ rp1
(2)
The retailer channel:
We assume that r < 1, so that own channel effects are greater than cross channel effects. a and r are assumed to be common knowledge.
3.2
Value-Adding Cost for the Retailer
When the retailer is allowed to add value to the product, there is a cost denoted by cv per unit. We assume a quadratic cost function for the retailer value-adding process. Specifically, we use the functional form: cv ¼
v2 2
(3)
170
S.K. Mukhopadhyay et al.
where , an efficiency parameter for the retailer’s value added cost, is retailer’s private information. Note that we have defined cv as per unit quadratic cost to capture the phenomenon that adding a large quantum of value is proportionately more costly than adding minimal amount of value. In some cases, there would be a fixed cost (due to infrastructure creation, e.g.) which could be applied to the total sales volume. We are not including this cost here. In this chapter we consider contracts under two information structures. In full information scenario, the retailer shares its private information to the manufacturer. In asymmetric information scenario, the manufacturer does not know . We assume that the manufacturer holds a prior cumulative distribution F() with density function f(), defined on ½ 0 ; 3 , where 0 0 3 1.
3.3
Retailer’s and Manufacturer’s Profit
The practice of a side payment, L, from the manufacturer to the retailer to alleviate the channel conflict is used in some cases. Incorporating this side payment would give the following profit functions: The retailer’s profit function: pR ¼ ðp2 w cv Þd2 þ L
(4)
And the manufacturer’s profit function: pM ¼ p1 d1 þ wd2 L
(5)
Where d1 and d2 are given by (1) and (2), w is the wholesale price charged by the manufacturer to the retailer. We include L as the manufacturer’s decision variable to make the contract more flexible and to achieve the supply chain coordination (Corbett et al. 2004). To maintain analytical tractability, we further assume there are no marginal costs incurred by the manufacturer for selling through direct channel and through the retailer. In reality, both the retailer and the manufacturer have a reservation profit level which they intend to achieve in order for a trade to take place. Let reservation profit levels for the retailer and manufacturer be pR and pM respectively.
4 Two Types of Contracts One type of contract we consider is full information (F) contract. The other type is the asymmetric information (A) contract. An integrated channel (I) provides the base case. Under (I), the contract is designed by maximizing the total profit of
Value-Added Retailer in a Mixed Channel
171
manufacturer and retailer and taking as common knowledge. Under (F), the manufacturer knows the retailer’s and designs the contract taking as common knowledge to maximize its own profit. Under (A), the manufacturer does not know the retailer’s and designs the contract using prior density function f() and cumulative distribution F() defined on ½0 ; 3 .
4.1
Integration Channel Contract (I)
In this case, the channel is integrated and thus would provide the first best solution. It is expected that the profits for the channel would be highest under this scenario and thus, can be used for comparison with other cases. In this case, the two channels are integrated and they together will behave as a single firm and therefore will optimize the joint channel profit. pI ¼ p1 d1 þ ½p2 cv d2
(6)
The optimal prices p1 and p2 and value added v can be obtained by taking first order condition and solve them simultaneously. We get, p1 ¼
a a 3 1 ; p ¼ þ ; v ¼ 2ð1 rÞ 2 2ð1 rÞ 4
The optimal joint profit for an integrated channel is given by a a2 1 þ 2ð1rÞ þ 16 p ¼ 4 2 Even though the two channel partners are integrated, they still need to decide how this total profit, derived above, be divided between the two. Suppose that the retailer has her own reservation profit as pR and the retailer, therefore, would participate in the contract only if the profit pR pR . One possible way of dividing the total profit is that the retailer is given pR to ensure her participation. The manufacturer, therefore, receives the remainder pI pR . A contract like this is proposed by Corbett et al. (2004). It can be shown that pM is a decreasing function of . Therefore, it is possible that when is high enough (approaching 3), pIM could be so low that it would be lower than his reservation profit pM . In that situation, the contract would be unattractive to the manufacturer and there would be no trade. Thus, the contract, to be viable, should be such that the manufacturer is guaranteed at least pM . Let N be that value of above which pIM is lower than pM . N, therefore, is the cut-off point above which there would be no trade, and the manufacturer is said to be following a cutoff policy (Ha 2001). Under this scenario, we also need to find the value of N. This is done in Proposition 1 which gives the complete channel contract under the base case, and the optimum channel profit and its division to the two partners. Proofs of all results are shown in the Appendix, unless stated otherwise. I
172
S.K. Mukhopadhyay et al.
Proposition 1. (a) The optimal contract under channel integration is given by: pI1 ¼
a 2ð1 rÞ
NI ¼
1 qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi 2a þ 2 4pM þ4pR a2 1þr 1r
pI2 ¼
a 3 þ 2ð1 rÞ 4
1 2 a ð1 þ rÞ where pM þpR 4ð1 rÞ vI ¼
(b) The optimal profits for the retailer and the manufacturer under channel integration are given by: pIR ¼ pR ( pIM ¼ pI ¼
a 4
2
1 a þ 16 2 þ 2ð1rÞ pR pM
N
)
N
2
a a 1 þ þ 4 2ð1 rÞ 162
It is interesting to note that the direct channel price does not depend on the retailer’s cost. Also, when r increases, the manufacturer will increase its direct channel price. Recall that r is the migration factor, and an increasing r will enable the manufacturer to attract more customers away from the retailer. This will enable manufacturer to increase his price, and thus his revenue. This result gives a managerial insight that the manufacturer should try operational and marketing means to increase r. This can be done, for example, by advertising, or by offering incentives like easy return policy for the internet purchase.
4.2
Full Information Contract (F)
The private information held by the retailer about her cost structure (about ) is shared with the manufacturer. The moves of manufacturer and retailer follow a Stackelberg type game: the manufacturer acts as the leader, announcing the p1 and w first; the retailer acts as the follower, announcing the p2 and v after that. The solution of this game follows. The manufacturer decides about his decision variables basing on the retailer’s best response function. This best response function is in terms of the manufacturer’s parameters. This function is obtained by maximizing the retailer’s profit pR with respect to her decision variables, namely p2 and v. Equation (7) gives the retailer’s best response function, as functions of p1 and w. pr2 ¼
3 w a p1 r þ þ þ 4 2 2 2
vr ¼
1
(7)
Value-Added Retailer in a Mixed Channel
173
Next, in stage 1 of the game, the manufacturer derives the optimal p1 and w by maximizing its own profit pM , given in (5), and substituting the optimum values of p2 and v thus making it a function of p1 and w alone. Using the first order conditions, we obtain the manufacturer’s optimal policies as: pF1 ¼
a 2ð1 rÞ
wF ¼
a 1 þ 2ð1 rÞ 4
(8)
In Stage 2 of the game, the retailer uses the manufacturer’s policy announcement given in (8), and maximizes her own profit function to obtain her own optimal policies as: pF2 ¼
ð3 rÞa 7 þ 4ð1 rÞ 8
vF ¼
1
(9)
From (8) and (9), we observe that w p1 . So, the manufacturer sees that selling one unit to the retailer at the wholesale price brings in more revenue than selling in the direct channel, he will have no incentive to open a direct channel, under the full information scenario, unless he wants to do it for reasons other than maximizing profits. These reasons could be to make customers aware of the product, provide product information, not to lose ground to competitors who have web presence, and so on. In that case, the cost penalty for the sub-optimal operation can be thought of as the cost of the above mentioned benefits.
4.3
Asymmetric Information Contract (A)
This is the most realistic case where the manufacturer does not know . As noted earlier, he knows the prior density function f() and cumulative distribution F() defined on ½0 ; 3 . The manufacturer offers the retailer a contract, which is a menu of {p1, w, L} meaning that it offers a number of alternative values for this tupple. The retailer has a choice of not accepting the contracts if none of the alternatives are attractive enough to her. Or she may select one alternative from the menu and decides to accept that. We include a side payment L in this case to formulate a two part nonlinear contract which gives the most flexible contract type (Corbett et al. 2004). Thus the profit for the manufacturer is pAM ¼ wd2 þ p1 d1 L and for the retailer is pAR ¼ ðp2 w cv Þd2 þ L pR . L > 0 is defined as a per-period payment from the manufacturer to the retailer. As noted earlier, this side payment is designed to alleviate the channel conflict in case the retailer is aggravated with the prospect of having competition with the manufacturer. This is also necessary if the retailer is more powerful than the manufacturer. For example, companies like Wal-Mart and Home depot can stop the manufacturer from opening a direct channel. For example, in 1999, Home Depot
174
S.K. Mukhopadhyay et al.
sent mail to more than 1,000 suppliers to ask them to stop online sale (Brooker 1999). We also include the possibility that L can be negative. L < 0 can be interpreted as a payment by the retailer to the manufacturer for getting the opportunity to do the business, as in the case of airline ticket. This can also be applied to the case of franchise, where the retailer has to pay the manufacturer. In most of these cases, there is little gain for the retailer to add value to the product, and the retailer has little power to impede the manufacturer’s sales in the direct channel strategy. The manufacturer offers a menu of contracts which is a function of because is unknown to the manufacturer. Thus the manufacturer offers fp1 ðÞ; wðÞ; LðÞg, and the retailer chooses a ^ to announce. Once the retailer has announced ^, direct Þ, wholesale price wð^ Þ and side payment Lð^Þ are fixed, so the channel price p1 ð^ Þ; wð^ ÞÞ using the best response function retailer will set retail channel price p2 ðp1 ð^ given in (7). This follows from the Revelation Principle of Fudenberg and Tirole (1991). The mechanism by which the retailer should chose which ^ to announce is as follows. First, she uses her own profit function pR and applies a first order condition and a local second order condition given by: @pR ð^ ; Þ ¼ 0 @^
and
@ 2 pR ð^; Þ 0 @^ @
Noting that, by substituting from Proposition 1(a) and earlier deductions, pR ð; ^Þ : ¼ ðpr2 ðp1 ð^ Þ; wð^ ÞÞ wð^ Þ crv Þd2 ðp1 ð^ Þ; wð^ Þ; pr2 Þ þ Lðwð^ ÞÞ 2 a 1 wð^ Þ rp1 ð^ Þ þ þ ¼ þ Lð^ Þ 2 4 2 2 Taking first order condition of pR w.r.t. ^ and solving at ^ ¼ we get: _ LðÞ ¼
1 a þ rp1 w _ _ ðwðÞ r pðÞÞ þ 4 2
This is what is called as the IC or Incentive Compatibility constraint. It can be also shown that _ ÞÞ @ 2 pR ðr p_ ð^ Þ wð^ 0 ð^ ; Þ ¼ 1 @^ @ 42 This is true under the common assumption that F() has decreasing reverse hazard rate, i.e., F()/f() is increasing in . Given that the IC constraint is derived as functions of the manufacturer’s variables, the next step for the manufacturer is to devise his optimal menu of contracts. This is done when the manufacturer maximizes his own profit function over the range of subject to the IC constraint and the individual-rationality (IR) constraint that the retailer will at least recover her own reservation profit. This is given in the following formulation.
Value-Added Retailer in a Mixed Channel
ðN Max
p1 ;w;L;N
0
175
ðwd2 þ p1 d1 LÞf ðÞdþ F
(10)
1 a þ rp1 w _ ðw_ r pÞ þ 4 2
(11)
subject to IC : L_ ¼
IR : pR ¼ ðp2 w cv Þd2 þ L pR
(12)
The first term in (10) gives the expected value of the manufacturer’s profit over the range of from the lowest possible value in the range, viz. 0 and N, the cutoff value explained earlier. For the range of between ½N; 3 , the manufacturer will gain his reservation profit giving him a total amount of F. Equation (11) is the IC constraint, forcing the retailer to truly announce ^ , as derived above. Equation (12) is the IR constraint. The structure of the above formulation fits the standard optimal control formulation with a salvage value. Solution. The above problem is complex as it is, but in this case its intractability is increased even further due to the fact the behavior of F would change the way the problem is solved. The reason is that depending upon the value of F, the “transversality condition” (see Kamien and Schwartz 1981, p. 148 for details) would be free. These points will be elaborated later. Now we enumerate below all possible cases that would arise for the transversality condition. There will be three possible cases depending on how the retailer’s and the manufacturer’s profits are behaving with respect to each other. Case 1. In this case, the manufacturer’s profit decreases in and the retailer’s profit increases in . Then at the cutoff point N, the manufacturer’s profit will hit his reservation profit pM and then remain constant at that value. Therefore F ¼ pM ð1 FÞ and transversality condition (used at cut-off point N) is free (as in case v of Kamien and Schwartz 1981, p. 148). Case 2. This is the case where both the manufacturer’s and the retailer’s profits decrease in . Thus again we have F ¼ pM ð1 FÞ and the transversality condition using when the K(IR) 0 will be required at cut-off point N (as in case vii of Kamien and Schwartz 1981, p. 148). Case 3. The manufacturer’s profit increases in Z and the retailer’s profit decreases profit in . Here the manufacturer’s profit is no longer fixed at pM like in the two earlier cases. Now the salvage value is given by F ¼ ½p1 ðNÞd1 þ wðNÞd2 LðNÞð1 FÞ. The transversality condition using when the K(IR) 0 will be required at cut-off point N (as in case vii of Kamien and Schwartz 1981, p. 148). It is not possible to have a case where both the manufacturer’s and retailer’s profits increase with . Because as increases, the total profit from these two channels is decreasing.
176
S.K. Mukhopadhyay et al.
Next, we will take Case 1, and solve the optimal control problem for this case. This is given in Proposition 2(a) which shows the menu of optimal pricing policies of the manufacturer and his side payment given that the retailer’s IR constraint is satisfied. In Part (b) of Proposition 2, we get the optimal profits for both channels. Proposition 2. (a) The manufacturer’s optimal contract under Asymmetric information for Case 1 is given by: a F ra ; wA ¼ ; 2ð1 rÞ 2f 2 2ð1 rÞ @LA a F 1 2 @wA ¼ ; þ @ @ 2 4f 2 4 pA1 ¼
a 3 F þ þ 2ð1 rÞ 4 4f 2 The optimal profits of the retailer and the manufacturer under asymmetric information are given by: (b) The retailer’s optimal price is given by p2 A ¼
pAR ¼ ðpA2 wA cv A Þd2A þ LA ¼ pAM ¼ pA1 d1A þ wA1 d2A LA ¼
a 1 F þ 2 4 4f 2
2 þ LA
F2 aF F a2 ð1 þ rÞ þ þ þ LA 84 f 2 42 f 83 f 4ð1 rÞ
During the course of the proof (found in Appendix), we obtain: @pAR ¼ 0, 0 satisfies ðpA2 wA cv A Þd2 þ LA ¼ pR , 1 ¼ N A ; 1 satisfies 2 @ F aF F a2 ð1 þ rÞ LðNÞA ¼ pM L(N)A satisfies 4 2 þ 2 þ 3 þ 8N f 4N f 8N f 4ð1 rÞ We derived above the analytical solution to the MEP problem giving the optimal policies of both parties when information asymmetry exists in the supply chain. We have done this for one of the cases, namely, Case 1. Given the complexity of a “twopoint boundary value” problem, this analytical exposition is a significant contribution. For the other cases, we will show our results of numerical solution. We will generate a number of insights into those cases and develop significant guidelines for decision making. These will be reported in Sect. 5. Next, we will study how the information asymmetry affects the optimal policies and the nature of profit from using these strategies by comparing them with those of the first best case, i.e., the case of channel integration.
4.4
Comparison of the Types of Contracts
The profits under the channel integration (I) case and the asymmetric information (A) case are compared here. Note that, intuitively, the channel integration is an
Value-Added Retailer in a Mixed Channel
177
ideal case in a supply chain, where both parties work for the benefit of the supply chain as a whole. But given the reality that the channel partners more often than not are separate entity, how does the more real case of asymmetric channel information compare with the ideal case? This question is answered in the following proposition. Proposition 3. If a supply chain moves from the information asymmetry case to complete channel integration, then (i) The manufacturer’s profit will increase, i.e., pIM pAM (ii) The retailer’s profit will decrease, i.e., pIR pAR (iii) The supply chain profit will increase, i.e., pI pAR þ pAM As we saw, under I, the manufacturer’s profit is decreasing in . The insight we gain here is that the manufacturer would prefer lower or higher v*. The less is the information asymmetry or the more the product is different, the more the manufacturer would benefit. Also, by channel integration, the manufacturer would always gain. He can, therefore, offer incentive to the retailer for being willing to share information. It is interesting to see that when supply chain integration is achieved, the retailer tends to lose some of its profit, even though the total supply chain profit increases. Thus the manufacturer, who was the aggrieved party under the information asymmetry, will benefit more than the total channel benefit, at the cost of the retailer. It intuitively follows that, if the manufacturer wishes to motivate channel coordination, he must offer some incentive to the retailer to make up for her lost profit. The difference of profit of the retailer between the cases of A and I can be thought of as the value of this information to the retailer. The profit realized under supply chain integration is always higher than the sum of the retailer’s and the manufacturer’s profits without such integration. This is generally the same result found in most supply chain research into other aspects of supply chain decision making. Basically, information asymmetry is inefficient for the supply chain as a whole. Assuming some known distribution function for , e.g., uniform, we can show that the more the products are different through the retailer’s value added process, the more the supply chain benefits. It is true for both scenarios, I and A. Next, we analyze the retailer’s optimal policies about its value added process and pricing under the two cases where information is shared and where it is not. We do the same for the manufacturer’s pricing policies. These results are given in the next two propositions. The proofs are straightforward using earlier results and are omitted. Proposition 4. (i) The retailer’s optimal value added amount remains same under both cases of A and I. (ii) The retailer can set higher retail price under A, i.e., pA2 pI2 . Proposition 5. The manufacturer set the same direct channel price p1 under I and A, i.e. pI1 ¼ pA1 . Also, this price is independent of .
178
S.K. Mukhopadhyay et al.
Again, it is interesting to see that the value added process by the retailer becomes unaffected by the level of coordination in the supply chain. It is also seen that the optimum value of the value added depends only on one parameter, namely, . Therefore, if the retailer can use operational means to reduce her cost of adding value, the optimal value-added will be higher. This action will start a ripple effect by allowing the retailer to charge a higher price and increase her profitability. Of course, this needs to be weighed against the cost of such operational means to reduce cost. Our study gives a useful managerial insight as to the retailer’s action about her own cost structure. The manufacturer, on the other hand, does not change his price with the supply chain structure, because his price is not dependent on , and thus on the amount of information sharing. But when this policy is coupled with the retailer’s policy of pA2 pI2 (from Proposition 4), we can see that double marginalization occurs due to the asymmetric information. This, in turn, reduces the whole supply chain efficiency. It will be also interesting to study the behavior of demand for both channels under the two scenarios. We do this in the next proposition. Proposition 6. The retail channel will experience increased demand if the supply chain structure moves from being asymmetric to integrated. At the same time the direct channel demand will decrease. This is a rather surprising finding. We can explain this by using the example of uniform distribution, as shown in the proof of this proposition. With increasing, the retailer channel demand d2 is decreasing and direct channel demand d1 is increasing for both the cases of I and A. The explanation of this can be found in the fact that when increases, the amount of value added decreases. This makes buying from the retailer channel less attractive to the customer. Therefore, more and more customers choose to buy the product from the direct channel. We also find that the cut-off point is higher under I than under A, i.e., N I N A . It means that the manufacturer and retailer can trade longer under I, before it becomes unattractive to either of them to trade (by possibly hitting one of the reservation profit levels). It can be explained as follows. In case of A, the manufacturer does not know . The manufacturer, therefore, would feel safer to trade with retailer only within a small range of . The manufacturer and retailer would both lose some trading opportunities to earn higher profit.
5 Results of Numerical Analysis To validate our analytical results and to gain more insights into the optimal policies, we carried out some numerical analysis. The results are briefly reported here. The numerical values used in this experiment are: a 40
r 0.500
pM 1,100
pR 600
0 0.03
3 0.07
Value-Added Retailer in a Mixed Channel
5.1
179
Variation of Profits Under Different Scenarios
We will start by investigating the three cases detailed in Sect. 4.3. We used Case 1 for our analytical exposition, but here we study the other two cases to see when they occur and what kind of guidelines we can achieve from these cases. We assume a Uniform distribution for with f ðÞ ¼
1 3 0
FðÞ ¼
0 3 0
and
over the interval ½0 ; 3 . The manufacturer’s profit as function of is: pAM ¼
0 0 2 a a0 a2 ð1 þ rÞ þ þ þ LA ðÞ 83 84 4 42 4ð1 rÞ
and the retailer’s profit is pAR ¼ pA1 d1A þ wA1 d2A þ LA ðÞ ¼
a2 0 a 2 þ 2 þ 0 4 þ LA ðÞ: 4 4 16
We plot these two profit expressions as functions of as shown in Fig. 2. This shows that both the manufacturer’s and the retailer’s profit are non-monotone function with . There are three very obvious regions of in the Profit
Region 1 (n0, n1)
Region 2 (n1, n2)
Region 3 (n2, n3)
1250.000 1150.000 1050.000 950.000 850.000 750.000 650.000 n 550.000 0.047 0.050 0.053 0.056 0.059 0.062 0.065 0.068
Fig. 2 The manufacturer and retailer’s profit for various
M (A) R (A)
180
S.K. Mukhopadhyay et al.
graph. We break the range ½0 ; 3 into three regions. In any one of these three regions, the profits show monotone property. Region 1. In this region, in the interval ð0 ; 1 Þ, the manufacturer’s profit decreases and the retailer’s profit increases with . This corresponds to Case 1 in Sect. 4.3. We start with Z0 ¼ 0.03. To obtain 1, we find that 1 satisfies 2 @pAR 0 1 0 ð161 4 þ 41 3 Þ0 2 a þ a ¼ @ 41 3 8 1 2 41 5 321 7 3 ð81 2 þ 1 Þ0 2 þ 0 7 ¼0 161 321 7 This gives 1 ¼ 1:910 ¼ 0:0573. Region 2. The interval ð1 ; 2 Þ gives us Region 2 where both the manufacturer’s and the retailer’s profits decrease with . This corresponds to Case 2 in Sect. 4.3. 1 ¼ 0:0573 as obtained above. We obtain Z2 from: @pAM 0 1 0 2 ð162 4 þ 42 3 Þ0 1 2 ¼ þ þ a þ a @ 42 3 82 2 42 5 322 7 42 2 3 ð162 2 þ 2 Þ0 2 30 ¼0 0 7þ 162 322 7 82 4 Giving
@pAR þ @
a 0 2 30 þ 42 45 84
¼ 0:
We get 2 ¼ 2:010 ¼ 0:0603 Substituting 1 ¼ 0:0573. Region 3. This is the remaining region and the range is given by ð2 ; 3 Þis (0.0603, 0.07). In this region, the manufacturer’s profit increases in and the retailer’s profit decreases. This corresponds to Case 3 in Sect. 4.3. In Region 1, is relatively small, giving the value added (¼1/) as relatively high. The manufacturer’s profit decreases and the retailer’s profit increases in . This can be seen in certain industries like electronics or computer industry. Here the manufacturers are generally locked into working with their retailers. In these industries, the retailers are “unlikely to get dis-intermediated”, says AMR Research’s Bob Parker (Gilbert and Bacheldor 2000). In fact, “Manufacturers are looking to strengthen the channel rather than circumvent it” (Gilbert and Bacheldor 2000). The higher the value the retailer adds to the base product, the higher profit the manufacturer earns. So the manufacturer should cooperate with the retailer when opening a new direct online channel and push the retailer to add more value to the base product on the retail channel. We see this kind of practice from IBM and HP. We also find that the retailer prefers to add small amount of value (with a large ) to avoid heavy cost burden. Another extreme case is shown in Region 3. In the region, is relatively high or value added is relatively low, the manufacturer’s profit increases in and the
Value-Added Retailer in a Mixed Channel
181
retailer’s profit decreases in . This result can explain the competition between manufacturer and retailer in industries such as an airline company and its airline ticket agent. It is hard for the agent (or the retailer) to add any value to the base product. Our study suggests that the airline company should open direct sales channel and compete with the agent. We also see that the less the value added, the more the manufacturer benefit from competition. Region 2 is the middle of the other two extreme cases. We see that both the manufacturer’s and the retailer’s profits decrease in and increase in value added. The high degree of value added would differentiate the product on the two channels and reduce channel conflict. Both the manufacturer and retailer would prefer higher value added and earn higher profits. From the manufacturer’s point of view, he would want to limit within Region 1. There are several reasons. First, when comparing Region 1 with the Region 2, we find that the manufacturer’s profit in Region 1 is dominant to that of Region 2. It implies that the manufacturer should always push the retailer add more value and reduce to bring it back within Region 1. Next, consider Region 3. From the analysis given above, the manufacturer should open a direct sales channel to compete with retail channel. For example, the manufacturer could set wholesale price w equal to or very close to direct sale price p1 and squeeze the retailer out of the market if she could not play any role in the value-adding process. In the airline industry, the ticket agents are facing this fate.
5.2
Behavior of Profits with Varying h
We analyze the behavior of the profits when the parameter is varied. This is shown in Region 1 of Fig. 3. From the figure, we have several findings besides those shown in Propositions 4–6. We can see that pAR pIR and pIM pAM are increasing with . Profit
η0 1250.000
η1
1150.000 1050.000
M (I)
950.000
M (A)
850.000
R (A) R (I)
750.000 650.000 05 7 0.
05 5 0.
05 1
04 9
05 3 0.
0.
0.
04 7 0.
04 5
n
0.
0.
04 3
550.000
Fig. 3 Variation of the manufacturer and retailer’s profit for various
182
S.K. Mukhopadhyay et al.
It means that the value of information is increasing in . With increasing, the retailer earns higher profit because she holds private information, but the manufacturer’s profit decreases. We also see that the cut-off point N I N A . We already know that under A, the manufacturer’s profit drops down to his reservation profit at the cut-off point, i.e., ¼ NA ¼ 1 . While at this point the manufacturer’s profit under I is still higher than his reservation profit, so the manufacturer could continue to trade with the retailer until his profit drops down to pM . At cut-off point NA, the manufacturer and the retailer both earn their reservation profits pM and pR , respectively. At this point, they both have exhausted all trading opportunity. We also carried out sensitivity analyses on the effect on profit of other parameters like base demand a and the migration parameter r. Because of length consideration, we do not report the entire findings here. In short, we find that, with the base demand a increasing, the value of information (given by the difference between the profits in A and I cases) increases. The managerial guideline here is that the retailer should try to increase the base demand by means of, say, advertising or offering better return policy etc. We also found that when the migration parameter r increases, the value of information increases. Again, the guideline for the retailer is that she should use marketing means to influence r.
6 Conclusions An important aspect of supply chain management in the Internet era has been studied in this chapter. More and more firms are introducing a direct channel in addition to the traditional retailer channel. In this new business model, the traditional channel is differentiated by an augmented role for the retailer namely modifying the basic product by adding value for the customer. We have presented a game theoretic formulation for this new business model. We studied two cases: the case with complete information and the case with asymmetric information. We obtained closed form contracts for both the channel partners in terms of market parameters and contrasted the optimum policies with those when the channels are completely integrated. Our study found that the manufacturer – the partner suffering from the asymmetry of the information – would always benefit (increased profit) with more information. We also found that, with information asymmetry, the direct channel price does not change, while the retailer enjoys higher price. One interesting finding is that the quantum of value-added does not change under any scenario and is only dependent on the retailer’s cost structure. Information asymmetry imposes inefficiency to the manufacturer and to the supply chain as a whole. The managerial insight gained from all these results would enable the manufacturer to decide about an information sharing contract which would include suitable incentive for the retailer. Our study showed that the actual values of the decisions variables in the optimum policy depend on the various market parameters like the base demand, and the migration parameter. Our results can be used as a guideline to set decisions
Value-Added Retailer in a Mixed Channel
183
about other variables, like product quality and return policy in order to influence these market parameters to move in the direction which would be beneficial to the channel partners. We also showed the benefit of the complete channel integration. Our model can be extended in many different directions. We can allow the manufacturer to provide a value added service, instead of the retailer. Customer’s special order requirement could be easily delivered to the manufacturer through online direct channel. So some companies let the manufacturers handle the customized order through the direct channel. For example, Disney only takes personalized orders (like putting customer’s name on the product) online and sell standardized product at stores. Another interesting extension could allow both the retailer and manufacturer to offer value added service on both channels, the traditional retailer channel and direct online channel. The value added service through the manufacturer on the direct channel could be modeled by a make-toorder process and the value added service on the traditional retailer channel through the retailer could be modeled by a make-to-stock process and/or a mass customization process. These two approaches of offering variety to the customers, namely, make-to-order and mass customization, could be analyzed and compared. We can expect further research in the mixed channel field with more and more companies adding online stores to their traditional brick-and-mortar stores. We hope that the research methodology and topic presented in this chapter are helpful for future research project in this field.
Appendix Proof of Proposition 1(a) v2 ða p2 þ v þ p1 rÞ pI ¼ p1 d1 þ ðp2 cv Þd2 ¼ p1 ða p1 þ rðp2 vÞÞ þ p2 2 Then we take first order condition with respect to p1, p2 and v, and set them equal to zero, respectively. After that, solving these three equations simultaneously, we can get the desired result. Proof of Proposition 1(b) pFR ¼ ðp2 w Cv Þd2 þ LF ¼ pR 2 2a þ 1 F ) L ¼ pR 4 ( pM ¼
a 1 a2 pR þ þ 4 162 2ð1 rÞ pM
N N
ðaÞ ðbÞ
)
184
S.K. Mukhopadhyay et al.
Setting (a) ¼ (b), we get N¼
1 rffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi 1þr 2a þ 2 4pM þ4pR a2 1r
where
pM þpR
a2 ð1 þ rÞ 4ð1 rÞ
Due to N > 0, we only keep the one with positive value. Proof of Proposition 2(a) The (10)–(12) can be written as: ðN max
mðÞd þ FðNÞ
s:t: _ _ LðÞ ¼ g1 ðÞ; wðÞ ¼ g2 ðÞ;
p_ 1 ðÞ ¼ g3 ðÞ
This is obtained by making the following variable substitution: m : ¼ ðp1 d1 ðpr2 Þ þ wd2 ðpr2 Þ LÞf 2 r r r a 1 w 1 p1 aþ þw þ rwp1 L f ; þ ¼ p1 1 þ 2 2 4 2 4 2 1 a þ rp1 w ðu1 ru2 Þ; g2 ¼ u1 ; g3 ¼ u2 ; þ g1 ¼ 4 2 FðNÞ ¼ pM ð1 FÞ: Using the multiplier equations gives following results: l_ 1 ¼ f
and l1 ¼ f
(13)
_l2 ¼ w þ a þ 1 þ rp1 f þ l1 ðu1 ru2 Þ 2 2 4
(14)
2
_l3 ¼ a 1 þ r þ 2p1 r 1 r þ rw f l1 rðu1 ru2 Þ 2 2 4 2
(15)
Using the optimality conditions gives following results: l1
1 a þ rp1 w þ l2 ¼ 0 þ 4 2
rl1
1 a þ rp1 w þ l3 ¼ 0 þ 4 2
(16)
(17)
Value-Added Retailer in a Mixed Channel
185
Taking derivative on both sides of (16) and using (13), we get 1 a þ rp1 w 1 r u1 f F 2 þ u2 þ l_ 2 ¼ 2 4 2 4 2
(18)
Solving (18) with (14), we get F ¼ fw frp1 22
(19)
Taking derivative on both sides of (17) and using (13), we get l_ 3 ¼ rf
1 a þ rp1 w 1 r u1 þ rF 2 þ u2 þ 2 4 2 4 2
(20)
Solving (20) with (15), we get 2 rF 3r rw ¼ f a þ ar þ þ 2 p 1 2 42 2
(21)
Solving (19) and (21) together, we get desired result pA1 ¼
a F ra ; wA ¼ 2ð1 rÞ 2f 2 2ð1 rÞ
and _ LðÞ ¼ g1 ðÞ ¼
1 a þ rp1 w 1 a þ rp1 w _ ðu1 ru2 Þ ¼ w: þ þ 4 2 4 2
Using the transversality conditions if N is free mðNÞ þ l1 ðNÞg1 ðNÞ þ l2 ðNÞg2 ðNÞ þ l3 ðNÞg3 ðNÞ þ FN ¼ 0 at N we get the following results: ðp1 d1 þ wd2 L pM Þf ¼ 0. Because f 6¼ 0, p1 d1 þ wd2 L pM must equals to 0. The manufacturer can make p1 d1 þ wd2 L pM 0 binding at 1 , 1 ¼ N. Then substitute p1 and w with pA1 (N) and wA (N), we get that L(N)A satisfies
F2 aF F a2 ð1 þ rÞ LðNÞA ¼ pM : þ 2 þ 3 þ 4 2 8N f 4N f 8N f 4ð1 rÞ
0 can be solved by let ðpA2 wA cv A Þd2 þ LA pR binding at 0 .
186
S.K. Mukhopadhyay et al.
Proof of Proposition 3 (i) Manufacturer: Adding pIR þ pIM pAR þ pAM from Proposition 3(ii) and pAR I pR from Proposition 3(iii), we can get pIM pAM . (ii) Retailer: Under (I), the retailer earns her reservation profit through the whole range of . Under (A), it is always higher or equal to her reservation profit. Therefore, pIR pAR for all . As an example, suppose follows a Uniform distribution where F¼
0 1 ; f ¼ : 3 0 3 0
Then, pAR ¼
a 0 þ 2 42
which is decreasing with to a value of pR at ¼ NA. At the same time, profit for the case I is constant at pR for all , so we have pR I pR A . (iii) The supply chain: The supply chain profit under (I) pI ¼
a 1 a2 þ þ 2 2ð1 rÞ 4 16
and the supply chain profit under (A) is pA ¼ pAR þ pAM ¼
a 1 a2 F2 þ þ 4 162 2ð1 rÞ 164 f 2
Obviously, pI > pA. Proof of Proposition 6 Under uniform distribution: d2I ¼
a 1 þ 2 4
and
d2A ¼
a 1 F : So d2I d2A : þ 2 4 4f 2
d1I ¼
a r 2 4
and
d1A ¼
a r rF : So d1I d1A : þ 2 4 4f 2
References Agatz NAH, Fleischmann M, van Nunen JAEE (2008) E-fulfillment and multi-channel distribution – a review. Eur J Oper Res 187(2):339–356 Balasubramanian S (1998) Mail versus mall: a strategic analysis of competition between direct marketers and conventional retailers. Mark Sci 17:181–195
Value-Added Retailer in a Mixed Channel
187
Bannon L (2000) Selling Barbie online may pit Mattel vs. stores. Wall Street J, 17 Nov Brooker K (1999) E-rivals seem to have home depot awfully nervous. Fortune 140(4):28–29 Cachon GP, Lariviere MA (2005) Supply chain coordination with revenue-sharing contracts: strengths and limitations. Manage Sci 51(1):30–44 Cakanyildirim M, Feng Q, Gan X, Sethi S (2010) Contracting and coordination under asymmetric production cost information. http://ssrn.com/abstract¼1084584 Chiang W, Chhajed D, Hess JD (2003) Direct marketing, indirect profits: a strategic analysis of dual-channel supply chain design. Manage Sci 49(1):1–20 Chiang W (2010) Product availability in competitive and cooperative dual-channel distribution with stock-out based substitution. Eur J Oper Res 200(1):111–126 Cohen M, Agrawal N, Agrawal V, Raman A (1995) Analysis of distribution strategies in the industrial paper and plastic industries. Oper Res 43(1):6–18 Collinger T (1998) Lines separating sales channels blur: manufacturers, direct sellers, retailers invade each other’s turf. Advert Age 34, 30 March Corbett C, de Groote X (2000) A supplier’s optimal quantity discount policy under asymmetric information. Manage Sci 46(3):444–450 Corbett C, Zhou D, Tang CS (2004) Designing supply contracts: contract type and information asymmetry. Manage Sci 50(4):550–559 Cotterill RW, Putsis WP (2001) Do models of vertical strategic interaction for national and store brands meet the market test? J Retailing 77(1):83–109 Desiraju R, Moorthy S (1997) Managing a distribution channel under asymmetric information with performance requirement. Manage Sci 43(12):1628–1644 Fay CJ (1999) The direct approach. Best’s Rev 99(11):91–93 Frazier GL (1999) Organizing and managing channels of distribution. J Acad Mark Sci 27 (2):226–241 Fudenberg D, Tirole J (1991) Game theory. MIT, Cambridge, MA Gavirneni S, Kapuscinski R, Tayur S (1999) Value of information in capacitated supply chains. Manage Sci 45(1):16–24 Gilbert A, Bacheldor B (2000) The big squeeze-in suppliers’ rush to sell directly to consumers over the Web, sales agents, distributors, and other channel partners worry that they’ll be pushed out of the picture. Inform Week, 27 March. http://www.informationweek.com/779/channel. htm Ha AY (2001) Supplier-buyer contracting: asymmetric cost information and cutoff level policy for buyer participation. Nav Res Logist 48:41–64 Hann LW (1999) Progressive, zurich show how it’s done. Best’s Rev 99(9):75 Hua G, Wang S, Cheng TCE (2010) Price and lead time decisions in dual-channel supply chains. Eur J Oper Res 205(1):113–126 Janah M (1999) Tech firms slow to use direct web sales. San Jose Mercury News, 24 Feb, C1. http://www.wsj.com Kamien MI, Schwartz N (1981) Dynamic optimization: the calculus of variations and optimal control in economics and management. North Holland, New York Khouja M, Park S, Cai G (2010) Channel selection and pricing in the presence of retail-captive consumers. Int J Prod Econ 125(1):84–95 Lee H, So KC, Tang C (2000) The value of information sharing in a two-level supply chain. Manage Sci 46:626–643 Levary R, Mathieu RG (2000) Hybrid retail: integrating e-commerce and physical stores. Ind Manage 42(5):6–13 Mukhopadhyay SK, Su X, Ghose S (2009) Motivating retail marketing effort: optimal contract design. Prod Oper Manage 18(2):197–211 Mukhopadhyay SK, Zhu X, Yue X (2008a) Optimal contract design for mixed channels under information asymmetry. Prod Oper Manage 17(6):641–650 Mukhopadhyay SK, Yao D, Yue X (2008b) Information sharing of value-adding retailer in a mixed channel hi-tech supply chain. J Bus Res 61:950–958
188
S.K. Mukhopadhyay et al.
Nasiretti R (1998) IBM plans to sell some gear directly to fight its rivals. Wall Street J, 5 June Plambeck EL, Taylor TA (2008) Implications of renegotiation for optimal contract flexibility and investment. Manage Sci 54(12):1997–2011 Su X, Wu L, Yue X (2010) Impact of introducing a direct channel on supply chain performance. Int J Electron Bus 8(2):101–125 Tsay AA, Nahmias S, Agrawal N (1999) Modeling supply chain contracts: a review. In: Tayur S, Ganeshan R, Magazine M (eds) Quantitative models for supply chain management, International series in operations research and management science. Kluwer, Norwell, MA, pp 299–336 Viswanathan S (2000) Competition across channels: do electronic markets complement or cannibalize traditional retailers. International Conference on Information Systems (ICIS) 2000 Proceedings, Brisbane, pp 513–519. http://aisel.aisnet.org/icis2000/51 Yao D, Liu J (2003) Channel redistribution with direct selling. Eur J Oper Res 144:646–658
Capacity Management and Price Discrimination under Demand Uncertainty Using Option Contracts Fang Fang and Andrew Whinston
Abstract This chapter considers the use of option contracts as a price discrimination tool under demand uncertainty to improve supplier profit and supply chain efficiency. Option contracts have long been used to manage demand or supply uncertainty, and the cost of the option is simply considered as the cost to avoid uncertainties. We give an example in a supply chain setting where a supplier has more than one downstream customer with private information. Under such a scenario, our game theoretical model shows that the option price shall be set taking into account the fact that only the customers who are more concerned about the demand uncertainty will purchase. Therefore, the supplier should be able to charge more for a unit of option contract compared to the traditional pricing method where simple expectations are taken. The supplier’s profit improves in three ways. First, the high type customers pay higher marginal prices on average. Second, the high type customers’ demand is satisfied as a first priority, guaranteeing allocation efficiency. Third, the supplier can observe the number of options being purchased and so determine customer types, improving capacity decision efficiency. We compare our results to those of classical second degree price discrimination literature. We show that the use of option contracts guarantee the same level of supplier profit as the level of second degree price discrimination. The overall supply chain efficiency improves to the full information benchmark. Keywords Capacity management • Demand uncertainty • Monopoly revenue management • Option contracts • Price discrimination F. Fang (*) Department of ISOM, College of Business Administration, California State University at San Marcos, 333 S. Twin Oaks Valley Road, San Marcos, CA 92096, USA e-mail: [email protected] A. Whinston Department of IROM, McCombs School of Business, The University of Texas at Austin, 1 University Station B6000, Austin, TX 78712, USA e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_8, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
189
190
F. Fang and A. Whinston
1 Introduction Nowadays, the trend of Globalization has significantly intensified competition among companies. The requirement of effectively managing uncertainties has also been raised to an unprecedent level. Companies are striving to find novel ways to manage any kind of uncertainties. Demand uncertainty, as one of the outstanding example, has attracted a lot of attention in the recent supply chain management literature. A lot of attention has been focused on how to improve forecasting accuracies by sharing information among supply chain partners to reduce the uncertainty (e.g. Cachon and Fisher 2000; Chen 2003; Guo et al. 2006; Li 2002; etc.). In this chapter, we will discuss an innovative method of using option contracts for demand forecast and profit management. Real options contracts has been studied in supply chain management literature as a tool to protect risk-averse partners from potential uncertainties, such as demand and material cost changes (see e.g., Huchzermeier and Cohen 1996). In an incomplete contract setup, option contracts can also improve contracting efficiency by solving the famous hold-up problem (see e.g. Noldeke and Schmidt 1995). In this chapter, we explore using option contracts as a price discrimination tool under demand uncertainty. In the classic economics literature, price discrimination relies on the supplier’s ability to determine customers’ different levels of willingness to pay and hence to charge different prices. When customer types are not observable, the supplier can offer a variety of products with different prices for the customers to choose from. This practice is known as second degree price discrimination (e.g. Tirole 1988). In a classical second degree price discrimination model, the monopoly knows that the customers’ have different valuations over the quality (in some other applications, the bundled quantity) of the product, hence produces a product with two different qualities (or two bundles with different quantities) and charges different prices. The customers with different types will then have to select the product quality/quantity bundles that meet their needs the best. We extend the classical model in a setting where the customers’ demand quantity is uncertain and the supplier’s capacity is tight. In addition, the customers do not obtain higher valuation from the quantity satisfied that exceeds their own need. Example of such scenario could be when customers may want to purchase a certain number of tickets to a game and will not be able to use the extra tickets they do not need. Other cases can be found in the network/telephone service, when a customer may need to send out a certain size of email or text message. Additional network traffic would be of no use. In both cases, demand might be uncertain ex ante when customers cannot decide whether they need to go to the game or to send the email. Under such scenarios, quantity bundling strategy used in traditional second degree discrimination is not feasible. This is because the customers’ desired quantities vary according to their realized demand and would not benefit if obtain a bundle with superior quantity.
Capacity Management and Price Discrimination under Demand Uncertainty
191
In this chapter, we propose using a new form of option contracts to solve such an issue. The main reason that the option contracts would be a good device to use is because of the capacity constrain. In situations when capacity may be tight, customers have an incentive to hedge the risk when their demand cannot be satisfied. The hedging incentive is higher for those customers with higher willingness to pay. Under such circumstance, we suggest the supplier sells a form of option contracts to the customers. Executing one unit of the option contracts guarantees a customer the availability of one unit of demand and meets customers’ hedging incentive. To distinguish customers with different types, we propose that the supplier should price the option contracts in such a way that only those customers with higher willingness to pay will buy the options. The supplier can take into account the fact that those customers who have purchased the options have a higher willingness to pay to the product/service and can charge a higher option price to those customers. Under such a pricing scheme, the high type customers (who will purchase the options) will self-select to pay more than their low type counterparts (who will not purchase the options) to ensure execution of their demand. The supplier would then be able to identify the customers’ types from the purchase of the option contracts. To demonstrate the effectiveness of the option contracts as a price discrimination tool, we present a game theoretic model where one monopolistic supplier or service provider (he) faces two customers each with uncertain future demand. Each customer (she) has private information about their willingness to pay for one unit of the future demand. The supplier has to build capacity before the customers’ demand is realized. Since capacity may be insufficient for the highest level of demand realization, customers suffer from potential demand losses. When demand exceeds capacity, the supplier can only serve the demand randomly. Option contracts can be adopted in the following manner. The supplier opens the option market to the customers before the capacity investment and uncertain demand realization. At that time, customers can purchase options with unit price po. After observing customers’ option purchase decisions, the supplier invests in capacity to prepare for future uncertain demand. Afterwards, the customers find out their actual demand, observe the supplier’s capacity and decide whether to exercise their options. Alternatively, the customers can submit regular demand. Each customer pays a strike price, pe, for each unit of option executed. The amount of demand protected by the options (referred to as the “option demand” in the context) will be satisfied as the first priority. The remaining demand will be satisfied at a unit price p if there is leftover capacity. Our proposed framework improves the supplier’s revenue in three ways. First, customers with a higher willingness to pay will pay a higher unit price when the capacity is tight, increasing the supplier’s overall revenue. Second, the customers’ option demands are executed as a first priority. The remaining demand will be executed only when there is extra capacity. Third, customers’ options purchases reveal their types. This knowledge allows the supplier to more efficiently adjust the capacity levels, better accommodating the potential demand. The last two effects
192
F. Fang and A. Whinston
also improve the supplier’s decision efficiency, leading to an enhanced overall social welfare. In order to successfully induce high type customers into purchasing options, the supplier needs to convince the customers that the capacity could be insufficient. If a supplier is able to change capacity after the options are purchased, however, it may undermine the customers’ initial incentives to purchase them. This is because customers know that the supplier will want to guarantee enough capacity to meet the demand, so as to maximize the revenue by serving as much customer demand as possible. Knowing their own types and the supplier’s capacity cost, a rational customer can always conjecture the expected capacity level that the supplier will invest in contingent on their counterpart’s type. They can therefore calculate the overall benefit of purchasing the options based on these “rationally expected” capacity levels. The supplier cannot mislead the customers. However, the capacity investment levels could be different if the supplier adopts different option contracts (e.g. different po and pe). Hence, the supplier’s pricing strategy of those option contract is critical in our framework. The supplier can decide not to build sufficient capacity to guarantee the execution of the entire option demand. The decision depends on what commitment the supplier makes in the option contracts when he fails to meet the option demand. If the supplier does not compensate unsatisfied customers, the customers will have less incentive to purchase the options. This disappoints the high type customers and reduces their valuation of the options. If the supplier promises too high a compensation, he has to always ensure to overinvest in capacity. This may be inefficient especially when the capacity cost is high. In this paper, we suggest the supplier offer an option buy-back price as a compensation mechanism which leaves the high type customers indifferent between whether to execute their options or to sell them back to the supplier. This buy-back price scheme reduces the high type customers’ strategic decision of exercising the options and induces the supplier’s efficient capacity investment which maximizes ex ante social welfare. Our option framework has the potential to improve revenue management in many industries wherever demand uncertainty and information asymmetry exist. One potential application is in network traffic management. Since business communication relies heavily upon emails and video conferences, network congestion can cause severe economic losses. Companies are willing to pay a premium more than what the regular users pay to ensure important business emails being delivered promptly. Another example application to use the options framework is in the ticket sale business. Many people want to go to a concert or a game but face the risk of not being able to attend ex post. They do not want to pay the full price for the tickets in advance because they do not want to waste money if they are unable to attend. However, if they wait too long, the tickets could be sold out. The option contracts are a good choice for these people. Similar applications can be implemented in airline ticket management, hospital facility management and the hotel reservations business. In hotel reservation business, customers who care more about getting the hotel room can make reservations
Capacity Management and Price Discrimination under Demand Uncertainty
193
before arrival. It bears resemblance to the option framework. However, in practice, reservation is often free (i.e. the option price po is zero). This chapter provides an analytical framework to determine the option price. Supply chain partners can also consider using the option contracts when coordinating with each other. Although some research in supply chain management has proposed using options contracts for risk hedging and improve downstream partners’ ordering efficiency, there has been no study when suppliers have incomplete information about downstream partners’ types. Our proposed framework filled the blank by suggesting that the supplier offer different pricing schemes and allow the downstream partners (e.g. retailers) to self select the type of contracts they prefer. Retailers who are in the regions where the product is more popular would be willing to pay more than other retailers. The supplier should take such fact into consideration when determining the prices of the option contracts, rather than applying traditional options evaluation equations widely used in finance literature. In the options framework, the supplier employs price discrimination by extending the customers’ decision problem into an intertemporal one. That is, the customers have to decide whether and how many options they should purchase to hedge the future risk of demand loss before their demand realization and the supplier’s capacity investment. To make the decision, they have to figure out the capacity level the supplier may invest in and the possibility when they will use the options. When they evaluate the options, rational customers also take into account the fact that their option purchase reveals their types to the supplier and affects supplier’s the capacity level. To illustrate the implementation of option contracts, we present a two-period game-theoretic model. The model has one monopolistic supplier and two potential customers with private valuation of the service. Figure 1 shows the time line of events.
Fig. 1 The time line of the base model
194
F. Fang and A. Whinston
In the first period – the contracting period – the monopolistic supplier announces the option purchase price, po, and the strike price, pe, to maximize his expected overall profit. Then each customer decides the number of options to purchase, Oi, according to their types. At the beginning of the second period – consumption period – the supplier observes the customers’ options purchases and decides on an optimal capacity investment, K. Afterwards, the customers demands, Di, are realized. Each customer decides how many options they are going to exercise (Doi ) based on the observation of the aggregate demand and the capacity level. The supplier satisfies the option demand as a first priority. If Do > K, some of the options cannot be executed and the supplier will compensate the customers. If Do < K, the extra capacity will be used to satisfy the remaining regular demand. The rest of this chapter is organized as follows. A brief literature review is provided in Sect. 2. Section 3 presents the game model and Sect. 4 analyzes the equilibrium strategies of the supplier and two customers. We compare the model outcome to two benchmark cases. In one of the benchmarks, the supplier cannot distinguish the customer types at all. In the other, the supplier can determine each customer’s type and can charge different prices to each of them. In Sect. 5, we discuss the implications and extensions of our model. Section 6 concludes the paper.
2 Literature Review This chapter discusses the use of the options contract for price discrimination under demand uncertainty. The idea of using options contract in supply chain coordination is not a new idea. Cachon (2002) and Lariviere (1999) have surveyed a variety of supply chain contracts, particularly the options contract that induce the supply chain partners to take the right actions under different circumstances. Sethi et al. (2004) formulate a multi-period model to study procurement strategy under an option-like quantity flexible contract with spot market purchasing opportunity. Kleindorfer and Wu (2003) integrated the use of options with operational decisions, such as capacity, technology choice, and production to improve the profitability in supply chain coordination and risk management. In addition, research has also shown that the quantity flexible contracts, buy-back contracts, and pay-to-delay contracts are special cases of a combination of a priceonly contract and a call-option contract (e.g. Cachon and Lariviere 2001; BarnesSchuster et al. 2002; Martı´nez-de-Albe´niz and Simchi-Levi 2005; etc.). Lin and Kulatilaka (2007) introduce an real options approach to evaluate companies’ high-risk investments, e.g. IT outsourcing decisions, IT procurements, etc. Our framework moves one step further to discuss the possible use of option contracts in price discrimination. There has been a rich economics literature on price discrimination. (e.g. Varian 1985; Armstrong and Vickers 2001; Corsetti and Dedola 2005; Mortimer 2007) An
Capacity Management and Price Discrimination under Demand Uncertainty
195
extensive discussion on price discrimination can be found in Tirole (1988) and Mas-Colell et al. (1995). Maskin and Riley (1984) discussed optimal mechanism design that can induce different agents to report truthfully their types. Their model primarily concerns a principle who is trying to allocate limited resources to a number of agents. The assumption was that the resource is rare and demand uncertainty is not an issue. The outstanding result shows that the lowest type of agent will be left no surplus and the higher type agents enjoy certain level of surplus, which is necessary for them to report their true information. Such surplus is called “information rent” in the literature of second degree price discrimination. Deshpande and Schwartz (2002) extend the mechanism into a constrained capacity setup. In this mechanism, non-linear pricing rules are adopted to guarantee incentive compatibility. Boyaci and Ray (2006) discussed the impact of capacity costs on product differentiation in a product delivery model. In our framework, the demand is uncertain so that the allocation for the two types of customers cannot be predeterimined. In this sense, Maskin and Riley’s mechanism cannot be directly applied to solve our problem. An alternative pricing scheme is the spot pricing scheme, which suggests that the price should be dynamically adjusted according to the congestion levels. Gupta et al. (1996, 1999) suggests using priority classes with different spot prices to efficiently allocate network resource. The idea is that the customers with higher delay costs will choose to pay more and send their demand to the network with lower expected delay time. Afeche (2006) suggests to add strategic delay in the queue to further discriminate customers and maximize the revenue of the supplier. However, under the spot pricing mechanism, customers decide whether to execute the demand when observing the spot price. The supplier cannot discover the customers’ type distribution before adjusting the capacity. In addition, consumers will face additional uncertain future spot price due to the different realizations of future. In practice, the spot price is not preferred by both individual consumers and companies due to the management difficulties.
3 Model Development A monopolistic supplier sells to two risk neutral customers (i ¼ 1,2). Each customer can be one of two unknown types. A “high” type customer enjoys higher marginal utility from the satisfied demand than a “low” type customer. Specifically, customer i receives total utility ui ¼ vti Dei mi if she is of type ti ∈ {l, h}. vti represents the customer’s marginal value of satisfied for type ti and vh > vl. Dei is customer i’s demand being satisfied by the supplier, and mi is the total monetary transfer from customer i to the supplier. Each customer knows her own type ti but does not know for certain the other’s type. The supplier can observe neither of the customers’ types. The common belief is that ti ¼ h with probability l ∈ (0,1) and ti ¼ l with probability 1 l. The realizations of t1 and t2 are independent.
196
F. Fang and A. Whinston
Each customer’s demand, Di, is uncertain and could be either DH (with probability a) or DL (with probability 1 a). The realization of (D1, D2) is independent of customers’ type realization (t1, t2). We denote D ¼ ðD1 ; D2 Þ as the demand vector and D ¼ D1 + D2 as the aggregate realized demand. To avoid the trivial case when the supplier will only concern the high demand situation, we assume that DH < 2DL. After observing the demand realization Di, each customer decides how much of the demand should be submitted to the supplier, which we denote as Dsi . In this model, we restrict Dsi bDi , implying that the customer cannot submit a demand higher than the realization of their actual demand. This restriction makes sense when the demand can be verified ex post. Taking the example of network traffic management, customer sends out files with certain sizes. A customer can increase the demand by extending the size of the file. However, she cannot benefit from doing so. Failure to impose the above restriction introduces customers’ strategic behavior when submitting their demand. Cachon and Lariviere (1999) analyzed this kind of strategic behavior under different allocation rules. They show that customers’ order inflation could be an equilibrium strategy and the supplier is worse-off due to the concern of such strategic behavior. However, this is not the focus of our paper. To serve the customer demand, the supplier has to invest in a certain level of capacity K before the demand, D is realized. The marginal cost of capacity investment is c0. Observing the customers’ submitted demand Ds ¼ ðDs1 ; Ds2 Þ, the supplier decides how much demand to execute for each customer, De ¼ ðDe1 ; De2 Þ, ðDei bDsi for i ¼ 1; 2Þ to maximize his expected revenue. The total amount of executed demand, De ¼ De1 þ De2 is constrained by the supplier’s capacity K. To avoid trivial results, we will impose the following three assumptions: Assumption 1. c0 > minfð2a a2 Þvl ; a2 vh g: This condition guarantees that the supplier’s capacity cost is non-trivial so that the supplier cannot simply decide to invest in the highest capacity level possible to avoid congestion. Violation of this condition will result in the trivial case where the customers do not expect any congestion and hence will not purchase any option. Assumption 2. c0 < ð2a a2 Þvh : This condition guarantees that the capacity cost is not prohibitively high so that the supplier can make a profit. Otherwise, the supplier will always choose to invest qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi in zero capacity level. h 0 Assumption 3. l < 1 v vc h . This condition reduces our focus to the case where the chance of having a high type customer is small enough so that the supplier will not ignore the possible existence of low type customers. Assuming the supplier is risk neutral and there is no cost for executing the customers’ demand, the potential supplier’s profit P is calculated as P ¼ m1 þ m2 c0 K: We propose that the supplier can use option contracts to manage congestion (i.e. in the event that D > K). When capacity is insufficient to meet the aggregate
Capacity Management and Price Discrimination under Demand Uncertainty
197
demand D, customers can choose to execute their options, guaranteeing that their demand be satisfied. One unit of the option contract guarantees the customer one unit of satisfied demand regardless of congestion. To implement price discrimination, the options are priced such that only high type customers will buy the options because they will suffer more from demand loss than low type customers. By using the options, high type customers can avoid demand loss but may pay a higher unit price on average. In addition, low type customers’ demand will be executed at a lower priority, increasing their chance of facing a demand loss. The supplier benefits from using the option contracts since he can, in effect, charge the high types a higher fee and is able to adjust capacity after observing customers’ actual types. From a social optimal perspective, the allocation efficiency is always guaranteed since those demands with higher marginal value always receive first priority execution.
4 Analysis In order to demonstrate the supplier’s revenue improvement and the overall supply chain efficiency increase, we first introduce two benchmark models to compare the result of the proposed options framework. The first benchmark outlines the problem when the supplier does not have the ability to distinguish customers’ types. He also have to invest in a certain capacity level before the demand uncertainty is resolved and can only charge a linear price, p, for each unit of executed demand. Our proposed options framework should be able to improve situations outlined in the first benchmark. For one, options contracts can help supplier identify the high type customers, if any. The high type customers, with a higher average unit price paid to the supplier, can be guaranteed demand satisfaction when capacity is tight. The second benchmark model is an ideal situation where the supplier has full information. That is, the supplier can observe the customers’ types before the capacity investment. The supplier can also charge different prices ph and pl to the high types and low types, respectively. In this case, allocation efficiency is guaranteed since the supplier always satisfies demand from high type customers first and uses the remaining capacity (if there is any) to serve the low type customers. In addition, the supplier can set the prices that leave no surplus to both types of customers. The capacity investment is efficient in this case since the supplier maximizes his own profit as well as the social welfare. Our options framework, with revenue and efficiency improvement from benchmark 1, would hope to be able to achieve efficiency level demonstrated in the second benchmark. Section 4.3 analyzes the option framework and provide results. In all three frameworks, we examine both the supplier’s expected profit EP and the overall supply chain efficiency W, defined as the sum of the supplier’s expected profit and the expected utilities of both customers. We then compare the outcomes to demonstrate the effectiveness of the proposed options framework.
198
4.1
F. Fang and A. Whinston
Benchmark I: No Discrimination Case
In this section, we examine the case where the supplier can only charge a single linear price p to the customers regardless of their types. In this case, the customers will only be able to submit their demand as regular demand, rather than the option demand. In addition, there is no reason why they will submit their demand fewer than the realized demand. Therefore, we have Dsi ¼ Di for both i ¼ 1,2. However, since the capacity might be constrained, the total satisfied demand would be the minimum between the supplier’s capacity level and the total submitted demand. That is, De ¼ min{K, Ds}. Each customer is charged mi ¼ pDei and the supplier’s profit is P(p,K) ¼ pDe c0K. In this case, we have Dsi ðpÞ
¼
Di 0
if pbvti otherwise:
To decide an optimal price level, the supplier have several alternatives. By charging a price higher than vl, the supplier only serves the high type customers. The supplier can enjoy a higher marginal profit from each unit of demand, but loses business if a customer is of low type. If the price is lower than or equal to vl, both types will be served. The following Proposition 1 concludes that the supplier should serve both types of customers by charging a price p ¼ vl under the conditions we discussed in Sect. 3. The proposition also derives the optimal capacity ND , the supplier’s expected profit EPND, and the overall efficiency decision K ND . The superscript ND represents the no discrimination W ND ¼ E PND þ uND 1 þ u2 case. Proposition 1. Assume that the supplier can only charge a unit price to both customers. The optimal unit price pND ¼ vl and the capacity KND ¼ 2DL. Both types of customers will submit their demand and the supplier’s profit is EPND ¼ ðvl c0 Þ2DL : The overall efficiency is W ND ¼ lvh þ ð1 lÞvl c0 2DL : Note. The proofs of all the lemmas and propositions are provided in Appendix 2. Proposition 1 provides a benchmark outcome when the supplier is least capable of identifying customer types and charge different pricing schemes. Under such conditions, the supplier is conservative in his capacity investment decision and the capacity level is only enough for the least possible level of aggregate demand, K* ¼ 2DL ¼ inf{D}. The low type customers are left no surplus and the high type customers can make strictly positive surplus which equals the product of the difference in the marginal utility of these two types, vh vl, and the capacity 2DL.
Capacity Management and Price Discrimination under Demand Uncertainty
199
In this case, the supplier’s profit (vl c0)2DL equals the surplus it can extract as if the customers are all low type and the demand is always DL. Therefore, the first benchmark is an inefficient case where the supplier cannot take advantage of the fact that there is possible demand increase and higher willingness to pay. In order to improve this situation, the supplier needs to seek effective ways for revenue management and price discrimination.
4.2
Benchmark II: Full Information Case
In the full information benchmark case, we assume that the supplier can distinguish the different types of the customers before the capacity is invested and charge different prices according to the customer types. We use superscript FI to indicate the “full information” case. It is straightforward to show that the optimal prices will be pFI(t ¼ h) ¼ vh and FI p (t ¼ l) ¼ vl. In this case, since the customers only have one venue to submit their demand, the submitted demand Dsi equals to their realized demand Di, for i ¼ 1,2. Under such prices, the supplier leaves no surplus to both types of customers and extracts the maximum profit he can get under capacity constraint KFI. When the capacity is insufficient to meet the total submitted demand Ds ¼ Ds1 þ Ds2 , the supplier will satisfy the high type customers’ demand first to obtain a higher margin. The other decision the supplier has to make is on the capacity level. Since the supplier already knows the types of the customers, the capacity level KFI will then be different according to different customers’ types (t1, t2). Due to symmetry, we have KFI(h,l) ¼ KFI(l,h). Lemma 1 summarizes this optimal capacity level. Lemma 1. In the full information benchmark case, the capacity investment decision is made contingent on the actual types of the two customers. KFI ðt1 ; t2 Þ ¼
DH þ DL 2DL
if t1 ¼ t2 ¼ h otherwise:
The result of Lemma 1 shows that the supplier is able to set a higher capacity level when both customers are of high type. However, when at least one customer is of low type, the supplier will maintain a relatively low capacity level. This is because the supplier is able to identify and charge different prices to customers and to allocate the capacity to serve high type customers first when capacity is tight. When there is at least one low type customer, only the low types who pays a lower unit price suffer. The supplier is expecting less revenue loss which cannot motivate him to increase capacity investment. Proposition 2. When the supplier can observe customer types before making a capacity investment and charges different prices accordingly, the expected supplier
200
F. Fang and A. Whinston
profit equals the overall efficiency. That is, EPFI ¼ WFI. Comparing with EPND and WND yields
EPFI ¼ EPND þ D1 þ D2 þ D3 W FI ¼ W ND þ D1 þ D3
where: 1. D1 ¼ 2lð1 lÞaðDH DL Þðvh vl Þ; 2. D2 ¼ ðvh vl Þl2DL and 3. D3 ¼ l2 ðð2a a2 Þvh c0 ÞðDH DL Þ: It can be shown that D1, D2, and D3 are all strictly positive. Therefore, the results that EPFI > EPND and WFI > WND always hold. Proposition 2 identifies the three sources where the supplier gains higher profit: 1. The profit gain from the supplier’s ability to prioritize the customers’ demand when capacity is tight, represented by D1. 2. The profit gain from the supplier’s ability to charge different prices according to different customer types, represented by D2. 3. The profit gain from the supplier’s ability to invest in capacity levels according to the actual realization of the customer types, represented by D3. The efficiency gain comes in only two parts and does not include D2. This is because the supplier’s ability to charge the high type customers a higher price only affects the monetary transfer among the three supply chain parties. It does not change overall efficiency when adding the profits of all three parties.
4.3
Option-Capacity Game
In this section, we discuss the framework in which the supplier offers the customers a form of option contracts to hedge their demand risk. The customers choose the number of options to purchase at a unit price po before the supplier builds his capacity. The supplier will then observe the number of options purchased by each customer, conjecture the customers types, and decide how much capacity he should build to meet the future demand. After the capacity investment and demand realization, customers observe the supplier’s capacity and the aggregate demand and decide how many options to execute, if they have purchased any. The number of options a customer chooses to execute is called the option demand and is denoted as Doi . For each unit of option demand executed, the customers pay a unit execution price pe. We assume that the customer cannot execute more options than the actual demand, that is Doi bDi . If Doi < Di , the customer’s remaining demand Di Doi will be satisfied randomly. A unit price p is charged if the remaining demand is satisfied.
Capacity Management and Price Discrimination under Demand Uncertainty
201
To successfully discriminate the customers, the supplier must set the option contract parameters (po, pe) in such a way that only high type customers will buy them. The supplier also sets a unit price p ¼ vl for the regular demand. If the aggregate option demand, Do ¼ Do1 þ Do2 , exceeds the capacity K, the supplier needs to buy back some of the options. The option buy back price has to be high enough so that the high type customers are willing to sell it back. Meanwhile, it cannot be too high to make the customers want to sell all the options back instead of executing them. Thus, the buy-back price, pb, should equal vh pe, the marginal benefit the high type customers get from the demand being executed. According to the time line in Fig. 1, the strategic interactions among the supplier and the two customers can be described in a three-stage game. In the first stage, the supplier announces the option contract parameters, po and pe. The customers simultaneously decide the number of options, Oi, to buy based on their own types. We are interested in the equilibrium cases where Oi ðt ¼ lÞ ¼ 0 and Oi ðt ¼ hÞ > 0. With our assumptions on the customer demand, the high type customers have actually two choices: whether to buy Oi ¼ DL for a minimal hedge or to buy Oi ¼ DH for a maximal hedge. The minimum hedge strategy, buying DL units of options, guarantees the customers to execute at least the minimal demand level, when capacity is tight. In our setup, the customers’ demand equals to DL with probability 1 a. When a is small, the customer may consider minimum hedging because the chance of its demand exceeds DL is small. However, the customers also have to consider the real chance when the option is executed. For example, when a is small, the other customers’ demand is also unlikely to be high, so the possibility that the capacity is tight is also very low. Therefore, the customers may not have a strong incentive to choose minimum hedge strategy. Maximum hedge strategy guarantees the customers’ ability to execute all the future realized demand. However, the customers may not need to use all of the options purchased. The option price must be properly set by the supplier to induce the high type customers purchase options with an appropriate hedge strategy. The supplier also need to calculate which customer hedge strategy is the most profitable to him. If the option price is set properly and only the high type customers will purchase them, then the supplier can observe (t1, t2) through the sale of the options and decide the capacity level, K(t1, t2), to maximize his expected profit in the following period, Ep(K). After the demand is realized, the customers simultaneously decide how much demand to submit to the supplier, denoted as Dsi , and how much of Dsi is submitted as option demand, Doi . When the regular price p ¼ vl, Dsi ¼ Di hold for both types of customers. The supplier gathers the total demand (Do, Ds) and decides how to allocate the constrained capacity with the priority of the option demand. Assume that the supplier executes Dei amount of demand from the customers, then if Dei > Doi , the additional demand Dei Doi will be executed as the regular demand at a unit price p ¼ vl. If Dei < Doi , the supplier did not satisfy all the option demand,
202
F. Fang and A. Whinston
and therefore has to buy back the additional option demand Doi Dei at the option buy back price pb ¼ vh pe. The total charge to a customer will be mi ¼ po Oi þ pe Doi þ vl ðDei Doi Þþ vh ðDoi Dei Þþ ; where the last term is the customer’s expected compensation if the option demand is not executed. For the low type customers, since they won’t buy any option in equilibrium, we can simplify the total charge by substituting condition Oi ¼ Doi ¼ 0 and obtain mi ðt ¼ lÞ ¼ vl Dei . The customer’s overall utility: ui ¼
ðvh pe ÞDoi þ ðvh vl ÞðDei Doi Þþ po Oi 0
if t ¼ h if t ¼ l
In the following Sects. 4.3.1–4.3.3, we use backward induction to solve the three-stage game.
4.3.1
The Consumption Period
In period 3, each customer observes her own demand, which could be either DH or DL . After observing the aggregate demand, D, and the capacity, K, the two customers simultaneously decide how many options to execute. Denote O ¼ ðO1 ; O2 Þ. There are six configurations that need to be discussed: O ¼ ðDH ; DH Þ; ðDH ; 0Þ; ðDL ; 0Þ; ðDL ; DL Þ; (0,0) and (DH ; DL Þ. Due to symmetry, we do not need to analyze the cases of (DL, DH), (0, DH) and (0, DL). On the equilibrium path, only the high type customers will buy options. Therefore, supplier will infer that both customers are of high type when O equals (DH, DH), (DL, DL), or (DH, DL). Configurations (DH, 0) and (DL, 0) indicate that only one customer is high type, and configuration (0, 0) indicates both customers are of low type. For the low type customers, it is straightforward that Doi ¼ 0 since they don’t have any options. For the high types, Doi is decided based on the following optimization problem: max
Doi b minfOi ;Di g
ðvh pe ÞDoi þ ðvh vl ÞðDi Doi Þ f
ðK Doi Doi Þþ s:t: f ¼ min 1; D Doi Doi
where Doi is the option demand submitted by the other customer. Doi ¼ 0 if that other customer is of low type. f indicates the probability that regular demand is satisfied. When D < K, there is no congestion and all the demand will be satisfied, f ¼ 1. When Do > K, the option demand along will exceeds the capacity. The supplier does not have additional capacity to serve the regular demand and hence f ¼ 0.
Capacity Management and Price Discrimination under Demand Uncertainty
203
Lemma 2. Denoting D o as the solution set of the above optimization problem, we have Do f0; minfDi ; Oi gg. Lemma 2 suggests that a high type customer will either execute all the options she has purchased up to her realized demand or not execute the options at all, depending on the option execute price pe. As pe increases, the customer pays more on executing the options and hence is increasingly reluctant to do so. Tables 1–6 show the solutions of Doi as functions of the six different realizations of O, respectively. In each table, Doi also varies according to different values of the realized demand D, the option exercise price pe and the available capacity K. From the results summarized in Tables 1–6, we can observe that the amount of options a high type customer will execute decreases as the option execution price pe increases. When pe rvh ðvh vl Þ2DKH , no option contracts will be executed in any possible configuration of O and the demand realization D. This is because that the options are too expensive to execute. Therefore, the options have no value. We can then conclude that the supplier will never charge such an option execution price. In the following discussion, we focus on the cases where the execution price pe < vh ðvh vl ÞDKH when the option contracts will possibly be executed.
Table 1 Option demand when O ¼ ðDH ; DH Þ O ¼ ðDH ; DH Þ
vh ðvh vl Þ minf2DKH ; 1g < pe bvh vh ðvh vl Þ minfDH KþDL ; 1g < pe bvh ðvh vl Þ minf2DKH ; 1g h K v ðvh vl Þ minf2D L ; 1g < h h l pe bv ðv v Þ minfDH KþDL ; 1g K pe bvh ðvh vl Þ minf2D L ; 1g
Table 2 Option demand when O ¼ ðDH ; DL Þ O ¼ ðDH ; DL Þ vh ðvh vl Þ minf2DKH ; 1g < pe bvh vh ðvh vl Þ minfDH KþDL ; 1g < pe bvh ðvh vl Þ minf2DKH ; 1g K vh ðvh vl Þ minf2D L ; 1g < pe bvh ðvh vl Þ minfDH KþDL ; 1g K vl < pe bvh ðvh vl Þ minf2D L ; 1g
p e b vl
D ¼ ðDH ; DH Þ Do1 ¼ 0 Do2 ¼ 0 Do1 ¼ DH Do2 ¼ DH Do1 ¼ DH Do2 ¼ DH Do1 ¼ DH Do2 ¼ DH
(DH,DL)
D ¼ ðDH ; DH Þ Do1 ¼ 0 Do2 ¼ 0 Do1 ¼ DH Do2 ¼ 0
(DH,DL)
Do1 ¼ DH Do2 ¼ 0 Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
¼ DH ¼0 ¼ DH ¼ DL
Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼ DH ¼ DL ¼ DH ¼ DL
(DL,DH) Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0
¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0
Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
¼ DH ¼ DL ¼ DH ¼ DL ¼ DH ¼ DL
Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0
¼ DL ¼ DH ¼ DL Do1 ¼ DL ¼ DH Do2 ¼ DL
(DL,DH)
Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
(DL,DL)
Do1 ¼ DL Do2 ¼ 0
Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0
¼ DL ¼0 ¼ DL ¼ DL
Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
¼ DL ¼0 ¼ DL ¼ DL
Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0
(DL,DL)
204
F. Fang and A. Whinston
Table 3 Option demand when O ¼ ðDH ; 0Þ O ¼ ðDH ; 0Þ v ðv v h
h
l
Þ minf2DKH ; 1g < pe
bv
D ¼ ðDH ; DH Þ Do1 ¼ 0 Do2 ¼ 0 Do1 ¼ DH Do2 ¼ 0
h
vh ðvh vl Þ minfDH KþDL ; 1g < pe bvh ðvh vl Þ minf2DKH ; 1g l v < pe bvh ðvh vl Þ minfDH KþDL ; 1g
Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
p e b vl
Table 4 Option demand when O ¼ ðDL ; DL Þ O ¼ ðDL ; DL Þ D Þ h vh ðvh vl Þ minfDKþ2ðD H þ2ðD H DL Þ; 1g < pe bv H
L
vh ðvh vl Þ minfDH KþDL ; 1g <
D Þ pe bvh ðvh vl Þ minfDKþ2ðD H þ2ðDH DL Þ; 1g H
L
vl < pe bvh ðvh vl Þ minfDH KþDL ; 1g
Table 5 Option demand when O ¼ ðDL ; 0Þ O ¼ ðDL ; 0Þ 1
vh ðvh vl Þ minf2
KDL D2L þDH DL DL ð2DH DL Þ ; 1g < pe
bvh
vh ðvh vl Þ minfDH KþDL ; 1g <
1 KDL D2 þDH DL
pe bvh ðvh vl Þ minf2 DL ð2DHL DL Þ ; 1g þD D D vh ðvh vl Þ minfKD ðD H þDL ÞDH L
b b
H
H
L
DL
; 1g <
pe v ðv v Þ minfDH KþDL ; 1g L þDH DH DL DL ; 1g vl < pe vh ðvh vl Þ minfKD ðD H þDL ÞDH h
h
l
p e b vl
Table 6 Optimal demand when O ¼ ð0; 0Þ O ¼ ð0; 0Þ D ¼ ðDH ; DH Þ For all pe bvl
Do1 ¼ 0 Do2 ¼ 0
D ¼ ðDH ; DH Þ Do1 ¼ 0 Do2 ¼ 0 Do1 ¼ DL Do2 ¼ DL Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
p e b vl
¼ DH ¼0 ¼ DH ¼0
¼ DL ¼ DL ¼ DL ¼ DL
(DH,DL) Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼ DH ¼0 ¼ DH ¼0
(DH,DL) Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
¼ DL ¼0 ¼ DL ¼0
(DL,DH)
Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼ DL ¼0
(DL,DL)
¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0
Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0
¼ DL ¼ DL ¼ DL ¼ DL
Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
¼ DL ¼ DL ¼ DL ¼ DL
Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
¼0 ¼0 ¼ DL ¼ DL
(DH,DL)
Do1 ¼ DL Do2 ¼ 0
Do1 ¼ 0 Do2 ¼ 0 Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0
(DL,DL)
¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0
Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
¼ DL ¼0 ¼ DL ¼0
Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
D ¼ ðDH ; DH Þ Do1 ¼ 0 Do2 ¼ 0 Do1 ¼ DL Do2 ¼ 0
Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
(DL,DH)
¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0
¼ DL ¼0 ¼ DL ¼0
(DL,DH) Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0
(DL,DL) Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
¼0 ¼0 ¼0 ¼0
Do1 ¼ DL Do1 ¼ 0 Do2 ¼ 0 Do2 ¼ 0 Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
¼ DL ¼0 ¼ DL ¼0
Do1 Do2 Do1 Do2
¼ DL ¼0 ¼ DL ¼0
(DH,DL)
(DL,DH)
(DL,DL)
Do1 ¼ 0 Do2 ¼ 0
Do1 ¼ 0 Do2 ¼ 0
Do1 ¼ 0 Do2 ¼ 0
Capacity Management and Price Discrimination under Demand Uncertainty
4.3.2
205
Capacity Investment Game
In the above subsection, we have determined both customers’ equilibrium decisions on Doi . This decision is contingent on the number of options both customers have purchased O, the realized demand D, the option strike price pe, and the capacity K. This subsection will analyze the supplier’s optimal capacity decision K*, which is made before the actual demand is realized. As stated previously, the optimal capacity decision K* depends on the supplier’s observation of option purchase by the customers O and the option execution price pe. Based on such information, the supplier shall expect the possible future demand realization D and the customers’ reaction of Doi , i ¼ 1,2. Once the customers have purchased the options, the supplier will only look at the future revenue excluding the revenue from option purchase, po(O1 + O2), to decide the optimal capacity. When K* increases, the chance of congestion decreases. The supplier’s revenue comes more from serving the regular demand. When pe < vl, the supplier has an incentive to prepare enough capacity to avoid the possible customers option demand. However, if pe > vl, the supplier tends to induce the customers into exercising their options by restricting the capacity K. However, restricting capacity may create problems when K < Do because the supplier fails to execute the option demand as he has promised in the option contract. He must compensate those customers whose option demands cannot be executed. The supplier’s capacity decision is to figure out an optimal level of capacity to trade off among the revenue, capacity investment cost, and the possible compensation. Customers are more willing to execute their options as pe decreases. Foreseeing this, the supplier tends to increase the capacity level to guarantee that all the option demand be satisfied. This will minimize the expected compensation. Hence, we predict capacity K* decreases as pe increases. Proposition 3. In a subgame perfect equilibrium, the supplier’s optimal capacity decision is as follows: 1. When O ¼ ðDH ; DH Þ, the optimal capacity 8 L L > if vh ðvh vl ÞDDH < pe bvh < 2D h H L h h l DL e K ¼ vvhp 2DH if vh ðvh vl ÞD2DþD H < pe bv ðv v ÞDH vl > H L : H D þ DL if pe bvh ðvh vl ÞD2DþD H 2. When O ¼ ðDH ; DL Þ, the optimal capacity
K ¼
8 L > < 2D
v pe H þ DL Þ h l ðD > : v v DH þ DL h
if vh ðvh vl ÞDH2DþDL < pe bvh L
if vl < pe bvh ðvh vl ÞDH2DþDL if pe bvl L
3. When O 2 fðDL ; DL Þ; ðDH ; 0Þ; ðDL ; 0Þ; ð0; 0Þg, the optimal capacity K* ¼ 2DL for all pe < vh.
206
F. Fang and A. Whinston K*
DH+DL
K*(D H,D H) K*(DH,D L)
2DL
K*(DL,DL),K*(DH,0),K*(DL,0), and K*(0,0)
h
h
l
L
H
L
v −(v −v )2D /(D +D )
vl
h
h
l
L
H
v −(v −v )D /D h
h
l
H
L
v −(v −v )(D +D )/2D
H
pe
Fig. 2 Optimal capacity levels
Figure 2 summarizes the optimal capacity level K* as a function of pe in all six configurations of O. The capacity is at least the minimal level of the aggregate demand 2DL. It is greater than 2DL only when both customers have purchased the options and at least one of them bought DH units of options. In all other cases, we have O1 + O2 < 2DL and hence the total number of options demand, which is smaller than the total number of options purchased, must be smaller than 2DL. As a result, the supplier will remain unconcerned about the compensation even when he sets the capacity K ¼ 2DL. However, when both customers have purchased options and at least one bought DH units, the supplier has to worry about the possibility that both customers execute all their options and the capacity may be insufficient for satisfying the aggregate option demand. If he stays with the capacity level K ¼ 2DL, the probability of providing compensation will be as high as 2a a2 when pe is low enough. So our assumption that (2a a2)vh > c0 suggests that the supplier should increase the capacity from 2DL to avoid the situation. The assumption that a2vh < c0 suggests that the supplier cannot be better off by increasing the capacity from DH + DL to avoid the possible compensation when D ¼ ðDH ; DH Þ. The optimal capacity is between 2DL and DH + DL.
Capacity Management and Price Discrimination under Demand Uncertainty
4.3.3
207
Optimal Option Prices
Given the optimal decisions of K* and ðDo1 ; Do2 Þ, we can now analyze the first stage of the option-capacity game to derive the optimal option prices (po, pe) and the supplier’s expected profit by using the option contracts. All the decisions analyzed in Sects. 4.3.1 and 4.3.2 are contingent on both the option execution price pe and the customer’s option purchase O. In addition, the customers decide O based on their own types (t1, t2) and how the supplier prices the options. The fundamental question to be addressed is: what is the optimal po and pe that induces the customer to purchase the right number of options and maximizes the supplier’s profit? In this period, the supplier announces the option prices (po, pe). Then the customers submit their option purchase demand Oi to the supplier simultaneously. In order to detect the customer types, the supplier will price the options so that the low type customers will not purchase but the high type customers will. The customers’ valuation of the option contracts is different when the other customer’s option purchase demand, Oi, varies. If we denote the expected value of a unit of option contract as fo(Oi, Oi, pe), then the value of fo can be calculated as follows: fo ðOi ; Oi ; pe Þ ¼
1 h Eui ðOi ; Oi ; pe Þ Euhi ð0; Oi ; pe Þ Oi
where Euhi ðOi ; Oi ; pe Þ represents the expected utility a high type customer gets after purchasing Oi units of options while the other customer has purchased Oi units of options. Lemma 3. fo ðOi ; DH ; pe Þrfo ðOi ; DL ; pe Þrfo ðOi ; 0; pe Þ: Lemma 3 demonstrates an important result that is useful in proving the following Propositions. The lemma mathematically proves the fact that the options contract is more valuable to a high type customer if the other customer also buys more. This is so because the two customers will compete for the limited capacity resource in the consumption period. Buying more options protects them in the competition. Consequently, if the supplier can induce one customer to buy DH units of options, the other customer would want to pay more for the options if she is also a high type. This implies that the supplier prefers to induce the subgame equilibrium where the high type customers choose the maximal hedge strategy. Based on this conclusion, the following Proposition 4 gives the optimal option price and execution price (po, pe). Proposition 4. The supplier maximizes his expected profit when setting pe 2 vl ; H L H H H vh ðvh vl ÞD2DþD H Þ and po ¼ lfo ðD ; D Þ þ ð1 lÞfo ðD ; 0Þ. In such an equilibrium, a high type customer will choose a maximal hedging strategy by purchasing Oi ¼ DH units of options. The expected supplier profit will be EP ¼ ðvl c0 Þ2DL þ 2alðvh vl ÞðDH DL Þ þ l2 ð2a a2 Þvh c0 ðDH DL Þ
208
F. Fang and A. Whinston
and the equilibrium capacity investment K ¼
D H þ DL 2DL
if O1 ¼ O2 ¼ DH otherwise:
The supplier’s capacity investment K* is the same as the one in the full information benchmark case (see Sect. 4.2) given the belief that Oi ðt ¼ hÞ ¼ DH and Oi ðt ¼ lÞ ¼ 0. By using option contracts, the supplier can make a contingent capacity investment based on the customer’s option purchase decision O, which reveals the customer types (t1, t2) in equilibrium. This flexibility improves the capacity investment decision. The option compensation pb ¼ vh pe is important in achieving the efficient capacity level K* ¼ KFI. Under the options framework, the supplier’s incentive to increase the capacity when both customers are of high type is to satisfy as many options as possible while reducing the compensation. That is, the marginal benefit the supplier gets is pe + pb ¼ vh when K < Do. This incentive is well-aligned with the full information benchmark case where the incentive of increasing capacity is to increase the ability of serving high type demand, which yields a marginal profit pFI(t ¼ h) ¼ vh. We can rewrite the supplier’s expected profit as: EP ¼ EPND þ D1 þ D3 þ D4 where EPND is the supplier’s expected profit in the first benchmark. D1 and D3 are defined in Proposition 2. D1 represents the gain from prioritizing the high type customer’s demand over the low type one’s. D3 refers to the gain achieved when the supplier increases capacity after observing two high type customers. D4 ¼ 2al2 (vh vl)(DH DL) > 0. a(vh vl)(DH DL) is the expected loss a high type customer suffers if she doesn’t buy options but competing for capacity with another high type customer who has options. D4 is 2l2 times this expected loss representing the supplier’s expected gain from the competition between two high type customers. Comparing the supplier’s expected profit using the option contracts, EP*, to the supplier’s expected profit in the full information benchmark, EPFI, we can characterize the supplier’s profit loss when he cannot distinguish the high type customer and extract full surplus from them as follows: EPFI EP ¼ D2 D4 ¼ 2l lEuhi ð0; DH Þ þ ð1 lÞEuhi ð0; 0Þ
lEuhi ð0; DH Þ þ ð1 lÞEuhi ð0; 0Þ is the reserve utility a high type customer has when she does not buy options. This reserve utility is also known as the “Information Rent” in the price discrimination literature, (Mas-Colell et al. 1995) representing the cost the supplier pays to induce a high type customer to reveal her type. The expected information rent the supplier pays is exactly D2 D4, which increases as the probability that a customer being high type, l, increases.
Capacity Management and Price Discrimination under Demand Uncertainty
209
Proposition 5. W* ¼ WFI. The capacity investment is efficient in equilibrium and high type customers will always be served as the first priority. Hence, it is not surprising that the option contracts can achieve the same efficiency level as the full information benchmark case. Proposition 5 justifies the optimality of our proposed options contract framework.
5 Discussion and Extensions 5.1
Using Options for Price Discrimination
In the literature of price discrimination with unobservable types, the supplier’s ability to employ a non-linear pricing scheme (e.g. quantity discount and bundling) is critical to his profit. In this paper, we show that with properly priced options, the supplier can achieve the same profit level with a simple linear pricing function using an option framework. Particularly, our framework works when the customer’s demand is uncertain. In our framework, a customer faces two purchase decisions. She chooses the number of options to purchase before the demand realization and the amount of demand (including the numbers of regular demand and option demand) to request afterwards. In both decisions, she has full flexibility to choose the quantities. A linear pricing scheme is applied in all the purchases. The customers prefer such flexibility when they suffer from demand uncertainty. To discriminate the customers, we pay our attention to the case where only high type customers will buy the options. A high type customer’s total charge in equilibrium can be divided into two parts. A fixed payment poDH is charged ex ante regardless of her actual demand realization D to guarantee the priority of their demand execution. In addition, she pays a contingent payment based on her actual demand realization. Adjusting the option price po and pe, the supplier essentially changes the ratio between the ex ante and ex post payments to affect the high type customers hedging incentive and exploit their willingness to pay for the demand. The option framework helps the supplier to conduct price discrimination when the customer’s demand is uncertain. When there is no demand uncertainty (i.e., DH ¼ DL), the capacity will always be enough for the aggregate demand under our assumption. Hence, the option has no value and the supplier cannot discriminate among the customers. Our assumption of the supplier’s marginal capacity cost is critical to derive the result. The discrimination framework is built based on the high type customer’s concern of potential demand loss. If the capacity cost is small, the customers can infer that the supplier will always build enough capacity for the demand and won’t pay money ex ante to hedge the potential demand loss. The discrimination is not implementable in this case. If the capacity cost is large, the supplier will find it
210
F. Fang and A. Whinston
profitable to charge a high regular price (e.g. vh) to exploit the high type customers’ surplus only.
5.2
Multiple Agents and Multiple Types
In this paper, we use a parsimonious model with one supplier and two customers to illustrate price discrimination. The model can be extended to a case where multiple customers with two possible types. In such a model, we could still design the option contracts so that only those high type customers will buy them. The major difference would be a more complicated aggregate demand pattern. In a symmetric equilibrium where all high type customers adopt the same strategy, the supplier can separate the customers into two groups and treat them as two representative agents. The same analysis can then be applied to figure out the optimal option contract. The efficiency level of the second degree price discrimination still holds. The model gets further complicated when customers are of multiple types. In that case, the supplier could design multiple option contracts with different combinations of strike prices pe and compensation pb for each type. The customers could then self-select the options and decide when to exercise them. The demand should then be prioritized according to the supplier’s marginal punishment of not fulfilling the demand (i.e. pb pe). As a result, different demand associated with different option contracts are categorized into different priority levels. Allocation efficiency can be achieved if the customers with higher willingness to pay will always buy the option contracts with higher priority (characterized by pb pe). The challenge is how to price the options to induce the customers to purchase the right options to reveal their types.
5.3
Spot Exchange Options Market
In our setup, customers purchase options to hedge their demand risk. After their demand is realized, they can decide how many of their options to exercise. In this setup, a customer cannot buy additional options from other customer ex post. This raises a question: what if they can exchange their options after observing their demand? On the one hand, an option exchange leads to more efficient option utilization. If a customer is able to sell her extra options after the demand is realized, she is more willing to buy the options ex ante. Thus, the ex post exchange encourages the option purchase ex ante. On the other hand, the customers’ incentive for a maximal hedge decreases with the possibility of option exchange. This is because she may find someone who will sell options to her if her demand is high. Between this conflicting incentives, it is not clear which incentive is stronger in general. However, if we assume that customer types may change ex post, then the existence of an option exchange market helps in some cases. A detailed analysis
Capacity Management and Price Discrimination under Demand Uncertainty
211
of when a spot exchange market helps increase a monopolist’s profit can be found in Geng et al. (2007). Moreover, ex post exchange reduces the customer’s ex post risk of purchasing options. Hence, the existence of an ex post exchange market always improves the option purchase incentive if the customers are risk-averse.
6 Conclusion In this paper, we propose using a form of options contract framework that allows a monopolistic supplier to conduct price discrimination among customers, thereby maximizing his expected revenue under demand uncertainty and a capacity constraint. Our analysis shows that option contracts can benefit the supplier because the high type customers will pay more for hedging potential demand loss. The supplier gains the additional benefit of being able to adjust capacity according to his observation of customer types. We also analyze the strategic interactions among the supplier and customers. We show that, in equilibrium, the efficient capacity level can be induced by setting a compensation price which leaves the high type customers indifferent about whether to exercise their options or to ask for compensation. Overall efficiency is guaranteed and the supplier and the high type customers share the efficiency gain from the efficient capacity investment. Our proposed structure replicates the classical price discrimination outcome where the low type customers do not gain surplus and the high type customers enjoy an information rent. Our proposed structure can easily be adopted in situations where the supplier is not allowed to sell a bundled product with fixed quantity and situations where the actual demand and capacity is not contractible. Our framework has significant revenue management implications for various industrial applications such as network capacity management, airline ticket reservation, and telephone and electricity providers.
Appendix 1: Notation Table i Di D D Dsi Ds Dei De De
Customer index The realized demand of customer i. Di ∈ {DH, DL} D ¼ D1 + D2 the aggregate demand D ¼ ðD1 ; D2 Þ is the demand vector of both customers The demand customer i submits to the supplier Ds ¼ ðDs1 ; Ds2 Þ is the vector of customers’ submitted demand The demand of customer i, being satisfied by the supplier De ¼ De1 þ De2 is the aggregated demand satisfied by the supplier De ¼ ðDe1 ; De2 Þ is the vector of customers’ satisfied demand
212
F. Fang and A. Whinston
Doi Doi Do fo K mi Oi O p po pe pb ti ui vt a l P p
The amount of options executed by customer i when capacity is tight The amount of options executed by the customer other than i Do ¼ Do1 þ Do2 the aggregated option demand submitted by both customers The high type customer’s valuation of one unit of option contract The supplier’s capacity level The amount of monetary transfer made from customer i to the supplier The amount of option contracts customer i will purchase O ¼ ðO1 ; O2 Þ the vector of customers’ options purchase The unit price for the regular demand The option price The option execution price The option buy back price Type of customer i. ti ∈ {l,h} The utility customer i receives The marginal value of demand satisfaction for each type t The probability that a customer’s realized demand is high (Di ¼ DH) The probability that a customer is a high type one The supplier’s profit The supplier’s profit gained after period 1, excluding the sale from the option contracts The probability that regular demand is satisfied under the option framework
f
Appendix 2: Proof of Lemmas and Propositions Proof of Proposition 1. If p ⩽ vl, both customers submit all their demand to the supplier, Dsi
¼ Di ¼
DH DL
with prob ¼ a with prob ¼ 1 a:
The supplier’s expected profit: h i EP ¼ p a2 minfK;2DH gþ2að1aÞminfK;DH þDL Þþð1aÞ2 minfK;2DL g c0 K: Maximizing the profit under the condition p ⩽ vl, we have p* ¼ vl and K* ¼ 2DL. The supplier’s expected profit is EP(p ¼ vl) ¼ (vl c0)2DL. Customer i’s expected utility is ui ¼ (vi vl)DL. If p ∈ (vl, vh), only high type customers will submit the demand. Therefore, Dsi ¼ Di when ti ¼ h and Dsi ¼ 0 for ti ¼ l. When vl < p ⩽ vh, the supplier’s expected profit
Capacity Management and Price Discrimination under Demand Uncertainty
213
h i EPðpÞ ¼ l2 p a2 minfK;2DH gþ2að1agminfK;DH þDL gþð1aÞ2 minfK;2DL g
þ2lð1lÞp aminfK;DH gþð1aÞminfK;DL g c0 K qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi h 0 Maximizing the expected profit and applying the assumption l < 1 v vc h , we * h * * h have p ¼ v and K ¼ 0. Thereby, EP (p ¼ v ) ¼ 0 and it is not worthwhile to build capacity and serve high type customers only, due to the low probability of a high type customer’s existence. Compare the two cases, we conclude that the supplier’s best strategy is to set pND ¼ vl and serve both types of customers. The optimal capacity will be KND ¼ 2DL. The expected profit EPND ¼ (vl c0)2DL and the overall efficiency: ND W ND ¼ EPND þ lEuND i ðti ¼ hÞ þ ð1 lÞEui ðti ¼ lÞ
¼ lvh þ ð1 lÞvl c0 2DL :
□ FI
Proof of Lemma 1. The optimal capacity K is made contingent on the customer types T ¼ ðt1 ; t2 Þ. When T ¼ ðh; hÞ, the supplier’s expected profit h EPFI ðK;TÞ¼vh a2 minfK;2DH gþ2að1aÞminfK;DH þDL g i þð1aÞ2 minfK;2DL g c0 K which is maximized when K(h,h) ¼ DH + DL due to the assumption avh < c0 < (2a a2)vh. When T ¼ ðl; lÞ, similarly, we can have KFI(l,l) ¼ 2DL, since (2a a2) l v < c 0 < v l. When T ¼ ðh; lÞ or (l,h) and K > DH, the supplier’s expected profit EPFI ðK; ðh; lÞÞ ¼ a2 vh DH þ vl minfK DH ; DH g þ að1 aÞ vh DH þ vl minfK DH ; DL gÞ þ að1 aÞ vh DL þ vl minfK DL ; DH g þ ð1 aÞ2 vh DL þ vl minfK DL ; DL g c0 K which is maximized when K* ¼ 2DL. It can also be shown that K ⩽ DH cannot be optimal. Therefore, KFI(h,l) ¼ KFI(l,h) ¼ 2DL. □ Proof of Proposition 2. For the supplier, the probability that both customers are high types is l2. The expected profit EPðh; hÞ ¼ vl c0 2DL þ vh vl 2DL þ ð2a a2 Þvh c0 DH DL :
214
F. Fang and A. Whinston
With probability 2l(1 l), one customer is of high type and the other is of low type. The expected profit EP(h, l) ¼ (vl c0)2DL + (vh vl) (aDH + (1 a)DL). With probability (1 l)2, both customers are of low type. The expected profit EP (l,l) ¼ (vl c0)2DL. Since ui(t ¼ h) ¼ ui(t ¼ l) ¼ 0, W FI ¼ EPFI ¼ l2 EPðh; hÞ þ 2lð1 lÞEPðh; lÞ þ ð1 lÞ2 EPðl; lÞ ¼ ðvl c0 Þ2DL þ vh vl 2alð1 lÞ DH DL þ vh vl l2DL þ l2 ð2a a2 Þvh c0 DH DL compared to EPND ¼ (vl c0)2DL and WND ¼ (lvh + (1 l)vl c0)2DL, we can easily conclude that EPFI ¼ EPND þ D1 þ D2 þ D3 W FI ¼ W ND þ D1 þ D3 □ Proof of Lemma 2. The proof is straightforward since we can show that the second order condition of the above objective function is non-negative. It means that the objective function is a convex function. The optimal solution of the maximization □ problem would exist on the boundary. That is, it is either 0 or min{Oi, Di}. Proof of Proposition 3. In this stage, the supplier determines the capacity level to maximize his future revenue less the capacity investment. That is, pðO; D; K; pe Þ ¼ m1 þ m2 po ðO1 þ O2 Þ c0 K ¼ pe Do ðO; D; K; pe Þ þ vl ðminðK; DÞ Do ðO; D; K; pe ÞÞþ vh ðDo ðO; D; K; pe Þ KÞþ c0 K Applying the outcomes from Tables 1–6, we can derive the profit function with parameters O; D; K, and pe. Taking expectation over the realized demand D, we obtain the expected profit function for each O; pe , and K. Maximizing those the expected profit function by choosing K, we can obtain the optimal capacity as stated □ in Proposition 3 as a function of O and option strike price pe. Proof of Lemma 3. From the result of 1. When pe rvh ðvh vl ÞDDH , optimal capacity K* ¼ 2DL for all the possible configurations of O. No options will be exercised for all possible realization of D. Therefore, the option has no value. In other words, fo ðOi ; DH ; pe Þ ¼ fo ðOi ; DL ; pe Þ ¼ fo ðOi ; 0; pe Þ ¼ 0 H h h l DL 2. When vh ðvh vl Þ2DD H DL bpe < v ðv v ÞDH , if the customer has bought Oi ¼ DL, she will never exercise the options no matter what type the other customer is. Therefore, at the first stage, the value of the options contract would be 0 and the customer should not purchase any options with a positive price L
Capacity Management and Price Discrimination under Demand Uncertainty
215
3. When vh ðvh vl ÞDH2DþDL bpe < vh ðvh vl Þ2DD H DL : if the customer has bought Oi ¼ DL units of options, she will only exercise it when D ¼ ðDH ; DH Þ and Doi 6¼ DH . Hence if the other customer is of high type, she is always better off if the other customer has purchased Oi ¼ DH rather than Oi ¼ DL units of options. However, given Oi ¼ DH, customer i will never exercise her options and the value of the options is 0. If the other customer is of low type, the customer’s expected utility from exercising the options are L
H
(a) Oi ¼ DH : ui ðDH Þ ¼ a2 ðvh pe ÞDH þ ð1 a2 ÞDL po DH L H 2 L L (b) Oi ¼ DL : ui ðDL Þ ¼ a2 ðvh pe ÞDL þ ðvh vl Þ2DDH D DL þ ð1 a ÞD po D h l L (c) Oi ¼ 0 : ui ð0Þ ¼ ðv v ÞD Þui ð0Þþpo D D From the results above, we can show that uuiiðD ðDH Þui ð0Þþpo DL > DL , meaning that the customer is better off by purchasing Oi ¼ DH units of options. Following the same calculation, we can show that DL is not the optimal choice when pe > vl. □ H
H
H
Proof of Proposition 4. We need to discuss the profit according to the different pe segments: 1. When pe r vh ðvh vl Þ DDH , no options will be exercised, po ¼ 0 and EP ¼ (vl c0)2DL H L h h l DL 2. When vh ðvh vl ÞD2DþD we have K ðDH ; DH Þ ¼ H bpe < v ðv v ÞDH , vh pe 2DH from Proposition 3. The supplier’s profit vh vl L
EP ¼ Ep þ 2lpo DH
vh pe H 2 2 l 2 l L ¼ l ð2a a Þv c0 h 2D þ ð1 a Þv 2D v vl
þ 2lð1 lÞ a2 ðpe vl ÞDH þ ðvl c0 Þ2DL þ ð1 lÞ2 ðvl c0 Þ2DL
þ 2l Euhi ðDH Þ Euhi ð0Þ which we can show dEP dpe < 0. H L * H H 3. When vl bpe < vh ðvh vl ÞD2DþD H , we have optimal capacity K (D ,D ) ¼ H L * H * L D + D and K (D ,0) ¼ K (0,0) ¼ 2D from Proposition 3. One can get EP ¼ ðvl c0 Þ2DL þ 2alðvh vl ÞðDH DL Þ þ l2 ð2a a2 Þvh c0 ðDH DL Þ: In this case, dEP dpe ¼ 0. In summary, we can conclude that the optimal option exercise price pe should be H L □ vh ðvh vl ÞD2DþD H Proof of Proposition 5. The proof is straightforward from the proof of Proposition 4. □
216
F. Fang and A. Whinston
References Afeche P (2006) Incentive-compatible revenue management in queueing systems: optimal strategic delay and other delaying Tactics. Working paper, The Kellogg School of Management, Northwestern University, Evanston, IL Armstrong M, Vickers J (2001) Competitive price discrimination. Rand J Econ 32:1–27 Barnes-Schuster D, Bassok Y, Anupindi R (2002) Coordination and flexibility in supply contracts with options. Manuf Serv Options Manage 43:171–207 Birge JR (2000) Option methods for incorporating risk into linear capacity planning models. Manuf Serv Operation Manage 2:19–31 Boyaci T, Ray S (2006) The impact of capacity costs on product differentiation in delivery time, delivery reliability, and prices. Prod Oper Manage 15:179–198 Cachon GP, Fisher M (2000) Supply chain inventory management and the value of shared information. Manage Sci 46:1032–1048 Cachon GP, Lariviere MA (1999) An equilibrium analysis of linear, proportional and uniform allocation of scarce capacity. IIE Trans 31:835–849 Cachon GP, Lariviere MA (2001) Contracting to assure supply: how to share demand forecasts in a supply chain. Manage Sci 47:629–646 Cachon GP (2002) Supply coordination with contracts. In: Graves S, Kok T (eds) Handbooks in operations research and management science. North-Holland, Amsterdam Chen F (2003) Information sharing and supply chain coordination. In: Graves SC, De Kok AG (eds) Handbooks in operations research and management science: supply chain management design, coordination and operation. Elsevier, Amsterdam Corsetti G, Dedola L (2005) A macroeconomic model of international price discrimination. J Int Econ 67:129–155 Deshpande V, Schwartz L (2002) Optimal capacity choice and allocation in decentralized supply chains. Technical report, Krannert School of Management, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN Geng X, Wu R, Whinston AB (2007) Profiting from partial allowance of ticket resale. J Mark 71:184–195 Guo Z, Fang F, Whinston AB (2006) Supply chain information sharing in a macro prediction market. Decis Support Syst 42:1944–1958 Gupta A, Stahl DO, Whinston AB (1996) An economic approach to network computing with priority classes. J Organ Comput Electron Commer 6:71–95 Gupta A, Stahl DO, Whinston AB (1999) The economics of network management. Commun ACM 42:57–63 Huchzermeier A, Cohen MA (1996) Valuing operational flexibility under exchange rate risk. Oper Res 44:100–113 Iyer AV, Deshpande V, Wu Z (2003) A postponement model for demand management. Manage Sci 49:983–1002 Kleindorfer PR, Wu DJ (2003) Integrating long-and-short term contracting via business-to-business exchanges for capacity intensive industries. Manage Sci 49:1597–1615 Lariviere M (1999) Supply chain contracting and coordination with stochastic demand. In: Tayur S, Ganeshan R, Magazine M (eds) Quantitative models for supply chain management. Kluwer, Boston Li L (2002) Information sharing in a supply chain with horizontal competition. Manage Sci 48:1196–1212 Lin L, Kulatilaka N (2007) Strategic Growth Options in Network Industries. In: Silverman B (eds) Advances in Strategic Management. Emerald Group Publishing Limited., pp. 177–198 Martı´nez-de-Albe´niz V, Simchi-Levi D (2005) A portfolio approach to procurement contracts. Prod Options Manage 14:90–114 Mas-Colell A, Whinston MD, Green JR (1995) Microeconomic theory. Oxford University Press, USA
Capacity Management and Price Discrimination under Demand Uncertainty
217
Maskin E, Riley J (1984) Monopoly under incomplete information. Rand J Econ 15:171–196 Mortimer JH (2007) Price discrimination, copyright law, and technological innovation: evidence from the introduction of DVDs. Q J Econ 122:1307–1350 Noldeke G, Schmidt KM (1995) Option contracts and renegotiation: a solution to the hold-up problem. Rand J Econ 26:163–179 ¨ zer O, Wei W (2004) Inventory control with limited capacity and advance demand information. O Oper Res 52:988–1000 Sethi SP, Yan H, Zhang H (2004) Quantity flexible contracts in supply chains with information updates and service-level constraints. Decis Sci 35:691–712 Sodhi M (2004) Managing demand risk in tactical supply chain planning. Prod Oper Manage 14(1):69–79 Tirole J (1988) The theory of industrial organization. MIT, Cambridge, MA Varian HR (1985) Price discrimination and social welfare. Am Econ Rev 75:870–875
.
Dynamic Procurement, Quantity Discounts, and Supply Chain Efficiency Feryal Erhun, Pinar Keskinocak, and Sridhar Tayur
Abstract We study a model with a single supplier and a single buyer who interact multiple times before the buyer sells her product in the end-consumer market. We show that when the supplier uses a wholesale price contract, even under perfect foresight, the supplier, the buyer, and the end-consumers benefit from multiple trading opportunities versus a one-shot procurement agreement. Keywords Advance capacity procurement • Incremental discounts • Strategic interactions • Supply chain coordination
quantity
1 Introduction This chapter studies the benefits of trading more than once while procuring/selling capacity. Consider a simple model with one supplier and one buyer. The buyer produces a product by using the capacity she buys from an uncapacitated supplier. Before the buyer’s selling season begins, there are N periods in which the buyer can procure capacity. The supplier uses a simple wholesale price contract; he
A significant part of the materials in this invited chapter is from the following original article: Erhun F, Keskinocak P, Tayur S (2008) Dynamic procurement, quantity discounts, and supply chain efficiency. Prod Oper Manage 17(5):1–8. F. Erhun (*) Department of Management Science and Engineering, Stanford University, Stanford, CA, USA e-mail: [email protected] P. Keskinocak School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, GA, USA e-mail: [email protected] S. Tayur Tepper School of Business, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA, USA e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_9, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
219
220
F. Erhun et al.
charges a unit capacity price of wn in period n ¼ 1; . . . ; N, which he determines dynamically. Once the buyer procures the capacity, she can produce the product with no additional cost and sell it in an end-consumer market, where the market price of the product is determined by the market clearance assumption. Dynamic procurement, i.e., simple wholesale price contracts repeated over time (possibly with different prices), is a commonly observed practice in a vertical channel. The typical justification for multiple procurement trades is risk hedging. In order to manage the demand risk, a buyer may prefer to procure capacity dynamically over time after receiving some update on demand. Other commonly observed reasons for dynamic procurement include spreading payments over a period of time, minimizing potential capacity risks (supplier’s or buyer’s), supplier’s decreasing cost over time which may translate to lower prices (e.g., as in the electronics industry), and forward buying. We discuss yet another potential impact of dynamic procurement, i.e., as a tool to influence future prices. In a vertical setting, we show that risk hedging is not the only justification for multiple trades. We derive a Pareto improving rationale for the use of additional trading periods in the case of deterministic demand (i.e., when the commonly known and intuitive benefits due to risk hedging are not present) and wholesale price contracts, where all participants (supplier, buyer, and end-consumers) benefit. The additional trading periods inherently create the equivalent of a non-linear pricing scheme, which makes the performance of the decentralized supply chain approach that of a centralized supply chain when the number of trading periods is sufficiently high.
2 Literature Review The paper that is closest to our work is by Allaz and Vila (1993). The authors study a deterministic model where two Cournot duopolists trade in forward markets for delivery in a single period. The authors conclude that even though producers are worse off by forward trading, in equilibrium they will trade forward. In the limit, as the number of forward markets goes to infinity, the competitive outcome is achieved in a duopoly setting. In our model, we look at vertical interactions, as opposed to the horizontal competition of Allaz and Vila. In a setting similar to ours, Anand et al. (2008) study a dynamic model of a procurement contract between a supplier and a buyer in a two-period, uncapacitated, deterministic demand game. The authors eliminate all the classical reasons for inventories, yet show that the buyer’s optimal strategy in equilibrium is to carry inventories, and the supplier is unable to prevent this. The inventories arise for “strategic” reasons. Keskinocak et al. (2003, 2008) extend Anand et al.’s model to limited capacity and limited capacity with backordering, respectively. Research on quantity discounts also relates to our problem. We refer readers to Benton and Park (1996) and Munson and Rosenblatt (1998) for extensive reviews, and to Dolan (1987) for a detailed survey of different variants of the quantity
Dynamic Procurement, Quantity Discounts, and Supply Chain Efficiency
221
discount problem from a marketing research standpoint. Jeuland and Shugan (1983) show that profit sharing mechanisms with quantity discounts can coordinate the supply chain. Following their work, many researchers study the role of quantity discounts as a channel coordination mechanism under different settings; e.g., Weng (1995) and Chen et al. (2001) combine channel coordination with price-sensitive demand and operating cost, Ingene and Parry (1995) introduce competing retailers, Raju and Zhang (2005) study channel coordination with a dominant retailer, and Chen and Roma (2010) consider a single manufacturer offering quantity discounts to competing retailers. Another stream of literature study quantity discounts to improve operational efficiency (Crowther 1964; Monahan 1984; Dada and Srikanth 1987). The dynamic procurement model that we study in this chapter falls in to this category by effectively creating an incremental quantity discount mechanism. Unlike the papers in the literature, the terms of trade are set by both the supplier and the buyer. Beside these two streams of literature that is closely related to our problem, there are three other streams that are related in spirit (1) timing of purchase commitments (2) two-period procurement and risk allocation, and (3) multi-period price and capacity adjustment. These streams consider multiple procurement opportunities in settings where the buyer can accrue additional demand information by postponing his procurement decision. The timing of purchase commitments has been the subject of many studies in the operations management literature. Iyer and Bergen (1997) study a supply chain with a single supplier and a single buyer to compare a traditional system, where the buyer places her order early on, to Quick Response (QR), where the buyer collects demand information before she places her order. The authors assume that the buyer pays the same wholesale price in either case and show that QR is not always Pareto improving. However, quantity discounts and volume commitments across products make QR Pareto improving. Ferguson (2003) and Ferguson et al. (2005) investigate an end-product buyer’s choice of when to commit to an order quantity when there is a demand information update during the supplier’s leadtime. The former paper assumes either all or none of the demand uncertainty is resolved, while the latter relaxes this assumption. The authors find that the buyer is not always better off delaying her quantity commitment and the supplier may prefer delayed commitment depending upon the amount of demand uncertainty resolved during the information update. Taylor (2006) studies a problem similar to the one in Ferguson (2003), however, he considers the sale timing of a supplier. The supplier may sell either early, i.e., well in advance of the selling season, or late, i.e., close to the selling season. Taylor shows that, in considerable generality, the supplier’s profit is greater when he sells late. In a duopolistic environment, Spencer and Brander (1992) identify conditions on demand variability under which the buyers would prefer to postpone their quantity decisions. Cvsa and Gilbert (2002) introduce a supplier to Spencer and Brander’s model and investigate how the supplier can influence the form of competition in the downstream market by offering a precommitment opportunity. In all of these papers, the buyer is limited to one mode of commitment (i.e., early or delayed). However, the buyer may prefer to use both
222
F. Erhun et al.
modes of commitment, which is the subject of the literature on two-period procurement and risk allocation. The literature on two-period procurement and risk allocation allows the buyer two purchasing opportunities: One is before and the other one is after demand realization. Gurnani and Tang (1999) analyze the trade-off between a more accurate demand information and a potentially higher procurement cost at the second period. Donohue (2000) studies a buy-back contract in a two-period setting where the procurement cost at the second period is higher and shows that this contract can coordinate the system. Cachon (2004) and Dong and Zhu (2007) study push (early commitment), pull (delayed commitment), and advance-purchase discount (purchase at a discounted price before the season and at a regular price during the selling season) to study how the inventory ownership impacts supply chain efficiency. Guo et al. (2009) study a three-tier supply chain with two outsourcing structures (delegation and control) to investigate how an OEM can use a two-wholesaleprice contract to increase the available upstream capacity. Erhun et al. (2008) and Li and Scheller-Wolf (2010) extend this literature to a vertical setting by considering the supplier’s pricing decisions as well. Erhun et al. study a capacitated two-tier supply chain and assume that the wholesale price is set by the supplier and the procurement quantity by the buyer. The authors investigate the impact of timing of the decisions and of additional demand information on the supplier’s pricing and the buyer’s procurement decisions. Li and Scheller-Wolf (2010) consider a supply chain composed of a buyer and multi-suppliers with private cost information. The buyer first offers a push or pull contract, and then selects the supplier through a wholesale price auction. The authors numerically find that a push system is more preferable by the buyer if the suppliers’ number is large and the demand level is high, while a pull system is more preferable if demand has high uncertainty and the suppliers’ cost is large. The literature on multi-period price and capacity adjustment seeks answers for when and how much to adjust the price or capacity or both in a dynamically changing environment. In particular, Burnetas and Gilbert (2001) consider a multi-period newsvendor model to study the trade-off between a more accurate demand information and increasing procurement costs. The authors numerically demonstrate that the broker tends to cluster his procurements just before price increases. Elmaghraby and Keskinocak (2003) and Van Mieghem (2003) provide a literature review on dynamic pricing and capacity investment and adjustment issues, respectively.
3 Main Model We study a model where there are N possible periods for capacity procurement before the buyer’s production/selling season begins. The supplier and the buyer maximize their profits. The supplier’s decisions are the wholesale prices for each period, wn, ðn ¼ 1; . . . ; N Þ. The buyer’s decisions are the procurement quantities
Dynamic Procurement, Quantity Discounts, and Supply Chain Efficiency
223
for each period, qn, ðn ¼ 1; . . . ; N Þ, and the production quantity, QN. (We set Q0 ¼ 0 and q0 ¼ 0.) The market is characterized by a linear inverse demand function P(QN) ¼ a bQN, where a is the market potential, b is the price sensitivity, P(QN) is the per-unit market price of the product for QN. We assume that the buyer’s unit cost of production is zero. However, the analysis of a positive, constant production cost (c < a) case is trivial. Since (a bQ)Q cQ ¼ ((a c) bQ)Q, we can simply modify the demand intercept a such that a^ ¼ a c, and the analysis follows. The sequence of events in each period n of the N-period gameis as follows (1) Given previous capacity procurements, qj ; j ¼ 1; . . . ; n 1 , the supplier price wn. (2) Given previous capacity procurements determines the capacity qj ; j ¼ 1; . . . ; n 1 and the current capacity price (wn), the buyer determines her procurement quantity qn. (3) In the last period N, the buyer chooses her production quantity QN and procures extra capacity, if necessary. The market clears only once at the end of the N-th period; i.e., there is only a single selling opportunity to end-consumers. We use backward induction and obtain the pure-strategy Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibrium (SPNE). Proposition 1 characterizes this equilibrium. Proposition 1. The unique pure-strategy SPNE for the N-period dynamic procurement model is the following. For n ¼ 1; . . . ; N 1, let n ¼ N n. Then, a a 2 nþ1 2 n 2 q1 ¼ qn ; wnþ1 ¼ wn ; ; w1 ¼ KN N ; qnþ1 ¼ 4Nb 2 2 n 2 nþ1 QN1 2kþ1 where K1 ¼ 1 and KN ¼ k¼1 The production 2kþ2. PN a a a . QN ¼ n¼1 qn ¼ 2b 4bKN . As N tends to infinity, QN tends to 2b
quantity
is
From Proposition 1, the production quantity for the N-period model is a a QN ¼ 2b 4b KN . As N increases, KN decreases, and the production quantity increases. Therefore, the double marginalization (DM) effect decreases, the efficiency increases and approaches that of the centralized solution. Similar to the argument of Allaz and Vila, a higher N does not necessarily imply that the capacity procurement is over a longer horizon, but rather that procurement occurs more frequently. Even though our model does not include a discount factor due to our interpretation of these N periods, the results of the main model are not sensitive to a discount factor. When we incorporate a discount factor d 1 to our analysis, ^n ¼ dNn wn , n ¼ 1; . . . ; N: The quantities maintain wholesale prices become w their original values. Figure 1 summarizes the prices and quantities in different periods a for the SPNE. 3a 5a The last period’s capacity price decreases & & & & 0 , while the first 2 8 16 9a 75a % % as N increases. The total period capacity price increases a2 % a 16 5a128 11a a production quantity, QN, increases 4b % 16b % 32b % % 2b ; and the market of the product (following the relationship P(QN) ¼ a bQN) decreases price 3a 11a 21a a . Even though the quantity in the first period decreases & & & & 4 16 32 2
224
F. Erhun et al.
n=1
1
a 2
2
9a 16
←⎯ ⎯⎯
3a 8
3
75a 128
←⎯ ⎯ ⎯ 5
15a 32
←⎯ ⎯ ⎯ 3
5a 16
4
1225a 2048
⎯ ←⎯ ⎯ 7
525a 1024
←⎯ ⎯⎯ ⎛ 5⎞
105a 256
…
…
Prices
N
n=2
n=4 …
n=3
n=1
Quantities n=3
n=2
n=4 …
a 8b
⎯⎯ → ⎯ 3
3a 16b
a 12b
⎯⎯ ⎯ → 5
5a ⎯⎯ ⎯→ ⎛×3 ⎞ ⎜ ⎟ 48b ⎝ 2⎠
5a 32b
a 16b
⎯⎯ ⎯ → 7
7a 96b
⎯⎯ ⎯ → 5
35a 384b
…
…
…
…
⎛× ⎞ ⎜ ⎟ ⎝ 6⎠
⎛× ⎞ ⎜ ⎟ ⎝ 4⎠
11a 32b ⎯⎯ ⎯ → 3 ⎛× ⎞ ⎜ ⎟ ⎝ 2⎠
35a 256
93a 256b …
⎛× ⎞ ⎜ ⎟ ⎝ 4⎠
5a 16b
…
⎛× ⎞ ⎜ ⎟ ⎝ 2⎠
…
35a 128
⎜× ⎟ ⎝ 2⎠
a 4b
…
←⎯ ⎯⎯ ⎛ 3⎞
…
⎜× ⎟ ⎝ 4⎠
…
⎛× ⎞ ⎜ ⎟ ⎝ 6⎠
⎛× ⎞ ⎜ ⎟ ⎝ 2⎠
…
⎛× ⎞ ⎜ ⎟ ⎝ 4⎠
…
⎛×3 ⎞ ⎜ ⎟ ⎝ 2⎠
…
a 4b
QN
Fig. 1 Capacity prices and quantities for different N values under dynamic procurement
100 90 80
% of Profits
70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0
1
3
DM Loss 25.00 9.77
5 6.06
7 4.39
9
11
13
15
17
19
3.44
2.83
2.40
2.09
1.85
1.65
Buyer
25.00 31.64 33.38 34.18 34.64 34.94 35.15 35.30 35.42 35.52
Supplier
50.00 58.59 60.56 61.43 61.92 62.23 62.45 62.61 62.73 62.83
Number of Periods, N
Fig. 2 The distribution of profits between the supplier, the buyer, and the double marginalization effect versus the number of periods (N)
a as N increases q1 ¼ 4Nb , the buyer procures capacity in each period. That is, trading occurs in all N periods. The buyer is willing to procure capacity at a given period (at a higher price) because she knows that by doing so the best response for the supplier is to lower the price in the subsequent periods. For a fixed N, the quantity that the buyer procures in each period increases and the capacity price decreases over time. As N increases, the double marginalization effect decreases and the supplier’s and the buyer’s profits both increase (see Fig. 2). Dynamic procurement not only increases the supply chain efficiency, but also naturally allocates the surplus to the supplier and the buyer such that both parties benefit. Independent of the values of a and b, the supplier’s profit converges to approximately 64% of the total profits, and the buyer’s profit converges to
Dynamic Procurement, Quantity Discounts, and Supply Chain Efficiency
225
approximately 36% of the total profits in the presence of additional capacity procurement periods. Even for small values of N, dynamic procurement decreases the inefficiency considerably. For example, for N ¼ 3, the inefficiency is already less than 10% (compared to 25% for N ¼ 1). In our analysis, we assume that N is exogenously determined, i.e., it is an input to the game. We show that as N increases, so do the profits of both players. Hence, the buyer and the supplier can jointly decide on an appropriate N value a priori, based on the marginal benefit of each additional trading period and the possible cost of each trade.
4 Extensions Our main result has two parts (1) as N increases, all participants (supplier, buyer, and end-consumers) strictly benefit and (2) as N goes to infinity, the performance of the decentralized supply chain approaches that of the centralized supply chain. However, we made several simplifying assumptions in our model. Hence we next discuss the implications of these assumptions on our main result and how they can be relaxed.
4.1
Limited Capacity
In this section, we consider the case where the supplier has a capacity of K units that he can sell throughout N periods. Let QN correspond to the total production quantity of an N-period uncapacitated game. For the N-period limited capacity a case, when the capacity is “tight,” i.e., CS b 4b , or when the capacity is “abundant”, i.e., CS ⩾ QN, the results are straightforward and intuitive. In the first case, as the capacity is tight, the supplier does not change his price through the game, so the N-period game is equivalent to a single-period game. When CS ⩾ QN, the problem is equivalent to an unlimited capacity game (Proposition 1). What happens in between these extremes is more interesting. Our main result is as follows. Proposition 2. The SPNE for the N-period capacitated model for CS < QN is as follows: Let N 2 f1; 2; ; Ng be such that QN 1
N X
qj ;
qN ¼
j¼NN þ2
wNN þ1 ¼
NY 1
i¼1
2i þ 1 wN ; 2i
wN ¼ 2
a 2b
a
CS ;
2 bCS ;
qNi ¼
2i qNiþ1 ; 2i þ 1
wNi ¼
2i þ 1 wNiþ1 : 2i
226
F. Erhun et al.
When CS < QN, depending on the capacity, the supplier and the buyer play an N*-period game (N* ⩽ N), the supplier sells all the capacity, and the supply chain is coordinated. Here, period N* corresponds to the smallest n (n 2 f1; 2; . . . ; Ng) for which the supplier’s capacity CS will not be enough for an n-period uncapacitated game. Contrary to the unlimited capacity case, increasing the number of trading periods beyond N* does not increase the profits of either player. The total profits for the buyer and the supplier can be maximized in a finite number of trading periods, N*, which depends on the capacity of the supplier.
4.2
Alternative Price-Sensitive Demand Functions
For most of the insights, we believe that the linear inverse demand function is not a critical assumption. When demand is price-sensitive, i.e., can be modeled by a downward-sloping demand curve, the intuition is as follows: When demand is price-sensitive, the purchasing power of each additional end-consumer is lower. Hence, if the buyer can reduce her marginal cost for each additional unit, she can profitably sell to a larger set of end-consumers. Dynamic procurement allows the supplier to charge lower prices as the number of units purchased by the buyer increases (as in the case of an incremental quantity discount), and hence, it allows the buyer to profitably sell to those end-consumers with lower valuations. Clearly, under a different demand curve, the split of profits between the buyer and the supplier will be different, but dynamic procurement will continue to occur as long as demand is price-sensitive. In order to verify our intuition, we study a multiplicative demand function where D(P) ¼ aP2 and an exponential demand function where D(P) ¼ a exp(P) for a two-period model. (For the multiplicative model we can no longer assume that the production cost of the buyer is zero, hence, for both cases we assume that the unit production cost is c.) Both multiplicative and exponential demand functions lead to similar dynamics to the linear inverse demand function. Therefore, even though we cannot verify the second part of our main result, we continue to show that all participants (supplier, buyer, and endconsumers) strictly benefit as N increases.
4.3
Newsvendor Setting
To test the robustness of our results to price-sensitive demand assumption, we study a setting where a newsvendor procures capacity N times before the demand is realized (we assume that there is no forecast update between periods). We analyze the case where demand is uniformly distributed between 0 and u, the market price is fixed at p per unit, and the buyer’s production cost is c < p per unit. Proposition 3 shows that dynamic procurement continues to increase the quantity that the buyer procures as the supplier is willing to decrease the wholesale price over time.
Dynamic Procurement, Quantity Discounts, and Supply Chain Efficiency
227
Proposition 3 (Newsvendor setting with uniform demand). The unique purestrategy SPNE for the N-period dynamic procurement model is the following. For n ¼ 1; . . . ; N 1, let n ¼ N n. Then, p c 2 nþ1 2 n u p c 2 ; w1 ¼ KN N qn ; wnþ1 ¼ wn ; ; qnþ1 ¼ q1 ¼ p 2 2 n 2 nþ1 2N QN1 2kþ1 The production quantity is where K1 ¼ 1 and KN ¼ k¼1 2kþ2. pc PN pc KN p . QN ¼ n¼1 qn ¼ u 1 2 p . As N tends to infinity, QN tends to u Furthermore, as N goes to infinity, the performance of the decentralized supply chain approaches that of the centralized supply chain. Therefore, our main result continues to hold in a newsvendor-setting with uniform demand distribution. Finally, the uniform distribution leads to the same profit split as in the linear inverse demand case.
4.4
Effort-Dependent Demand
In order to understand the impact of dynamic procurement in case of effort-dependent demand, we study an N-period model where demand is a function of the sales effort in addition to price, i.e., D(P, e) ¼ a P þ e (cost of the effort is e2). Proposition 4 shows that dynamic procurement continues to benefit both parties. Proposition 4 (Effort-dependent demand). The unique pure-strategy SPNE for the N-period dynamic procurement model is the following. For n ¼ 1; . . . ; N 1, let n ¼ N n. Then, a a 2 nþ1 2 n QN ; qn ; wnþ1 ¼ wn ; e ¼ q1 ¼ ; w1 ¼ KN2 N ; qnþ1 ¼ 2 3N 2 2 n 2 nþ1 QN1 2kþ1 The production quantity is where K1 ¼ 1 and KN ¼ k¼1 2kþ2. P a QN ¼ Nn¼1 qn ¼ 2a K . As N tends to infinity, QN tends to 2a 3 3 N 3. Furthermore, as N tends to infinity, both the effort level and the production quantity tend to those of the centralized supply chain. Due to dynamic procurement, the buyer can afford to invest more in the sales effort (as her average procurement cost decreases) and decrease the price of the product; therefore, demand for the product increases. The division of the profits, as well as the improvement of the system performance, mimic those of the setting with linear inverse demand function.
4.5
Information Asymmetry
In practice, the buyer is closer to the end-consumer market and may have more information about the demand compared to the supplier. Hence, we consider
228
F. Erhun et al.
1.5 Increase in the supplier’s 1 expected 0.5 profit 0 0
1 0.8 0.6 0.4
0.2 0.4
α
al /ah
0.2
0.6 0.8 1
0
Fig. 3 The increase in the supplier’s expected profits due to the additional period (ah ¼ 10)
information asymmetry between the supplier and the buyer regarding the market potential. According to the supplier, the market potential can either be “high”, ah, with a probability of a, or “low”, al, with a probability of 1 a. The buyer, on the other hand, knows the exact value of the market potential. (For simplicity, we assume that bi ¼ 1, i ¼ l, h.) Under asymmetric information, depending on the relative values of al and ah, the buyer and the supplier may engage in dynamic procurement. However, despite improving the system performance for a large range of parameters, the additional trading period is not always beneficial, i.e., the result in part (i) can be reversed under asymmetric information. Figure 3 illustrates these facts by plotting the increase in the supplier’s expected profits due to the additional period for different values of al and a. When al is relatively low compared to ah, the supplier does not benefit from the additional period. For higher values of al, there are values of a for which dynamic procurement improves the system performance. Hence, under asymmetric information the additional trading period may continue to enable dynamic procurement depending on the relative values of al and ah. However, our main result may also be reversed under asymmetric information.
4.6
Competition
In this section, we study the impact of dynamic procurement under competition. In this model, we restrict ourselves to two periods and study two competing buyers. Using the capacity they procure from the supplier, the buyers produce similar products, which they sell to end-consumers at the end of the second period. Before production takes place, the buyers can procure capacity in both periods. Firms simultaneously choose their procurement quantities in the first period; these become common knowledge and then firms simultaneously decide how much
Dynamic Procurement, Quantity Discounts, and Supply Chain Efficiency
229
additional capacity to procure in the second period before the market clears. Erhun (2007) studies this setting in detail (when there are more than two periods, more than two buyers, etc.) We present one of their results below to show how dynamic procurement extends to the situations with competition. The following proposition presents the unique SPNE for the dynamic procurement model under competition. Proposition 5. The unique SPNE for the dynamic procurement model is symmetric and is as follows. 9a (i) The wholesale prices for first and second periods are w1 ¼ 31a 60 and w2 ¼ 20, respectively. a . (ii) The buyers’ first period procurement quantity is: q1;1 ¼ q1;2 ¼ 30b 3a . (iii) The buyers’ second period procurement quantity is: q2;1 ¼ q2;2 ¼ 20b
Dynamic procurement continues to increase supply chain efficiency under competition. When N ¼ 1, the supply chain inefficiency is around 11%. With dynamic procurement, this inefficiency decreases to 7% when N ¼ 2. Furthermore, dynamic procurement naturally allocates the surplus to the supplier and the buyers such that they all benefit.
4.7
Demand Uncertainty with Information Update
Even though our goal in this chapter is to characterize a potential impact of dynamic procurement other than mitigating demand risk, as our final extension, we also discuss the dynamics of dynamic procurement when mitigating demand risk is an option. We consider a two-period extension of our main model where the endconsumer market can be in one of two states (indexed by i): “high” demand state, i ¼ h, or “low” demand state, i ¼ l. The probability that the demand market will be in state i is fi, i ¼ l, h, such that fh + fl ¼ 1. The buyer and the supplier learn the state of the demand sometime during the planning horizon. Therefore, the information update splits the planning horizon into two periods, possibly of unequal lengths. The buyer can procure capacity in both periods before the selling season begins. We assume that bh ¼ bl ¼ 1; i.e., the market is characterized by a linear inverse demand function Pi(Qi) ¼ ai Qi, where Pi(Qi) is the price of the product when Qi is the quantity sold by the buyer in the end-consumer market when the demand is in state i and ai is the market potential in state i. We assume that 0 < al ⩽ ah, that is, the market potential is positive in both states and higher under the high demand state. In this two-period model, the supplier announces the first period wholesale price at the beginning of the first period. He announces the second period wholesale price at the beginning of the second period after the demand state is revealed. The buyer chooses the first period procurement quantity before the demand state is revealed. She chooses the second period procurement quantity after the demand state is revealed. The market clears at the end of the second period.
230
F. Erhun et al.
Erhun et al. (2008) study this setting in detail (when there is limited capacity, more than two demand states, etc.). We present one of their results below to show how dynamic procurement extends to the situations with uncertain demand: Proposition 6. When demand is uncertain, the prices and quantities are set as follows: 8 < 9ðfh ah þfl al Þ; fh ah þfl al 16 8 ðw1 ; q1 Þ ¼ : 9fh ah ; ah 16 8 ðw2;i ; q2;i Þ ¼
if fh <
3al ah al
2
otherwise
þ a q þ ai i 1 q1 ; ; 2 4 2
i ¼ h; l:
Depending on the demand state, dynamic prices may increase (advance purchase discount) or decrease (markdown) over time. Dynamic procurement works for the supplier even under uncertain demand; the supplier’s increase with dynamic procurement. However, for the buyer, the value of dynamic procurement depends on when the supplier sets the price in a single procurement situation. If the supplier sets to price after the uncertainty is revealed (no-commitment model), then the buyer’s expected profits are also higher. Since both players benefit, it is a natural consequence that dynamic procurement eliminates supply chain inefficiencies compared to the no-commitment case. If the supplier sets to price before the uncertainty is revealed (early commitment model), the buyer’s expected profits may either increase or decrease under dynamic procurement. Especially when the difference between the market potentials of the high and low demand states is considerable, the buyer becomes worse off with dynamic procurement compared to the early commitment model. However, when the supplier chooses his capacity as well as the prices, for a wide-range of parameters, dynamic procurement is the best alternative for all parties, including the end customers.
5 Conclusion Dynamic procurement is commonly used to mitigate demand risk. However, our research shows that this may not be the only reason why companies use dynamic procurement. During our discussions with a consulting firm for a major manufacturer of finished goods, we observed a strong indication that the manufacturer was able to impact its raw material costs by using a multiple period sourcing approach. Interestingly, there was very little uncertainty in the finished good demand for this particular manufacturer and the supply of the material was constrained. Based on a data analysis over a 4-year horizon, the consulting firm concluded that higher inventory levels at the manufacturer showed strong correlations with reduced sourcing costs on a per-unit basis. A likely reason that the multiple period sourcing
Dynamic Procurement, Quantity Discounts, and Supply Chain Efficiency
231
helped to reduce prices was expressed by many of the manufacturer’s purchasers as “being able to walk away from the table.” The raw material supplier tended to know the inventory position of the manufacturer and understood the economics of the manufacturer’s business such that she could leverage her supply when the manufacturer had immediate shortage concerns. When the manufacturer felt strong enough to walk away, the negotiating position was reversed. In this paper, we analyzed this phenomenon with a stylized model. Similar to the efficiency result of Allaz and Vila, our main result states that, as the number of trading periods increases, the total output of the supply chain increases and approaches that of the centralized supply chain. Contrary to their result, we show that all the parties benefit from multiple trading periods. In equilibrium, dynamic procurement is similar to an incremental quantity discount where the supplier sets the prices and the buyer sets the breakpoints (Fig. 4). It can be viewed as a sequence of bilateral negotiations between the supplier and the buyer, and it provides incentives to both parties to increase the total supply chain profits. There are several directions for future research. In our model, the number of trading periods is known in advance. However, the situation where this information is not common knowledge, either to the buyer and/or to the supplier, would be interesting to analyze. Another possibility is to extend Erhun et al. (2008) and model a setting where the uncertainty is revealed to either player partially. Studying models with signalling or screening would be particularly beneficial to understand the dynamics when the uncertainty revelation is only partial. Finally, further studying a more general model where the wholesale prices can be negotiated and the products can be sold via N possible periods to competing buyers under partial demand revelation would be interesting.
a
b 1500 60
Unit Cost
Total Cost
55 1000
500
50 45 40
0
35 0
10
20 30 Quantity
40
0
10
20
30
40
Quantity
Fig. 4 The total and unit capacity costs versus quantities under dynamic procurement when N ¼ 20 (P(Q20) ¼ 100 Q20)
232
F. Erhun et al.
Acknowledgements The first author was partially supported by NSF Award DMI-0400345 and the second author was supported by NSF Career Award DMII-0093844. The authors would like to express their deepest gratitude to two anonymous reviewers for their constructive comments and suggestions.
References Allaz B, Vila JL (1993) Cournot competition, forward markets and efficiency. J Econ Theory 59 (1):1–16 Anand K, Anupindi R, Bassok Y (2008) Strategic inventories in vertical contracts. Manage Sci 54 (10):1792–1804 Benton WC, Park S (1996) A classification of literature on determining the lot size under quantity discounts. Eur J Oper Res 92(2):219–238 Burnetas A, Gilbert S (2001) Future capacity procurements under unknown demand and increasing costs. Manage Sci 47(7):979–992 Cachon GP (2004) The allocation of inventory risk in a supply chain: push, pull, and advancepurchase discount contracts. Manage Sci 50(2):222–238 Chen R, Roma P (2010) Group buying of competing retailers. Prod Oper Manage 20(2):181–197 Chen F, Federgruen A, Zheng Y (2001) Coordination mechanism for a distribution system with one supplier and multiple retailers. Manage Sci 47(5):693–708 Crowther J (1964) Rationale for quantity discounts. Harv Bus Rev 42(2):121–127 Cvsa V, Gilbert SM (2002) Strategic commitment versus postponement in a two-tier supply chain. Eur J Oper Res 141(3):526–543 Dada M, Srikanth KN (1987) Pricing policies for quantity discounts. Manage Sci 33 (10):1247–1252 Dolan RJ (1987) Quantity discounts: managerial issues and research opportunities. Mark Sci 6 (1):1–23 Dong L, Zhu K (2007) Two-wholesale-price contracts: push, pull, and advance purchase discount contracts. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 9(3):291–311 Donohue KL (2000) Efficient supply contracts for fashion goods with forecast updating and two production modes. Manage Sci 46(11):1397–1411 Elmaghraby W, Keskinocak P (2003) Dynamic pricing in the presence of inventory considerations: research overview, current practices, and future directions. Manage Sci 49 (10):1287–1309 Erhun F (2007) Dynamic pricing in Cournot duopoly with two production periods. Working paper, Department of Management Science and Engineering, Stanford University, Stanford, CA Erhun F, Keskinocak P, Tayur S (2008) Dynamic procurement in a capacitated supply chain facing uncertain demand. IIE Trans 40(8):733–748 Ferguson ME (2003) When to commit in a serial supply chain with forecast updating. Nav Res Logist 50(8):917–936 Ferguson ME, DeCroix GA, Zipkin PH (2005) Commitment decisions with partial information updating. Nav Res Logist 52(8):780–795 Guo P, Niu B, Wang Y (2009) Two-wholesale-price contract in a three-tier supply chain. Working paper, Hong Kong Polytechnic University, Hung Hom, Kowloon Gurnani H, Tang CS (1999) Note: optimal ordering decisions with uncertain cost and demand forecast updating. Manage Sci 45(10):1456–1462 Ingene CA, Parry ME (1995) Channel coordination when retailers compete. Mark Sci 14 (4):360–377 Iyer AV, Bergen ME (1997) Quick response in manufacturer-retailer channels. Manage Sci 43 (4):559–570
Dynamic Procurement, Quantity Discounts, and Supply Chain Efficiency
233
Jeuland AP, Shugan SM (1983) Managing channel profits. Mark Sci 2(3):239–272 Keskinocak P, Charnsirisakskul K, Griffin P (2003) Supply chain procurement with inventory and backordering options. Working paper, School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, GA Keskinocak P, Charnsirisakskul K, Griffin P (2008) Strategic inventory in capacitated supply chain procurement. Managerial Decis Econ 29(1):23–36 Li C, Scheller-Wolf A (2010) Push or pull? Auctioning supply contracts. Prod Oper Manage 20(2): 198–213 Monahan JP (1984) A quantity discount pricing model to increase vendor profits. Manage Sci 30 (6):720–726 Munson CL, Rosenblatt MJ (1998) Theories and realities of quantity discounts: an exploratory study. Prod Oper Manage 7(4):352–369 Raju J, Zhang ZJ (2005) Channel coordination in presence of a dominant retailer. Mark Sci 24 (2):254–262 Spencer BJ, Brander JA (1992) Pre-commitment and flexibility: applications to oligopoly theory. Eur Econ Rev 36(8):1601–1626 Taylor T (2006) Sale timing in a supply chain: when to sell to the retailer. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 8(1):23–42 Van Mieghem JA (2003) Capacity management, investment, and hedging: review and recent developments. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 5(4):269–302 Weng ZK (1995) Channel coordination and quantity discounts. Manage Sci 41(9):1509–1522
.
Coordination of the Supplier–Retailer Relationship in a Multi-period Setting: The Additional Ordering Cost Contract Nicola Bellantuono, Ilaria Giannoccaro, and Pierpaolo Pontrandolfo
Abstract Coordinating supply chains by adopting a centralized decision making approach, which is theoretically desirable, is often practically infeasible, if not ineffective: the high number of involved companies in a supply chain, the lack of adequate contractual power concentrated in the hand of only a few of them, the difficulty to gather all the relevant information by the unique/few decision maker/s, are some of the many reasons preventing supply chains from implementing such a centralized coordination approach. Supply contracts have been proposed in the literature as an alternate way to face such a problem: they let the chain’s partners to autonomously make decision, but at the same time guide them to behave coherently among each other as well as with the chain’s goal. Designing a contract is quite a challenging task, especially under the hypothesis of multi-period settings, which is the assumption considered in this chapter. In the majority of cases, multi-period supply contracts are inherently complex (e.g. many parameters that need to be frequently updated), therefore difficult to be implemented, as well as often designed under hypotheses barely realistic (e.g. null order costs). We propose a supply contract for a two-stage supply chain (supplier–retailer) in a multi-period setting, which tries to overcome such drawbacks. The proposed contract is based on two key mechanisms: additional ordering cost for retailer and price discount offered by the supplier to the retailer. A numerical analysis is finally conducted to identify the conditions that allow the best performance to be achieved. N. Bellantuono (*) • P. Pontrandolfo Dipartimento di Ingegneria dell’Ambiente e per lo Sviluppo Sostenibile, Politecnico di Bari, via De Gasperi s.n., 74100 Taranto, Italy e-mail: [email protected]; [email protected] I. Giannoccaro Dipartimento di Ingegneria Meccanica e Gestionale, Politecnico di Bari, viale Japigia 182, 70125 Bari, Italy e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_10, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
235
236
N. Bellantuono et al.
Keywords Multi-period setting • Supply chain coordination • Supply contracts
1 Introduction A supply chain is a network of organizations that are involved in the different processes and activities to produce value in the form of products and services in the hands of the ultimate consumer (Christopher 1992). The coordination of this network is a key issue in supply chain management. System efficiency is assured when the supply chain is globally managed by a single decision maker who optimizes the performance of the whole system (channel coordination). This approach is usually referred to as centralized strategy (Federgruen 1993). Coordination problem becomes complex when different decision makers coexist within the supply chain, each taking decisions by pursuing their own goals, which are likely to be conflicting against each other (Schneeweiss 2003). These locally rational behaviours result in global inefficiency of the supply chain (Whang 1995). To improve the overall performance, the decision makers should be pushed to behave in the interest of the global supply chain rather than in their own ones. Such a problem is referred to as alignment of incentives in decentralized supply chains (Narayanan and Raman 2004). To align incentives in supply chains, supply contracts should be adopted. They formally rule the transaction between the actors and force them to pursue channel coordination. These mechanisms are based on transfer payment schemes that rule how to split the savings (or the increase in revenues) and let risks be fairly shared (Tsay et al. 1999; Cachon 2003). Transfer payment schemes are designed to increase the system-wide profit so as to make it closer – possibly equal – to the profit resulting from a centralized control (channel coordination). They modify the decision makers’ goals, bringing them to take the same decisions that the single decision maker would take. A further important issue for the contract design is the so-called win-win condition, which occurs if the contract makes every actor gain a profit higher than the one he or she would gain in default of the contract, i.e. under a decentralized setting. Indeed, if the win–win condition is not satisfied, the actor would not be prompted to adopt the contract (Giannoccaro and Pontrandolfo 2004). A number of supply contracts have been developed in the literature. They include quantity/volume discounts (Monahan 1984; Li and Liu 2006), buy back or return policies (Pasternack 1985; Emmons and Gilbert 1998), backup agreements (Eppen and Iyer 1997), allocation rules (Cachon and Lariviere 1999), quantity flexibility contracts (Tsay 1999; Wang and Tsao 2006), and revenue sharing contracts (Giannoccaro and Pontrandolfo 2004; Cachon and Lariviere 2005). For a complete review of supply contract the reader is referred to Tsay et al. (1999), Cachon (2003), and Tang (2006). Most of these contracts address the problem of coordinating supply chains under a single-period setting, namely assuming that the items that flow along the supply
Coordination of the Supplier–Retailer Relationship in a Multi-period Setting
237
chain are perishable or have a quickly decreasing demand. In these cases, the selling season is assumed short enough to impel both new orders be issued once demand has revealed and stocks in excess be held until the following selling season. This assumption permits the adoption of models deriving from the classical newsvendor model (Wadsworth 1959; Hadley and Whitin 1963). On the contrary, few studies have analyzed the same problem under a multi-period setting. In this case, further parameters (e.g. the ordering and inventory costs) must be taken into account, so making more complex not only the design of the contract but also its implementation in practice. The aim of this work is thus to develop an supply contract to coordinate a twostage supply chain under a multi-period setting, which is effective as well as simple to be implemented. In particular, we consider a supply chain in which a supplier provides in a random lead time a single product to a retailer, who in turn serves the market characterized by uncertain demand. Both incur ordering and inventory holding costs. Moreover, when final demand cannot be immediately satisfied, the retailer incurs backorder cost. The contract is designed so as to achieve both channel coordination and win–win condition and is mainly based on two mechanisms (1) the additional ordering cost that the retailer pays to the supplier and (2) the price discount that the supplier gives to the retailer. In the following section a review of contracts for multi-period settings is presented. Then, the supply chain model is described and the contract is designed. A numerical analysis is finally carried out to illustrate how the supply contract works and to identify the scenarios where the contract is more effective.
2 Supply Contracts in Multi-period Settings: A Review Since the 1980s, several studies have been carried out to design contracts for supply chain management, yet only lately research has addressed also multi-period settings. This section reviews the literature on multi-period contracts and describes the most significant contract models. The review proves useful to derive insights and suggestions supporting the design of an innovative contract. The quantity-flexibility multi-period contract by Tsay and Lovejoy (1999) derives from the homonymous contract for the single-period setting (Tsay 1999), which is modified mainly through the adoption of a rolling horizon: at the beginning of each selling season, the retailer and the supplier agree on (1) the wholesale price of the product, (2) the demand forecast for each season up to the planning horizon, and (3) the minimum and maximum quantity for the delivery. In the following seasons, actors update the demand forecast and the contract parameters, to reduce the allowable demand fluctuation for every future season as it becomes closer. Tsay and Lovejoy (1999) argue that their contract enables actors to share the risk related to demand uncertainty: the retailer is guaranteed for a minimum delivery of goods and so she recedes from the rationing game (Lee et al. 1997), i.e. the practice
238
N. Bellantuono et al.
to communicate overestimated forecasts in order to secure the possible delivery of more units than expected as demand. In turn, the supplier is kept from the risk that actual retailer’s orders will be lower than he predicts. Nevertheless, the need to continually update contract parameters restricts the adoption of the quantityflexibility contract to firms willing to cooperate and having human resources able to deal with so complex schemes. Steady-state contracts are simpler to be implemented; indeed, once they have been agreed, they are valid also in future periods without any need for parameters’ updating. Recently, literature has focused on this class of contracts (for a review, see Cachon 2003) and pointed out which clauses can be useful to coordinate the SC. They may include: – Additional penalties for the backorder at each stage of the SC – Grants to boost holdings – Time lag between physical and financial flows Cachon and Zipkin (1999) recur to the game theory to affirm that a supply chain can be coordinated by a contract that uses a linear money transfer from an actor to another to align the Nash equilibrium (i.e. the equilibrium in a decentralized setting) to the global optimum. By adopting such a contract, the retailer is encouraged to increase her stock; the supplier, in turn, increases the punctuality of his deliveries to avoid retailer’s stockouts. A contract similar to that by Cachon and Zipkin (1999) is the additional backlog penalty contract (Lee and Whang 1999): by a shortage reimbursement contract, the supplier pays the retailer when he cannot meet her orders and receives money from her when she has a stockout. Such a mechanism urges actors to increase their holding stock, which otherwise in a decentralized setting would be lower then what the optimal solution prescribes. Lee and Whang (1999) emphasize three properties of the proposed contract, which indeed are common to many others: cost conservation, incentive compatibility, and information decentrability. Cachon (2003) shows that the shortage reimbursement contract substantially agrees with the methodology by Chen (1999) to coordinate systems with a delayed receipt of orders. Also the contract by Porteus (2000), based on the so called responsibility tokens, is similar to the shortage reimbursement contract. In fact, it results in the same transfer payment between actors, although it assigns to the supplier a penalty per late delivered unit, instead of a penalty per occurrence of a – partial or total – late delivery. Lee and Whang (1999) observe that a method to coordinate supply chains based on time discounting consists in abandoning the hypothesis that physical transfers and related financial flows are concurrent. In particular, authors describe the consignment contract, by which retailers give money to the suppliers only once products are sold to the final customers. The steady-state contracts do not need to continually update the parameters, differently from the rolling horizon contracts. Unfortunately, to our knowledge the steady-state contracts so far developed hold under hypotheses that are barely realistic. Their most critical aspect refers to the ordering cost, which in the literature
Coordination of the Supplier–Retailer Relationship in a Multi-period Setting
239
on supply chain inventory management is generally assumed as null (Axs€ater 1990; Axs€ater 1993; Cachon and Zipkin 1999; Lee and Whang 1999) or proportional to order quantity (Shang and Song 2003). In both cases, the optimal replenishment quantity becomes qi ¼ 1 and the search of optimal policies collapses to the simple search – for each actor – of the order point that minimizes the sum of expected holding and backorder costs. By analyzing each cost factor that adds up to the ordering cost, one can demonstrate the ineffectiveness of these assumptions: in fact, the ordering cost is a step-function of the order quantity and thus it can be assumed as constant for a wide interval of values for the latter.
3 The Model Consider a serial two-stage supply chain consisting of a retailer, who faces the market demand, and a supplier, who provides items to the retailer.1 Both actors are risk-neutral, i.e. their utility functions are proportional to the profit (Schweitzer and Cachon 2000), and financial flows occur simultaneously to the corresponding physical flows. At both stages inventories are managed by a continuous review system ruled by the pair ðqi ; ri Þ, the former being the order quantity ðqi > 0Þ and the latter the reorder point ðri > 0Þ. The unmet demand is fully backordered (Fig. 1). The instantaneous demand is a continuous random variable. All the notations are summarized in Table 1. For the sake of simplicity, we prefer to assume that the supplier’s lead time is null, so that the latter can issue his orders at the same time he receives the retailer’s order. In fact, this assumption is usually adopted when it is wished to neglect the effect of suppliers external to the supply chain. This assumption also implies that the demand during the supplier’s lead time is null ðm2 ¼ s2 ¼ 0Þ, as well as the
external supplier
L2
supplier
L1
retailer
(stage 2)
(stage 1)
A2 h2
A1 h1 b
market
d
Fig. 1 The supply chain model
1 For the sake of clarity, we denote the retailer as actor 1 and the supplier as actor 2. Moreover, we use the pronoun “she” for the retailer and “he” the supplier.
240 Table 1 Model notations
N. Bellantuono et al.
Variable D 1 2 mi si Ai hi b qi ri k n ’(k) F(k) () Ci() C() d * c a d
Description Expected annual demand Retailer’s subscript Supplier’s subscript Mean of the demand during the i-th actor’s lead time Standard deviation of the demand during the i-th actor’s lead time Ordering cost at the i-th stage Annual holding cost per unit at the i-th stage Backorder cost per unit Order quantity at the i-th stage Reorder point at the i-th stage Safety factor Nested factor p.d.f. of the standard normal distribution c.d.f. of the standard normal distribution Expected shortage per replenishment cycle Expected annual cost of the i-th actor Expected annual cost of the supply chain Decentralized setting superscript Centralized setting superscript Contract setting superscript Additional ordering cost (contract parameter) Discount per unit sold (contract parameter)
supplier’s reorder point ðr2 ¼ 0Þ and his expected backorder stock. The retailer’s lead time, in turn, is a random positive variable; demand during the retailer’s lead time is normally distributed and its mean m1 and standard deviation are both known and denoted as m1 and s1 , respectively. The probability density function and cumulative distribution function of the standard normal distribution are respectively denoted as ’ðkÞ and FðkÞ. Thus, the retailer’s order point can be expressed in terms of the safety factor, as follows: k¼
r1 m1 : s1
(1)
Therefore, the supplier’s expected annual cost consists in the sum of expected ordering and holding cost: the former is proportional to the expected number of orders per year, whereas the latter is proportional to the units that he holds on average. We assume also that the holding cost of the pipeline stock (units in transit from the supplier to the retailer) is paid by the former. The retailer, in turn, is affected by ordering, holding, and backorder cost. The latter is assumed proportional to the number of units backlogged, irrespective of the time for which the backorder lasts.
Coordination of the Supplier–Retailer Relationship in a Multi-period Setting
3.1
241
Decentralized Setting
Each actor autonomously makes inventory policy decisions, aimed at minimizing his/her own cost. Hence, two separate optimization problems have to be solved (1) finding the pair ðqd1 ; kd Þ that minimizes the retailer’s cost, and (2) identifying the parameter qd2 that minimizes the supplier’s cost, given the retailer’s policy. Under the assumptions above described, the retailer’s expected annual cost is calculated as follows (Hadley and Whitin 1963; Silver et al. 1998)2: C1 ðq1 ; kÞ ¼ A1
hq i D D 1 þ s1 k þ b ðkÞ; þ h1 2 q1 q1
(2)
where the quantity between square brackets is the expected net inventory and: ðkÞ ¼ s1 ½’ðkÞ þ kFðkÞ k
(3)
is the expected shortage per replenishment cycle, i.e. the unmet demand between two consecutive orders [see Appendix A.2]. The optimal retailer’s policy ðqd1 ; kd Þ minimizing (2) can be obtained by the iterative procedure described in Hadley and Whitin (1963) using the following equations [see Appendix A.3]: qd1
rffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi 2D ¼ ½A1 þ bðkd Þ; h1
(4)
and h1 qd1 kd ¼ F1 1 : bD
(5)
To solve the supplier’s optimization problem, we assume that he adopts a nested policy, which allows the computational complexity of the problem to be reduced at the expense of a slight possible decrease of the solution effectiveness (Schwarz and Schrage 1975; Roundy 1985; Axs€ater and Rosling 1993). When a nested policy is used, a stage can issue a order only when the downstream stage does the same. This implies that when the supplier makes a order, his order quantity will be: q2 ¼ nq1 ;
(6)
being the nested factor n a positive integer. 2
The (2) is an approximation but consistent with a wide stream of the literature on inventory management (Hadley and Whitin 1963; De Bodt and Graves 1985; Silver et al. 1998; Mitra and Chatterjee 2004). See Appendix A.1.
242
N. Bellantuono et al.
Therefore, the supplier’s inventory problem is reduced to finding the positive integer nd that minimizes his expected annual cost: C2 ðn; q1 Þ ¼ A2
D n1 þ h2 q1 þ m1 ; nq1 2
(7)
where the quantity between square brackets is the expected net inventory at the supplier’s stage and includes the expected pipeline stock, i.e. the expected quantity in transit from the supplier to the retailer. To this aim, the following procedure is suggested: 1. Compute: qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi n^ ¼
2A2 D h2 : d q1
(8)
2. If n^ is an integer, then nd ¼ n^; otherwise: nd ¼ arg min C2 ðn; qd1 Þ; n2fn1 ;n2 g
(9)
where n1 and n2 are the positive integers that surround n^.
3.2
Centralized Setting
Under a centralized setting, the optimal inventory policy is the one that minimizes the expected annual cost of the whole supply chain, whose formula is given by referring to the model by De Bodt and Graves (1985). This model adopts a nested policy using an echelon perspective. The echelon perspective requires to compute (1) the echelon stock of each stage, i.e. the sum of the stock at the stage and all the downstream stages, including the pipeline stock, (2) the echelon holding cost (i.e. the incremental inventory cost at a given stage with reference to the upstream stage), and (3) the echelon order point (i.e. the sum of the order point at the considered stage and those at all the upstream stages). Under the current hypotheses, the expected total supply chain cost is given by De Bodt and Graves (1985). By substituting the echelon cost expressions with the correspondent installation ones, it follows that: hq i A2 D n1 D 1 þ s1 k þ h2 Cðq1 ; k; nÞ ¼ A1 þ þ h1 q1 þ m1 þ b ðkÞ; (10) n q1 2 2 q1 wherein the expected shortage per replenishment cycle ðkÞ is given by (3) and the nested factor n is a positive integer. The retailer’s and supplier’s expected annual costs are given by (2) and (7), respectively.
Coordination of the Supplier–Retailer Relationship in a Multi-period Setting
243
The centralized inventory problem is to find the optimal policy ðq1 ; k ; n Þ that minimizes (10). To solve it, a heuristics based on the continuous relaxation of the problem is proposed, consisting of the following steps (see Appendix A.4): 1. Assume ðkÞ ¼ 0 and compute:
rffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi A2 h1 h2 : n~ ¼ A1 h2
(11)
2. Compute: sffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi 2D A2 q1 ð~ nÞ ¼ A1 þ þ bðkÞ n~ h1 þ ð~ n 1Þh2
(12)
3. Compute: 1
kðq1 Þ ¼ F
h1 q1 ð~ nÞ 1 bD
pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi 2A2 D=h2 n~ðq1 Þ ¼ q1
(13)
(14)
4. Iterate steps 2–3 until a suitable approximation is obtained. 5. If n~ðq1 Þ is an integer, then n ¼ n~ðq1 Þ; otherwise denote the positive integers that surround n~ as n1 and n2 . 6. For both n1 and n2 iteratively use (12) and (13) until convergence to compute q1 ðn1 Þ and k ðn1 Þ and, respectively, q1 ðn2 Þ and k ðn2 Þ. 7. Compute (10). The optimal value for the nested factor is: n ¼ arg min C n; q1 ðnÞ; k ðnÞ ; (15) n2fn1 ;n2 g
where q1 ðnÞ and k ðnÞ are the correspondent conditionally optimal values of the other two variables, as determined at step 6.
4 The Additional Ordering Cost Contract The additional ordering cost contract aims to push retailer to make larger orders than she will do under a decentralized setting, so as to led the supply chain to behave like in a centralized fashion. In fact, by comparing the decentralized and the centralized settings, we notice that the inefficiency of the decentralized setting is due to the fact that the retailer makes smaller and more frequent orders. The additional ordering cost contract is then based on a transfer payment from the supplier to the retailer, so defined:
244
N. Bellantuono et al.
FTðq1 ; a; dÞ ¼ dD aA1
D : q1
(16)
It is ruled by two parameters (1) the penalty that the supplier gives to the retailer for each order she issues ðaÞ, and (2) the discount that the suppliers grants to the retailer for each unit sold ðdÞ. Through a suitable design of the values for a and d both the channel coordination and the win–win condition are assured. The retailer’s and the supplier’s expected annual costs under the contract setting are given by the equations, respectively: Cc1 ðq1 ; k; a; dÞ ¼ C1 ðq1 ; kÞ FTðq1 ; a; dÞ hq i D D 1 þ s1 k þ b ðkÞ dD ¼ ð1 þ aÞA1 þ h1 2 q1 q1
(17)
and: Cc2 ðn; q1 ; a; dÞ ¼ C2 ðn; q1 Þ þ FTðq1 ; a; dÞ D n1 D þ h2 ¼ A2 q1 þ m1 þ dD aA1 : nq1 2 q1
(18)
Thus, as in the decentralized setting even under the contract two separate optimization problems have to be solved (1) the retailer’s problem is to identify the pair ðqc1 ; kc Þ that minimizes (17), and (2) the supplier’s problem is to find the positive integer nc that minimizes (18). In particular, from (17) it follows: rffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi 2D c q1 ðaÞ ¼ ½ð1 þ aÞA1 þ bðkc Þ: (19) h1 and 1
k ¼F c
h1 qc1 1 : bD
(20)
Proposition 1. The channel coordination is achieved if the actors agree on an additional ordering cost contract where: a¼
h1 A 2 n
ðn 1Þh2 ½A1 þ bðk Þ : A1 ½h1 þ ðn 1Þh2
(21)
(Proof: See Appendix A.5). Proposition 2. Once the channel coordination is achieved, there exists a range of values for d which assure the win–win condition. (Proof: See Appendix A.6). Observation 1. Channel coordination does not depend on d. Observation 2. The annual expected costs of both actors linearly depend on the value of d.
Coordination of the Supplier–Retailer Relationship in a Multi-period Setting
245
5 Numerical Analysis For illustrative purposes, in this section a numerical analysis is provided to give a measure of the inefficiency of the decentralized approach and to show how the additional ordering cost contract works. Results prove that the contract coordinates the channel and assures a win–win condition. As a measurement of the inefficiency of the decentralized setting, the competition penalty (Cachon and Zipkin 1999) is defined as follows: C qd1 ; kd ; nd C q1 ; k ; n CP ¼ 100 : C q1 ; k ; n
(22)
The higher CP, the higher the penalty in terms of increase of the supply chain expected cost. Data used in the numerical analysis are shown in Table 2. The latter consists of 27 scenarios designed by varying the value ðs1 =m1 Þ, the ratios between the ordering costs ðA1 =A2 Þ, and the annual holding costs per unit ðh2 =h1 Þ. The sensitivity analysis aims to identify the scenarios where the contract is more effective. Table 3 shows the retailer’s, the supplier’s, and the system-wide expected annual costs both in the decentralized and in the centralized setting, as well as the corresponding competition penalty in all scenarios. As we expected, CP is always positive, which means that the centralized setting provides better system-wide performances than the decentralized one. Furthermore, the retailer’s performance gets worse moving from the decentralized to the centralized setting, so explaining why the retailer has no incentive to agree on system-wide optimal policy and why a supply contract is thus necessary. The data presented in Table 3 are analyzed in Table 4, where for each value of s1 , A1 , and h2 the means of the competition penalty obtained for the three levels of the other two variables are reported. Results show that CP is positively affected by h2 and to a smaller extent by A1 , whereas the effects of s1 on CP are in general negligible, in spite of the differences in the expected costs. Therefore, the contract proves very useful especially when the holding costs per unit at both stages are similar, irrespective of the demand variability or the difference between retailer’s Table 2 Values used in the numerical analysis.
Variable D m1 s1 A1 A2 h1 h2 b
Levels 1 1 3 3 1 1 3 1
Values 1,000 100 10, 20, 30 5, 20, 35 50 1 0.5, 0.7, 0.9 10
246
N. Bellantuono et al.
Table 3 Retailer’s, supplier’s and system-wide expected annual costs in decentralized and centralized settings for different values of s1, A1, and h2, given D ¼ 1,000, m1 ¼ 100, A2 ¼ 50, h1 ¼ 1, and b ¼ 10 A1 h2 Decentralized setting Centralized setting CP (%) s1 10
5
20
35
20
5
20
35
30
5
20
35
0.5 0.7 0.9 0.5 0.7 0.9 0.5 0.7 0.9 0.5 0.7 0.9 0.5 0.7 0.9 0.5 0.7 0.9 0.5 0.7 0.9 0.5 0.7 0.9 0.5 0.7 0.9
C
C1
375.01 426.05 470.80 447.82 488.20 528.57 497.95 543.99 563.99 400.12 452.24 495.10 470.64 511.39 552.14 520.67 564.39 584.39 425.35 477.41 519.57 493.43 534.57 575.71 543.37 584.77 604.77
126.59 126.59 126.59 224.18 224.18 224.18 287.71 287.71 287.71 153.07 153.07 153.07 248.28 248.28 248.28 310.79 310.79 310.79 179.43 179.43 179.43 272.32 272.32 272.32 333.82 333.82 333.82
Table 4 Mean competition penalty for different values of s1, A1, and h2, given D ¼ 1,000, m1 ¼ 100, A2 ¼ 50, h1 ¼ 1, and b ¼ 10
A1 Mean (CP) h2 Mean (CP) s1 mean (CP)
C2 248.42 299.45 344.21 223.65 264.02 304.39 210.24 256.28 276.28 247.05 299.17 342.03 222.35 263.10 303.86 209.88 253.60 273.60 245.91 297.98 340.14 221.11 262.25 303.39 209.56 250.95 270.95
C 369.68 413.79 443.93 440.86 465.96 485.96 483.71 503.71 523.71 394.93 438.17 466.15 464.26 487.70 507.70 505.07 525.07 545.07 420.14 462.50 488.32 487.61 509.41 529.41 526.39 546.39 566.39
5 3.56% 0.5 1.93% 10 4.91%
C1 132.56 145.72 204.95 227.97 263.75 263.75 312.21 313.63 313.63 159.01 170.83 228.93 251.76 286.91 286.91 333.31 336.17 336.17 184.63 195.87 252.85 275.50 310.01 310.01 354.36 358.67 358.67
C2 236.36 268.07 238.98 212.89 202.21 222.21 170.08 190.08 210.08 235.92 267.34 237.22 212.49 200.80 220.80 168.90 188.90 208.90 235.51 266.63 235.47 212.12 199.40 219.40 167.73 187.73 207.73
20 5.00% 0.7 5.16% 20 4.83%
1.44 2.96 6.05 1.58 4.77 8.77 2.94 8.00 7.69 1.31 3.21 6.21 1.37 4.86 8.75 3.09 7.49 7.21 1.24 3.22 6.40 1.19 4.94 8.75 3.23 7.02 6.78
35 5.94% 0.9 7.40% 30 4.75%
and supplier’s ordering costs. Moreover, as ordering costs at both stages become similar, the competition penalty increases ceteris paribus, thus the possible benefit deriving from the adoption of the contract grows. Finally, keeping equal the ratios A1 =A2 and h2 =h1 , an increase in demand variability results in a CP slightly decreasing. However, it does not mean that the additional ordering contract
Coordination of the Supplier–Retailer Relationship in a Multi-period Setting
247
becomes ineffective or unnecessary: indeed, since the expected annual cost increase in demand variability, even if CP reduces the savings that can be obtained through the contract are significant. From Table 5, which gives the optimal values for q1 ; k; and n in both settings, we can see that in all the scenarios the optimal retailer’s order quantity is higher in the centralized policy than in the decentralized one. This justifies why the additional ordering cost contract has been designed so as to make the retailer increase her order quantity, by a penalty paid whenever she issues an order. Table 6 illustrates the value of a that allows the channel coordination be achieved in all the scenarios and the corresponding range for d where also the win–win condition is satisfied. In particular, below the minimum value of such an interval the contract is not convenient for the retailer (namely, it increases her expected cost compared to the decentralized setting), whereas above the maximum value it is not convenient for the supplier. Table 5 Optimal values for q1 ; k; and n in decentralized and centralized settings for different values of s1, A1, and h2, given D ¼ 1,000, m1 ¼ 100, A2 ¼ 50, h1 ¼ 1, and b. ¼ 10 A1 h2 Decentralized setting Centralized setting s1 10
5
20
35
20
5
20
35
30
5
20
35
0.5 0.7 0.9 0.5 0.7 0.9 0.5 0.7 0.9 0.5 0.7 0.9 0.5 0.7 0.9 0.5 0.7 0.9 0.5 0.7 0.9 0.5 0.7 0.9 0.5 0.7 0.9
qd1
kd
nd
q1
k
n
103.5 103.5 103.5 203.7 203.7 203.7 268.4 268.4 268.4 107.1 107.1 107.1 207.5 207.5 207.5 272.3 272.3 272.3 110.8 110.8 110.8 211.4 211.4 211.4 276.3 276.3 276.3
2.3136 2.3136 2.3136 2.0461 2.0461 2.0461 1.9294 1.9294 1.9294 2.3006 2.3006 2.3006 2.0385 2.0385 2.0385 1.9231 1.9231 1.9231 2.2876 2.2876 2.2876 2.0308 2.0308 2.0308 1.9168 1.9168 1.9168
4 4 3 2 2 2 2 1 1 4 4 3 2 2 2 2 1 1 4 3 3 2 2 2 2 1 1
149.0 190.0 335.6 247.5 378.2 378.2 416.4 416.4 416.4 150.8 192.2 339.6 250.0 382.3 382.3 420.5 420.5 420.5 152.6 194.4 343.7 252.6 386.4 386.4 424.7 424.7 424.7
2.1728 2.0748 1.8308 1.9643 1.7766 1.7766 1.7320 1.7320 1.7320 2.1680 2.0701 1.8255 1.9599 1.7716 1.7716 1.7273 1.7273 1.7273 2.1632 2.0654 1.8201 1.9555 1.7667 1.7667 1.7227 1.7227 1.7227
3 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 3 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 3 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1
248
N. Bellantuono et al.
Table 6 Optimal value for a and minimum and maximum value for d that let the additional ordering cost contract achieve channel coordination and win–win condition for different values of s1, A1, and h2, given D ¼ 1,000, m1 ¼ 100, A2 ¼ 50, h1 ¼ 1, and b ¼ 10 A1 h2 a dmin dmax s1 10 5 0.5 1.1253 0.0437 0.0498 0.7 2.4723 0.0842 0.0964 0.9 10.0000 0.2273 0.2542 20 0.5 0.4844 0.0429 0.0499 0.7 2.5000 0.1718 0.1940 0.9 2.5000 0.1718 0.2144 35 0.5 1.4286 0.1446 0.1602 0.7 1.4286 0.1460 0.1863 0.9 1.4286 0.1460 0.1863 20 5 0.5 1.0597 0.0411 0.0463 0.7 2.4137 0.0805 0.0946 0.9 10.0000 0.2231 0.2520 20 0.5 0.4685 0.0410 0.0473 0.7 2.5000 0.1694 0.1931 0.9 2.5000 0.1694 0.2139 35 0.5 1.4286 0.1414 0.1599 0.7 1.4286 0.1443 0.1836 0.9 1.4286 0.1443 0.1836 30 5 0.5 1.0040 0.0381 0.0433 0.7 2.3537 0.0770 0.0919 0.9 10.0000 0.2189 0.2501 20 0.5 0.4522 0.0390 0.0448 0.7 2.5000 0.1671 0.1922 0.9 2.5000 0.1671 0.2134 35 0.5 1.4286 0.1383 0.1596 0.7 1.4286 0.1426 0.1810 0.9 1.4286 0.1426 0.1810
6 Concluding Remarks This work has proposed an innovative contract to manage supplies in decentralized two-stage supply chains characterized by: random, independent demand and lead time; infinite planning horizon; continuous review of inventory; total backorder of the unmet demand. The contract is innovative because it takes into account ordering costs, which are usually neglected in the literature on multi-period supply contracts. It ensures both the system-wide efficiency and the win–win condition. Furthermore, the proposed contract is straightforward to be implemented, since it requires that the actors agree on two parameters only, which control how costs are split up among the actors. In particular, the contract is ruled by the parameter a, which is the penalty that the retailer imposes to the supplier for each order, and the parameter d, which specifies the discount per unit that the supplier grants to the retailer.
Coordination of the Supplier–Retailer Relationship in a Multi-period Setting
249
Finally, the contract has two interesting properties (1) the parameter a is enough to drive the system to efficiency; (2) the parameter d has a linear effect on the expected cost of each actor. As a result, each actor is able to assess the benefits that the contract provides not only to him/her but also to his/her counterpart. In this way typical cautious behaviour that characterize the negotiation phase on the contract parameters should be mitigated. We believe that there are several directions to which this field of study can be extended. Further research would be addressed to the application of the additional ordering cost contract to more complex supply chains: in particular, it can be interesting to analyze how to extend its application field to distribution supply chain, characterized by arborescent topologies, as well as to supply chains having more than two stages. Another possible extension of this research would consist in analyzing if the actors perceive as fair the agreement of the contract: to this aim the research could encompass both on field studies and laboratory experiments. Finally, the performance of contract can be compared to the ones assured by other coordination schemes. Acknowledgments This work has been supported by Regione Puglia (APQ PS025 - ICT supporting logistics services: a model of organized market).
Appendix: Proofs and Discussions Approximations in Equation (2) Two approximations are made in (2). They refer to the computations of the expected on hand inventory and the expected annual shortage, which respectively affect the expected annual inventory cost and backorder cost. We discuss both approximations in the followings. Let us denote the retailer’s lead time as L1 and the probability density function of the demand during L1 as f ðxjL1 Þ. By definition, the expected on hand inventory: OHðq1 ; r1 Þ ¼
q1 þ 2
ð r1
ðr1 xÞf ðxjL1 Þdx
(23)
0
is equal to the expected net inventory plus the expected backorder stock. However, if the backorder cost per unit is high, the expected backorder stock is negligible compared to the expected net inventory. Thus, the expected on hand inventory can be assumed equal to: NIðq1 ; r1 Þ ¼
q1 þ 2
ð þ1 0
ðr1 xÞf ðxjL1 Þdx ¼
q1 þ r 1 m1 : 2
(24)
250
N. Bellantuono et al.
If the demand during the retailer’s lead time is normally distributed, by recurring to the safety factor defined in (1), the expected net inventory can be also expressed as: NIðq1 ; kÞ ¼
q1 þ ks1 : 2
(25)
The expected annual shortage is equal to the number of replenishments per year ðD=qi Þ times the expected shortage per replenishment cycle ðkÞ. The approximation made in (2) consists in assuming that the latter is equal to the expected backorder stock when an order arrives, which is exact only if all backorders are satisfied within one cycle.
Proof of Equation (3) The expected shortage per replenishment cycle is: ðr1 Þ ¼
ð þ1
ðx r1 ÞfðxjL1 Þdx:
(26)
r1
By assuming the demand during the retailer’s lead time normally distributed, being z ¼ ðx m1 Þ=s1 and k as in (1), we obtain that x ¼ m1 þ s1 z and r1 ¼ m1 þ s1 k, and observe that dx ¼ s1 dz. Therefore, (26) becomes: ðkÞ ¼
ð þ1
s1 ðz kÞ’ðzÞdz ¼ s1 ½’ðkÞ þ kFðkÞ k:
(27)
k
Proof of Equations (4) and (5) To minimize (2), we impose the first order conditions: 8 @ D h1 D > > < 0 ¼ @q C1 ðq1 ; kÞ ¼ A1 q þ b q ðkÞ 2 1 1 1 ; > @ D > : 0 ¼ C1 ðq1 ; kÞ ¼ h1 s1 þ b s1 ½FðkÞ 1 @k q1
(28)
where we have observed that, in case of normally distributed demand, since: @’ðkÞ @ 1 k2 =2 p ffiffiffiffiffi ffi e ¼ k’ðkÞ; ¼ @k @k 2p
(29)
Coordination of the Supplier–Retailer Relationship in a Multi-period Setting
251
then: @ ðkÞ ¼ s1 ½FðkÞ 1: @k
(30)
Rearranging (28), both (4) and (5) derive.
Discussion on the Heuristics for the Centralized Setting The continuous relaxation of the problem consist in finding the minimum of the following equation: h i ~ 1 ; k; n~Þ ¼ A1 þ A2 þ bðkÞ D þ h1 q1 þ s1 k þ h2 n~ 1 q1 þ m1 : (31) Cðq q1 n~ 2 2 It is equal to (10) except for the variable n~, which is a positive real number instead of a positive integer as n. The first order condition consists in imposing that the first derivatives of (31) are null: @ ~ A2 D 1 Cðq1 ; k; n~Þ ¼ A1 þ þ bðkÞ 2 þ ½h1 þ ðn 1Þh2 0¼ @q1 n~ q1 2 0¼
(32)
@ ~ bD Cðq1 ; k; n~Þ ¼ h1 þ ½FðkÞ 1 @r1 q1
(33)
@ ~ A2 D h2 q1 Cðq1 ; k; n~Þ ¼ þ 2 @ n~ q1 n~2
(34)
0¼
which respectively result in (12)–(14). Rearranging (14) and combining it with (12), we obtain: sffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi A2 h1 h2 n~ ¼ : A1 þ bðkÞ h2
(35)
Assuming ðkÞ ¼ 0, from (35) we derive (11), which can be used as starting value for the heuristics. It can be observed that (11) is equal to the optimal choice for n in the continuous relaxation of the deterministic problem, as described in Silver et al. (1998). By recursively calculating (12)–(14), the optimal solution for the relaxed problem (31) is obtained. To derive the one for the original problem, as in De Bodt and Graves (1985) we conjecture that (10) is unimodal in q1 ðnÞ; k ðnÞ; n .
252
N. Bellantuono et al.
Proof of Proposition 1 The achievement of the channel coordination implies that the actors autonomously define their policies so as to allow the expected annual system-wide cost be minimized. By summing (17) and (18), it can be observed that the expected annual system-wide cost is the same as the one in default of the contract – see (10) – and does not depend on the contract parameters. Therefore, a sufficient condition is to assure that: qc1 ¼ q1 ;
(36)
k1c ¼ k1 ;
(37)
nc ¼ n :
(38)
and
To prove (37), it is enough to observe that (13) and (20) have the same analytical expression, and are identical if (36) holds. Moreover, combining (12) and (20), (36) can be written as: rffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi sffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi 2D 2D A2 c ½ð1 þ aÞA1 þ bðk Þ ¼ A1 þ þ bðk Þ : n h1 h1 þ ðn 1Þh2
(39)
When (20) holds, (39) can be rearranged so as to obtain (21). Once both (36) and (37) are satisfied, to obtain the channel coordination it is enough to choose nc so as to satisfy (38), too.
Proof of Proposition 2 The win–win condition is assured if each actor incurs lower cost under the contract setting than under the decentralized setting. Thus, it follows that:
Cc1 qc1 ; kc ; a; d C1 qd1 ; kd : Cc2 qc1 ; nc ; a; d C2 qd1 ; nd
(40)
Let us remember that, when the actors agree on the additional ordering cost contract, the expected annual retailer’s and supplier’s costs can be expressed in terms of the cost they sustain in default of the contract and the transfer payment, as shown in (17) and (18). Therefore, (40) can be written also as:
Coordination of the Supplier–Retailer Relationship in a Multi-period Setting
8 d d D > > < C1 q1 ; k dD þ aA1 q C1 q1 ; k 1 d d ; > D > : C2 q1 ; n þ dD aA1 C2 r1 ; n q1
253
(41)
which can be rearranged so as to obtain: C1 q1 ; k C1 qd1 ; kd C2 qd1 ; nd C2 q1 ; n aA1 aA1 þ d þ : q1 q1 D D
(42)
To prove that such a range for d is defined in a consistent domain, we consider the first and third members of (42), which can be rearranged to obtain: C1 q1 ; k þ C2 q1 ; n C1 qd1 ; kd þ C2 qd1 ; nd :
(43)
C q1 ; k ; n C qd1 ; kd ; nd :
(44)
which means:
The inequality above is always true by definition.
References Axs€ater S (1990) Simple solution procedures for a class of two echelon inventory problems. Oper Res 38(1):64–69 Axs€ater S (1993) Exact and approximate evaluation of batch-ordering policies for two level inventory systems. Oper Res 41(4):777–785 Axs€ater S, Rosling K (1993) Notes: installation vs. echelon stock policies for multilevel inventory control. Manage Sci 39(10):1274–1280 Cachon GP (2003) Supply chain coordination with contracts. In: Graves S, de Kok T (eds) Handbooks in operations research and management science: supply chain management. North-Holland, Amsterdam Cachon GP, Lariviere MA (1999) Capacity choice and allocation: strategic behaviour and supply chain performance. Manage Sci 45(8):1091–1108 Cachon GP, Lariviere MA (2005) Supply chain coordination with revenue sharing contracts: strength and limitations. Manage Sci 51(1):30–44 Cachon GP, Zipkin PH (1999) Competitive and cooperative inventory policies in a two stage supply chain. Manage Sci 45(7):936–953 Chen F (1999) Decentralized supply chains subject to information delays. Manage Sci 45(8): S221–S234 Christopher M (1992) Logistics and supply chain management. Pitman, London De Bodt MA, Graves SC (1985) Continuous review policies for a multi-echelon inventory problem with stochastic demand. Manage Sci 31(10):1286–1299 Emmons H, Gilbert S (1998) Return policies in pricing and inventory decision for catalogue goods. Manage Sci 44(2):276–283
254
N. Bellantuono et al.
Eppen GD, Iyer AV (1997) Backup agreements in fashion buying: the value of upstream flexibility. Manage Sci 43(11):1469–1484 Federgruen A (1993) Centralized planning models for multi-echelon inventory systems under uncertainty. In: Graves S, Rinnooy Kan A, Zipkin P (eds) Logistics of production and inventory. North Holland, Amsterdam, pp 133–173 Giannoccaro I, Pontrandolfo P (2004) Supply chain coordination by revenue sharing contracts. Int J Prod Econ 89:131–139 Hadley G, Whitin TM (1963) Analysis of inventory systems. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ Lee H, Padmanabhan V, Whang S (1997) Information distortion in a supply chain. The bullwhip effect. Manage Sci 43(4):546–558 Lee H, Whang S (1999) Decentralized multi-echelon supply chains: incentives and information. Manage Sci 45(5):633–639 Li J, Liu L (2006) Supply chain coordination with quantity discount policy. Int J Prod Econ 101:89–98 Mitra S, Chatterjee AK (2004) Echelon stock based continuous review (R, Q) policy for fast moving items. Omega 32:161–166 Monahan JP (1984) A quantitative discount pricing model to increase vendor profits. Manage Sci 30(6):720–726 Narayanan VG, Raman A (2004) Aligning incentives in supply chains. Harv Bus Rev 82 (11):94–102 Pasternack BA (1985) Optimal pricing and returns policies for perishable commodities. Mark Sci 4(2):166–176 Porteus E (2000) Responsibility tokens in supply chain management. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 2:203–219 Roundy R (1985) 98%-effective integer-ratio lot-sizing for one-warehouse multi-retailer systems. Manage Sci 31(11):1416–1430 Shang KH, Song JS (2003) Newsvendor bounds and heuristic for optimal policies in serial supply chains. Manage Sci 49(5):618–638 Schneeweiss C (2003) Distributed decision making – a unified approach. Eur J Oper Res 150:237–252 Schwarz LB, Schrage L (1975) Optimal and system myopic policies for multi-echelon production/ inventory systems. Manage Sci 21(11):1285–1294 Schweitzer ME, Cachon GP (2000) Decision bias in the newsvendor problem with a known demand distribution: experimental evidence. Manage Sci 46(3):404–420 Silver EA, Pyke DF, Peterson R (1998) Inventory management and production planning and scheduling. Wiley, New York Tang CS (2006) Perspectives in supply chain risk management. Int J Prod Econ 103(2):451–488 Tsay AA (1999) Quantity-flexibility contract and supplier–customer incentives. Manage Sci 45 (10):1339–1358 Tsay AA, Lovejoy WS (1999) Quantity flexibility contracts and supply chain performance. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 1(2):89–111 Tsay AA, Nahmias S, Agrawal N (1999) Modeling supply chain contracts: a review. In: Tayur S, Ganeshan R, Magazine M (eds) Quantitative models for supply chain. Kluwer, Norwell, MA, pp 299–336 Wadsworth GP (1959) Probability. In: Wadsworth GP (ed) Notes on operations research. Technology Press, Cambridge, MA Wang Q, Tsao D (2006) Supply contract with bidirectional options: the buyer’s perspective. Int J Prod Econ 101:30–52 Whang S (1995) Coordination in operations: a taxonomy. J Oper Manage 12:412–422
Use of Supply Chain Contract to Motivate Selling Effort Samar K. Mukhopadhyay and Xuemei Su
Abstract Selling of a product is often delegated by the Original Equipment Manufacturers (OEM) to another firm called sales agent. The OEM needs to devise a mechanism to motivate the agent to exert higher marketing effort in order to boost her sales revenue. She also needs to design a profit allocation scheme, a complex task because of the fact that she has incomplete information about the agent’s marketing cost. In this chapter, two important contract forms are analyzed, compared and the OEM’s strategy are developed. Closed form solutions have been derived for three decision variables: marketing effort, order quantity and retail price for both forms of contracts. The revelation principle has been applied in that derivation which find inefficiency and “distribution distortion” due to information asymmetry. We show that the two contract forms perform differently, and each party’s preference toward a particular contract form is linked with the total reservation profit level and/or the sales agent’s cost type. We find that full trading opportunity, as in the full information case, cannot be achieved by any of the two contracts and the OEM suffers due to information deficiency. The chapter also identifies guidelines for the OEM to exert higher control or be more flexible. Further research avenues are also identified. Keywords Distribution channel • Game theory • Retail contracts • Sales agent • Supply chain
S.K. Mukhopadhyay (*) Graduate School of Business, Sungkyunkwan University, Jongno-Gu, Seoul 110–745, South Korea e-mail: [email protected] X. Su College of Business Administration, California State University Long Beach, 1250 Bellflower Blvd, Long Beach, CA 90840, USA e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_11, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
255
256
S.K. Mukhopadhyay and X. Su
1 Introduction A common practice among Original Equipment Manufacturers (OEM) is to delegate the sales of the product to another firm variously called sales agent, franchisee, or sales representative. The motivation from the OEM’s point of view is to concentrate their effort to product design and manufacturing while leaving the sales and marketing to another firm with suitable expertise. This mode is one of the prominent methods in product distribution (Kaufmann and Dant 2001). This is especially true in global distribution when the OEM wants to introduce their products in foreign markets. In that situation, a local firm with its knowledge of local market would be invaluable and in some cases, inevitable. The sales agent provides services like presale advice, after sales service and advertising. These services are selling efforts that would enhance demand for the product. In the industrial goods market, this will also include customer information sessions, product demonstrations, trade shows and so on. It is, therefore, common for an OEM to use incentives to increase an agent’s effort (Lafontaine and Slade 1997). These incentives are formalized in sales contracts between the OEM and the sales agent. Two common types of contracts used in supply chain franchising are the Franchise Fee (FF) contract and the Retail Price Maintenance (RPM) contract. The FF contract is characterized by a variable wholesale price per unit and a fixed franchise fee. Thus, the FF contract is a two-part-tariff contract. The agent is free to set the retail price. When the RPM contract is employed, it is the OEM that sets the retail price and also the order quantity. Then a cost-plus payment from the agent to the OEM is specified. We study these two types of contracts in this chapter. Other forms of contracts that are used in a supply chain are revenue-sharing contract (Foros et al. 2009; Cachon and Lariviere 2005), quantity discounts contract (Raju and Zhang 2005), channel rebates contract (Taylor 2002), buy-back contract (Zhao et al. 2010), quantity flexibility contract (Krishnan et al. 2004; Tsay 1999) and optimal contracts via mechanism design (Laffont and Martimort 2000; Watson 2007). This chapter investigates how an OEM can use the FF and RPM contracts to motivate the sales agent to put in more efforts which in turn increases the demand for her product and thus her revenue. To design an effective contract, a number of parameters are needed to be specified. Note that the agent’s sales effort cannot be effectively monitored and therefore cannot be put in the contract as a parameter. We also recognize the fact that the agent’s cost of selling effort is only known to himself. So the OEM designs the contract without this information. We will devise the optimal contract design by the OEM under this information asymmetry and will identify the conditions under which one type of contract is preferred over the other. Our model includes “reservation profits” for both the OEM and the sales agent. The reservation profit of each party is the level of the profit they expect from their respective outside opportunities. The sales agent, therefore, would refuse to enter into a contract with the OEM if the expected profit under any contract is less than his reservation profit. The same is true for the OEM. As will be seen later, we
Use of Supply Chain Contract to Motivate Selling Effort
257
uncover an important role for the total of two reservation profits. We find that given the information asymmetry suffered by the OEM, her preference to one contract form or the other depends on the total reservation profits. Also, when the total is within certain ranges, the OEM has a dominant strategy because her preference does not depend on the agent’s cost. This book chapter is based on the authors’ original work of Mukhopadhyay et al. (2009). Some of the research work that studied contract design in the presence of an agent’s service effort are cited below. Desai and Srinivasan (1995) investigate a franchising channel where an informed principal (the contract designer) signals the market demand to an agent whose effort cannot be monitored. Unlike their paper, we assume that the contract designer is less informed and a screening game is played. Desiraju and Moorthy (1997) study how the requirements set by the manufacturer on retail price or service or both may improve the working of a distribution channel. The agent’s service is not contractible in our study. Blair and Lewis (1994) investigate optimal retail contracts that can be used by the manufacturer to encourage dealer promotion, and conclude that the optimal contract exhibits a form of resale price maintenance and quantity fixing. Our study develops new insights for helping an OEM to make a judicious choice between two contract forms under different conditions. Chen et al. (2010) study the coordination mechanism for the supply chain with leadtime consideration and price-dependent demand. Zhu and Mukhopadhyay (2009) study contract design in call-center outsourcing where the agent determines the service level. Dukes and Liu (2010) study the effects of retailer in-store media (ISM) on distribution channel relationships. They show that ISM is important in coordinating a distribution channel on advertising volume and product sales. Information asymmetry is considered in research by Gal-Or (1991). In that study the retailer has private information about demand and retailing cost. Buyer’s marginal cost is private information in the study by Ha (2001). Better information as value to the supplier is characterized by Corbett et al. (2004). Supplier’s cost is private information in Gan et al. (2005) who find that supply chain coordination can be achieved only when the supplier’s reservation profit decreases with production cost. Co-ordination can be achieved, as Krishnan et al. (2004) find, when buy backs can be combined with promotional cost-sharing agreements. In Cakanyildirim et al. (2008), production cost is private information. The retailer designs a menu of contracts specifying the order quality and profit percentage. Yang et al. (2009) study a manufacturer that faces a supplier privileged with private information about supply disruptions. Information asymmetry is also studied by Mukhopadhyay et al. (2008) and Su et al. (2010) in dual-channel distribution. Our study includes the effect of the OEM’s incentive to motivate the agent’s effort to increase sales. Agent compensation literature typically includes moral hazard (selling effort not observable to the firm) and adverse selection (the salesperson has superior information about the market prior to contracting with the firm). Kreps (1990) and Laffont and Martimort (2001) devise a menu of contracts offered to the agent as a typical solution to these types of problems. Laffont and Tirole (1986) and Gibbons (1987) show that in some cases a menu of linear contracts would be optimal. Chen (2005)
258
S.K. Mukhopadhyay and X. Su
studies Gonik’s (1978) scheme and compares it with a menu of linear contracts in a model where the market information possessed by the salesforce is important for the firm’s production and inventory-planning decisions. Ayra et al. (2009) study a Quasi-Robust multiagent model in which the mechanism must be designed before the environment is as well understood as is usually assumed. Wu et al. (2008) argue that people not only care about outcomes, but also about the process that produces these outcomes. They analytically show why fair process is not always used even though fair process enhances both employee motivation and performance. A comprehensive review of salesforce compensation problems can be found in Coughlan (1993). An emerging research stream studies contracting in a complex supply chain with multiple manufacturers and/or multiple retailers. Cui et al. (2008) proposes a trade promotion model that can price discriminate between a dominant retailer and small independents. Krishnan and Winter (2010) study a channel where a manufacturer distributes a product through retailers who compete on both price and fill rate. Cachon and Kok (2010) study a contracting scenario where multiple manufacturers compete for a retailer’s business, and conclude that the same contractual form can exhibit quite different properties from that seen in a one-manufacturer supply chain. Majumder and Srinivasan (2008) show that contract leadership, as well as the position in the supply chain network, affect the performance of the entire supply chain. This chapter is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces our model and derives contracts under full information. Section 3 derives the contracts under asymmetric information, compares the two forms of contracts and discusses the OEM’s strategies. Section 4 concludes the chapter including some avenues for the future research.
2 Contract Under Full Information Our supply chain consists of an OEM who sells her product through a sales agent. The sales agent uses a selling effort denoted by e aimed at increasing demand. We assume that the cost of exerting marketing effort is a convex, increasing function of e, say 12 ke2 . The constant k denotes the agent’s cost type and reflects how efficiently the agent conducts the marketing effort. The OEM’s unit production cost is s. The reservation profits of the OEM and the agent are pM and pR respectively. The reservation profits are lowest level of profits expected by the parties and represent the amount of profits that can be obtained from outside opportunities. Thus, neither party would enter the contract if the expected profit is below their respective reservation profit. The sales agent can choose to either sign the contract or reject it. Negotiation is not allowed. The demand function is: q ¼ a bp þ e
(1)
Where p is the retail price, a is the base demand that depends on factors not included in our model, and b is the sensitiveness of demand with respect to price.
Use of Supply Chain Contract to Motivate Selling Effort
259
Notice that the sales effort e positively impacts the demand. a and b are constants and common knowledge. The linear demand function is widely used in the literature (Desiraju and Moorthy 1997; Lal 1990; Gal-Or 1991).
2.1
The FF and RPM Contracts
In this subsection, we will model the two types of contracts. 2.1.1
FF Contract
In the Franchise Fee (FF) contract, the OEM specifies the unit wholesale price w and a fixed fee L, paid by the agent. Wimmer and Garen (1997) and Federal Trade Commission’s Guide (2005) gives a comprehensive guide of franchising and its fees. L can possibly be negative in which case it is the OEM who makes the payment to the agent, presumably to subsidize the agent’s marketing effort. Positive L, though, is more common. The agent’s total payment to the OEM is wq + L for an order quality q. The OEM’s profit is, pM ¼ ðw sÞq þ L
(2)
1 pR ¼ ðp wÞq ke2 L 2
(3)
The agent’s profit is,
2.1.2
RPM Contract
In Retail Price Maintenance (RPM) Contract, the OEM specifies the retail price. These types of contracts are widely adopted in practice, for example, in the fashion and luxury goods industry, companies such as Gucci set the retail price of their goods for sale through both vertically integrated and independent retailers. Nike requires its retailers to not sell their shoes below a suggested retail price (Gurnani and Xu 2006). RPM contracts are characterized by three parameters: the retail price p, the order quantity q, and a cost plus payment amount R. Thus the total payment to OEM is s q þ R, where s q covers the OEM’s total production cost, and R is her profit. If the agent decides to accept the contract, each party’s profit is pM ¼ R
(4)
1 pR ¼ pq ke2 sq R 2
(5)
260
2.2
S.K. Mukhopadhyay and X. Su
The Full Information Case
In this section, we derive the optimal contract under full information. Here, the agent’s cost type k is common knowledge. The OEM maximizes her profit by maximizing the total channel profit and letting the agent earn his reservation profit pR , thereby extracting the rest of the channel profit for herself. The joint profit maximization function is: 1 Max pT ðp; q; e; kÞ ¼ ðp sÞq ke2 p;q;e 2
(6)
Equation (6) is maximized to obtain the optimum values of the decision variables as follows: e ¼
ða bsÞ ; 2bk 1
q ¼
bkða bsÞ ; 2bk 1
p ¼
kða þ bsÞ s ; 2bk 1
pT ¼
kða bsÞ2 2ð2bk 1Þ
These optimum values are the “first best” solutions, because other solutions, due to information asymmetry, would be inferior to these solutions. With full information, the OEM can maximize the channel profit by specifying that the sales agent adopt the fist-best solutions for marketing effort level, sales level and retail price. Then, the OEM can extract the whole channel profit by specifying L (in case of FF contract) or R (in case of RPM contract). It is intuitive that these first best solutions are all decreasing in k. This means that a cost-inefficient agent cannot provide optimal marketing effort, leading to optimal sales, and costumers would not likely pay a high price for a low service level. An inefficient sales agent, therefore, brings sluggish channel profit. Obviously, the two parties will enter into a contract only if pM þ pR pT , which mandates that the agent’s cost type k bT . bT , a threshold value, is called the cutoff point, and is derived as: bT ¼
2ðpM þ pR Þ 4bðpM þ pR Þ ða bsÞ2
We will use, “1” and “2” as subscripts or superscripts to represent FF contract and RPM contract respectively. Table 1 shows the solutions for both contract forms. Table 1 Equilibrium results under complete information
FF contract w¼s L ¼ pT pR b1 ¼ bT pT pR if k bT p1M ¼ pM if bT k p1R ¼ pR
RPM contract p2 ¼ p ; q2 ¼ q R ¼ pT pR b2 ¼ bT pT pR if k bT p2M ¼ pM if bT k p2R ¼ pR
Use of Supply Chain Contract to Motivate Selling Effort
261
3 The Asymmetric Information Case In this section, we consider the problem of contract design when k is unknown to the OEM. She only has a prior knowledge that k is somewhere within the range [k; k], with a distribution denoted by FðkÞ. f ðkÞ is the probability density function. Without knowing the exact value of k, the OEM has no way of determining optimal values of the parameters w, L, and R. In these cases, it is customary to offer a “menu” of contracts. This menu is a set of options for the agent to choose from based on his cost type k, known only to himself.
3.1
FF Contract Menu
The OEM’s menu of contracts consists of a number of tuples {w(k),L(k)}, each item consisting of parameters w and L for a given value of k. By virtue of the “revelation principle” (Myerson 1979), the OEM hopes that the agent would declare the true value of k because the menu is designed in such a way that a truthful revelation of the information would yield highest profit for the agent. Define pR ðk~jkÞ as the profit ~ LðkÞg ~ from the of an agent who is of a cost type k and chooses a contract fwðkÞ; menu. The agent solves the problem: ~ wðkÞÞ ~ q/ ðwðkÞÞ ~ 1 k e/ ðwðkÞÞ ~ 2 LðkÞ ~ R1 : Max pR ðk~jkÞ :¼ ðp/ ðwðkÞÞ 2 k~ ~ 2 kða bwðkÞÞ ~ ¼ LðkÞ 2ð2kb 1Þ Where “k” is the true cost type, and k~ is the announced cost type by the agent. ~ as obtained by using the First p ; q/ and e/ are the agent’s best responses to wðkÞ Order Condition (FOC) on (3). Revelation principle requires that pR ðk~jkÞ be concave in k~ and achieves the maximum at k~ ¼ k. Only then it will be to the agent’s interest to reveal k. Depending on the range of k and the value of b, some common types of distributions like uniform, beta and truncated normal meet this requirement. We, therefore, can write the OEM’s problem as /
ð b1 M1 Max
wðkÞ;LðkÞ
k
pM ðk; qðkÞÞf ðkÞdk þ
ðk b1
pM f ðkÞdk
(7)
S:t: IC : qðkÞ ¼ arg max pR ðk; qÞ
(8)
1 IR : pR ðk; qðkÞÞ ¼ ðp wðkÞÞqðkÞ ke2 LðkÞ pR 2
(9)
262
S.K. Mukhopadhyay and X. Su
pM ðk; qðkÞÞ ¼ ðwðkÞ sÞqðkÞ þ LðkÞ
(10)
The OEM profit in (7) depends on the quantity q ordered by the agent, which in turn depends on the agent’s cost type k. Constraint (8) is called the agent’s “Incentive-Compatibility” constraint. This constraint ensures that, an agent with cost type k will choose q to maximize its profit. Constraint (9) represents the agent’s “Individual Rationality” constraint. This states that the agent’s profit must be no less than his reservation profit pR for him to agree to trade. The quantity b1 in the objective function (7) is a value of k 2 ½k; k, such that when k ¼ b1 either of the two parties hits their respective reservation profit. Therefore, for the values k > b1 , no contract is signed between the two parties and the OEM would earn her reservation profit (pM ) elsewhere. As pM is a decreasing function of k (see Corollary 1c,) we would have pM ðk; qðkÞÞ pM for k b1 . The formulation given in (7) through (10) fits the optimal control formulation with variable endpoint conditions and salvage value (see Kamien and Schwartz 1981, pp. 143–148). We use the methodology therein to solve the problem M1 . The solution to this problem is given in proposition 1. Proofs of all propositions, unless otherwise stated, are given in the Appendix. We use the notation x?½l; u :¼ max fl; min fx; ugg as the projection of x on the interval [l; u]. Proposition 1. Under asymmetric information the optimal values of the OEM’s parameters in the franchise fee contract is given by: w¼sþ
ða bsÞFðkÞ bFðkÞ þ bkð2bk 1Þf ðkÞ
L(k) is given by the solution of @L bk2 ða bsÞf ðkÞ @w ¼ @k FðkÞ þ kð2bk 1Þf ðkÞ @k Lðb1 Þ
satisfies
Lðb1 Þ ¼ pM
8k k b1
ða bsÞ2 b21 Fðb1 Þf ðb1 Þ 2ðFðb1 Þ þ b1 ð2bb1 1Þf ðb1 ÞÞ2
The resulting cutoff point is given by b1 ¼ b0 ?½k; k where b0 is the solution of: 2ðpM þ pR Þ b2 f ðbÞ ¼ FðbÞ þ bð2bb 1Þf ðbÞ ða bsÞ2 The second column of Table 2 gives a summary of equilibrium results for FF contract. Corollary 1 summarizes major properties of the equilibrium results.
Use of Supply Chain Contract to Motivate Selling Effort
263
Corollary 1. Under the FF contract with asymmetric information, (a) As k increases, w increases, and L decreases (b) At equilibrium, e1 ; q1 and p1 are all decreasing in k, and e1 < e ; q1 < q ; p1 > p , for any k 2 ðk; k. (c) pM ðkÞ and pR ðkÞ are decreasing in k, until the cutoff point b1 ; where b1 bT . (d) For any k 6¼ k, the agent’s profit is higher and the OEM’s profit is lower compared to their counterparts under full information. Total channel profit is lower than that under full information. We observe the following from Corollary 1. A higher fixed fee is associated with a lower unit wholesale price and vice versa. As seen in Fig. 1. As also reported by Wimmer and Garen (1997), factors that increase the franchisee’s effort (e here), would lower the recurring fee (w here), and increase the franchise fee (L here). The insight here is that a cost-efficient sales agent (with low k) will enjoy a discounted wholesale price, would exert higher marketing effort to gain higher demand, and can charge customers a higher price. All of these actions would contribute to higher profits for both the OEM and the agent. This is an important finding of this chapter. We also see that the cut-off point, if it exists, is unique. It is possible for the franchise fee to go negative for a high cost type agent. In that case, the “franchise fee” is from the OEM to the sales agent meaning that the OEM subsidizes an inefficient sales agent, or simply because the effort required is costly, and the OEM offers to cover part of the investment. Proposition 1 requires the revelation principle to work. The design of the menu of contract must ensure that w is increasing in k, and L is decreasing in k. This will make w > s (the production cost), giving rise to the double marginalization problem. This double marginalization phenomenon was first identified by Spengler (1950). In our case, double marginalization is reflected as higher retail price, lower 250
L
200
150
100
50
0 2.00
2.17
2.35
2.52
2.69
2.87 k
Fig. 1 Optimal w and L for varying k
3.04
3.21
3.39
3.56
w
264
S.K. Mukhopadhyay and X. Su
Table 2 Results of FF and RPM contracts under asymmetric information FF contract: fwðkÞ; LðkÞg Unit transfer price Retail price Marketing effort Sales Total channel profit
RPM contract: fpðkÞ; qðkÞ; RðkÞg
ða bsÞFðkÞ bFðkÞ þ bkð2bk 1Þf ðkÞ ða bsÞðFðkÞ þ bk2 f ðkÞÞ p1 ¼ s þ bFðkÞ þ bkð2bk 1Þf ðkÞ ða bsÞkf ðkÞ e1 ¼ FðkÞ þ kð2bk 1Þf ðkÞ ða bsÞbk2 f ðkÞ q1 ¼ FðkÞ þ kð2bk 1Þf ðkÞ
sþ
p1T ¼
s ða bsÞðFðkÞ þ kf ðkÞÞ 2bðFðkÞ þ kf ðkÞÞ f ðkÞ ða bsÞf ðkÞ e2 ¼ 2bðFðkÞ þ kf ðkÞÞ f ðkÞ ða bsÞbðFðkÞ þ kf ðkÞÞ q2 ¼ 2bðFðkÞ þ kf ðkÞÞ f ðkÞ p2 ¼ s þ
ða bsÞ2 k2 f ðkÞð2FðkÞ þ kð2bk 1Þf ðkÞÞ 2ðFðkÞ þ kð2bk 1Þf ðkÞÞ
2
p2T ¼
ða bsÞ2 ðFðkÞ þ kf ðkÞÞ 4bðFðkÞ þ kf ðkÞÞ 2f ðkÞ
ða bsÞ2 ðk þ zðkÞÞ 4bðk þ zðkÞÞ 2 ð 1 k ða bsÞ2 dx pR 2 k ð2bðx þ zðxÞÞ 1Þ2 ðk 1 ða bsÞ2 p2R ¼ pR þ dx 2 k ð2bðx þ zðxÞÞ 1Þ2 p2M ¼
Profit of the OEM
p1M ¼
Profit of the sales agent p1R ¼
ða bsÞ2 k2 FðkÞf ðkÞ ðFðkÞ þ kð2bk 1Þ f ðkÞÞ2 2 3
ða bsÞ k ð2bk 1Þ f ðkÞ
þL
2
2ðFðkÞ þ kð2bk 1Þ f ðkÞÞ2
L
sales, and less marketing effort compared to the first-best. The inefficiency caused by information asymmetry is further reflected on the cutoff point. Since b1 bT , the FF contract cannot fully explore all the trading opportunities as presented under the full information case. Part (d) of the corollary shows that the OEM is worse off and the sales agent is better off under asymmetric information. This phenomenon is called information rent, that is, the benefit earned due to holding private information. To visualize this, we use the results in the Table 2 to draw Fig. 2, to show the variation of p1M pM ; p1R pR and p1T pT with respect to k respectively. Of these values, p1R pR measures the information rent. As we can see from Fig. 2, the lower the cost type, the higher the information rent. Gal-Or (1991) refers to this as a “distributional distortion”, since it relates to the distribution of the surplus between the OEM and the agent. Obviously, the channel as a whole is worse off compared to the full information case. Figure 2 shows that p1T pT is negative and decrease as k increases, but almost close to zero, which means the channel’s profit loss due to information asymmetry is trivial. We will further discuss it in Sect. 3.3.
3.2
The RPM Contract Menu
In the RPM contract, the menu consists of a tuple fpðkÞ; qðkÞ; RðkÞg. Each item on the menu is intended for an agent of a specific cost type. The profit of the agent of cost type k declaring a cost type k~ is given by ~ sÞ qðkÞ ~ 1 keðkÞ ~ ¼ pT ðpðkÞ; ~ qðkÞ; ~ kÞ RðkÞ ~ ~ 2 RðkÞ pR ðk~jkÞ ¼ ðpðkÞ 2
Use of Supply Chain Contract to Motivate Selling Effort
265
250 200 150 100 50 0 2.00 -50
2.17
2.35
2.52
2.69
2.87 k
3.04
3.21
3.39
3.56
-100 -150 -200 Series 2
-250
Series 1
Series 3
Fig. 2 Information rent under FF contract1
Where pT is defined in function (6). The OEM’s problem M2 of designing the optimal contract is: ð b2 M2
max
pðkÞ;qðkÞ;RðkÞ
RðkÞf ðkÞdk þ
k
ðk b2
pM f ðkÞdk
~ pR ðkjkÞ ~ S:t: pR ðkÞ pR ðk~jkÞ and pR ðkÞ
(11)
k k; k~ k;
pR ðkÞ pR qðkÞ 0 Lemma 1 provides a characterization of problem M2, to be used for deriving the optimal contract menu. Lemma 1. A solution fpðkÞ; qðkÞ; RðkÞg is feasible for problem ðM2 Þ if and only if Rk (a) pR ðkÞ ¼ pR þ 12 k eðxÞ2 dx (b) eðkÞ is decreasing in k (c) qðkÞ 0 The design problem M2 can then be reformulated as: ðk max
pðkÞ;qðkÞ0
k
ðpT ðpðkÞ; qðkÞ; kÞ
zðkÞ eðkÞ2 ÞdFðkÞ 2
Data series 1, 2, 3 denote p1M pM ; p1R pR and p1T pT respectively.
1
(12)
266
S.K. Mukhopadhyay and X. Su
We need two constraints: (1) qðkÞ is nonnegative and (2) eðkÞ is decreasing in k (Proof is provided in the Appendix). zðkÞ is defined as zðkÞ ¼ FðkÞ=f ðkÞ. If we ignore the feasibility requirements, we can maximize the integrand in function (12) for each k like in (6) with a cost factor k þ zðkÞ for the agent. So, we substitute pðkÞ ¼ p ðk þ zðkÞÞ and qðkÞ ¼ q ðk þ zðkÞÞ where p and q are the first-best solutions. To have a feasible solution, we need eðk þ zðkÞÞ to be decreasing in k and zðkÞ ¼ FðkÞ=f ðkÞ increasing in k. We now consider the contract menu ^ k k kg with f^ pðkÞ; q^ðkÞ; RðkÞ q^ðkÞ ¼ q ðk þ zðkÞÞ p^ðkÞ ¼ p ðk þ zðkÞÞ 1 ^ ¼ pT ð^ pðkÞ; q^ðkÞ; kÞ RðkÞ 2
ðk k
e^ðxÞ2 dx pR
The optimal solutions are shown in Proposition 2. Proposition 2. If zðxÞ ¼ FðxÞ=f ðxÞis increasing in x, ^ (a) f^ pðkÞ; q^ðkÞ; RðkÞg is the optimal solution to M2 ^ðkÞs (b) p^ðkÞ; q^ðkÞ; and e^ðkÞ, are all decreasing in k, and e^ðkÞ ¼ pkþzðkÞ < e ðkÞ; q^ðkÞ < q ðkÞ; p^ðkÞ < p ðkÞ for any k 2 ðk; k (c) pM ðkÞ and pR ðkÞ are decreasing in k until the cutoff point. (d) The agent’s profit is higher and the OEM’s profit is lower compared to their counterparts under full information. Total supply chain profit is lower than that under full information. (e) The cutoff point b2 ¼ b0 ?½k; k where b0 is the solution of: b þ zðbÞ 2bðb þ zðbÞÞ 1
ðk b
dx ð2bðx þ zðxÞÞ 1Þ
2
¼
2ðpM þ pR Þ ða bsÞ2
The results are shown in the third column of Table 2. Under RPM contract, the OEM makes all the decisions using a cost factor of k þ zðkÞ instead of k. Compared to the first best solution, the OEM is worse off and the agent is better off; the agent orders less and exerts less marketing effort; and the retail price is lower. The channel as a whole is also worse off, for every cost type k. We show the variation of p2M pM , p2T pT and p2R pR with respect to k in Fig. 3. Like earlier, the information rent decreases with the agent’s cost type k. Both parties’ profits and the total channel profit are monotonically decreasing in k till k ¼ b2 . The cutoff point b2 bT . This shows that the RPM contract cannot fully explore all the trading opportunities compared to the full information case. There are two insights from the monotonic property: a low cost type agent benefits both the agent and the OEM, and therefore the channel; and, that the cutoff point is unique.
Use of Supply Chain Contract to Motivate Selling Effort
267
60
40
20
0 2.00
2.17
2.35
2.52
2.69
2.87 k
3.04
3.21
3.39
3.56
-20
-40
-60
Series1
Series2
Series3
Fig. 3 Information rent under RPM contract2
3.3
FF and RPM Contracts Compared
In the above analysis, we found that, under information asymmetry, both FF and RPM contract forms induce less marketing effort provisions, realize less sales, and generate lower channel profit compared to the full information case. Also, neither contract explores all the trading opportunities. Under full information, the trade stops only when both are earning no more than their respective reservation profits. However, under asymmetric information, the trade stops as soon as either party hits their respective reservation profit first. We will now compare these two contract forms, using subscripts 1 and 2 to denote the result of FF and RPM contracts respectively. Also, to simplify notations we use p2 ; q2 , and e2 for the RPM contract, instead of p^ðkÞ; q^ðkÞ; and e^ðkÞ respectively. The comprehensive comparison of the two forms of contracts is given in Corollary 2, while Fig. 4 shows a visual portray. Corollary 2. (a) Marketing level comparison: e e1 e2 . FF Contracts exerts more marketing effort than RPM contracts and both are less than the first best effort. (b) Price comparison: p1 p p2 . Price is highest in FF contract. RPM contract price is lower than the first best price. (c) Sales level comparison: q q2 q1 . FF sales level is lowest of all. First best sales level is highest. Data series 1, 2, 3 denote p2M pM ; p2R pR and p2T pT respectively.
2
268
S.K. Mukhopadhyay and X. Su
50
p1
e1
q1
p2
e2
q2
45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 2.00
2.17
2.35
2.52
2.69
2.87 k
3.04
3.21
3.39
3.56
Fig. 4 Optimal p, e and q for two contract forms
The equalities only hold when k ¼ k. An agent with a cost type k 6¼ k, given an FF contract, will price the product higher, provide higher marketing effort, but sell less compared to when given a RPM contract. Some more observations follow. 1. The FF contract provides a better mechanism to motivate marketing effort provisions. The sales agent is free to choose the marketing effort level and set the retail price. This flexibility motivates him to exert more marketing effort compared to that of an RPM contract, and enables him to charge higher retail price. This flexibility becomes even more critical when the agent is of a high cost type. Recall that, in the RPM contract, the OEM specifies that e2 ðkÞ ¼ e ðk þ zðkÞÞ which is greatly distorted down from the first-best level when k is high because zðkÞ increases in k and e decreases in k. In the FF contract, it is true that a high cost type agent will face a high unit wholesale price, but the detrimental effect of the increase in unit wholesale price is softened when the increase in the unit wholesale price is combined with the offer of a more dramatic decrease in franchise fee. As a result, the agent still has the room to exert reasonable level of marketing effort. The decrease in marketing effort is not seen as dramatic as it is in the RPM contract. Relatively speaking, FF contract provides the agent higherpowered incentives. 2. It is notable that higher retail price in an FF contract results from not only the higher marketing effort as seen above but also from “double marginalization”. The double marginalization hurts the channel profit and the OEM’s profit as well. In contrast, double marginalization is avoided in the RPM contract because the OEM acts like a central planner and dictates a retail price and order quantity to the agent. However, with incomplete information, this centralized decision is
Use of Supply Chain Contract to Motivate Selling Effort
269
not trouble free. With RPM contract, both the retail price and the marketing effort level are distorted down from the first-best solutions ðp2 < p and e2 < e Þ for inducing truthful information reporting. These distortions hurt the channel profit too. Further discussions will follow Corollary 3. 3. It seems counter-intuitive that the FF contract realizes lower sales level with more marketing effort compared to the RPM contract. The high retail price in the FF contract will shed light on this. It is to the benefit of the agent to increase profit through pricing higher, instead of selling more units under the FF contract. There are two reasons for this. One is that customers would like to pay higher price given better services. The other is the sales agent finds it harder to induce more demand through price cut, which is limited by the double marginalization problem. Next, we examine the effect on the channel profit for each of the two contract forms. Corollary 3 summarizes the results and Fig. 5 visually depicts the channel profit under each of the two contract forms. Corollary 3. With information asymmetry, the total channel profit for each contract form is equal at k ¼ k, and decreases monotonically with k. For any k > k, the total channel profit of an FF contract is higher than that of the RPM contract. The difference in channel profit increases as k increases. Note that the conclusion drawn in Corollary 3 is based on the assumptions presented earlier in Sects. 3.1 and 3.2. Those assumptions guarantee that the profit functions are concave and revelation principle can be applied. Corollary 3 shows that for any cost type k, the RPM contract generates less channel profit and this worsens when the agent is of a high cost type. This is because the way the RPM contract is designed. In a RPM contract, the OEM acts like a central planner and directly specifies the agent’s order quantity and retail price. The marketing effort
Profit--FF
Profit--RPM
500
450
400
350 2.00
2.17
2.35
2.52
2.69
2.87 k
3.04
Fig. 5 Channel profits under FF contract and RPM contract
3.21
3.39
3.56
270
S.K. Mukhopadhyay and X. Su
level is indirectly specified by the OEM through specifying order quantity and retail price according to (1). However, with asymmetric information, this tight control comes with a cost. It requires distorting price, output and marketing effort level to induce the agent’s truthful information reporting. Specifically, q^ðkÞ ¼ q ðk þ zðkÞÞ; p^ðkÞ ¼ p ðk þ zðkÞÞ; and e^ðkÞ ¼ e ðk þ zðkÞÞ. Note that q ; p and e are decreasing in k, and zðkÞ is increasing in k. As a result, e^ðkÞ, q^ðkÞ and p^ðkÞ will be quite off the first-best solutions of e ðkÞ, q ðkÞ and p ðkÞ if the agent is of a high cost type. As a result, the channel profit will be greatly reduced. Figure 3 displays that the channel profit loss, p2T pT ; is substantial when the agent is of a high cost type. By comparing Fig. 2 with Fig. 3, we can see that the channel profit loss is minimal with the FF contract. We do recognize that the channel profit gets hurt as double marginalization problem is introduced into the design of the FF contract. But because the agent has the freedom to choose its retail price, the agent has the motivation to exert more marketing effort so as to charge customers a higher price. In addition, due to the arrangement that the fixed fee charge decreases as the agent’ cost type k increases, even a high cost type retailer is encouraged to exert a reasonable amount of marketing effort. With this flexibility in design, the FF contract can better align the agent’s interests with that of the channel.
3.4
Profit Allocation Mechanisms and the OEM’s Strategy
We treat the allocation of channel profit as a two-phase process. Note that no matter which contract form is offered, each party has to get at least their reservation profit before they would enter a contract. First, each party takes their reservation profit (pM or pR ) out of the total channel profit; Second, the two parties share the rest of the channel profit, the allocation of which is dependent on the contract form. This profit allocation mechanism in FF contract is analytically complex. We do the analysis for the RPM contract. The term “allocable profit” is defined as the profit in excess of the total of reservation profits i.e. Allocable profit ¼ total channel profit ðpM þ pR Þ The optimal strategy for contract offering is guided by the value of the allocable profit and, therefore, the total reservation profit. This observation is one of the main contributions of this chapter. Recall that the agent’s profit under the RPM contract is, 1 pR ðkÞ ¼ pR þ 2
ðk
eðxÞ2 dx ðLemma 1ðaÞÞ
(13)
k
Ðk Then the agent’s marginal utility from entering the RPM contract is 12 k eðxÞ2 dx. For a particular k, the realized total channel profit is fixed (refer to Table 2), and the
Use of Supply Chain Contract to Motivate Selling Effort
271
Ðk agent’s share of the allocable profit, 12 k eðxÞ2 dx, is also a fixed amount. If pM þ pR is small, the allocable profit is large and the OEM’s share of allocable profit will be large by restricting the agent’s share. Therefore, the RPM contract is favorable to the OEM. When pMÐ þ pR is large, the allocable profit is small. But the OEM still k has to allocate 12 k eðxÞ2 dx to the agent. This makes the RPM contract less attractive to the OEM. We now study the question of what contract the OEM would prefer based on an agent’ cost type for a fixed pM þ pR . For a low k, the realized channel profit, and hence the allocable profit would be large. The agent would benefit because equilibrium eðkÞ is larger for a smaller k, and the agent’s share of allocable profit is higher according to (13). But as the allocable profit generated by this cost efficient agent is large, the OEM may benefit even more. Thus, the RPM contract is favorable to the OEM when k is small, and becomes less attractive when k is large. However, this discussion holds only when pM þ pR is moderately small. If pM þ pR is very large, the allocable profit is very small, leaving the OEM almost nothing even with a cost efficient agent. This is summarized below. Observation 1. For a given combination of ðpM þ pR ; kÞ, where k is a value below cutoff points, and for a large allocable profit, the profit allocation mechanism of a RPM contract is favorable to the OEM. The OEM should offer RPM contract to the agent. For small allocable profits, the OEM should offer FF contract to the agent. When k is high enough so that either b1 or b2 comes into play, the monotonic property of either party’s profit with respect to k will be interrupted. Each party’s preference toward a certain contract type may change accordingly. Figure 6 summarizes the impact of cutoff points, pM þ pR and k on the OEM’s choice of a certain contract form. Figure 6 depicts the OEM’s preferred contract forms as a function of pM þ pR . It plots the tracks of kM , b1 and b2 where kM is a possible cost type of the agent, at which the OEM switches its preference between the two contract forms. Below kM , the combinations of ðpM þ pR ; kÞ result in adequate allocable profit, which makes the RPM contract attractive to the OEM. Above the tracks of b1 and b2 , no trading is possible either because the total reservation profit is too high, or because the agent is too inefficient, or both. For the combinations of ðpM þ pR ; kÞ which are between the tracks kM and b1 , the FF contract is more attractive to the OEM. For the small area above the track of b1 but below the track of b2 , the OEM prefers RPM contract because no trading is possible for FF contract.
3.5
The OEM’s Dominant Strategy
The OEM’s choice of a certain contract form are dependent on the different combinations of ðpM þ pR ; kÞ and the cutoff points. However, the OEM does not know the agent’s cost type k at the time of deciding about the contract form. Recall the sequence of events. First, the OEM chooses a contract form, FF or RPM.
272
S.K. Mukhopadhyay and X. Su
pM + pR
Z
hY,Z
Y
hX,Y
X k
k increase
k
k
Preference is RPM contract
Track of kM
Preference is FF contract
Track of b1
Indifferent between the two contract forms
Track of b2
Fig. 6 The OEM’s preferred contract form
Second, for the selected contract form, the OEM provides a menu of contracts, each of which is intended for an agent of a particular cost type k. Finally, k is revealed when the agent selects one contract from that menu. It would, therefore, be practically meaningful to investigate if the OEM can make a choice between the two contract forms before knowing the agent’s cost type k. Noting that the total reservation profit pM þ pR is common knowledge, the area in Fig. 6 is divided into three regions X; Y and Z with two thresholds of X;Y and Y;Z . The threshold X;Y is the value of pM þ pR where kM ¼ k and Y;Z is the value of pM þ pR where kM ¼ k. The values of X;Y and Y;Z can be uniquely determined and X;Y < Y;Z . Proposition 3 summarizes the OEM’s dominant strategy. Proposition 3. If pM þ pR X;Y , the OEM prefers the RPM contract regardless of the value of k; If pM þ pR Y;Z , the OEM prefers the FF contract or no contract, regardless of the value of k. Proposition 3 provides some clear cut strategies for the OEM even when the agent’s marketing cost information is not known. For moderate level of total
Use of Supply Chain Contract to Motivate Selling Effort
273
reservation profit, i.e., X;Y < pM þ pR Y;Z the OEM’s optimal strategy depends on the unknown k, so any choice has some risks.
4 Conclusion and Further Research When an OEM is dependent on the sales agent for the marketing of her product, she needs to devise a mechanism to motivate the agent to exert higher marketing effort in order to boost her sales revenue. She also needs to design a profit allocation scheme, a complex task because of the fact that she has incomplete information about the agent’s marketing cost. In this chapter, two important contract forms are analyzed, compared and the OEM’s strategy are developed. Closed form solutions have been derived for three decision variables: marketing effort, order quantity and retail price for both forms of contracts. The revelation principle has been applied in that derivation which find inefficiency and “distribution distortion” due to information asymmetry. Full trading opportunity, as in the full information case, cannot be achieved by any of the two contracts and the OEM suffers due to information deficiency. The operational differences of the two contract forms and marginal guidelines are fully identified in this chapter. For example, the FF contract motivates more marketing effort and generates more channel profit. This chapter identifies the role of total reservation profit for selecting a suitable contract form. Figure 6 highlights the guidelines in selecting a contract form for varying k and different values of the total reservation profit. It also identifies ranges where the OEM’s strategy, surprisingly, does not depend on the value of k, thereby making the lack of cost information irrelevant. Double marginalization is a concern in supply chain coordination literature. This chapter finds some further insight into the problem. It is present in the FF contract, but not in the RPM contract. But, it has been proved that, in FF contract, channel profit is always higher, and so is the OEM’s profit under certain conditions. Therefore, double marginalization need not to be viewed as detrimental. As per the RPM contract is concerned, the OEM has higher control of even determining the agent’s order quantity and retail price. But it still does not guarantee higher profit for her – a fact that is counter intuitive. In this form of contract, larger value of k results in reduced channel profit and the allocable profit, and it hurts the OEM more than the agent. The chapter identifies guidelines for the OEM to exert higher control or to be more flexible. We now identify avenues for further research. We have identified regions in Fig. 6 where the OEM’s choice is not clear cut and a risk is involved in selecting a contract form. A coordination plan can be developed for such cases. Two possible directions could be to devise an incentive plan for the agent to divulge private information, and to offer both contract forms with the provision of compensation for the OEM. Contract forms, other than the two studied here, can also be examined and designed. A further research area will be examining multiple agents.
274
S.K. Mukhopadhyay and X. Su
Appendix Proof of Proposition 1 We can rewrite the OEM’s problem as, bð1
M1
mðkÞdk þ Fðb1 Þ
Max
wðkÞ;LðkÞ;b1 k
s:t: L ðkÞ ¼ g1 ðkÞ w ðkÞ ¼ g2 ðkÞ where mðkÞ :¼ ððw sÞq þ LÞf ðkÞ ¼ ððw sÞ bkðabwÞ 2bk1 þ LÞf ðkÞ g1 ðkÞ :¼
bkða bwÞ u1 2bk 1
g2 ðkÞ :¼ u1 ¼ w
and
Fðb1 Þ :¼ pM ð1 FðkÞÞ
Using the multiplier equations
@mðkÞ @g1 @g2 þ l2 Þ ¼ f ðkÞ þ l1 @L @L @L ) l1 ¼ FðkÞ
l1 ¼ ð
@mðkÞ @g1 @g2 þ l2 Þ þ l1 @w @w @w bkða bwÞ b2 k b2 k ¼ f ðkÞ ð Þ þ f ðkÞ ðw sÞ l1 u1 2bk 1 2bk 1 2bk 1
(14)
l2 ¼ ð
(15)
Using the optimality conditions @mðkÞ @g1 @g2 bkða bwÞ þ l2 ¼ 0 þ l1 þ l2 ¼ 0 ) l1 @u1 2bk 1 @u1 @u1
(16)
Because both pM and pR are decreasing in k (we will verify it later), IRM and IRR need only hold at k ¼ b1 . They will then be satisfied at all k b1 . Write: Kðb1 Þ :¼
b1 ða bwÞ2 Lðb1 Þ pR 0 2ð2bb1 1Þ
The transversality conditions then require that there exists p such that: l1 ðb1 Þ ¼
@F @K þp ¼ p @L @L
(17)
Use of Supply Chain Contract to Motivate Selling Effort
l2 ðb1 Þ ¼
275
@F @K a bw þp ¼ pbb1 @w @w 2bb1 1
mðb1 Þ þ l1 ðb1 Þg1 ðb1 Þ þ l2 ðb1 Þg2 ðb1 Þ pM f ðb1 Þ þ p
(18) @K ¼0 @b1
p 0; Kðb1 Þ 0; pKðb1 Þ ¼ 0
(19) (20)
Taking derivative on both sides of (16) and using (14)
) l2 ¼ FðkÞð
bða bwÞ
b2 ku1 bkða bwÞ Þ f ðkÞ þ 2 2bk 1 2bk 1 ð2bk 1Þ
(21)
Solving (21) and (15) ) w¼sþ
ða bsÞFðkÞ bFðkÞ þ bkð2bk 1Þf ðkÞ
From (19) ððwðb1 Þ sÞ
bb1 ða bwðb1 ÞÞ p ða bwðb1 ÞÞ2 þ Lðb1 ÞÞf ðb1 Þ pM f ðb1 Þ ¼0 2bb1 1 2 ð2bb1 1Þ2 2
@K 1 ÞÞ ¼ ðabwðb and p ¼ F) (Note that @b 2ð2bb1 1Þ2 1 Plug in wðb1 Þ
) Lðb1 Þ ¼ pM
ða bsÞ2 b21 Fðb1 Þf ðb1 Þ 2ðFðb1 Þ þ b1 ð2bb1 1Þf ðb1 ÞÞ2
(22)
or f ðb1 Þ ¼ 0 FðkÞ=f ðkÞ is increasing in k (one of the assumptions), so f ðb1 Þ ¼ 0 can only occur at b1 ¼ k or b1 ¼ k. For k < b1 < k, using p ¼ F(b1 Þ > 0 gives Kðb1 Þ ¼ 0, which, combined with (22) )
2ðpM þ pR Þ b21 f ðb1 Þ ¼ Fðb1 Þ þ b1 ð2bb1 1Þf ðb1 Þ ða bsÞ2
Proof of Corollary 1 Part (b) e e1 ¼ ¼
ða bsÞ ða bsÞkf ðkÞ 2bk 1 FðkÞ þ kð2bk 1Þf ðkÞ ða bsÞFðkÞ >0 ð2bk 1ÞðFðkÞ þ kð2bk 1Þf ðkÞÞ
276
S.K. Mukhopadhyay and X. Su
q q1 ¼ ¼
p p 1 ¼
ða bsÞbkFðkÞ >0 ð2bk 1ÞðFðkÞ þ kð2bk 1Þf ðkÞÞ
kða þ bsÞ s ða bsÞðFðkÞ þ bk2 f ðkÞÞ ðs þ Þ 2bk 1 bFðkÞ þ bkð2bk 1Þf ðkÞ
¼
q1
bkða bsÞ ða bsÞbk2 f ðkÞ 2bk 1 FðkÞ þ kð2bk 1Þf ðkÞ
ða bsÞðbk 1ÞFðkÞ <0 bð2bk 1ÞðFðkÞ þ kð2bk 1Þf ðkÞÞ
bkða bwÞ 0 bða bwÞ b2 k w ¼ð < 0ðsince w > 0Þ Þk ¼ 2 2bk 1 2bk 1 ð2bk 1Þ
Proof of Corollary 1 Part (c)
p1M ¼ ðw sÞq þ L ¼ ðw sÞ
bkða bwÞ þL 2bk 1
@p1M bðw sÞ ¼ ða bw þ bkð2bk 1Þ wÞ < 0ðsince w > 0Þ 2 @k ð2bk 1Þ
1 kða bwÞ2 L p1R ¼ ðp wÞq ke2 L ¼ 2ð2bk 1Þ 2 @p1R ða bwÞ2 bkða bwÞ ¼ < 0ð recall that L ¼ wÞ 2 @k 2bk 1 2ð2bk 1Þ
Since both p1M and p1R are decreasing in k, p1T ¼ p1M þ p1R is decreasing in k.
Proof of Corollary 1 Part (d) Under complete information, pM ¼ pT pR Under asymmetric information p1M ¼ p1T p1R As has been approved, the agent’s profit is monotonically decreasing in k, until hitting its reservation profit pR . However, under complete information, the agent
Use of Supply Chain Contract to Motivate Selling Effort
277
always earns its reservation profit pR . Hence, the agent’s profit is always better off under asymmetric information, i.e., p1R > pR For any k > k, p1T pT ¼ Hence p1M < pM
kða bsÞ2 FðkÞ2 2ð2bk 1ÞðFðkÞ þ kð2bk 1Þf ðkÞÞ2
<0
Proof of Lemma 1 ~2 eðkÞ ~ ~ ~ pR ðkjkÞ ¼ pR ðkÞ þ ðk kÞ 2 Let ~ þ ðk~ kÞ pR ðk~jkÞ pR ðkÞ ) pR ðkÞ
~ eðkÞ pR ðkÞ 2 2
(23)
For the same reason, 2
~ eðkÞ pR ðkÞ ~ pR ðkÞ þ ðk kÞ 2
(24)
2 ~ eðkÞ ~ ðk~ kÞ eðkÞ pR ðkÞ pR ðkÞ 2 2
(25)
From (23) and (24), ðk~ kÞ
2
Divided by k~ k, and take limitation k~ ! k ) pR ðkÞ ¼ eðkÞ 2 Part (a)
2
pR ðkÞ ¼
ðk k
pR ðkÞdk ¼
ðk k
pR ðkÞdk
ðk k
pR ðkÞdk ¼ pR þ
Part (b) 2 ~2 from (25): ðk~ kÞ eð2kÞ ðk~ kÞ eðkÞ 2 ~ 2 eðkÞ2 ) eðkÞ ~ eðkÞ when k~> k ) eðkÞ 2 2 ~ eðkÞ ~ ~ when k < k ) eðkÞ eðkÞ ) eðkÞ This finishes the proof that eðkÞ is decreasing in k
1 2
ðk k
eðkÞ2 dk
(26)
278
S.K. Mukhopadhyay and X. Su
Derivation of Equation (12) The objective function (11) can be written as: ðk
RðkÞdFðkÞ ¼
k
ðk
where ðk ðk
ðpT ðpðkÞ;qðkÞ;kÞ pR ðkÞÞdFðkÞ ¼
k
1 2
eðxÞ2 dxdFðkÞ ¼
k k
ðk ðk k k
ðk
ðk
pT ðpðkÞ;qðkÞ;kÞdFðkÞ
k
eðxÞ2 dxdFðkÞ pR
FðkÞeðxÞ2 dk
k
¼
ðk
ðpT ðpðkÞ;qðkÞ;kÞ
1 FðkÞ eðkÞ2 ÞdFðkÞ pR 2 f ðkÞ
ðpT ðpðkÞ;qðkÞ;kÞ
zðkÞ eðkÞ2 ÞdFðkÞ pR 2
k
¼
ðk k
where zðkÞ ¼
FðkÞ f ðkÞ
Proof of Proposition 2, Part (c)
p2R ¼
e^ðkÞ2 ða bsÞ2 ¼ <0 2 2ð2bðk þ zðkÞÞ 1Þ2
2
ðabsÞ ð1þzðkÞÞ p2T ¼ 2ð2bðkþzðkÞÞ1Þ 2 < 0 total supply chain profit is decreasing in k p2M
¼
p2T
p2R
ða bsÞ2 1 þ zðkÞ 1 ð ¼ Þ 2 2 ð2bðk þ zðkÞÞ 1Þ2 ð2bðk þ zðkÞÞ 1Þ
¼
ða bsÞ2 zðkÞ 2ð2bðk þ zðkÞÞ 1Þ2
< 0:
where zðkÞ ¼
FðkÞ and zðkÞ > 0; f ðkÞ
The OEM’s profit is also monotonically decreasing in k.
Use of Supply Chain Contract to Motivate Selling Effort
279
Proof of Proposition 2, Part (e) Since the retailer earns a profit strictly higher than pR for any k 6¼ k the cutoff point should be where the OEM’s profit hits pM if there is one on the support ½k; k. Let p2M
ð ða bsÞ2 ðb þ zðkÞÞ 1 k ða bsÞ2 ¼ dx pR ¼ pM 2ð2bðb þ zðkÞÞ 1Þ 2 b ð2bðx þ zðxÞÞ 1Þ2 ðk 2ðpM þ pR Þ b þ zðkÞ 1 ) dx ¼ 2 2bðb þ zðkÞÞ 1 ða bsÞ2 b ð2bðx þ zðxÞÞ 1Þ
References Ayra A, Demski J, Glover J, Liang P (2009) Quasi-robust multiagent contracts. Manage Sci 55(5):752–762 Blair BF, Lewis TR (1994) Optimal retail contracts with asymmetric information and moral hazard. Rand J Econ 25(2):284–296 Cachon GP, Kok AG (2010) Competing manufacturers in a retail supply chain: on contractual form and coordination. Manage Sci 56(3):571–589 Cachon GP, Lariviere MA (2005) Supply chain coordination with revenue-sharing contracts: strengths and limitations. Manage Sci 51(1):30–45 Cakanyildirim M, Feng Q, Gan X, Sethi SP (2008) Contracting and coordination under asymmetric production cost information. SSRN Working Paper Series. http://ssrn.com/abstract¼1084584 Chen F (2005) Salesforce incentives, market information, and production/inventory planning. Manage Sci 51(1):60–75 Chen H, Chen Y, Chiu CH, Choi TM, Sethi SP (2010) Coordination mechanism for the supply chain with leadtime consideration and price-dependent demand. Eur J Oper Res 203(1):70–80 Corbett CJ, Zhou D, Tang CS (2004) Designing supply contracts: contract type and information asymmetry. Manage Sci 50(4):550–559 Coughlan AT (1993) Salesforce compensation: a review of MS/OR advances. In: Eliashberg J, Lilien GL (eds) Handbooks in OR&MS, vol 5. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 611–651 Cui TH, Raju JS, Zhang ZJ (2008) A price discrimination model of trade promotions. Mark Sci 27(5):779–795 Desai PS, Srinivasan K (1995) Demand signaling under unobservable effort in franchising: linear and nonlinear price contracts. Manage Sci 41(10):1608–1623 Desiraju R, Moorthy S (1997) Managing a distribution channel under asymmetric information with performance requirements. Manage Sci 43(12):1628–1644 Dukes A, Liu Y (2010) In-store media and distribution channel coordination. Mark Sci 29(1): 94–107 Federal Trade Commission (2005) Consumer guide to buying a franchise. Purch World 37(4):17 Foros Ø, Hagen KP, Kind HJ (2009) Price-dependent profit sharing as a channel coordination device. Manage Sci 55(8):1280–1291 Gal-Or E (1991) Vertical restraints with incomplete information. J Ind Econ 39(5):503–516 Gan X, Sethi SP, Yan H (2005) Channel coordination with a risk-neutral supplier and a downsiderisk-averse retailer. Prod Oper Manage 14(1):80–89 Gibbons R (1987) Price-rate incentive schemes. J Labor Econ 5(4):413–429 Gonik J (1978) Tie salesmen’s bonuses to their forecasts. Harv Bus Rev 56(3):116–122
280
S.K. Mukhopadhyay and X. Su
Gurnani H, Xu Y (2006) Resale price maintenance contracts with retailer sales effort: effect of flexibility and competition. Nav Res Logistics 53(5):448–463 Ha AY (2001) Supplier–buyer contracting: asymmetric cost information and cutoff level policy for buyer participation. Nav Res Logistics 48:41–64 Kamien MI, Schwartz N (1981) Dynamic optimization: the calculus of variations and optimal control in economics and management. North-Holland, New York Kaufmann PJ, Dant RP (2001) The pricing of franchise rights. J Retail 77:537–545 Kreps D (1990) A course in microeconomic theory. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ Krishnan H, Winter A (2010) Inventory dynamics and supply chain coordination. Manage Sci 56(1):141–147 Krishnan H, Kapuscinski R, Butz DA (2004) Coordinating contracts for decentralized supply chains with retailer promotional effort. Manage Sci 50(1):48–62 Laffont JJ, Martimort D (2000) Mechanism design with collusion and correlation. Econometrica 68(2):309–342 Laffont JJ, Martimort D (2001) The theory of incentives: the principal-agent model. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ Laffont JJ, Tirole J (1986) Using cost observation to regulate firms. J Polit Econ 94(3):614–641 Lafontaine F, Slade ME (1997) Retail contracting: theory and practice. J Ind Econ 45(1):1–25 Lal R (1990) Manufacturer trade deals and retail price promotions. J Mark Res 27(4):428–444 Majumder P, Srinivasan A (2008) Leadership and competition in network supply chains. Manage Sci 54(6):1189–1204 Mukhopadhyay SK, Zhu X, Yue X (2008) Optimal contract design for mixed channels under information asymmetry. Prod Oper Manage 17(6):641–650 Mukhopadhyay SK, Su X, Ghose S (2009) Motivating retail marketing effort: optimal contract design. Prod Oper Manage 18(2):197–211 Myerson RB (1979) Incentive compatibility and the bargaining problem. Econometrica 47:61–74 Raju J, Zhang ZJ (2005) Channel coordination in the presence of a dominant retailer. Mark Sci 24(2):254–304 Spengler JJ (1950) Vertical integration and antitrust policy. J Polit Econ 58:347–352 Su X, Wu L, Yue X (2010) Impact of introducing a direct channel on supply chain performance. Int J Electron Bus 8(2):101–112 Taylor TA (2002) Supply chain coordination under channel rebates with sales effort effects. Manage Sci 48(8):992–1007 Tsay A (1999) Quantity flexibility contract and supplier-customer incentives. Manage Sci 45(10):1339–1358 Watson J (2007) Contract, mechanism design, and technological detail. Econometrica 75(1):55–81 Wimmer BS, Garen JE (1997) Moral hazard, asset specificity, implicit bonding, and compensation: the case of franchising. Econ Enquiry 35(3):544–555 Wu Y, Loch CH, Heyden LV (2008) A model of fair process and its limits. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 10(4):637–653 Yang Z, Aydin G, Babich V, Beil DR (2009) Supply disruptions, asymmetric information, and a backup production option. Manage Sci 55(2):192–209 Zhao Y, Choi TM, Cheng TCE, Sethi SP, Wang S (2010) Buyback contracts with a stochastic demand curve. SSRN Working Paper Series. http://ssrn.com/abstract¼1559475 Zhu X, Mukhopadhyay SK (2009) Optimal contract design for outsourcing: pricing and quality decisions. Int J Revenue Manage 3(2):197–217
Price and Warranty Competition in a Duopoly Supply Chain Santanu Sinha and S.P. Sarmah
Abstract This chapter analyzes the coordination and competition issues in a twostage distribution channel where two different retailers compete on their retail price and warranty policy to sell two substitutable products in the same market. The demand faced by each retailer not only depends on its own price and warranty duration, but also on the price and warranty duration set by the other. Mathematical models have been developed to analyze the dynamic competition and coordination mechanism for three different cases where retailers compete (1) exclusively on price; (2) exclusively on warranty duration; (3) both price and warranty duration. The mathematical models show that under price/warranty competition, the steady state equilibrium is dynamically stable in nature under certain condition(s). Further, it has been shown that the channel profit for each case is higher under coordination than that of under competition and the maximum channel profit is achieved when retailers coordinate each other to adopt a centralized policy to set both price and warranty duration. However, it has been observed that though coordination enhances overall supply-chain profitability, it may make consumers worse-off due to higher product prices. The model is illustrated with suitable numerical examples. Keywords Competition • Coordination • Game-theory • Pricing • Stability • Supply-chain management • Warranty
S. Sinha Complex Decision Support Systems, Tata Consultancy Services, Akruti Trade Centre, MIDC, Andheri (E), Mumbai 400093, India e-mail: [email protected] S.P. Sarmah (*) Department of Industrial Engineering and Management, Indian Institute of Technology, Kharagpur 721302, India e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_12, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
281
282
S. Sinha and S.P. Sarmah
1 Introduction The landscape of business environment has experienced significant changes in recent years. Among many factors, globalization of business, increased market competition, awareness of customers, and increased demand for the value added products/services have largely contributed to the change in the shift. The changing face of business environment has compelled academic researchers and industry leaders to rethink about how to manage business operations more efficiently and effectively. Since, the scope for improvement within an organization is restricted with limited resources; the researchers and practitioners are looking for newer alternatives. In this sense, the importance of integrating business activities, both inside and outside the organization’s boundary have been realized by all. The concept of integrating business functions beyond the organization’s boundary has led to the development of the theory and practices of Supply Chain Management (SCM) and one of the important issues in SCM is coordination. There is a growing body of academic researchers and practitioners from a variety of disciplines who focus on different issues of supply chain coordination and strive to establish potential coordination mechanisms to eliminate sub-optimization within a supply chain and enhance overall performance. An important finding from the existing body of literature is that in most of the coordination models, the buyers are assigned to the supplier(s) exogenously, i.e. products are considered independent. However, when there are many vendors in the market who can supply similar type of the product to the buyers, there is a pricecompetition among the vendors. In real-life business, there are many substitutable products in different market place where the respective vendors/retailers have to compete the others to sell the products. For example, Pepsi and Coca-Cola in soft drink market, Sotheby’s and Christie’s in diamond auctions; Kodak and Fuji-film in motion picture film stock market; ABC, CBS, and NBC in US television (before FOX); GM, Ford and Chrysler in auto industry (before the 1970s); etc. Under such scenario, development of coordination mechanism and analysis of competition is an important area of study (Sinha and Sarmah 2010). There are numerous papers on monopolistic and duopolistic competition in marketing and operations management literature; for example, Moorthy (1988), Choi (2003), Yao and Liu (2005), etc. The authors have studied several issues on price competition in supply-chain distribution channels under different contexts. In most of these models, demand of a product is assumed to be a function both its own price as well as the price of the other. However, one critical observation is that in addition to price, consumers also look for additional “value” from the various nonprice attributes, such as quality, service, delivery flexibility, etc. In this sense, the suppliers may also consider the non-price attribute(s) as a competitive tool in their marketing strategy and tend to compete on both price and non-price attribute(s). Several researchers have brought many dimensions of such competition, for example, quality (Banker et al. 1998), service (Tsay and Agrawal 2000), delivery frequency (Ha et al. 2003), etc.
Price and Warranty Competition in a Duopoly Supply Chain
283
The end consumers’ value perception and purchase decisions are also significantly influenced by warranty duration. This is perfectly related with the growing consumption pattern of FMCG, engineering instruments, manufacturing/electronics products where customers not only look for comparable prices but also associated product value/risk. Thus, offering free repair/replacement during the warranty/protection period often enhances the purchase decision of buyers. Many manufacturers/retailers offer warranties to the end consumers in different forms to boost up the overall sales demand. For example, automobile manufacturer Hyundai is well known for their extensive warranty coverage. GM and Ford have extended the powertrain warranty for their 2007 vehicles from 3 years/36,000 miles to 5 years/100,000 miles and 5 years/60,000 miles respectively (Scherer 2006). This has resulted in higher sales, bringing greater profit (Connelly 2006). Following GM, several imported brands have offered broader powertrain coverage on their 2007 vehicles (Hu 2008). Mitsubishi has started offering warranty coverage over 10 years or 100,000 miles. Similarly Suzuki vehicles have powertrain warranty coverage for 7 years or 100,000 miles (Scherer 2006). Similar to automobile industry, FMCG industry have also applied various forms of warranty to escalate the overall market demand. Similarly, several other firms have also used warranty as a marketing weapon to boost up the product demand – along with pricing strategy. However, the issue of price and warranty competition among competing vendors is still an unaddressed research question which requires further analysis. In this chapter, we consider the issues of price and warranty competition between two different retailers. The two competing retailers obtain a product from a common manufacturer, add some value on it, and finally sell it to the market. Three different cases are considered here where the retailers compete (1) exclusively on price; (2) exclusively on warranty duration; (3) both price and warranty duration. For each case, we have developed the steady state equilibrium for dynamic competition and system-wide solution under integrated/coordination mechanism. The main features that make a distinction of this work from the existing related literature is that the formulations and equilibrium strategies of our models explicitly depend on the pricing and warranty policy of competing retailers. We have considered here the inherent dynamics associated with the process of price adjustment while modeling competition. Static modeling of retail price competition can derive the equilibrium but the adjustment of retail price to equilibrium does not occur instantaneously. Like most of the dynamic economic systems, the mechanism of dynamic adjustment is an iterative process converging to equilibrium over a period of time. This chapter analyzes the stability of such equilibrium. Here, the term “stability” means that whether the process of dynamic adjustment of price/warranty duration will eventually converge to equilibrium over a period of time and there is no further divergence from that “fixed/stable” point. We have derived the conditions for the equilibrium to be dynamically stable. This chapter has been organized as follows. A brief review of literature is included in Sect. 2. Section 3 includes the notation and modeling assumptions. The mathematical models are developed in Sect. 4. Section 5 illustrates the dynamics of price, warranty, and simultaneous price and warranty competition.
284
S. Sinha and S.P. Sarmah
The impact of coordination has been analyzed in Sect. 6. Further, numerical illustration has been included in Sect. 7. Finally, the conclusion of the chapter is given in Sect. 8 along with a few possible future research directions.
2 Review of Literature In this section we have provided a brief review of literature related to the work. From the perspective of economic theory, a large number of research papers are available on market competition. Most of the papers deal with either quantitycompetition (Cournot 1938) or price-competition (Bertrand 1883) and their primary focus is on applying game theory to derive equilibria under varied assumptions. On the other hand, in marketing and operations management literature, there are many papers on monopolistic and duopolistic competition. The aspects of coordination and competition have received a considerable amount of attention from the researchers. Moorthy (1988) has considered two identical firms competing on quality and price and analyzed the role of consumer preferences, firms’ costs and price competition in determining a firm’s equilibrium product strategy. Rao (1991) has developed a modelling framework to derive the equilibrium in a duopoly market where the members compete on price and promotions. Competition between direct and indirect channels has been analyzed by Choi (2003). Further, Yao and Liu (2005) have developed competitive equilibrium pricing policies under the Bertrand and the Stackelberg competition model between a mixed e-tail and retail distribution channel. They have shown that introduction of e-tail into a manufacturing distribution system not only generates competitive pricing and payoffs, but also encourages cost-effective retail services. They have also proposed a strategic approach for the manufacturer to add an e-tail channel. However, most of these models have focused only on price competition. Apart from price competition, there are several other models where the authors have studied the aspect of non-price competition. For example, Ha et al. (2003) have considered a supply chain in which two suppliers compete on price and delivery frequency to supply to a customer. They have shown that the customer is better off under delivery competition, while the suppliers are better off under price competition. However, the model did not consider any coordination aspects within the channel and the demand was assumed to be price-independent. Banker et al. (1998) have studied both price and quality competition and addressed the question of how quality is influenced by competitive intensity in an oligopoly market. So (2000) has studied the aspect of price and delivery time as the competition attributes and illustrated how different firms and market characteristics might affect the price and delivery time competition in the market. Tsay and Agrawal (2000) have studied a distribution system in which a manufacturer supplies a common product to two independent retailers, who in turn use service as well as retail price to directly compete for end customers. They have examined the drivers of each firm’s strategy, and the consequences for total sales, market share, and profitability. Finally, it has
Price and Warranty Competition in a Duopoly Supply Chain
285
been shown that the relative intensity of competition with respect to each competitive dimension plays a key role, as does the degree of cooperation between the retailers. Another important non-price attributes is warranty policy – which is also a very popular marketing tool. Most common form of warranty policy may include free replacement of failed product, coverage of parts/labor work, repair of failed products within a specified interval – known as warranty duration. As a common practice in industry, warranties have received the attention of researchers from many diverse disciplines. Authors like, Menezes and Currim (1992) and Padmanabhan (1993) have justified how application of warranty policy could be a marketing tool to differentiate from competitors. A comprehensive review of related research in different application domains can be found in Blischke and Murthy (1996). Several researchers have explored various aspects of warranties, such as warranty type, product failures during warranty period, warranty claims, warranty costs, and warranty logistics. A review has been provided by Hu (2008). However, though there is a stream of literature that has focused exclusively on design of warranty policy (Murthy 2006; Wu et al. 2009), there are not much research on warranty competition. Further, most of the competition models have dealt with deriving static equilibrium, and not studied the aspects of dynamic process adjustment. Thus, in order to address the issues, in this chapter, we extend the aspects of price and warranty competition in a duopoly market. We also extend the analysis to include the dynamics of such competition under various scenarios.
3 Notation and Assumptions The following notations are used to develop the mathematical model (where i ¼ 1, 2) Di Demand of product i pi Unit retail price of manufacturer i ti Warranty length of product i Unit repair cost of product i ci w Per unit wholesale price of the manufacturer pi Profit of retailer i
3.1
Demand Function
In this study, a two-stage distribution channel is considered where a manufacturer distributes a single product to two different retailers. The retailers add some value to the product and sell it to the end customers. The end products are substitute to each other. Further, in addition to product prices of the product itself and those of
286
S. Sinha and S.P. Sarmah
related substitute products, demand also depends on a variety of other non-price factors such as quality, delivery, service, etc. In this study we consider warranty length as another factor that influences demand. In this sense, the demand function is assumed to take the following linear form (Banker et al. 1998): Di ¼ a bpi þ gpj þ y ti mtj
ði; j ¼ 1; 2; i 6¼ jÞ
(1)
The price and cross-price elasticity parameters b and g move independently. It is assumed that a; b>0 so that demand for each product declines with the product’s own price. Further, b>jgj so that “own-price effect” always dominates the “crossprice effect”. The assumed demand function is downward slopping, a variation of a class of more general linear demand functions used in many previous studies (McGuire and Staelin 1983; Choi 1991).
3.2
Warranty Cost
Under the warranty policy, retailer i is responsible to repair each failed product during the warranty length ti with no extra charge to the customer. Following Wu et al. (2009), let us consider that N(t) is the number of failures for the product over a warranty duration of t. Thus, assuming the failure time of the products is independently and identically distributed with the cumulative distribution function F(ti), the expected value of N(ti) is given by E½N ðti Þ ¼ Mðti Þ, where M(ti) is the expected number of renewals of the product with warranty length ti. Further, considering Fðti Þ as a Weibull distribution with failure rate li and a n shape parametern, Fðti Þ ¼ 1 eðli ti Þ . Accordingly, the expected number of failures of product with warranty length ti can be obtained as: Mðti Þ ¼ ðli ti Þn (Wu et al. 2009). Thus, the warranty-related cost of product i in the warranty duration can be given as, Ci ¼ ci ðli ti Þn Di .
4 Mathematical Models Let us consider a typical market model with two competing retailers where each retailer procures the same material from the sole manufacturer at a certain wholesale price w, adds some value on it, and finally sells it in the market – as shown in Fig. 1. Depending on the nature of competition between the two retailers, three different cases have been considered here: (i) Price competition where both the retailers compete each other on price only. (ii) Warranty competition where both retailers compete each other on warranty length. (iii) Price and Warranty competition where both retailers compete each other on price and warranty duration simultaneously.
Price and Warranty Competition in a Duopoly Supply Chain
287
Manufacturer
w
Retailer 1
{p1,t1}
Retailer 2
{p2,t2}
D1
D2
MARKET
Fig. 1 The distribution channel
4.1
Equilibrium in Price Competition
The expected profit function of retailer i can be given as: pi ðpi Þ ¼ Di ½pi w ci ðli ti Þn ¼ a bpi þ gpj þ y ti mtj ½pi w ci ðli ti Þn ; ði; j ¼ 1; 2; i 6¼ jÞ The objective of retailer i, Max pi ðpi Þ
(2)
Since, @@ppi 2i ¼ 2b<0, pi ðpi Þ is concave in nature and the optimal solution can be i achieved from first order conditions: @p @pi ¼ a 2bpi þ gpj þ y ti mtj þ wbþ n ci ðli ti Þ b ¼ 0 Or, 2
pi ¼
a þ wb þ gpj þ y ti þ ci ðli ti Þn b mtj 2b
(3)
This is known as the best response function1 of retailer i. The objective of each retailer is to find out the best response function against each other’s retail price and accordingly find out the Pareto-optimal solution. It is obvious that a change in the retail price of a product can influence demand for other product. Since both retailers are profit maximizer, each retailer will adjust her retail price in response to the
1 A retail price p1 ¼ p1 ðp2 Þ is defined as the best response function against retail price p2 if and only if p1 ðp1 ðp2 Þ; p2 Þ p1 ðp1 ; p2 Þ, for any p1 . Similarly, a retail price p2 ¼ p2 ðp1 Þ is defined as the best response function against retail price p1 if and only if p1 ðp1 ðp2 Þ; p2 Þ p1 ðp1 ; p2 Þ, for any p2 (Shy 2003).
288
S. Sinha and S.P. Sarmah
p1(p2)
p2
p2(p1)
{p1*, p2*}
p1
Fig. 2 Best response functions in price competition
other. The process of price-adjustment then leads to further price rise/fall till it reaches the equilibrium (Fig. 2). This equilibrium is a Pareto-optimal solution derived by the intersection(s) of the best response functions beyond which no retailer has an incentive to unilaterally change its strategy given the other’s equilibrium strategy and hence it is a Paretooptimal solution. In this particular case, the Pareto-optimal solution is Nash–Bertrand equilibrium.2 Proposition 1. (a) Under the general retail price competition, both retailers adjust their retail prices in the similar direction of the change (i.e. simultaneously either increase or decrease). (b) Under the general retail price competition, given retailer j sets her retail pricepj , retailer i will increase her retail price pi , if a þ gpj þ y ti mtj þ wb þ ci ðli ti Þn b >pi . 2b Proof. The proof is given in Appendix A. The Nash–Bertrand equilibrium ðp1 ; p2 Þ can be derived by solving the best response functions as given by (3) and accordingly, pi ¼
n 2abþaggmti þ2byti þ2b2 ci ðli ti Þn 2bmtj þgyt2 þbcj g lj tj þ2b2 wþbgw 4b2 l2 (4)
2 A Nash–Bertrand equilibrium point is a pair of retail prices ðp1 ; p2 Þ offered by the retailers, each of which is a best response of the other: p1 ¼ p1 ðp2 Þ and p2 ¼ p2 ðp1 Þ (Shy 2003).
Price and Warranty Competition in a Duopoly Supply Chain
289
Finally, ½pi p ¼ Di ðp1 ; p2 Þðpi w ci ðli ti Þn Þ
(5)
Proposition 2. Under the general retail price competition, the Nash–Bertrand equilibrium increases with failure rate li and warranty length ti . However, the Nash–Bertrand equilibrium increases with shape factor n if 2b2 ci ðli ti Þn lnðli ti Þþ n bcj g lj tj ln lj tj >0. Proof. The proof is given in Appendix B.
4.2
Equilibrium in Warranty Competition
In this case, both retailers are assumed to compete each other on warranty length. Thus, the objective of retailer i, Max pi ðti Þ
(6)
It is straightforward to derive that, @ 2 pi ¼ ci nli n ðti Þn2 ½2y ti þ Di ðn 1Þ @ti 2 Since, ci nli n ðti Þn2 >0, for Di >0 and n 1, @@tip2i <0. Thus, pi ðti Þ is concave in nature and the optimal solution can be achieved from first order conditions: 2
@pi ¼ ci li n ðti Þn1 y ti þ a bpi þ gpj þ y ti mtj n pi y þ wy ¼ 0 @ti Or, ðti Þn1 ¼
ðpi wÞy ; ci li n ðy ti þ Di nÞ
where
Di ¼ a bpi þ gpj þ y ti mtj :
(7)
The intermittent values of ti can be derived by iterative computations and finally, the Nash equilibrium ðt1 ; t2 Þ can be derived by solving, ðti Þn1 ¼
ðpi wÞy ; where Di ¼ a bpi þ gpj þ yti mtj ci li ðy ti þ Di nÞ n
(8)
Accordingly, ½pi w ¼ Di ðt1 ; t2 Þðpi w ci li ti Þ
(9)
290
S. Sinha and S.P. Sarmah
t1(t2)
t2
t2(t1)
{t1*,t2*}
t1
Fig. 3 Best response functions in warranty competition
Following (7), it has been observed that the best response functions ti tj , ði; j ¼ 1; 2; i 6¼ jÞ are nonlinear in nature due to the shape parameter n. Thus, the dynamic adjustment of warranty duration, starting from an initial condition, could further go uphill or downhill to reach the Nash equilibrium ðt1 ; t2 Þ – as shown in Fig. 3 as an example. However, it is to be noted that the slopes and the trajectory of any such best response functions and the number of intersection points (equilibrium) depend on the functional form and type of the profit functions.
4.3
Equilibrium in Price and Warranty Competition
In this case, both the retailers compete each other on warranty length. Thus, the objective of retailer i, Max pi ðpi ; ti Þ
(10)
The Hessian matrix of pi ðpi ; ti Þ is given as, 2
@ 2 pi 6 @pi 2 Hi ¼ 6 4 @ 2 pi @ti @pi
3 @ 2 pi 2b @pi @ti 7 7 ¼ @ 2 pi 5 y þ bci nli n ti n1 @ti 2
y þ bci nli n ti n1 n ci nli ðti Þn2 ½2y ti þ Di ðn 1Þ
Price and Warranty Competition in a Duopoly Supply Chain
291
Here, the members of the principal diagonal are negative; thus, the objective function pi ðpi ; ti Þ is a concave function if jHi j<0, 2 Or, ðy þ bci nli n ti n1 Þ >2bci nli n ðti Þn2 ½2y ti þ Di ðn 1Þ: The Nash equilibrium under simultaneous price and warranty competition ðp~i ; ~ti Þ can be derived by solving the following set of best response functions, 9 a þ wb þ gpj þ y ti þ ci ðli ti Þn b mtj > > = 2b > ðpi wÞy > ; ti n1 ¼ n ci li ðy ti þ Di nÞ
pi ¼
(11)
The Nash equilibrium ðp~1 ; ~t1 Þ and ðp~2 ; ~t2 Þ can be found by simultaneously solving the sets of equations in (11). Finally, ½pi p;w ¼ D~i ðp~i ; ~ti Þðp~i w ci li~ti Þ
(12)
5 Dynamics of Competition In the earlier section, we have derived the Nash–Bertrand equilibrium under three different cases where the retailers compete each other on (1) price, (2) warranty duration, (3) both price and warranty duration. However, the adjustment of initial price or warranty duration gradually leads toward the Nash–Bertrand equilibrium following an iterative process, where at each step; each retailer chooses a policy which maximizes the individual profit based on the expected policy set by her opponent. Hence, at each time period every retailer depends on an expectation of the other retailer’s policy in the next time period to determine the corresponding profit-maximizing policy for that period. This leads to a dynamic adjustment of price and warranty duration which finally reaches to the Nash–Bertrand equilibrium. Here, we analyze the behavior of such dynamic adjustment process of price and warranty competition under two different scenarios (1) naı¨ve expectation and (2) adaptive expectation. In the former case, each player assumes the last values taken by the competitors without estimation of their future reactions in each step. However, in case of adaptive expectation, each retailer revises her beliefs according to the adaptive expectations rules which compute the outputs with weights between last period’s outputs and her reaction function. A related discussion is included in Agiza and Elsadany (2003) and Shone (2001). In this section, we develop mathematical models to capture the scenario where retailers compete each other in (1) price, (2) warranty duration, (3) both price and warranty duration under both naı¨ve and adaptive .expectation. We have investigated the stability condition(s) corresponding to each case. The main objective of the
292
S. Sinha and S.P. Sarmah
models is to investigate the dynamic behavior of a duopoly game with price and warranty competition under different expectation rules. Through a numerical we further explain the movement of the system variables over a period of time.
5.1
Dynamics of Price Competition
If we denote the retail price of product i at time period t by pi ðtÞ, then the retail price pi ðt þ 1Þ for the period ðt þ 1Þ is decided by solving the two optimization problems (Agiza and Elsadany 2003): p1 ðt þ 1Þ ¼ arg max p1 ðp1 ðtÞ; p2 e ðt þ 1ÞÞ p1
p2 ðt þ 1Þ ¼ arg max p2 ðp1 e ðt þ 1Þ; p2 ðtÞÞ;
(13)
p2
where the function pi ð:Þ denotes the profit of the retailer i and pj e ðt þ 1Þ represents the expectation of retailer i about the pricing decision of retailer j, ði; j ¼ 1; 2; j 6¼ iÞ. We consider that the retailers could be naı¨ve or adaptive players – depending on their adjustment process.
5.2
Dynamics of Price Competition with Naı¨ve Expectation
We assume that both the retailers are naı¨ve. With the assumption, we can express the process of duopoly game which can be defined as, 9 a þ wb þ gp2 ðtÞ þ y t1 þ c1 ðl1 t1 Þn b mt2 > > p1 ðt þ 1Þ ¼ = 2b > a þ wb þ gp1 ðtÞ þ y t2 þ c2 ðl2 t2 Þn b mt1 > ; p2 ðt þ 1Þ ¼ 2b
(14)
In equilibrium, pi ðt þ 1Þ ¼ pi ðtÞ and thus we are interested in the solution of the system with non-negative equilibrium points defined as, 9 a þ wb þ gp2 ðtÞ þ y t1 þ c1 ðl1 t1 Þn b mt2 > > = 2b a þ wb þ gp1 ðtÞ þ y t2 þ c2 ðl2 t2 Þn b mt1 > > ; p2 ðtÞ ¼ 2b
p1 ðtÞ ¼
The equilibrium point ðp1 ; p2 Þ has already been derived as,
(15)
Price and Warranty Competition in a Duopoly Supply Chain
pi ¼
293
n 2abþaggmti þ2byti þ2b2 ci ðli ti Þn 2bmtj þgyt2 þbcj g lj tj þ2b2 wþbgw 4b2 g2
It is clear that the Nash equilibrium ðp1 ; p2 Þ is located at the intersection of the two reaction functions. In this study, we are interested in studying the local stability of equilibrium point at ðp1 ; p2 Þ. This can be analyzed by the eigen values of the Jacobian matrix of the system (14) on the complex plane. The Jacobian matrix of (14) at the point ðp1 ; p2 Þ has the following form, 2
@f1 6 @p1 JpN ðp1 ; p2 Þ ¼ 6 4 @f2 @p1
3 @f1 @p2 7 7; @f2 5
(16)
@p2
a þ wb þ gpj ðtÞ þ y ti þ ci ðli ti Þn b mtj ¼ fi 2b 2 g 3 0 6 2b 7 Thus, JpN ðp1 ; p2 Þ ¼ 4 g 5 0 2b We now investigate the local stability The characteristic of Nash equilibrium. @f1 @f2 2 N N N equation is given as, f ðeÞ ¼ e Tr Jp e þ Det Jp ,where Tr Jp ¼ @p þ @p 1 2 @f1 @f2 @f1 @f2 N is the trace and Det Jp ¼ @p1 @p2 @p2 @p1 is the determinant of the Jacobian where, pi ðt þ 1Þ ¼
matrix defined in (16). 2 2 N J Now, Tr JpN ¼ 0 and Det JpN ¼ g 4Det JpN ¼ 2 <0. Thus, Tr p 4b 2 g >0. b2 Since, Tr2 JpN 4Det JpN >0, the eigen values of Nash equilibrium are real. Following a standard stability analysis, the necessary and sufficient condition for the stability of Nash equilibrium at ðp1 ; p2 Þ is that the eigen values of the Jacobian matrix JpN ðp1 ; p2 Þ are inside the unit circle of the complex plane. This is true if and only if the following conditions are hold (Puu 2002; Agiza and Elsadany 2004): 1. 1 Tr JpN þ Det JpN >0 2. 1 þ Tr JpN þ Det JpN >0 3. Det JpN 1<0 2 g Since, Det JpN 1 ¼ 4b 2 þ 1 <0, the third condition is already satisfied. g2 The first and second conditions imply, 1 4b 2 >0. Thus, the dynamic adjustment of retail price eventually reaches to a stable Nash equilibrium for b2 > g4 . 2
294
5.3
S. Sinha and S.P. Sarmah
Dynamics of Price Competition with Adaptive Expectation
Assuming both the retailers to be adaptive, the dynamic equation of the adaptive expectation can be defined as below, pi ðt þ 1Þ ¼ ð1 vi Þpi ðtÞ þ
vi a þ wb þ gpj ðtÞ þ y ti þ ci ðli ti Þn b mtj ; 2b
(17)
ði; j ¼ 1; 2; i 6¼ jÞ Here, vi 2 ½0; 1 is the speed of adjustment of the adaptive players. It can easily be noted that, if vi ¼ 1, it reduces to the form of naı¨ve expectation. This implies that naive expectation is a special case of adaptive expectations behavior. Now, we look for the equilibrium of the system (17) and discuss their stability properties. The fixed points of the map (17) are obtained as nonnegative solutions of the algebraic system by setting pi ðt þ 1Þ ¼ pi ðtÞ. This implies, vi a þ wb þ gpj ðtÞ þ y ti þ ci ðli ti Þn b mtj 2pi b ¼ 0; 2b
(18)
ði; j ¼ 1; 2; i 6¼ jÞ Since, v1 ; v2 > 0; the equilibrium point ðp1 ; p2 Þ can be derived as,
pi ¼
n 2abþaggmti þ2byti þ2b2 ci ðli ti Þn 2bmtj þgyt2 þbcj g lj tj þ2b2 wþbgw 4b2 g2
This shows that, the Nash equilibrium does not change with adaptive expectation; however the speed to reach Nash equilibrium depends on the speed of adjustment. Here, we are interested in studying the local stability of equilibrium point at ðp1 ; p2 Þ which can be analyzed by the eigen values of the Jacobian matrix of the system (17) on the complex plane – as shown below, 2
@g1 6 @p1 JpAD ðp1 ; p2 Þ ¼ 6 4 @g2 @p1
3 @g1 @p2 7 7; @g2 5
(19)
@p2
vi where, pi ðt þ 1Þ ¼ ð1 vi Þpi ðtÞ þ 2b a þ wb þ gpj þ y ti þ ci ðli ti Þn b mtj ¼ gi 2 v1 g 3 ð1 v1 Þ 6 2b 7 Thus, JpAD ðp0 1 ; p0 2 Þ ¼ 4 v2 g 5 ð 1 v2 Þ 2b v2 g2 AD Now, Tr Jp ¼ 2 v1 v2 and Det JpAD ¼ ð1 v1 Þð1 v2 Þ v14b 2 . For stable equilibrium, the following conditions have to be fulfilled,
Price and Warranty Competition in a Duopoly Supply Chain
295
C1. 1 Tr JpAD þ Det JpAD >0 C2. 1 þ Tr JpAD þ Det JpAD >0 C3. Det JpAD 1<0 Proposition 3. The Nash equilibrium is dynamically stable in price competition 2 under adaptive expectation if b2 > g4 . Proof. The proof is given in Appendix C.
5.4
Dynamics of Warranty Competition
Similar to the earlier model of dynamic price competition, the simultaneous game of warranty competition through warranty length adjustment can be represented in the following form, 9 t1 ðT þ 1Þ ¼ arg max p1 ðt1 ðTÞ; t2 e ðT þ 1ÞÞ = t1
t2 ðT þ 1Þ ¼ arg max p2 ðt1 e ðT þ 1Þ; t2 ðTÞÞ ;
(20)
t2
where warranty length offered for product i at time period T and T+1 is represented by ti ðTÞ and ti ðT þ 1Þ respectively. Here, we analyze the adjustment process and predict whether the Nash equilibrium is globally stable. The term “stability”, means whether during the process of dynamic price adjustment, an initial combination of warranty length will eventually converge to equilibrium in the long run without further deviation. The present dynamic system can be represented by (Ferguson and Lim 1998): t_1 ¼ c1 ðt1 t1 Þ
(21)
t_2 ¼ c2 ðt2 t2 Þ;
(22)
where, t_1 ¼ dt1 =dT, t_2 ¼ dt2 =dT and c1 ; c2 > 0 are adjustment coefficients representing the speed of the adjustment. The terms ðt1 ; t2 Þ and ðt1 ; t2 Þ denote the Nash equilibrium and the actual level of warranty length at any time-period (T) respectively. Since the present system is non-linear, we apply the following theorem developed by Olech (1963) to check the dynamic stability of the system given by (21). Theorem 1. Consider an autonomous system x_ ¼ f ðx; yÞ y_ ¼ gðx; yÞ
) (23)
296
S. Sinha and S.P. Sarmah
where x_ ¼ dx=dt, y_ ¼ dx=dt, and ðx; yÞ 2 R2 . The functions f and g are assumed to be of class C1 onR2 . Suppose that there is a unique equilibrium point ðx; yÞ on R2 , i.e., a point such that f ðx; yÞ ¼ 0 and gðx; yÞ ¼ 0. If the following conditions are satisfied, the equilibrium is asymptotically stable in the large (i) Trace J ðx; yÞ fx þ gy <0, for all ðx; yÞ in R2 : for all ðx; yÞ in R2 : (ii) Det J ðx; yÞ fx gy fy gx >0, (iii) Either fx gy 6¼ 0, for all ðx; yÞ in R2 : for all ðx; yÞ in R2 . or fy gx 6¼ 0, where, fx ð@ =@xÞf ðx; yÞ and fy , gx , and gy are similarly defined. A proof of the theorem is given in Olech (1963). We have considered this theorem as given and proceed to look for conditions which guarantee the global stability of the mentioned system. It is straight-forward to derive the following differential equations: 2
1 !n1
ðp1 wÞy t_i ¼ ci 4 n ci li y ti þ a bpi þ gpj þ y ti mtj n
3 ti 5;
ði; j ¼ 1; 2; i 6¼ jÞ (24)
Conditions under which the above nonlinear system will be dynamically stable have been derived and shown in the form of the following proposition. Proposition 4. The Nash equilibrium under non-coordinated warranty length competition, is globally asymptotically stable for the following: (a) n 1,
i h ih i h n n n Di >0 and K1 ðy t1 þ D1 nÞn1 þ 1 K2 ðy t2 þ D2 nÞn1 þ 1 > L1 ðyt1 þ D1 nÞn1 h i n L2 ðy t2 þ D2 nÞn1
(b) For n<1
h i n n Di >0, Ki ðy ti þ Di nÞn1 < 1, and K1 ðy t1 þ D1 nÞn1 þ 1 h i h ih i n n n K2 ðy t2 þ D2 nÞn1 þ 1 > L1 ðy t1 þ D1 nÞn1 L2 ðy t2 þ D2 nÞn1
1
yðn þ 1Þ pi y wy n1 nm pi y wy n1 1 and L ¼ where, Ki ¼ : i ðn 1Þ ci li n n1 ci l i n
Proof. The Jacobian matrix of t_i (i ¼ 1, 2) is given as, 2
@ t_1 6 @t 1 J¼6 4 @ t_2 @t1 It is straight-forward to derive,
3 @ t_1 @t2 7 7 ¼ J1 @ t_2 5 J3 @t2
J2 J4
Price and Warranty Competition in a Duopoly Supply Chain
h i9 n @ t_i > ¼ ci Ki ðy ti þ Di nÞn1 þ 1 > = @ti h i n > @ t_i > ; ¼ ci Li ðy ti þ Di nÞn1 @tj
297
ði; j ¼ 1; 2; i 6¼ jÞ
(25)
(I) From stability condition (i), • for n 1 and Di >0, Trace J ðx; yÞ fx þ gy ¼ J1 þ J4 <0 • for n<1 and Di >0, Trace J ðx; yÞ fx þ gy ¼ J1 þ J4 <0 n Ki ðy ti þ Di nÞn1 < 1
if
(II) From stability condition (ii), h ih i n n Det ¼ c1 c2 K1 ðy t1 þ D1 nÞn1 þ 1 K2 ðy t2 þ D2 nÞn1 þ 1 h ih i n n c1 c2 L1 ðy t1 þ D1 nÞn1 L2 ðy t2 þ D2 nÞn1 If Det J ðx; yÞ>0, then, h
ih i h i n n n K1 ðy t1 þ D1 nÞn1 þ 1 K2 ðy t2 þ D2 nÞn1 þ 1 > L1 ðy t1 þ D1 nÞn1 h i n L2 ðy t2 þ D2 nÞn1
(III) Since no element in the matrix J is zero the other conditions of the theorem are also satisfied. □
Hence proved.
5.5
Dynamics of Warranty Competition with Adaptive Expectation
Assuming both the retailers to be adaptive, the dynamics of warranty length adjustment can be defined as below,
ti ðT þ 1Þ ¼ ð1 wi Þti ðTÞ þ wi
ðpi wÞy ci li n ½y ti ðT þ 1Þ þ Di n
1 n1
ði ¼ 1; 2Þ
298
S. Sinha and S.P. Sarmah
Here, wi 2 ½0; 1 is the speed of adjustment of the adaptive players which considers both previous warranty policy and the best response function. Now, we look for the equilibrium of the system (25). The fixed points of the map (25) are obtained as nonnegative solutions of the algebraic system by setting ti ðT þ 1Þ ¼ ti ðTÞ. This implies,
ti ðTÞ ¼
ðpi wÞy ci li n ½y ti ðT þ 1Þ þ Di n
1 n1
ði ¼ 1; 2Þ
(26)
This clearly shows that Nash equilibrium remains unchanged irrespective of the speed of adjustment. Under adaptive expectation, the warranty competition leads to the same Nash equilibrium and the Nash equilibrium is dynamically stable under the conditions shown in Proposition 4.
5.6
Dynamics of Price and Warranty Competition
In this case, we consider that both retailers dynamically adjust both retail price and warranty length in each time period. The retail price pi ðT þ 1Þ and warranty length ti ðT þ 1Þ for the period ðT þ 1Þ is decided by solving the two optimization problems (Agiza and Elsadany 2003): 9 p1 ðT þ 1Þ ¼ arg max p1 ðp1 ðTÞ; p2 e ðT þ 1ÞÞ > > p1 > > > e > p2 ðT þ 1Þ ¼ arg max p2 ðp1 ðT þ 1Þ; p2 ðTÞÞ > = p 2
t1 ðT þ 1Þ ¼ arg max p1 ðt1 ðTÞ; t2 e ðT þ 1ÞÞ > > > t1 > > > > e t2 ðT þ 1Þ ¼ arg max p2 ðt1 ðT þ 1Þ; t2 ðTÞÞ ;
(27)
t2
Here, the function pi ð:Þ denotes the profit of the retailer i and ð:Þj e ðT þ 1Þ represents the expectation of retailer i about the strategy of retailer j, ði; j ¼ 1; 2; j 6¼ iÞ. The dynamic adjustment of retail price and warranty length adjustment can be represented as follows (Ferguson and Lim 1998): 9 p_ 1 ¼ t1 ðp1 p1 Þ > > > p_ 2 ¼ t2 ðp2 p2 Þ = t_1 ¼ t3 ðt1 t1 Þ > > > ; t_2 ¼ t4 ðt2 t2 Þ
(28)
where, p_ i ¼ dpi =dT, t_i ¼ dti =dT and t1 ; t2 ; t3 ; t4 >0 are adjustment coefficients representing the speed of the adjustment. The terms ðp1 ; p2 Þ, ðt1 ; t2 Þ and
Price and Warranty Competition in a Duopoly Supply Chain
299
ðt1 ; t2 Þ, ðp1 ; p2 Þ denote the Nash equilibrium and the actual level of price and warranty length respectively at any time-period (T). We now check the dynamic stability of the system given by (28). The dynamic process can be represented by the following differential equations: p_ i ¼ ti
n 2ab þ ag gmti þ 2byti þ 2b2 ci ðli ti Þn 2bmtj þ gytj þ bcj g lj tj þ 2b2 w þ bgw 2 t_i ¼ t2þi 4
4b2 l2
! pi
3 !1 n1 ðp1 wÞy ti 5 ci li n y ti þ a bpi þ gpj þ y ti mtj n (29)
The Jacobian matrix of the dynamic system (28) is given as, 2
@ p_ 1 6 @p1 6 6 @ p_ 2 6 6 @p1 J ðp; tÞ ¼ 6 6 @ t_1 6 6 @p1 6 4 @ t_2 @p1
@ p_ 1 @p2 @ p_ 2 @p2 @ t_1 @p2 @ t_2 @p2
@ p_ 1 @t1 @ p_ 2 @t1 @ t_1 @t1 @ t_2 @t1
3 @ p_ 1 @t2 7 7 @ p_ 2 7 7 @t2 7 7 @ t_1 7 7 @t2 7 7 @ t_2 5 @t2
(30)
Further derivation of the Jacobian matrix J ðp; tÞ is given in Appendix D. Proposition 5. The Nash equilibrium under price and warranty length competition is globally asymptotically stable for the following: • For n 1: Di >0 and Det ¼ jJ ðp; tÞj>0 n • For n<1: Di >0, Ki ðy ti þ Di nÞn1 < 1, and Det ¼ jJ ðp; tÞj>0
Proof. The proof is straightforward from Theorem 1.
6 Channel Coordination In this section, we consider the different aspects of channel coordination between the retailers. A typical case may occur where both the retailers, understanding their inter-dependence, coordinate each other to set the optimal values of price/warranty duration that maximize the overall system/channel profit and thereby the individual pay-offs. The centralized policy thus includes deciding globally optimal retail price and warranty duration. The retailers can choose to decide system-wide optimal (1) retail price, (2) warranty duration, (3) both retail price and warranty duration.
300
S. Sinha and S.P. Sarmah
However, the current discussion excludes the aspect of sharing of coordination benefit.
6.1
Coordinated Policy to Set Retail Price
The system/channel profit is the total profit of the two retailers as follows, Pch ¼ p1 þ p2 Or, Pch ¼ ða bp1 þ gp2 þ yt1 mt2 Þ½p1 w c1 ðl1 t1 Þn þ ða bp2 þ gp1 þ yt2 mt1 Þ½p2 w c2 ðl2 t2 Þn . From the first order conditions, n @Pch ¼a 2bpi þ 2gpj þ yti mtj þ wb þ ci bðli ti Þn wg cj g lj tj ¼ 0; @pi ði;j ¼ 1; 2;j 6¼ iÞ
(31)
Solving, Ab þ Bg pi cp ¼ 2 2 b g2
(32)
n where, A ¼ a þ yti mtj þ wb þ ci bðli ti Þn wg cj g lj tj and, B ¼ a þ ytj n mti þ wb þ cj b lj tj wg ci gðli ti Þn ; where i; j ¼ 1; 2; i 6¼ j. The super-script “cp” indicates coordinated retail price. Finally, the system profit can be represented as, Pch cp ¼ p1 ðp1 cp ; p2 cp Þ þ p2 ðp1 cp ; p2 cp Þ.
6.2
Coordinated Policy to Set Warranty Duration
The objective of this model is to find out the system-wide optimal warranty duration for both the retailers. Since, the system profit, Pch ¼ p1 þ p2 is the total profit of the two retailers as follows, from the first order conditions, @Pch ¼0 @ti Or, "
1 n #n1 y½pi w ci ðli ti Þn m pj w cj lj tj ; ti ¼ ci li n Di n
ði; j ¼ 1; 2; j 6¼ iÞ (33)
Price and Warranty Competition in a Duopoly Supply Chain
301
The explicit solution of (33) is intractable; however iterative computation can be applied to derive the optimal solutionðt1 cw ; t2 cw Þ. The super-script “cw” indicates coordinated warranty length. The system profit is given as, Pch cw ¼ p1 ðt1 cw ; t2 cw Þ þ p2 ðt1 cw ; t2 cw Þ
6.3
(34)
Global Coordination
We use the term “global coordination” to mention a typical case where the retailers take a centralized decision to set both retail price and warranty duration to maximize system/channel profit. The system profit is the total profit of the two retailers as follows, Pch ðp1 ; p2 ; t1 ; t2 Þ ¼ p1 ðp1 ; p2 ; t1 ; t2 Þ þ p2 ðp1 ; p2 ; t1 ; t2 Þ From the first order conditions, @Pch @Pch @pi ¼ 0 and @ti ¼ 0 9 a þ 2gpj þ y ti mtj þ wb þ c1 bðli ti Þn wg cj g lj tj > > pi ¼ > > = 2b 1 " # n n1 > y½pi w ci ðli ti Þn m pj w cj lj tj > > > ti ¼ ; n ci nli Di
(35)
ði; j ¼ 1; 2; j 6¼ iÞ Solving the above simultaneous equations, the optimal ðpi g ; ti g Þ can be derived. Here, the super-script “g” indicates global coordination policy. Accordingly, Pch g ¼ p1 ðt1 g ; t2 g Þ þ p2 ðt1 g ; t2 g Þ.
7 Numerical Illustration A numerical illustration has been included to validate the mathematical models. The following data are considered for the numerical example. The data are very similar to Banker et al. (1998). a ¼ 1; 000; b ¼ 10; g ¼ 8:8; y ¼ 6; m ¼ 5:4; l1 ; l2 ¼ ½0:5; 6:0; c1 ¼ 2:5; c2 ¼ 2; w ¼ 5; n ¼ ½1:5; 5:0.
302
7.1
S. Sinha and S.P. Sarmah
Price Competition
Let us consider a typical case with, n ¼ 2:5, l1 ¼ l2 ¼ 0:5, t1 ¼ 0:5, and t2 ¼ 1:5. Let us further assume that, at t ¼ 0, retailer 1 and retailer 2 have the following offering in the market: fp1 ð0Þ ¼ 35; t1 ð0Þ ¼ 0:5g and fp2 ð0Þ ¼ 40; t2 ð0Þ ¼ 1:5g. If both the retailers compete only on the retail price, the price equilibrium is achieved at: fp1 ; p2 g ¼ f93:92; 94:63g.
7.2
Dynamics of Price Competition
Let us consider at typical case with, n ¼ 2:5, l1 ¼ l2 ¼ 0:5, t1 ¼ 0:5, and t2 ¼ 1:5. The dynamics of the price competition under naı¨ve expectation has been shown below (Table 1; Fig. 4): Dynamics of price competition with adaptive expectation has been shown below under varying speed of adjustment. It has been found that irrespective of the speed, the dynamical system converges to the same equilibrium. However, with faster speed, the equilibrium is reached faster and if v1 ¼ v2 ¼ 1, the system behaves like a dynamical system under naı¨ve expectation (Fig. 5).
7.3
Price Competition: Sensitivity Analysis
The following table shows the sensitivity of the price equilibrium on different parameters. In this experiment we have assumed the basic initial data: n ¼ 2:5, l1 ¼ l2 ¼ 0:5, t1 ¼ 0:5, and t2 ¼ 1:5 (Table 2). Table 1 Dynamics of price competition with naı¨ve expectation Sr. p1 p2 D1 p1 D2 1 35 40 997 29,829.12 914 2 69.88 68.70 901 58,366.70 934 3 82.51 84.05 909 70,420.82 892 4 89.27 89.61 891 74,993.68 896 5 91.71 92.58 892 77,318.90 888 6 93.02 93.66 889 78,168.52 888 7 93.49 94.23 889 78,618.36 887 8 93.75 94.44 889 78,781.51 887 9 93.84 94.55 889 78,868.59 887 10 93.89 94.59 888 78,900.13 887 11 93.90 94.61 888 78,916.99 887 12 93.91 94.62 888 78,923.09 887 13 93.92 94.62 888 78,926.35 887 14 93.92 94.63 888 78,927.53 887 15 93.92 94.63 888 78,928.17 887
p2 31,109.72 58,604.03 69,636.99 74,916.21 76,867.88 77,888.30 78,259.24 78,456.73 78,528.28 78,566.52 78,580.36 78,587.76 78,590.44 78,591.87 78,592.39
Pch 60,938.83 116,970.73 140,057.81 149,909.89 154,186.78 156,056.82 156,877.60 157,238.24 157,396.88 157,466.64 157,497.35 157,510.85 157,516.79 157,519.41 157,520.56
Price and Warranty Competition in a Duopoly Supply Chain
303
100
pi
75
50
p1 p2
25
0 0
5
10
15
20
25
Time period
Fig. 4 Dynamics of price competition with naı¨ve expectation 100 90 80 70
p1 p2 p1 p2 p1 p2 p1 p2
Pi
60 50 40 30 20
(v (v (v (v (v (v (v (v
= = = = = = = =
0.25) 0.25) 0.5) 0.5) 0.75) 0.75) 1.0) 1.0)
10 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43
Time period
Fig. 5 Dynamics of price competition with adaptive expectation
It shows that, the equilibrium price fp1 ; p2 g increases with increase in li and ti . However, the equilibrium price decreases with increase in n. Further, it has been observed that the channel profit increases with increase in n and decreases with increase in ti .
7.4
Price Coordination
Assuming, n ¼ 2:5, l1 ¼ l2 ¼ 0:5, t1 ¼ 0:5, and t2 ¼ 1:5, under integrated pricing policy, the optimal retail prices can be derived as: p1 cp ¼ 419:30 and p2 cp ¼ 420:05. Accordingly, the demand and profits are as below (Table 3),
304
S. Sinha and S.P. Sarmah
Table 2 Sensitivity analysis: price competition p2 Parameter Value p1 n 1.5 94.15 94.89 2.0 94.01 94.74 2.5 93.92 94.63 3.0 93.86 94.54 3.5 93.82 94.46 4.0 93.78 94.40 4.5 93.76 94.34 5.0 93.74 94.30 li 0.5 93.92 94.63 1.0 95.38 97.54 1.5 98.50 103.75 2.0 103.66 114.01 2.5 111.17 128.96 3.0 121.32 149.15 3.5 134.34 175.08 4.0 150.49 207.21 5.0 192.98 291.77 6.0 250.36 405.97 0.5 93.84 93.84 ti 1.0 94.17 94.14 1.5 94.85 94.77 2.0 95.95 95.78 2.5 97.55 97.24 3.0 99.69 99.21 3.5 102.43 101.72 4.0 105.82 104.84 4.5 109.91 108.59 5.0 114.73 113.01 Table 3 Price coordination p2 cp D1 cp p1 cp 419.30 420.05 498
p1 cp 206,427.95
p1 78,927.79 78,948.91 78,928.59 78,891.70 78,850.10 78,809.26 78,771.50 78,737.59 78,928.59 80,894.41 85,167.67 92,470.06 103,642.42 119,742.08 142,124.85 172,520.80 266,577.51 425,957.74 78,790.74 78,733.86 78,558.83 78,239.11 77,753.07 77,082.58 76,212.36 75,129.73 73,824.48 72,288.85
D2 cp 495
p2 78,487.47 78,529.12 78,592.85 78,661.91 78,728.66 78,789.95 78,844.78 78,893.15 78,592.85 75,738.65 69,827.89 60,586.82 48,300.93 33,915.78 19,160.67 6,681.53 4,546.26 72,296.33 78,808.85 78,836.28 78,840.93 78,817.57 78,761.86 78,669.99 78,538.57 78,364.53 78,145.05 77,877.56
p2 cp 205,227.87
Pch 157,415.26 157,478.03 157,521.44 157,553.60 157,578.76 157,599.21 157,616.28 157,630.74 157,521.44 156,633.07 154,995.56 153,056.88 151,943.35 153,657.86 161,285.52 179,202.33 271,123.78 498,254.06 157,599.59 157,570.14 157,399.76 157,056.68 156,514.93 155,752.57 154,750.93 153,494.26 151,969.52 150,166.40
Pch cp 411,655.82
A comparison between price competition and global coordination has been illustrated through the Fig. 6. This shows that price coordination can generate significantly higher profit as compared to that of under price competition.
7.5
Warranty Competition
We consider a case with, n ¼ 2:5, l1 ¼ l2 ¼ 0:5, p1 ¼ 35, and p2 ¼ 40. Let us further assume that, at t ¼ 0, retailer 1 and retailer 2 have the following offering in
Price and Warranty Competition in a Duopoly Supply Chain
305
450000 400000
Profit
350000
Profit of R1 (Price Competition)
300000 250000
Profit of R2 (Price Competition)
200000
Channel Profit (Price Competition)
150000
Profit of R1 (Price Coord.)
100000
Profit of R2 (Price Coord.) Channel Profit (Price Coord.)
50000 0 1
3
5
7
9
11
13
15
17
19
Time Period
Fig. 6 Price competition vs. price coordination: a comparison Table 4 Dynamics of price competition with naı¨ve expectation Sr. t1 t2 D1 p1 D2 1 0.500 t2 997 29,829.12 914 2 0.299 64.30 1,002 30,025.94 909 3 0.298 81.15 1,002 30,026.00 909 4 0.298 88.76 1,002 30,026.00 909 5 0.298 92.02 1,002 30,026.00 909
p2 31,109.72 31,775.00 31,775.22 31,775.22 31,775.22
Pch 6,0938.83 61,800.94 61,801.22 61,801.22 61,801.22
the market: t1 ð0Þ ¼ 0:5 and t2 ð0Þ ¼ 1:5. If both the retailers compete only on the warranty length, the equilibrium is achieved at:ft1 ; t2 g ¼ f0:30; 0:41g.
7.6
Dynamics of Warranty Competition
Assuming, n ¼ 2:5, l1 ¼ l2 ¼ 0:5, p1 ¼ 35, p2 ¼ 40, t1 ð0Þ ¼ 0:5 and t2 ð0Þ ¼ 1:5, the dynamics of the warranty length competition under naı¨ve expectation has been shown below (Table 4; Fig. 7): Dynamics of warranty competition with adaptive expectation has been shown below under varying speed of adjustment. It has been found that irrespective of the speed, the dynamical system converges to the same equilibrium – similar to price competition. However, with faster speed, the equilibrium is reached faster and if w1 ¼ w2 ¼ 1, the system behaves like a dynamical system under naı¨ve expectation – as observed earlier in the case of price competition (Fig. 8).
7.7
Warranty Competition: Sensitivity Analysis
The following table shows the sensitivity of the warranty equilibrium with respect to different parameters. In this experiment the basic initial data have been assumed as: n ¼ 2:5, l1 ¼ l2 ¼ 0:5, p1 ¼ 35, and p2 ¼ 40. The following table shows the sensitivity of the price equilibrium on different parameters (Table 5).
306
S. Sinha and S.P. Sarmah 1.600 1.400 1.200 t1
t(i)
1.000
t2
0.800 0.600 0.400 0.200 0.000 1
2
3 Time period
4
5
Fig. 7 Dynamics of warranty length competition with naı¨ve expectation
1.6
t1 (v = 0.25) t2 (v = 0.25)
1.4
t1 (v = 0.5) 1.2
t2 (v = 0.5) t1 (v = 0.75)
1.0 ti
t2 (v = 0.75) 0.8
t1 (v = 1.0) t2 (v = 1.0)
0.6 0.4 0.2 0.0 1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8 9 10 Time period
11
12
13
14
15
16
Fig. 8 Dynamics of warranty competition with adaptive expectation
It shows that, the equilibrium price ft1 ; t2 g increases with increase in nand pi and decreases with increase in li . The channel profit is found to increase with increase in li and pi .
7.8
Coordinated Warranty Policy
Assuming, n ¼ 2:5, l1 ¼ l2 ¼ 0:5, p1 ¼ 35, p2 ¼ 40, under integrated warranty policy, the optimal warranty length are: t1 cw ¼ 0 and t2 cw ¼ 0:15. Accordingly, the demand and profits are derived as below (Table 6),
Price and Warranty Competition in a Duopoly Supply Chain
307
Table 5 Sensitivity analysis: warranty competition t2 p1 Parameter Value t1 n 1.5 0.02 0.05 30,053.41 2.0 0.14 0.23 30,035.53 2.5 0.30 0.41 30,026.00 3.0 0.44 0.55 30,022.68 3.5 0.56 0.67 30,022.53 4.0 0.66 0.77 30,023.92 4.5 0.75 0.86 30,026.02 5.0 0.82 0.93 30,028.42 li 0.5 0.30 0.41 30,026.00 1.0 0.09 0.13 30,049.27 1.5 0.05 0.07 30,054.54 2.0 0.03 0.04 30,056.62 2.5 0.02 0.03 30,057.67 25.0 0.23 0.27 19,387.63 pi 35.0 0.31 0.36 28,715.50 45.0 0.37 0.43 37,800.12 50.0 0.41 0.47 42,251.28 60.0 0.47 0.54 50,971.38 70.0 0.53 0.61 59,448.60 80.0 0.59 0.68 67,683.02 90.0 0.64 0.75 75,674.67 100.0 0.70 0.81 83,423.57 125.0 0.84 0.97 101,733.84 150.0 0.97 1.13 118,526.83
p2 31,779.86 31,777.11 31,775.22 31,774.99 31,775.77 31,777.06 31,778.58 31,780.17 31,775.22 31,778.50 31,779.24 31,779.53 31,779.67 19,394.32 28,728.75 37,821.68 42,277.62 51,008.46 59,497.98 67,746.21 75,753.15 83,518.82 101,877.44 118,728.02
Pch 61,833.26 61,812.63 61,801.22 61,797.67 61,798.30 61,800.98 61,804.60 61,808.59 61,801.22 61,827.77 61,833.78 61,836.15 61,837.34 38,781.96 57,444.26 75,621.80 84,528.89 101,979.84 118,946.59 135,429.22 151,427.82 166,942.39 203,611.28 237,254.84
Table 6 Integrated warranty policy t2 cw D1 cw p1 cw t1 cw 0 0.15 1001 30,035.25
p2 cw 31,809.15
Pch cw 61,844.40
D2 cw 909
A comparison between warranty competition and warranty coordination has been illustrated through Fig. 9. This shows that integrated warranty policy can generate higher profit as compared to that of warranty competition.
7.9
Price and Warranty Competition
In this case, we illustrate a case where both retailers simultaneously compete on retail price and warranty length. For this example, we consider n ¼ 1:5 and 2:5, l1 ¼ l2 ¼ 0:5. Let us further assume that, at t ¼ 0, retailer 1 and retailer 2 have the following offering in the market: p1 ð0Þ ¼ 35, p2 ð0Þ ¼ 40 and t1 ð0Þ ¼ 0:5, t2 ð0Þ ¼ 1:5. Accordingly, the equilibrium price and warranty length have been derived as below (Table 7):
308
S. Sinha and S.P. Sarmah
Ch Profit (Warranty Competition)
Profit R2 (Warranty Competition)
Profit R1 (Warranty Competition)
Ch Profit (Warranty Coord.)
70000 60000
Profit
50000 40000 30000 20000 10000 0 1
2
3 Time period
4
5
Fig. 9 Warranty competition vs. warranty coordination: a comparison Table 7 Price and warranty competition ~t1 ~t2 D1 p~2 n p~1 1.5 93.83 0.20 93.89 0.32 887 2.5 93.92 0.67 93.97 0.77 888
p1 78,756.68 78,778.10
D2 888 888
p2 78,784.02 78,823.38
Pch 157,540.70 157,601.48
This shows that channel profit increases with increase in shape parameter n. Below, Fig. 10 represents the dynamics of the equilibrium for n ¼ 1:5; 2:5, l1 ¼ l2 ¼ 0:5 and the initial condition p1 ð0Þ ¼ 35, p2 ð0Þ ¼ 40 and t1 ð0Þ ¼ 0:5, t2 ð0Þ ¼ 1:5.
7.10
Global coordination
Assuming, n ¼ 2:5, l1 ¼ l2 ¼ 0:5, under integrated price and warranty policy, the optimal solutions have been derived as below (Table 8), A comparison between warranty competition and warranty coordination has been illustrated through Fig. 11.
7.11
Global Coordination: Sensitivity Analysis
Here, further experiments have been conducted to study the impact of n, Li, and ci on global coordination. The basic parameters assumed as, n ¼ 2:5, l1 ¼ l2 ¼ 0:5, c1 ¼ 2:5 and c2 ¼ 2. The results have been tabulated in Table 9. It shows that increase in shape parameter n increases channel profit, retail price, and warranty duration. However, increase in failure rate li and repair cost ci decreases channel profit, retail price, and warranty duration.
p1 (n=1.5)
p1 (n=2.5) p2 (n=2.5)
p2 (n=1.5)
309
t1 (n=1.5)
t1 (n=2.5)
t2 (n=1.5)
t2 (n=2.5)
100.0
1.6
90.0
1.4
80.0
1.2
Profit
70.0 60.0
1.0
50.0
0.8
40.0
0.6
30.0
0.4
20.0
Warranty Length
Price and Warranty Competition in a Duopoly Supply Chain
0.2
10.0 0.0
0.0 1
2
3
4
5
6
7 8 9 Time period
10
11
12
13
14
15
Fig. 10 Dynamics of price and warranty competition Table 8 Optimal price and warranty length under global coordination n p1 g t1 g p2 g t2 g D1 g p1 g D2 g p2 g 2.5
419.4
0.59
419.41
0.68
497
205,856.3
497
206,015.22
Pch g 411,871.56
450000 400000 350000 Profit R1 (Price & Warr. Comp.)
Profit
300000
Profit R2 (Price & Warr. Comp.)
250000
Channel Profit (Price & Warr. Comp.)
200000
Profit R1 (Price & Warr. Coord.) Profit R2 (Price & Warr. Coord.)
150000
Channel Profit (Price & Warr. Coord.)
100000 50000 0 1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10 11 12 13 14 15
Time period
Fig. 11 Price and warranty policy: competition vs. global coordination
8 Conclusion This chapter analyzes the coordination and competition issues in a two-stage distribution channel where two different retailers compete each other on their retail price and warranty policy to sell two substitute products in the same market.
310 Table 9 Sensitivity analysis: global coordination t1 g p2 g t2 g Parameter Value p1 g n 1.5 419.2 0.14 419.26 0.22 2.0 419.3 0.40 419.36 0.50 2.5 419.4 0.59 419.41 0.68 3.0 419.4 0.73 419.44 0.82 3.5 419.4 0.84 419.46 0.92 5 419.5 1.06 419.48 1.12 Li 0.05 428.6 27.29 430.44 31.82 0.1 422.1 8.61 422.71 10.01 0.25 419.8 1.87 419.93 2.17 0.5 419.4 0.59 419.41 0.68 1 419.2 0.19 419.24 0.22 2.5 419.2 0.04 419.18 0.05 2.5 419.4 0.59 419.37 0.59 ci 5 419.3 0.37 419.30 0.37 7.5 419.3 0.28 419.26 0.28 10 419.2 0.23 419.25 0.23 15 419.2 0.18 419.23 0.18
S. Sinha and S.P. Sarmah
D1 g 497 497 497 497 497 497 494 496 497 497 497 497 497 497 497 497 497
D2 g 497 497 497 497 497 498 511 501 498 497 497 497 497 497 497 497 497
p1 g 205,810.7 205,822.7 205,856.3 205,890.3 205,921.6 205,836.9 206,510.6 206,061.0 205,889.5 205,856.3 205,845.6 205,841.9 205,928.7 205,896.2 205,883.1 205,875.7 205,867.5
p2 g 205,901.2 205,970.8 206,015.2 206,047.7 206,072.2 206,279.9 214,038.8 208,402.0 206,395.3 206,015.2 205,895.8 205,852.8 205,928.7 205,896.2 205,883.1 205,875.7 205,867.5
Pch g 411,711.9 411,793.5 411,871.6 411,938.0 411,993.8 412,116.8 420,549.3 414,463.0 412,284.7 411,871.6 411,741.5 411,694.7 411,857.5 411,792.4 411,766.2 411,751.4 411,734.9
The demand faced by each retailer not only depends on its own price and warranty duration, but also on the price and warranty duration set by the other. Mathematical models have been developed to analyze the dynamic competition and coordination mechanism for three different cases where retailers compete (1) exclusively on price; (2) exclusively on warranty duration; (3) both price and warranty duration. The adjustment of initial price or warranty duration during dynamic competition gradually leads toward the Nash–Bertrand equilibrium following an iterative process, where at each step each retailer chooses a policy which maximizes the individual profit based on the expected policy set by her opponent. Further, we analyze the behavior of such dynamic adjustment process of price and warranty competition under two different scenarios (1) naı¨ve expectation and (2) adaptive expectation – depending on the adjustment of expectation function of each retailer. Finally, it has been shown that under non-cooperative price/warranty competition, the steady state equilibrium is dynamically stable in nature under certain conditions. It has been shown here that the channel profit for each case is higher under coordination that of under competition. The channel profit is found to be the maximum under global coordination where retailers adopt centralized policy to set price and warranty duration. However, it has been observed that though coordination enhances overall supply-chain profitability, it may make consumers worseoff due to higher product prices. The model is illustrated with suitable numerical examples. The model can significantly help industry practitioners to visualize and understand the dynamic nature of price and non-price (warranty) competition. It also can predict the overall pay-off in case of centralized or coordinated strategy.
Price and Warranty Competition in a Duopoly Supply Chain
311
Accordingly, a delicate balance between coordination and competition can be achieved in case the existing business model fails to meet profitability expectation. Thus, the industry practitioners can take a pro-active role in choosing the attribute to compete and decide when to coordinate with their competitor. The model could be extended in several directions. Various other forms of demand function could be used to replicate more realistic scenarios. Also, in most of the industrial cases, price/warranty competition takes place under asymmetric information. Further, there could be more number of players in the market; and one interesting dimension towards further research is the “entry” and “exit” decisions of a firm in the market. Finally, all retailers may not set price simultaneously. There are cases where one firm takes the role of a price-leader while the others are followers. Such type of competition model under Stackelberg game framework is also worth mentioning for future research.
Appendix A: Proof of Proposition 1 g i Proof. 1(a). It is straightforward to derive, @p @pj ¼ 2b >0, which shows both retailers change their retail price in the similar direction. (b). It has already been derived,
@pi ¼ a 2bpi þ gpj þ y ti mtj þ wb þ ci ðli ti Þn b ¼ 0 @pi @pi @pi
Given retailer j sets her retail price pj , retailer i will increase her retail price pi , if >0, a þ gpj þ y ti mtj þ wb þ ci ðli ti Þn b >pi . Or, 2b Hence proved. □
Appendix B: Proof of Proposition 2 It is straight forward to derive,
@pi 2b2 ci nðti Þn ðli Þn1 ¼ >0 @li 4b2 g2
@pi gm þ 2by þ 2b2 ci nðli Þn ðti Þn1 ¼ >0 @ti 4b2 g2 Since, g < b, m < y, then gm þ 2by > 0. Hence,
@pi @ti
>0
312
S. Sinha and S.P. Sarmah
n n @pi 2b2 ci ðli ti Þ lnðli ti Þ þ bcj g lj tj ln lj tj ¼ @n 4b2 g2
Thus,
@pi @n
n >0 if 2b2 ci ðli ti Þn lnðli ti Þ þ bcj g lj tj ln lj tj >0
Appendix C: Proof of Proposition 3 Substituting Tr JpAD and Det JpAD in condition C1, C2 and C3, (i)
v1 v2 g2 1 Tr JpAD þ Det JpAD ¼ 1 ð2 v1 v2 Þ þ ð1 v1 Þð1 v2 Þ 4b2 g2 Or, 1 Tr JpAD þ Det JpAD ¼ v1 v2 1 4b 2 . Since, v1 v2 >0, the first condi-
g 2 g tion yields 1 4b 2 >0, or, b > 4 . 2
(ii)
2
v1 v2 g2 1 þ Tr JpAD þ Det JpAD ¼ 1 þ ð2 v1 v2 Þ þ ð1 v1 Þð1 v2 Þ 4b2
g2 Or, 1 Tr JpAD þ Det JpAD ¼ 4 2ðv1 þ v2 Þ þ v1 v2 1 4b 2 . Since,0 g4 . (iii)
v1 v2 g2 Det JpAD 1 ¼ ð1 v1 Þð1 v2 Þ 1 4b2
v2 g Let, f ðvÞ ¼ ð1 v1 Þð1 v2 Þ v14b 2 g2 C ¼ 1 4b . 2 0 The Hessian matrix for f ðvÞ, Hv ¼ C following the first order conditions, v1 ¼ v2
2
if C>0 or, b2 > g4 . □ Hence Proved. 2
1 ¼ ðv1 v2 þ v1 v2 CÞ,
where
C shows that f ðvÞ is concave. Thus, 0 ¼ C1 and f ðvÞ ¼ 1 C . Thus, Max: f ðvÞ<0
gmþ2byþ2b2 c1 nl1 n t1 n1
!
2bmþgyþbc2 gnl2 n t2 n1
!3
where, X1 ¼
p1 y wy p2 y wy ; Y ; Y2 ¼ ½y t2 þ D2 n. ¼ ½ y t þ D n , X ¼ 1 1 1 2 c 1 l1 n c2 l2 n
t1 t1 0 t1 6 7 6 7 4b2 l2 4b2 l2 6 ! !7 6 7 6 2bmþgyþbc1 gnl1 n t1 n1 gmþ2byþ2b2 c2 nl2 n t2 n1 7 6 7 0 t t t2 1 2 6 7 6 7 4b2 l2 4b2 l2 6 7 2 3 6 7 1 J ðp;tÞ ¼ 6
h i h i 7 n1 2n 1 1 n 1 n n t p ywy 6 3 7 1 4 5 X1 n1 Y1 n1 þX1 n1 bnY1 n1 t3 K1 ðyt1 þD1 nÞn1 þ1 t3 ½gnn1 t3 L1 ðyt1 þD1 nÞn1 6 7 n 6 n1 7 c1 l1 6 7 6 7 2 3 6 7 1
h i h i 6 7 n1 1 2n 1 1 n n n p ywy t 2 4 4 5 4 5 n1 n1 n1 n1 n1 n1 n1 X2 Y2 t4 t4 K2 ðyt2 þD2 nÞ t4 L2 ðyt2 þD2 nÞ ðgnÞ þX2 bnY2 þ1 n1 c2 l2 n
2
Appendix D: The Jacobian Matrix J ðp; tÞ
314
S. Sinha and S.P. Sarmah
References Agiza HN, Elsadany AA (2003) Nonlinear dynamics in the Cournot duopoly game with heterogeneous players. Phys A 320:512–524 Agiza HN, and Elsadany AA (2004) Chaotic dynamics in nonlinear duopoly game with heterogeneous players, Applied Mathematics and Computation 149(3):843–860 Agliari A, Gardini L, Puu T (2000) The dynamics of a triopoly Cournot game, Chaos, Solitons and Fractals 11(15):2531–2560 Bertrand J (1883) ‘Theorie mathematique de la Richesse Sociale par Leon Walras and Recherches sur les principes mathematique de la theorie des dicheses par Augustin Coumot’, Journal des Savants, pp. 499–508, translated by Friedman, J.W. (1988). In: Daughety AR (ed) Coumot oligopoly. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 73–81 Blischke W, Murthy D (1996) Product warranty handbook. Marcel Dekker, New York Choi SC (1991) Price competition in a channel structure with a common retailer, Marketing Science 10(4):271–296 Choi SC (2003) Expanding to direct channel: market converges as entry barrier. J Interact Mark 17(1):25–40 Connelly M (2006) Dealers: extended factory warranties boost profits. Automot News Detroit 81:46 Cournot A (1938) Researches into the mathematical principles of the theory of wealth, translated by Bacon NT (1960). Kelley, New York Ferguson BS, Lim GC (1998) Introduction to Dynamic Economic models. Manchester University Press, Manchester, M13 9NR, UK Ha A, Li L, Ng SM (2003) Price and delivery logistics competition in a supply chain. Manage Sci 49(9):1139–1153 Hu W-T (2008) Supply chain coordination contracts with free replacement warranty. Doctoral dissertation, Drexel University, Philadelphia, PA McGuire TW, Staelin R (1983) An industry equilibrium analysis of downstream vertical integration, Marketing Science, 2 (Spring), 161–191 Menezes MAJ, Currim IS (1992) An approach for determination of warranty length. Int J Res Mark 9:177–196 Moorthy KS (1988) Product and price competition in a duopoly. Mark Sci 7(2):141–168 Murthy NP (2006) Product warranty and reliability. Ann Oper Res 143:133–146 Olech C (1963) On the global stability of an autonomous system on the plane, in Contributions to Differential Equations. In: Lasalle JP, Diaz JB. (Eds.), Vol.1, Wiley, New York Padmanabhan V (1993) Warranty policy and extended service contracts: theory and an application to automobiles. Mark Sci 12:230–248 Rao CR (1991) Pricing and promotions in asymmetric duopoly. Mark Sci 10(2):131–144 Scherer K (2006) GM warranties take big leap. Automot News Detroit 81:30 Shone R (2001) An introduction to economic dynamics. Cambridge University Press, New York, pp 1–5 Shy O (2003) How to price. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Sinha S, Sarmah SP (2010) Coordination and price competition in a duopoly common retailer supply chain. Comput Ind Eng 59(2):280–295 So KC (2000) Price and time competition for service delivery. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 2(4):392–409 Tsay A, Agrawal N (2000) Channel dynamics under price and service competition. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 2(4):372–391 Wu C-C, Lin P-C, Chou C-Y (2009) Optimal price, warranty length and production rate for free replacement policy in the static demand market. Omega 37(1):29–39 Yao DQ, Liu J (2005) Competitive pricing of mixed retail and e-tail distribution channels. Omega 33:235–247
Supply Chain Coordination for Newsvendor-Type Products with Two Ordering Opportunities Yong-Wu Zhou and Sheng-Dong Wang
Abstract This chapter discusses supply chain coordination issues for a newsvendor-type product with two ordering opportunities. We consider a twoechelon supply chain consisting of one manufacturer and one buyer, where the manufacturer sells his product through the buyer who faces a random demand. The manufacturer does not hold inventory but activates production with a fixed production setup cost to respond to the buyer’s order. At the start of the selling period, the buyer’s first order is delivered. By the end of the sales period, an urgent second order is allowed to meet the willingly-backordered demand if the buyer shares the manufacturer’s setup cost incurred by the second order. We discuss two parties’ optimal order policies in the decentralized setting, and examine the impact of pool schemes of the second setup cost on the decentralized system performance. We show that the decentralized system would perform best if the manufacturer covers utterly the second production setup cost. Also, we prove that under the twice-order framework in the chapter the expected profit of the centralized system is not equal to but greater than the sum of two members’ expected profits in the decentralized system, which is not consistent with our expectation. In order to maximize the expected profit of the channel, two coordinated policies are proposed to achieve perfect coordination: a two-part-tariff policy for the special case that the buyer pays all the manufacturing setup cost, and a revised revenue-sharing contract for the case that two parties share the manufacturing setup cost. Keywords Supply chain coordination • Newsvendor model • Two ordering opportunities • Partial backlogging • Revised revenue-sharing contract Y.-W. Zhou (*) School of Business Administration, South China University of Technology, Guangzhou, Guangdong, P.R. China e-mail: [email protected] S.-D. Wang Department of Mathematics, Hefei Electronic Engineering Institute, Hefei, Anhui, P.R. China e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_13, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
315
316
Y.-W. Zhou and S.-D. Wang
1 Introduction Like our human beings, products have also their own life cycle. From introduction to decline products pass through various stages: introduction, growth, maturity, saturation and decline. Nowadays, with the rapid improvement of technology, the life cycle of products becomes shorter and shorter. It makes more and more products, like USB flash drivers, personal computers, mobile phones, fashion apparel, etc., to have the attributes of fashion or seasonal goods. We call all of short life-cycle products as fashion products or newsvendor-type products. For nonfashion products, like most of fast moving consumer products, we all know that there exists substantial progress in theory and application of supply chain management. But the same success has not been achieved for fashion products. Fisher and Raman (1999) pointed out three possible reasons. First, the demand patterns for these products make the estimation of demand and demand variability extremely difficult. Second, traditional demand forecasting methods usually assume that at least 1 year of demand history is available, which is not possible for short life-cycle products since their life cycles are generally less than 1 year. Finally, the cost of carrying inventory is much higher for short life-cycle products because of the risk of obsolescence. The challenge in managing supply chains for newsvendor-type products is to ensure product availability while keeping leftover products as low as possible. In the past five decades, both researchers and practitioners paid much attention on supply chain management for newsvendor-type products. A lot of models on this topic can be found in literature (see Sect. 2). Most of the existing models, which studied supply chain coordination problems for single-period items under the newsvendor framework, assumed that products could be ordered (or produced) only once during the whole selling period. Consequently, the decision maker is unable to take advantage of the subsequent information that becomes available as the season draws closer or after the season begins. In reality, however, newsvendortype products can be replenished many times in the selling season. For example, in the 1980s Benetton, the fashion retail giant, significantly reduced markdowns and leftover inventory by employing a second order opportunity around the start of the season. This phenomenon leads to a lot of researches on the newsvendor models with two order opportunities. Most of these researches, such as Lau and Lau (1998) and Li et al. (2009b), considered the following twice-order framework: the first order is placed at the start of the preseason and delivered at the start of the selling season; the second order is placed at or after the start of the selling season for subsequent delivery. Besides, there is yet another class of models, in which twice orders are placed before the start of the season. However, the models just mentioned only considered how retailers make their twice-order decisions but neglected the coordination issues of supply chains. The main aim of this chapter is to discuss coordination issues of a manufacturerbuyer supply chain for newsvendor-type products with two ordering opportunities. Unlike the two twice-order frameworks mentioned above, we consider such
Supply Chain Coordination for Newsvendor-Type Products
317
a twice-order framework, in which the first order is placed at the start of the season and the second one (if needed) is placed at the end of the season. This framework is first employed by Weng (2004). Its benefit is mainly in that placing the second order at the end of the season can obtain accurate demand information. Under the framework, we will consider such a situation that a manufacturer supplies a newsvendor-type product to a buyer who faces a stochastic demand. The manufacturer does not hold inventory but activates production with a fixed production setup cost to respond to the buyer’s order. At the beginning of the selling period, the buyer’s first order is delivered from the manufacturer to the buyer in order to meet random demand. Due to the uncertainty of demand, the actual demand during the selling period may deviate from the ordered lot size. By the end of the sales period, if the demand exceeds the ordered quantity, the buyer would have an opportunity to place an urgent second order from the manufacturer to meet the willinglybackordered demand as long as the buyer shares the manufacturer’s second setup cost incurred by the second order. The main questions we concern are the following (1) What is the first order lot size of the buyer and whether should he/she place the second order? (2) Whether should the manufacturer activate an urgent second production in response to the buyer’s second order? (3) How do we design an effective mechanism to coordinate the whole supply chain? The coordination problem considered in this chapter generalizes that in Weng (2004), where the manufacturing setup cost of the second order (if happened) is paid utterly by the buyer and the demands exceeded the first order quantity are all backordered. One of the aims of this chapter is to observe the impact of the fraction that the buyer shares the second setup cost on the decentralized system performance. Our research shows that the performance of the decentralized system decreases as the proportion of the second production setup cost shared by the buyer increases. It implies that the decentralized system performs best if the second setup cost is utterly paid by the manufacturer itself but worst if the second setup cost is paid only by the buyer, like in Weng (2004). Another difference between Weng (2004) and this chapter is that Weng (2004) considered the sum of the two members’ expected profits as the total expected profit of the centralized system, whereas this chapter has shown that the expected profit of the centralized system is always greater than the sum of the two members’ expected profits. Consequently, the quantity discount mechanism shown in Weng (2004) could not coordinate the decentralized channel really to the “centralized” system. We present in the chapter two perfect coordination scenarios: a two-part-tariff policy for the special case that the buyer pays all the manufacturing setup cost, and a revised revenue-sharing contract for the general case that the two parties share the manufacturing setup cost. The two coordination mechanisms optimize the expected profit of the whole supply chain rather than the sum of two parties’ expected profits. Hence, they achieve the perfect coordination of the decentralized system. While our work directly generalizes the work of Weng (2004), it also nicely complements the work of Lau and Lau (1998) and Milner and Kouvelis (2005). The key differences are that (1) they do not allow for partial backorders, (2) they focus on determining the buyer’s twice order policies, whereas we focus on how the buyer
318
Y.-W. Zhou and S.-D. Wang
sets the twice-order policies but also on how to design the perfect coordination mechanism of the whole channel, and (3) two different twice-order frameworks are considered. The remainder of the chapter is organized as the following. Section 2 reviews briefly the related literature. Section 3 describes the problems discussed in the chapter and introduces notations and assumptions needed by developing the model. While Sect. 4 shows the mathematical model for the decentralized system, Sect. 5 develops the mathematical model for the centralized system. Also, Sect. 5 compares the optimal policies between the decentralized and centralized system and discusses the property of the decentralized system performance. Section 6 presents a two-part-tariff model that can achieve perfect coordination of the system under the special case that the buyer pays all the manufacturing setup cost, and a revised revenue-sharing contract that can realize perfect coordination of the channel under the case that two parties share the manufacturing setup cost. In Sect. 7, two numerical examples are shown to illustrate the model. Conclusions are given in Sect. 8.
2 Literature Review Over the past five decades, both researchers and practitioners have had great interest in operations management issues for newsvendor-type products. A lot of models on this topic can be found in publications, of which the earlier ones mainly focused on how to find the buyer’s appropriate ordering policies to maximize (minimize) his or her expected profit (cost) (see, e.g., Whitin 1955; Goodman and Moody 1970; Kabak and Schiff 1978; Ismail and Louderback 1979; Atkinson 1979; Lau 1980; Nahmias and Schmidt 1984). An excellent review about these earlier researches can be seen in Khouja (1999). Due to the globalization of market and competition, the idea of supply chain management becomes very popular. Many researchers have shifted their attention to coordination issues of the supply chain for newsvendor-type products. For example, through the returns policy, Pasternack (1985) presented a supply chain coordination model in which a single manufacturer sold a single newsvendor-type product to a single retailer. He pointed out that it was an effective coordinating policy to take back residual products from the retailer at the end of selling period. Emmons and Gilbert (1998) further studied the role of returns policies in pricing and inventory decisions for catalogue goods. Taylor (2002) employed a one-period model with one supplier and one retailer to explore the rebate policy. Cachon (2003) developed a supply chain coordination model with price dependent demand. Webster and Weng (2008) presented an ordering and pricing model in a manufacturing and distribution supply chain for newsvendor-type products. Arcelus et al. (2008) developed a two-echelon supply chain model to depict the profitability of a secondary market to a profit-maximizing manufacturer, who was offering to the retailer a buyback policy for the unsold merchandise left at the end of
Supply Chain Coordination for Newsvendor-Type Products
319
the selling season. Due to the difficulty of obtaining the analytical results, they resorted to the numerical analysis. Li et al. (2009a) considered the supply chain coordination and decision making issue under consignment contract with revenue sharing. Chen et al. (2010) studied a coordination contract for a supplier–retailer channel where a fashionable product with a stochastic price-dependent demand is produced and sold. They formulated a two-stage optimization problem in which the supplier first decides the amount of capacity reservation, and the retailer then determines the order quantity and the retail price after observing the demand information. Other related studies included Chen et al. (2006), Wong et al. (2009), etc. However, all the researches mentioned above ignored demand information updating. That is, they assumed that the retailer orders only once during the whole selling period (including the lead time). The existing literature concerning the newsvendor model with two ordering opportunities can be divided into three categories. The first category assumed that the retailer’s two ordering opportunities take place before the season. Following the initial order, additional market information is obtained. Then, based on an improved demand forecast, the second-order amount is decided before the selling period. For example, Donohue (2000) formulated an efficient supply contract for fashion goods with forecast updating before the season and two production modes. Choi et al. (2003) developed a two-stage optimal ordering model with Bayesian information updating. Serel (2009) investigated a quick response system in which retailers place separate orders for a product at two different times before the selling season. The second one assumed that the retailer’s first order happens at the beginning of the season and the other within the season. Lau and Lau (1997, 1998) were possibly the first to consider the situation in which a second order is placed within the selling period. Through dynamic programming, Milner and Kouvelis (2005) also proposed a single-period inventory model with two ordering opportunities. Yet they focused on examining the interplay between the value of information and flexibility in their order decisions. Li et al. (2009b) further conducted a comprehensive analysis of the stocking problem with two order opportunities, with focus on elucidating the optimal ordering policy structure, whereas Pan et al. (2009) presented a two-period pricing and ordering model for the dominant retailer in a two-echelon supply chain with demand information updating. However, these researches considered retailers’ ordering and pricing issues only. In the third category, it is assumed that retailers have two ordering opportunities happening at the beginning and the end of the season, respectively. For instance, Weng (2004) developed a newsvendor-type coordination model for a single-manufacturer single-buyer supply chain with two ordering opportunities. Zhou and Li (2007) discussed an issue similar to that in Weng (2004) by considering the buyer’s inventory cost but neglecting the buyer’s backorder cost. Wang et al. (2010) developed a supply chain coordination model for newsvendor-type products with two ordering opportunities. In their model, they allowed the manufacturer to use two different production modes to respond to the retailer’s twice orders, and employed the general functions of different forms to model the expected market demand that is dependent on price and advertising expenditure.
320
Y.-W. Zhou and S.-D. Wang
3 Notations and Assumptions Consider a two-echelon supply chain where a manufacturer sells a newsvendor-type product through a buyer, who faces a stochastic demand. The manufacturer does not hold inventory of finished products but activates production with a fixed production setup cost and the negligible manufacturing or assembling time to respond to the buyer’s order. At the beginning of the selling period, an initial order is delivered from the manufacturer to the buyer. Then, the buyer uses the initial order delivered to meet random demand. Due to the uncertainty of demand, the actual demand during the selling period may deviate from the ordered lot size. By the end of the sales period, if the demand exceeds the ordered quantity, the buyer would have an opportunity to place an urgent second order from the manufacturer to meet the willingly-backordered demand as long as the buyer shares the manufacturer’s second setup cost incurred by the second order. Our key questions are the following (1) What is the optimal lot size of the first order? (2) Whether should a second order be placed and an urgent second production activated? (3) What is the impact of pool schemes of the urgent setup cost on the decentralized system performance? (4) How do we design coordination mechanism of the supply chain? A number of industries fall into our model. For example, in the mobile telecom industry, each mobile phone manufacturer (such as Motorola, Nokia or Sumsung) may sell through its downstream telecom service companies who use its equipment. For a new-model mobile phone, telecom service providers would tend to purchase an initial lot size of the new equipment from the mobile phone manufacturer, and then bind some special service with the new-style mobile phone. While the newstyle mobile phone is out of stock during the selling period, part of customers may be willing to wait till the next order is delivered due to their preference to the service and brand. The model we will present in the chapter can be applied to this case. In order to develop our model, the following notations and assumptions are used. Some other notations are given where they are needed. Assumptions 1. The buyer faces a random demand. 2. Each of the two parties has complete information about the other’s cost structure. 3. The manufacturer does not hold inventory and the production time for any lot size is neglected. 4. The buyer has complete demand information before she places her second order and all excess demand (after the first order) is observed but partially backlogged. 5. Both the manufacturer and the buyer share the second production setup cost once the second production happened at the end of the selling season. 6. Among many alternative objectives, we use the common expected profit function as the objectives of two parties. Notations x The random demand for the buyer with increasing concave CDF F(x), PDF f(x) and mean m
Supply Chain Coordination for Newsvendor-Type Products
p c r b
b k Q ti si l
v
321
The buyer’s unit sales price The buyer’s unit purchase price, or the manufacturer’s wholesale price The buyer’s salvage value (e.g., unit discount sales price) The backlogging rate (0 b 1), which means a fraction b of the excess demand during the stock out period is backordered, and the remaining fraction (1 b) is lost The buyer’s unit backorder cost The buyer’s unit shortage cost for the lost sales The buyer’s (first) order quantity The buyer’s ordering and transportation cost for the i-th (i ¼ 1,2) order The manufacturer’s production setup cost for the i-th (i ¼ 1,2) setup The proportion of the manufacturer’s second production setup cost shared by the buyer once the second production happened. This can be explained as a compensation for the manufacturer’s loss incurred by changing the production plan or an incentive for the manufacturer to activate the second production when the buyer place a second order, where 0l1 The manufacturer’s unit production cost
To avoid unrealistic and trivial cases, assume that the following relationship is kept: p > c > v > r and p + k c b > 0.
4 Decentralized Order Policies Consider first the decentralized decision-making system. In this setting, the profitmaximizing buyer would determine independently the initial order quantity Q for the whole sales period, and whether to place a second order to satisfy the part of the unfilled demand at the end of the selling period if he is required to share the setup cost incurred by his second order. The manufacturer would then determine whether to activate a second production in response to the buyer’s second order. Since an order of Q units is placed by the buyer at the start of the sales period, then by the end of the selling period, if demand x exceeds the order quantity Q, there would be a shortage of (x Q) units, of which b(x Q) units could be backordered. Therefore, at the end of the sales period, the buyer will have two alternatives: either place a second order of b(x Q) units, or do not. If the buyer chooses the former, her or his profit will be (p c b)b(x Q) k(1 b) (x Q) t2 ls2. In contrast, if the buyer selects the latter, the corresponding profit is k(x Q). Generally, the buyer is willing to place a second order if the former can have the buyer get more profits than does the latter, i.e., ðp c bÞbðx QÞ kð1 bÞðx QÞ t2 ls2 kðx QÞ or bðx QÞ qb ¼ ðt2 þ ls2 Þ=ðp þ k c bÞ: It means that qb is the buyer’s threshold quantity beyond which the buyer places a second order. On the other hand, as pointed out by Weng (2004), the manufacturer
322
Y.-W. Zhou and S.-D. Wang
would be usually willing to satisfy the second order if it yields positive profit. Hence, the manufacturer is willing to activate a second production in response to the buyer’s second order as long as (c v)b(x Q) (1 l)s2 0 or b(x Q) qm ¼ (1 l)s2/(c v). It shows that qm is a threshold quantity beyond which the manufacturer makes a second production. Generally speaking, qb and qm are probably unequal. That is to say, the manufacturer may not be willing to activate a second production while the buyer is willing to place a second order. Likewise, the buyer may not be willing to place a second order yet while the manufacturer is willing to activate a second run production. In what follows, for convenience, we first derive the expected profits of both the manufacturer and the buyer respectively in terms of two cases: qb qm and qb qm. We then develop the buyer’s optimal ordering policy in the decentralized system.
4.1
Case with qb qm
In this case, by the end of the selling period, there might be four situations pertaining to the practical demand x. Figure 1 shows a sketch of the four situations. Situation 1: The practical demand x does not exceed the order quantity Q. In such a situation, the buyer has (Q x) units left at the end of the selling period. Hence, the buyer’s and manufacturer’s profits will be respectively given by BP1 ðx; QÞ ¼ px þ rðQ xÞ cQ t1 ;
MP1 ðx; QÞ ¼ ðc vÞQ s1 :
Situation 2: Q < x < Q + qb/b. Under this situation, the backordered demand b(x Q) is less than the buyer’s threshold quantity qb. So the buyer does not place a second order and the demand of (x Q) units is lost. Thus, the profits of both parties can be expressed as BP1 ðx; QÞ ¼ ðp cÞQ kðx QÞ t1 ;
MP1 ðx; QÞ ¼ ðc vÞQ s1 :
Situation 3: Q + qb/b x < Q + qm/b. In this situation, the backordered demand b(x Q) exceeds the buyer’s threshold quantity but does not reach the manufacturer’s. It means that the buyer is willing to place a second order but the manufacturer is not willing to activate a second production if the buyer orders only b(x Q) units. If to want the second order satisfied, the buyer has to order at least qm units. However, the order quantity qm is larger than the backlogged demand, which means that the buyer would bear the loss in purchasing costs of unsold items of (qm b(x Q)) units. If the buyer places a second order of qm units, the buyer’s profit is ðp c bÞbðx QÞ kð1 bÞðx QÞ ðc rÞ½qm bðx QÞ t2 ls2 : 1
2 Q
3 Q+ qb /b
Fig. 1 Four possible situations of the practical demand
4 Q+ qm /b
x
Supply Chain Coordination for Newsvendor-Type Products
323
In contrast, if the buyer does not place a second order, the corresponding profit is k(x Q). It is obvious that the buyer is willing to place a second order of qm units if the difference of these profits is nonnegative, i.e., (p c b)b(x Q) which k(1 b)(x Q) (c r)[qm b(x Q)] t2 ls2 k(x Q), is equivalent to b(x Q) q0 ¼ [t2 þ ls2 þ (c r)qm]/(p þ k r b) or x Q þ q0/b. Therefore, when Q þ qb/b x < Q þ q0/b, there is no second transaction happened and both parties’ profits still are BP1(x, Q)¼(p c)Q k(x Q) t1 and MP1(x, Q) ¼ (c v)Q s1; whereas when Q þ q0/b x < Q þ qm/b, the buyer will place a second order of qm units and the manufacturer is also willing to reproduce qm units. Then, when Q þ q0/b x < Q þ qm /b, the profits of the buyer and manufacturer will respectively be BP1 ðx; QÞ ¼ ðp cÞQ þ ðp c bÞbðx QÞ kð1 bÞðx QÞ ðc rÞ½qm bðx QÞ t1 t2 ls; MP1 ðx; QÞ ¼ ðc vÞ½Q þ qm s1 ð1 lÞs2 : Situation 4: x Q+qm/b. That is, the backlogged demand b(x Q) is larger than both partners’ threshold quantities. Thus, the buyer will place a second order with quantity b(x Q), and the manufacturer will also quickly activate a second production in order to ensure the ordered items satisfied in time. Hence, under such a situation, both parties’ profits are given by BP1 ðx; QÞ ¼ ðp cÞQ þ ðp c bÞbðx QÞ kð1 bÞðx QÞ t1 t2 ls2 : MP1 ðx; QÞ ¼ ðc vÞ½Q þ bðx QÞ s1 ð1 lÞs2 : Based on the above analysis, one easily derived that the buyer’s expected profit is: BP1 ðQÞ ¼
ðQ 0
þ
BP1 ðx; QÞf ðxÞdx þ
ð Qþqm =b Qþq0 =b
ð Qþq0 =b Q
BP1 ðx; QÞf ðxÞdx þ
¼ ðp þ k c bÞ½Q þ b þ ðp þ k rÞ
ðQ
BP1 ðx; QÞf ðxÞdx
ð þ1
ð þ1 Qþq0 =b
Qþqm =b
BP1 ðx; QÞf ðxÞdx
ðx QÞf ðxÞdx
ðx QÞf ðxÞdx þ bQ km
0
t1 ðt2 þ ls2 Þ½1 FðQ þ q0 =bÞ ð Qþqm =b ½qm bðx QÞf ðxÞdx: ðc rÞ Qþq0 =b
(1)
324
Y.-W. Zhou and S.-D. Wang
The manufacturer’s expected profit is given by MP1 ðQÞ ¼
ð Qþq0 =b 0
þ
MP1 ðx; QÞf ðxÞdx þ
ð þ1 Qþqm =b
ð Qþqm =b Qþq0 =b
MP1 ðx; QÞf ðxÞdx
MP1 ðx; QÞf ðxÞdx:
¼ ðc vÞ½Q þ b
ð þ1 Qþq0 =b
(2)
ðx QÞf ðxÞdx
s1 ð1 lÞs2 ½1 FðQ þ q0 =bÞ ð Qþqm =b þ ðc vÞ ½qm bðx QÞf ðxÞdx Qþq0 =b
4.2
Case with qb qm
Similarly, when qb qm, if by the end of the selling period the practical demand x is less than or equal to Q, there are (Q x) units left at the end of the sales period. Hence, the buyer does not need to place a second order. When Q < x < Q þ qb/b, the backlogged demand b(x Q) is less than the buyer’s threshold quantity. So the buyer has no incentive to place a second order. If x Q þ qb/b, the backordered demand b(x Q) is larger than the threshold quantities of both parties. Thus, the buyer will place a second order with quantity b(x Q) whereas the manufacturer will also activate a second production for the buyer’s second order. Figure 2 describes graphically the buyer’s second order decision. Under the above twice-ordering strategy, one can obtain that the buyer’s expected profit is: BP2 ðQÞ ¼ ðp þ k c bÞ½Q þ b þ ðp þ k r Þ
ðQ
ð þ1 Qþqb =b
ðx QÞf ðxÞdx (3)
ðx QÞf ðxÞdx
0
þ bQ km t1 ðt2 þ ls2 Þ½1 FðQ þ qb =bÞ:
No shortage
Q
No second order
Q+ qm /b
Fig. 2 The buyer’s second decision
Place a second order of b(x-Q) units Q+ qb /b
x
Supply Chain Coordination for Newsvendor-Type Products
And, the manufacturer’s expected profit is given by ð þ1 ðx QÞf ðxÞdx s1 ð1 lÞs2 MP2 ðQÞ ¼ðc vÞ½Q þ b Qþqb =b
325
(4)
½1 FðQ þ qb =bÞ: Summarizing the above two cases will give the expected profits of the buyer and the manufacturer in the decentralized system respectively as MP1 ðQÞ qb qm BP1 ðQÞ qb qm and MPðQÞ ¼ : (5) BPðQÞ ¼ BP2 ðQÞ qb qm MP2 ðQÞ qb qm From (5), one can derive the property of the manufacturer’s expected profit function, MP(Q). Property 1. The manufacturer’s expected profit under the decentralized system, MP(Q), is a monotone increasing function with respect to Q. Proof. (i) If qb qm, the first-order derivative of MP1(Q) with respect to Q will be MP01 ðQÞ ¼ ðc vÞ½1 b þ bFðQ þ qm =bÞþ½ð1 lÞs2 ðc vÞqm f ðQ þ q0 =bÞ ¼ ðc vÞ½1 b þ bFðQ þ qm =bÞ > 0; which means that MP1(Q) is a monotone increasing function of Q. (ii) If qb qm, the first-order derivative of MP2(Q) with respect to Q is MP02 ðQÞ ¼ ðc vÞ½1 b þ bFðQ þ qb =bÞþ½ð1 lÞs2 ðc vÞqb f ðQ þ qb =bÞ:
(6)
Since f 0 (x) < 0, then FðQ þ qb =bÞ > ðQ þ qb =bÞf ðQ þ qb =bÞ:
(7)
Substituting (7) into (6) gives MP0 2(Q) > (c v)(1 b) þ [(c v)bQ þ (1 l)s2]f(Q þ qb/b) > 0. Hence, MP2(Q) is also a monotone increasing function of Q. □ Based on Property 1, we present the buyer’s optimal ordering policies in the decentralized system in Theorem 1. Theorem 1. For any increasing concave CDF F(.), the buyer’s unique optimal ordering policy, Qb, that maximizes the buyer’s expected profit is given by Qb1 ; qb qm Qb ¼ ; Qb2 ; qb qm
326
Y.-W. Zhou and S.-D. Wang
where Qb1 and Qb2 are respectively given by ðp þ k rÞFðQb 1 Þ þ ðp þ k r bÞbFðQb 1 þ q0 =bÞ ðc rÞbFðQb 1 þ qm =bÞ þ ðp þ k cÞð1 bÞ þ bb ¼ 0 ðp þ k rÞFðQb 2 Þ þ ðp þ k c bÞbFðQb 2 þ qb =bÞ þ ðp þ k cÞð1 bÞ þ bb ¼ 0:
(8)
(9)
Proof. (i) For the case with qb qm, taking the first- and second-order derivatives of BP1(Q) shown in (1) with respect to Q will respectively give
BP01 ðQÞ ¼ ðp þ k rÞFðQÞ þ ðp þ k r bÞbFðQ þ q0 =bÞ ðc rÞbFðQ þ qm =bÞ þ ðp þ k cÞð1 bÞ þ b
(10)
BP001 ðQÞ¼ðpþkrÞ½f ðQÞbf ðQþq0 =bÞbbf ðQþq0 =bÞðcrÞbf ðQþqm =bÞ: (11) Since F00 (x) < 0, i.e., f 0 (x) < 0, f(Q) > f(Q + q0/b). Hence, from (11) one has BP00 1(Q) < 0. Additionally, from (10) one easily derives that limQ !þ1 BP01 ðQÞ ¼ ðc rÞ < 0 and limQ !0þ BP01 ðQÞ ¼ ðp þ k r bÞbFðq0 =bÞ ðc rÞbFðqm =bÞ þ ðp þ k cÞð1 bÞ þ bb: It is obvious that if (p þ k r b)bF(q0/b) (c r)bF(qm/b) þ (p þ k c) (1 b) þ bb 0, then BP0 1(Q) 0, i.e., BP1(Q) is a monotone decreasing function of Q. Thus, the buyer’s optimal order quantity will be Qb1 ¼ 0, which implies that no business happens between the manufacturer and the buyer. In order to avoid such unrealistic and trivial cases, we assume in the subsequent analysis that if qb qm, ðp þ k r bÞbFðq0 =bÞ ðc rÞbFðqm =bÞ þ ðp þ k cÞð1 bÞ þ bb > 0: (12) Hence, there exists a unique positive root Qb1 to equation BP0 1(Q) ¼ 0. Since BP00 1(Q) < 0, BP1(Q) reaches its maximum at Qb1. (ii) If qb qm, the first- and second-order derivatives of BP2(Q) given in (3) with respect to Q will be respectively BP02 ðQÞ ¼ ðpþk rÞFðQÞþðpþk cbÞbFðQþqb =bÞþðpþk cÞð1bÞþbb
Supply Chain Coordination for Newsvendor-Type Products
327
and BP002 ðQÞ ¼ ðp þ k rÞf ðQÞ þ ðp þ k c bÞbf ðQ þ qb =bÞ: Since F00 (x) < 0 and 0 b 1, one has BP00 2(Q) < 0. It is easy to check that limQ !þ1 BP02 ðQÞ ¼ ðc rÞ < 0 and limQ !0þ BP02 ðQÞ ¼ ðp þ k c bÞbFðqb =bÞ þ ðp þ k cÞð1 bÞ þ bb > 0: Thus, there exists a unique positive root Qb2 to BP0 2(Qb2) ¼ 0. Hence, Qb2 is the maximum point of BP2(Q). □ Substituting Qb1 into (1) and (2) if qb qm and Qb2 into (3) and (4) if qb qm will give the optimal expected profits of the buyer and the manufacturer, BP(Qb) and MP(Qb).
5 Centralized Order Policy Consider now a situation where both the manufacturer and the buyer are willing to cooperate to pursue the centralized optimal ordering policy. Hence, unlike in the decentralized channel, the objective in this setting is to maximize the expected total profit of the system. In the subsequent analysis, we first formulate the expected total profit of the system. As described in Sect. 4, the second transaction between the two parties in the decentralized system will occur only if both parties have profits higher than those in the case without the second order (or production). In the centralized system, however, even if the second transaction results in the decrease of one party’s profit, it will still occur if it can lead to the increase of the channel’s profit. That is to say, the occurrence of the second transaction will be subject only to the following condition ðp c bÞbðx QÞ kð1 bÞðx QÞ t2 þ ðc vÞbðx QÞ s2 kðx QÞ or bðx QÞ qc ¼ ðt2 þ s2 Þ=ðp þ k v bÞ: It indicates that qc is the threshold quantity of the centralized system, beyond which the second transaction will occur.
328
Y.-W. Zhou and S.-D. Wang
Similarly, for the centralized system, if the practical demand during the selling period is x, the profit of the system is given by 8 px þ rðQ xÞ vQ t1 s1 ; if x Q > > > > > < ðp vÞQ kðx QÞ t1 s1 ; if Q < x < Q þ qc =b JPðx; QÞ ¼ > ðp vÞQ þ ðp v bÞbðx QÞ kð1 bÞðx QÞ > > > > : t1 t2 s1 s2 ; if x Q þ qc =b Hence, the expected total profit of the system, JP(Q), will be given by ð þ1 JPðQÞ ¼ ðp þ k v bÞ½Q þ b ðx QÞf ðxÞdx þ ðp þ k rÞ
ðQ
Qþqc =b
ðx QÞf ðxÞdx
(13)
0
þ bQ km t1 s1 ðt2 þ s2 Þ½1 FðQ þ qc =bÞ: Maximizing JP(Q) will give Theorem 2. Theorem 2. For any increasing concave CDF F(.), the unique optimal ordering policy, QJ, for the centralized system is given by ðp þ k rÞFðQJ Þ þ ðp þ k v bÞbFðQJ þ qc =bÞ þ ðp þ k vÞð1 bÞ þ bb ¼ 0: (14) Proof. Taking the first- and second-order derivatives of JP(Q) with respect to Q, we obtain JP0 ðQÞ ¼ ðp þ k rÞFðQÞ þ ðp þ k v bÞbFðQ þ qc =bÞ þ ðp þ k vÞð1 bÞ þ bb JP00 ðQÞ ¼ ðp þ k rÞf ðQÞ þ ðp þ k v bÞbf ðQ þ qc =bÞ: Since f(Q) > f(Q + qc/b) and p + k r > p + k v b, we have JP00 (Q) < 0. It is easy to check that limQ!0+JP0 (Q) ¼ (p + k v b)bF(qc/b) + (p + k v)(1 b) + bb > 0 and limQ!+1JP0 (Q) ¼ (v r) < 0. Hence, there exists a unique positive root QJ to JP0 (QJ) ¼ 0, and JP(Q) reaches its maximum at QJ. □ As to a two-echelon supply chain for newsvendor-type products with a single order opportunity, a common fact is that the expected profit of the centralized system is exactly equal to the sum of two members’ expected profits in the decentralized system. Many researchers like Taylor (2002), Cachon (2003), etc., have presented a lot of effective coordination mechanisms by employing successfully this fact. Weng (2004) applied directly this common fact to a supply chain for newsvendor-type products under the twice-order framework defined in this chapter. Then, he presented a quantity discount scheme that could maximize the expected
Supply Chain Coordination for Newsvendor-Type Products
329
profit of his so-called centralized channel. However, Theorem 3 shows that the above common fact does not hold in the supply chain under the twice-order framework considered in the chapter. We find out that the expected profit function [shown in (8)] of the centralized channel is always greater than the sum of the expected profits of two members in the decentralized system. Before giving Theorem 3, we need to show the following lemma. Lemma 1. (i) If qb qm, then qc q0; (ii) if qb qm, then qc qb. Proof. (i) If qb qm, one has qc q0 ¼ ðt2 þ s2 Þ=ðp þ k v bÞ ½t2 þ ls2 þ ð1 lÞs2 ðc rÞ=ðc vÞ=ðp þ k r bÞ ¼ ½t2 þ ls2 ð1 lÞs2 ðp þ k c bÞ=ðc vÞðv rÞ=½ðp þ k v bÞ ðp þ k r bÞ: Since qb qm, t2 þ ls2 (1 l)s2(p þ k c b)/(c v). From assumptions presented in Sect. 2 that p > c > v > r and p þ k c b > 0, one can easily derive p þ k r b > p þ k v b > p þ k c b > 0. Hence, we have qc q0. (ii) If qb qm, one can get (t2 + ls2)/(p + k c b) (1 l)s2/(c v). Therefore, one has qc ¼ ½t2 þ ls2 þ ð1 lÞs2 =ðp þ k v bÞ ½t2 þ ls2 þ ðt2 þ ls2 Þðc vÞ=ðp þ k c bÞ=ðp þ k v bÞ ¼ qb : □ Lemma 1 means that, the threshold value beyond which the centralized system implements the second transaction is always less than or equal to its counterpart in the decentralized system. From (1)–(4) and Lemma 1, one can derive Theorem 3. Theorem 3. The expected profit of the centralized channel is always greater than the sum of the expected profits of two members in the decentralized system. Proof. For the case of qb qm, due to (1) and (2), one can easily derive the expected total profit of the decentralized system as BP1 ðQÞ þ MP1 ðQÞ ¼ ðp þ k v bÞ½Q þ b þ ðp þ k rÞ
ðQ
ð þ1 Qþq0 =b
ðx QÞf ðxÞdx
ðx QÞf ðxÞdx
0
þ bQ km ðt1 þ s1 Þ ðt2 þ s2 Þ½1 FðQ þ q0 =bÞ ð Qþqm =b ðv rÞ ½qm bðx QÞf ðxÞdx Qþq0 =b
(15)
330
Y.-W. Zhou and S.-D. Wang
Due to (13), the expected profit for the centralized system can be expressed as JPðQÞ ¼ ðp þ k v bÞ½Q þ b þ ðp þ k rÞ
ðQ
ð þ1 Qþq0 =b
ðx QÞf ðxÞdx þ b
ð Qþq0 =b Qþqc =b
ðx QÞf ðxÞdx
ðx QÞf ðxÞdx þ bQ km ðt1 þ s1 Þ
0
ðt2 þ s2 Þ½1 FðQ þ q0 =bÞ ðt2 þ s2 Þ½FðQ þ q0 =bÞ FðQ þ qc =bÞ (16) Combining (15) and (16) gives JPðQÞ ¼ BP1 ðQÞ þ MP1 ðQÞ þ f ðxÞdx þ ðv rÞ
ð Qþq0 =b Qþqc =b
ð Qþqm =b Qþq0 =b
½ðp þ k v bÞbðx QÞ t2 s2 (17)
½qm bðx QÞf ðxÞdx
Similarly, for the case of qb qm, combining (3) and (4) with (13), the expected profit for the centralized system can be rewritten as JPðQÞ ¼ BP2 ðQÞ þ MP2 ðQÞ ð Qþqb =b ½ðp þ k v bÞbðx QÞ t2 s2 f ðxÞdx þ
(18)
Qþqc =b
From (17) and (18), one can observe that the expected profit function of the centralized system is not simply equal to, but larger than, the sum of the expected profit functions of the two partners in the system. □ In the following, we give the explanation of this phenomenon. In fact, under the case of qb qm, as analyzed earlier, if the practical demand x is less than Q þ qc/b (of course, also less than Q þ q0/b due to Lemma 1), the buyer, no matter whether in the centralized or decentralized system, does not place a second order. If the practical demand x is greater than Q þ qm/b(of course, also greater than Q + qc/b due to Lemma 1), a second order of b(x Q) units is implemented in both the centralized and the decentralized system. It implies that, under such two situations, the profit for the centralized system is just equal to the sum of two parties’ profits in the decentralized system. However, if the practical demand x satisfies Q þ qc/b x < Q þ q0/b, the centralized system is willing to activate a production to supply a second order of b(x Q) units. This second transaction brings the system the profit of (p v b)b(x Q) k(1 b) (x Q) t2 s2. In contrast, the second transaction will not occur in the decentralized system. Consequently, the sum of two parties’ profits is equal to k (x Q). The difference of these two profits is equal to (p þ k v b)b(x Q) t2 s2, which represents the increment in the channel profit yielded by two
Supply Chain Coordination for Newsvendor-Type Products
331
partners’ cooperation when the practical demand x falls into [Q þ qc/b, Q þ q0/b]. If the practical demand x satisfies Q þ q0/b x < Q þ qm/b, the second order of b(x Q) units will occur in the centralized system, which brings the system the profit of (p v b)b(x Q) k(1 b)(x Q) t2 s2. In the decentralized system, however, the second order of qm units will happen. The sum of two members’ profits resulted from the second transaction is given by ðp c bÞbðx QÞ kð1 bÞðx QÞ ðc rÞ½qm bðx QÞ t2 þ ðc vÞqm s2: The difference of the two profits is equal to (v r)[qm b(x Q)], which denotes the increment in the system profit incurred by the cooperation between the manufacturer and the buyer when the practical demand x belongs to [Q + q0/b, Q + qm/b]. Thus, the third and fourth terms in (17) exactly represents the expected increment of the system profit when two members in the channel are willing to make a decision jointly. Similarly, one can also obtain the intuitive explanation of (18). The above analysis has revealed that if we simply consider the sum of the expected profit of two parties in the considered decentralized system as the jointly decision-making objective or the expected profit of the centralized system, then this cooperative-looking system does not actually reach perfect coordination or complete cooperation state. The main reason is that in the cooperative-looking centralized system, the second order decision made by the buyer is still based on the buyer’s benefit rather than on the channel’s benefit. Hence, we refer to this type of cooperation as incomplete cooperation (ic for brevity) and this cooperative-looking system as an ic system. Let JPic(Q) be the expected profit of this ic system. Then, one has JPic1 ðQÞ; qb qm JPic ðQÞ ¼ JPic2 ðQÞ; qb qm where JPic1(Q) ¼ BP1(Q) þ MP1(Q) and JPic2(Q) ¼ BP2(Q) þ MP2(Q). It is obvious from (17) and (18) that JP(Q) JPic(Q) for any given Q. Theorem 4 shows the optimal ordering policies under the ic system just mentioned. Theorem 4. For any increasing concave CDF F(.), the unique optimal ordering policy, QJic, that maximizes the sum of the expected profit of two members, i.e., JPic(Q), will be given by ic1 QJ ; qb qm QJ ic ¼ Qic2 J ; q b qm where QJic1 and QJic2 satisfy respectively ðp þ k rÞF QJ ic1 þ ðp þ k r bÞbF QJ ic1 þ q0 =b ðv rÞbF QJ ic1 þ qm =b þ ðp þ k vÞð1 bÞ þ bb ¼ 0
(19)
332
Y.-W. Zhou and S.-D. Wang
ðp þ k rÞF QJ ic2 þ ðp þ k v bÞbF QJ ic2 þ qb =b þ ðp þ k vÞð1 bÞ þ bb ½ðp þ k v bÞqb ðt2 þ s2 Þ f QJ ic2 þ qb =b ¼ 0: (20) Proof. (i) If qb qm, taking the first- and second-order derivatives of JPic1(Q) with respect to Q, we have JP0ic1 ðQÞ ¼ ðp þ k rÞFðQÞ þ ðp þ k r bÞbFðQ þ q0 =bÞ ðv rÞbFðQ þ qm =bÞ þ ðp þ k vÞð1 bÞ þ bb; JP00ic1 ðQÞ ¼ ðp þ k rÞ½f ðQÞ bf ðQ þ q0 =bÞ bbf ðQ þ q0 =bÞ ðv rÞ bf ðQ þ qm =bÞ: Since f(Q) > f(Q + q0/b), one has JP00 ic1(Q) < 0. It is easy to check that limQ !þ1 JP0ic1 ðQÞ ¼ ðv rÞ < 0 and limQ !0þ JP0ic1 ðQÞ ¼ ðp þ k r bÞbFðq0 =bÞ ðv rÞbFðqm =bÞ þ ðp þ k vÞ ð1 bÞ þ bb: From (12), one can derive ðp þ k r bÞbFðq0 =bÞ ðv rÞbFðqm =bÞ þ ðp þ k vÞð1 bÞ þ bb ¼ ðp þ k r bÞbFðq0 =bÞ ðc rÞbFðqm =bÞ þ ðp þ k cÞð1 bÞ þ bb þ ðc vÞbFðqm =bÞ > ðc vÞbFðqm =bÞ > 0; which implies limQ!0+ JP0 ic1(Q) > 0. Hence, there exists a unique positive root QJic1 to equation JP0 ic1(QJic1) ¼ 0, at which JPic1(Q) reaches its maximum. (ii) If qb qm, the first- and second-order derivatives of JPic2(Q)with respect to Q will be JP0ic2 ðQÞ ¼ ðp þ k rÞFðQÞ þ ðp þ k v bÞbFðQ þ qb =bÞ þ ðp þ k vÞð1 bÞ þ bb ½ðp þ k v bÞqb ðt2 þ s2 Þf ðQ þ qb =bÞ; JP00ic2 ðQÞ ¼ ðp þ k rÞf ðQÞ þ ðp þ k v bÞbf ðQ þ qb =bÞ ½ðp þ k v bÞqb ðt2 þ s2 Þf 0 ðQ þ qb =bÞ:
Supply Chain Coordination for Newsvendor-Type Products
333
Since f(Q) > f(Q + qb/b), from Lemma 1 one knows that qc qb. Thus, one can derive JP00ic2 ðQÞ ðv þ b rÞf ðQ þ qb =bÞ ½ðp þ k v bÞqc ðt2 þ s2 Þf 0 ðQ þ qb =bÞ ¼ ðv þ b rÞf ðQ þ qb =bÞ 0: Due to limQ !þ1 JP0ic2 ðQÞ ¼ limQ !þ1 fðv rÞ ½ðp þ k v bÞqb ðt2 þ s2 Þ f ðQ þ qb =bÞg < ðv rÞ < 0 and limQ !0þ JP0ic2 ðQÞ ¼ ðp þ k v bÞbFðqb =bÞ þ ðp þ k vÞð1 bÞ þ bb ½ðp þ k v bÞqb ðt2 þ s2 Þf ðqb =bÞ > ðp þ k v bÞqb f ðqb =bÞ þ ðp þ k vÞð1 bÞ þ bb ½ðp þ k v bÞqb ðt2 þ s2 Þf ðqb =bÞ > 0; there exists a unique positive root QJic2 to equation JP0 ic2(QJic2) ¼ 0, at which JPic2(Q) reaches its maximum. □ Before comparing optimal ordering policies under both decentralized and centralized system, we introduce Lemma 2. Lemma 2. If qb qm, then ½FðQ þ q0 =bÞ FðQ þ qc =bÞ=½FðQ þ qm =bÞ FðQ þ qc =bÞ ðv rÞ= ðp þ k r bÞ: Proof. From the integral mean value theorem, one has ð Qþq0 =b
FðQ þ q0 =bÞ FðQ þ qc =bÞ ¼
Qþqc =b
FðQ þ qm =bÞ FðQ þ qc =bÞ ¼
f ðxÞdx ¼ f ðx1 Þðq0 qc Þ=b;
ð Qþqm =b Qþqc =b
f ðxÞdx ¼ f ðx3 Þðqm qc Þ=b
and ð Qþqm =b Qþqc =b
f ðxÞdx ¼
ð Qþq0 =b Qþqc =b
f ðxÞdx þ
ð Qþqm =b Qþq0 =b
f ðxÞdx
¼ f ðx1 Þðq0 qc Þ=b þ f ðx2 Þðqm q0 Þ=b; where x1 2 ðQ þ qc =b; Q þ q0 =bÞ, x2 2 ðQ þ q0 =b; Q þ qm =bÞand x3 2 ðQ þ qc = b; Q þ qm =bÞ.
334
Y.-W. Zhou and S.-D. Wang
Thus, one has f(x3)(qm qc) ¼ f(x1)(q0 qc) + f(x2)(qm q0). Since f(x) is a decreasing function, f(x3)(qm qc) < f(x1)(q0 qc + qm q0) ¼ f(x1)(qm qc) due to x1 < x2. It leads to f(x3) < f(x1). Noting that q0 may be equal to qc, one can obtain ½FðQ þ q0 =bÞ FðQ þ qc =bÞ=½FðQ þ qm =bÞ FðQ þ qc =bÞ ¼ f ðx1 Þðq0 qc Þ=½f ðx3 Þðqm qc Þ ðq0 qc Þ=ðqm qc Þ:
(21)
ðv rÞðp þ k c bÞ ðqm qb Þ and ðp þ k v bÞðp þ k r bÞ ðpþk cbÞ ðpþk cbÞ ðqm qb Þþðq0 qc Þ ¼ qm qc ¼ qm q0 þq0 qc ¼ pþk r b pþk vb ðqm qb Þ, one easily derives Due to q0 qc ¼
ðq0 qc Þ=ðqm qc Þ ¼ ðv rÞ=ðp þ k r bÞ: From (21) and (22), it is obvious to have Lemma 2. Based on Lemma 2, one can obtain the following results.
(22) □
Theorem 5. (i) QJic QJ, QJic > Qb; (ii) JP(QJ) JPic(QJic) > BP(Qb) + MP (Qb). Proof. (i) We first prove QJic QJ. If qb qm, one can get from Lemma 2 that ðp þ k r bÞFðQ þ q0 =bÞ ðv rÞFðQ þ qm =bÞ ðp þ k v bÞ FðQ þ qc =bÞ: Noting (17) and (23), one has 0 ¼ ðp þ k rÞF QJ ic1 þ ðp þ k r bÞbF QJ ic1 þ q0 =b ðv rÞbF QJ ic1 þ qm =b þ ðp þ k vÞð1 bÞ þ bb ðp þ k rÞF QJ ic1 þ ðp þ k v bÞbF QJ ic1 þ qc =b
(23)
(24)
þ ðp þ k vÞð1 bÞ þ bb; which is equivalent to JP0 (QJic1) 0. In addition, from the proof of Theorem 2, one can see that JP0 (QJ) ¼ 0 and JP00 (Q) < 0. Hence, it is clear to have QJic1 QJ . If qb qm, then from Lemma 1 one has qc qb. Letting G(q) ¼ the left side of (13), one can derive dGðqÞ=dq ¼ ½ðp þ k v bÞq t2 s2 f 0 QJ ic2 þ q=b =b: When qc q qb, it is obvious to have (p + k v b)q t2 s2 (p + k v b)qc t2 s2¼0. Since f 0 (x) < 0, dG(q)/dq 0 if qc q qb, which
Supply Chain Coordination for Newsvendor-Type Products
335
means that G(q) is a monotone increasing function of q in [qc, qb]. Therefore, one has G(qc) G(qb) ¼ 0, i.e., ðp þ k rÞF QJ ic2 þ ðp þ k v bÞbF QJ ic2 þ qc =b þ ðp þ k vÞð1 bÞ þ bb 0;
(25)
which is just equivalent to JP0 (QJic2) 0. This together with JP0 (QJ) ¼ 0 and JP00 (Q) < 0 will give QJic2 QJ. The proof of QJic QJ is completed. Next, we prove QJic > Qb. If qb qm, one can know from (13) that the buyer’s optimal order quantity Qb1 satisfies: ðp þ k rÞFðQb 1 Þ þ ðp þ k r bÞbFðQb 1 þ q0 =bÞ ðc rÞbFðQb 1 þ qm =bÞ þ ðp þ k cÞð1 bÞ þ bb ¼ 0; which gives ðp þ k rÞFðQb 1 Þ þ ðp þ k r bÞbFðQb 1 þ q0 =bÞ ðv rÞb FðQb 1 þ qm =bÞ þ ðp þ k vÞð1 bÞ þ bb > 0:
(26)
(26) can be rewritten as JP0 ic1(Qb1) > 0. Additionally, from the proof of Theorem 4 one has JP00 ic1(Q) < 0. It implies that JP0 ic1(Q) is monotone decreasing. Hence, after noting JP0 ic1(QJic1) ¼ 0, one can derive QJic1 > Qb1. Similarly, one can prove QJic2 > Qb2. The proof is omitted. (ii) From Theorem 4, we know that JPic(Q) reaches its maximum at QJic. Since QJic > Qb, JPic(QJic) > BP(Qb) + MP(Qb). In addition, (17) and (18) have implied that JP(Q) > BP(Q) + MP(Q) ¼ JPic(Q) for any Q (>0). Hence, it is obvious to have JPic(QJic) < JP(QJic) < JP(QJ). Theorem 5 indicates that, for the considered two-echelon supply chain, the cooperation between two parties in decision making, even the aforesaid incomplete cooperation, will lead to an increase in the system’s expected profit, and that the buyer’s optimal order quantity in the ic setting is greater than the counterparts in both centralized and decentralized setting.
5.1
Property of the ic and Decentralized System Performance
From the definitions of qb, qm, and q0, one can easily obtain that all these threshold quantities have to do with l. It implies that JPic(Q) depends on l as well. Property 2 shows the monotonity of JPic(Q, l) with respect to l.
336
Y.-W. Zhou and S.-D. Wang
Property 2. For any given Q, JPic(Q, l) is a decreasing function with respect to l. Proof. (i) Prove that JPic1(Q, l) is a monotone decreasing function of l. For a given Q, the first-order partial derivative of JPic1(Q, l) with respect to l is @JPic1 ðQ; lÞ=@l ¼ ½ðp þ k v bÞq0 þ t2 þ s2 þ ðv rÞðqm q0 Þ ½f ðQ þ q0 =bÞ=b dq0 =dl
(27)
þ ½FðQ þ qm =bÞ FðQ þ q0 =bÞdqm =dl From definitions of qm and q0, one has ðp þ k v bÞq0 þ t2 þ s2 þ ðv rÞðqm q0 Þ ¼ ½t2 þ ls2 þ ðc rÞqm þ ðv rÞqm þ t2 þ s2 ¼ ðc vÞqm þ ð1 lÞs2 ¼ 0: (28) Substituting (28) into (27) will give @JPic1 ðQ; lÞ=@l ¼ ½FðQ þ qm =bÞ FðQ þ q0 =bÞdqm =dl:
(29)
Since q0 qm (see definitions of q0 and qm) and dqm/dl ¼ s2/(c v), (29) means ∂JPic1(Q, l)/∂l 0, i.e., JPic1(Q, l) is a decreasing function of l. (ii) Prove that JPic2(Q, l) is a decreasing function of l. For a given Q, the first-order partial derivative of JPic2(Q, l) about l is @JPic2 ðQ; lÞ=@l ¼ ½ðp þ k v bÞqb þ t2 þ s2 ½f ðQ þ qb =bÞ=b dqb =dl: (30) Noting that qb qm and definitions of qb and qm, one can get ðp þ k v bÞqb þ t2 þ s2 ¼ ðp þ k c bÞqb ðc vÞqb þ t2 þ ls2 þ ð1 lÞs2 ¼ ðc vÞqb þ ð1 lÞs2
(31)
ðc vÞqm þ ð1 lÞs2 ¼ 0: Since dqb/dl ¼ s2/(p þ k c b) > 0, substituting (31) into (30) gives ∂JPic2(Q, l)/∂l 0. Namely, JPic2(Q, l) is a monotone decreasing function of l. □ Property 2 indicates that the bigger the value of l, the smaller the expected profit of the ic system. That is to say, the expected profit of the ic system depends on how two parties share the manufacturer’s second production setup cost. Especially, if the manufacturer independently pays all of the second production setup cost, i.e., l ¼ 0, the expected profit of the ic system will be always maximal for any given order quantity Q. In contrast, the buyer’s payment for all of the second setup cost will lead to the minimal expected profit of the ic system. Therefore, the best option
Supply Chain Coordination for Newsvendor-Type Products
337
for the ic system is to let the manufacturer pay all of the second setup cost. This is exactly opposite to the conclusion announced by Weng (2004) that “the general results obtained on the effect of coordination do not depend on how the manufacture’s production setup cost in the second order is allocated between two parties (whether it is paid by the buyer, paid by the manufacturer, or shared by both parties )” (Weng 2004, p. 151). A direct corollary of Property 2 is the following. Corollary 1. The sum of the optimal expected profits of two parties in the decentralized system decreases as l increases. Proof. As known in Sect. 4, the sum of the optimal expected profits of both entities is BP(Qb) þ MP(Qb), which is exactly equal to JPic(Qb, l). Hence, Property 2 also means Corollary 1. □ This corollary explains that sharing the manufacturer’s second production setup cost other than utterly paid by the retailer can increase the decentralized system performance. Moreover, the decentralized system would perform best if the manufacturer covers the second production setup cost completely.
5.2
A Special Case
If l ¼ 1 and b ¼ 1, all excess demand is completely backordered, and the second production setup cost is utterly paid by the buyer. It means that the threshold value that the manufacturer is willing to activate a second production in the decentralized system will be equal to zero, i.e., qm ¼ 0. Under such a case, the expected profit of the ic system, denoted as JPic(Q, l, b), becomes JPic ðQ; l ¼ 1; b ¼ 1Þ ¼ BP2 ðQ; l ¼ 1; b ¼ 1Þ þ MP2 ðQ; l ¼ 1; b ¼ 1Þ; which is just equal to the system’s expected profit (2.7) defined in Weng (2004). For notational convenience, let JPw(Q) denote the system’s expected profit and QJw be the corresponding optimal coordinated ordering quantity in Weng (2004). Then, JPw(Q) ¼ JPic(Q, l ¼ 1, b ¼ 1). Hence, Corollary 2 can also be derived directly from Property 2. Corollary 2. JPw ðQJw Þ JPic ðQJ ic ; l; b ¼ 1Þ: Proof. From the analysis presented in the second paragraph in Sect. 5.2, one has JPw(QJw) ¼ JPic(QJw, l ¼ 1, b ¼ 1). And Theorem 4 means JPic(QJw, l ¼ 1, b ¼ 1) JPic(QJic, l ¼ 1, b ¼ 1). Since JPic(Q, l, b) is a monotone decreasing function with respect to l, one can get JPic(QJic, l ¼ 1, b ¼ 1) JPic(QJic, l, □ b ¼ 1), where 0 l 1. Hence, one has JPw(QJw) JPic(QJic, l, b ¼ 1).
338
Y.-W. Zhou and S.-D. Wang
Corollary 2 further verifies that for any l (0 l < 1), the optimal expected profit of the system in Weng (2004) is always less than that of the ic system in the present model, of course, also less than that of the system under complete cooperation in this chapter.
6 Possible Perfect Coordination Scenarios By designing a simple quantity discount policy, Weng (2004) realized coordination of the ic system under the special case with l ¼ 1 and b ¼ 1. Following the way in Weng (2004), one can also achieve coordination of the ic system under the case with 0 l 1 and 0 b 1 but cannot realize perfect coordination of the system, even if under the special case with l ¼ 1 and b ¼ 1. Maybe, a more complicated quantity discount policy could achieve perfect coordination of the whole channel, but designing such a policy is out of our ability. Then, we pay our attention to a widely-used effective coordination mechanism: two-part tariff (hereafter, TPT for brevity), characterized by a two-tuple parameter (ct, K) in which the manufacturer sells the product to the buyer at the unit wholesale price ct ¼ v and charges the buyer a fixed franchise fee K. For the special case with l ¼ 1, it can be easily shown that for any given K, the buyer’s optimal order quantity would be Qt ¼ QJ, the counterpart of the centralized system, if the buyer accepts the TPT. Hence, the TPT achieves perfect coordination of the channel. Thus, as long as the manufacturer sets a suitable K-value that makes both parties’ benefits greater than before, both parties would accept the TPT that realizes perfect coordination of the channel. However, for the general case with l 6¼ 1, a common TPT mechanism is not able to achieve perfect coordination of the chain. Next, we move to another widely-used effective coordination mechanism: Revenue-Sharing Contract (hereafter, RSC for brevity), proposed by Cachon and Lariviere (2000). It is described by two parameters (cr, F), i.e., the manufacturer charges the buyer a unit wholesale price cr, lower than the unit marginal cost v, in exchange for a percentage (1 F) of the buyer’s revenue. Unfortunately, we find out that RSC also fails to coordinate the supply chain presented in our model. However, a revised revenue-sharing contract (hereafter, RRSC for brevity) would be able to complete perfect coordination of the supply chain. Before describing the RRSC, we need define the buyer’s generalized revenue as follows: Definition 1. Buyer’s generalized revenue ¼ Buyer’s revenue (Buyer’s shortage cost + Buyer’s backorder cost) The considered RRSC is characterized by three-tuple parameters (cr, F, T). Parameters cr and F are used to achieve the supply chain coordination, whereas parameter T is adopted to split the expected profit of the coordinated system between two parties. In such a RRSC, the manufacturer charges the buyer a unit wholesale price cr so that the threshold quantities of both the manufacturer and the
Supply Chain Coordination for Newsvendor-Type Products
339
buyer are equal to the counterpart of the centralized system, then selectively requires from the buyer a percentage (1 F) of his generalized revenue to keep the buyer’s optimal order quantity consistent with the centralized system’s, and finally gives the buyer a return profit T to compensate the buyer’s possible loss for accepting the RRSC. As explained above, under the RRSC, the optimal wholesale price should be chosen to make the threshold quantities of both parties equal to one of the centralized system. That is, cr satisfies qb ¼ qm ¼ qc, which leads to the manufacturer’s optimal wholesale price as: cr ¼ v þ ð1 lÞs2 ðp þ k v bÞ=ðt2 þ s2 Þ:
(32)
It is clear from (32) that this optimal wholesale price is larger than the unit marginal cost v, which is opposite to the counterpart in common RSC. If the buyer places an order of Q units at the wholesale price cr* given by (32), the generalized revenue of the buyer will be GRðQÞ ¼ ðp þ k cr bÞ½Q þ b
ðQ
ð þ1 Qþqc =b
ðx QÞf ðxÞdx þ ðp þ k rÞ
ðx QÞf ðxÞdx þ bQ km:
(33)
0
Thus, for any return profit T set by the manufacturer, the expected profits of the buyer and the manufacturer under the RRSC are respectively BPr ðQ; F; T Þ ¼ FGRðQÞ t1 ðt2 þ ls2 Þ½1 FðQ þ qc =bÞ þ T;
(34)
MPr ðQ; F; T Þ ¼ ð1 FÞGRðQÞ þ MCr ðQÞ s1 ð1 lÞs2 ½1 FðQ þ qc =bÞ T; (35) where MCr ðQÞ ¼ ðcr vÞ½Q þ b
ð þ1 Qþqc =b
ðx QÞf ðxÞdx:
Due to f 0 (x) < 0 and cr* > v > r, one can easily get that BPr(Q,F,T) is a concave function about Q. Hence, to achieve supply chain coordination, the manufacturer should select a F so that under the RRSC the buyer’s optimal order quantity Qr is just equal to the optimal order quantity QJ of the centralized system. That is, ðQ;F;TÞ * this F should satisfy @BPr@Q Q¼QJ ¼ 0, which gives the optimal fraction, F , of the generalized revenue kept by the buyer as F ¼ ðt2 þ ls2 Þf ðQJ þ qc =bÞ=½ðt2 þ ls2 Þf ðQJ þ qc =bÞ þ BCr ðQJ Þ;
(36)
340
Y.-W. Zhou and S.-D. Wang
where BCr ðQÞ ¼ ðp þ k rÞFðQÞ ðp þ k cr bÞbFðQ þ qc =bÞ ðp þ k cr Þð1 bÞ bb: From (14) and cr* > v > r, it is not difficult to show that 0 < F* < 1, which means that the F* is indeed a feasible fraction of the generalized revenue. Thus, for any given T, the RRSC, (cr*, F*, T), had actually achieved perfect coordination of the supply chain if it were accepted to implement. However, whether this RRSC can be implemented would depend on whether both parties gain more expected profits under the RRSC or what values the parameter T takes. Suppose that the manufacturer is willing to offer the RRSC only if her expected profit under the RRSC increases by e 100% (e 0) as compared to her original expected profit (MP(Qb)), and that the buyer is willing to accept the RRSC only when it can let the buyer’s expected profit increased by d 100% (d 0). Then, it is easy to show that the values of T available to both parties should satisfy Tmin T Tmax, where Tmax is the manufacturer’s largest endurable return profit and Tmax ¼ ð1 F ÞGRðQJ Þ þ MCr ðQJ Þ s1 ð1 lÞs2 ½1 FðQJ þ qc =bÞ (37) ð1 þ eÞMPðQb Þ Tmin is the buyer’s smallest acceptable return profit and Tmin ¼ ð1 þ dÞBPðQb Þ F GRðQJ Þ þ t1 þ ðt2 þ ls2 Þ½1 FðQJ þ qc =bÞ (38) It can be easily derived from (13), (33), (37) and (38) that Tmin T Tmax is equivalent to ð1 þ dÞBPðQb Þ þ ð1 þ eÞMPðQb Þ JPðQJ Þ
(39)
Thus, if (39) holds, the manufacturer certainly offers the buyer a return profit so that the buyer keeps his reservation profit only, because she, as the designer of the contract, will always want to capture the lion’s share of the channel profit. So, the optimal return profit set by the manufacturer is T* ¼ Tmin. Furthermore, whether (39) holds will depend on what values of d and e (required by the retailer and the manufacturer, respectively) take. For example, for some e specified by the manufacturer, if dmax ¼ {JP(QJ) (1 + e) MP(Qb)}/BP(Qb) 1 0, then (39) will hold as long as the value of d required by the retailer does not exceed dmax. If dmax < 0, (39) does not hold for any d 0. This implies that the manufacturer has asked for a too big e. To sum up, we have the following. Theorem 6. (i)The necessary condition that there exists any feasible RRSC is given by (39). (ii) If the necessary condition is satisfied, then the optimal RRSC that can achieve perfect coordination of the channel will be (cr*, F*, T*), where cr*, F* and T* are given by (32), (36) and (38), respectively.
Supply Chain Coordination for Newsvendor-Type Products
341
7 Numerical Examples In order to illustrate the model, we show a numerical example for each of two cases: qb < qm and qb > qm. Example 1. Case with qb < qm The parameters of the model are listed below: p ¼ 10, c ¼ 6.5, v ¼ 3, b ¼ 1, k ¼ 4, r ¼ 0.5, t1 ¼ 50, t2 ¼ 150, s1 ¼ 200, s2 ¼ 300, l ¼ 0, b ¼ 1 and d ¼ 0. The random demand x is assumed to follow the exponential distribution with m ¼ 150. Following the model presented in this chapter, one can obtain that (1) the optimal first order quantity in the decentralized setting is Qb1 ¼ 45.3, the expected profits of the manufacturer and the buyer are respectively MP(Qb1) ¼ 177.8 and BP (Qb1) ¼ 203.0, and the sum of two parties’ expected profits is 380.8; (2) the optimal first order quantity of the centralized system is QJ ¼ 133.6, the optimal RRSC is (cr*, F*, T*) ¼ (9.7, 0.062, 325.2), which achieves perfect coordination of the supply chain and enhances the system’s expected profit to JP(QJ) ¼ 466.1. However, for the same values of parameters given in Example 1, the coordinated order policy in Weng (2004) enhanced the system’s expected profit only to JPw(167.7) ¼ 460.6. Example 2. Case with qb > qm The parameters of the model are listed below: p ¼ 11, c ¼ 7, v ¼ 1.5, k ¼ 1, b ¼ 0.5, t2 ¼ 260. Other parameters are kept the same as in Example 1. Based on the presented solution procedure in this chapter, the following can be obtained (1) In the decentralized setting, the optimal first order quantity is Qb2 ¼ 39.2, the expected profits of the manufacturer and the buyer are respectively MP(Qb2) ¼ 457.0 and BP(Qb2) ¼ 295.5, and the sum of two parties’ expected profits is 752.5; (2) the optimal first order quantity of the centralized system is QJ ¼ 229.4, the optimal RRSC is (cr*, F*, T*) ¼ (6.9, 0.054, 390.4), which can perfectly coordinate the whole channel and enhance the system’s expected profit to JP(QJ) ¼ 945.6. However, for the same values of parameters given in Example 2, the coordinated order policy in Weng (2004) enhanced the system’s expected profit only to JPw(195.7) ¼ 929.2.
8 Conclusions Most of the literature on coordination issues of the supply chain with single period products assumed that only one order happened during the whole period. However, in practice, buyers probably choose to place more than once order in the selling period because they know more exact information about demand as time moves ahead. In this chapter, we further generalize the newsboy-type order coordination issue considered by Weng (2004) for a two-echelon supply chain with two ordering opportunities, and extend it to cover the case with two-party-shared second setup
342
Y.-W. Zhou and S.-D. Wang
cost and partial backlogging. We prove that the ic system and decentralized system would perform best if the manufacturer covers utterly the second production setup cost. We find out that the expected profit of the centralized system is not always equal to the sum of two members’ expected profits in the decentralized system, which is not consistent with our intuitive expectation and those in the existing related literature, like Cachon (2003), Weng (2004), Zhou and Li (2007), etc. In order to achieve perfect coordination of the considered channel, we try three widely-used effective mechanisms: simple quantity discount, two-part tariff and revenue-sharing contract. Consequently, both simple quantity discount and revenue-sharing contract is not able to achieve the channel’s perfect coordination. Neither can the two-part tariff except the special case that the buyer pays all the manufacturing setup cost. The chapter then presents a RRSC policy that completes the perfect coordination of the supply chain. Worthwhile to mention is that for simplicity the chapter only considers a constant backordered fraction of the unfilled demand in the sales period. In reality, however, this backordered fraction may probably influence the buyer’s expected profit directly. In that case, it would be beneficial for the buyer to choose a suitable second order quantity. This problem will be considered in our future research. Other possible extensions of the model include: considering multiple manufacturers, multiple buyers with price or quantity competition, random demand with unknown probability distribution, etc.
References Arcelus FJ, Kumar S, Srinivasan G (2008) Evaluating manufacturer’s buyback policies in a singleperiod two-echelon framework under price-dependent stochastic demand. Omega 36(5): 808–824 Atkinson AA (1979) Incentives, uncertainty and risk in newsboy problem. Decis Sci 10:341–357 Cachon G, Lariviere M (2000) Supply chain coordination with revenue sharing: strengths and limitations. Working paper, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA Cachon G (2003) Supply chain coordination with contracts. In: de Kok AG, Graves SC (eds) Handbooks in operations research and management science, Chap 6, vol 11. Elsevier, Amsterdam Chen H, Chen J, Chen Y (2006) A coordination mechanism for a supply chain with demand information updating. Int J Prod Econ 103:347–361 Chen H, Chen Y, Chiu CH, Choi TM, Sethi S (2010) Coordination mechanism for the supply chain with leadtime consideration and price-dependent demand. Eur J Oper Res 203(1):70–80 Choi TM, Li D, Yan H (2003) Optimal two-stage ordering policy with Bayesian information updating. J Oper Res Soc 54:846–856 Donohue KL (2000) Efficient supply contracts for fashion goods with forecast updating and two production modes. Manage Sci 46(11):1397–1411 Emmons H, Gilbert SM (1998) The role of returns policies in pricing and inventory decisions for catalogue goods. Manage Sci 44(2):276–283 Fisher M, Raman A (1999) Managing short life-cycle products. Ascet 1 Goodman DA, Moody KW (1970) Determining optimal price promotion quantities. J Mark 34: 31–39 Ismail B, Louderback J (1979) Optimizing and satisfying in stochastic cost-volume-profit analysis. Decis Sci 10:205–217
Supply Chain Coordination for Newsvendor-Type Products
343
Kabak I, Schiff A (1978) Inventory models and management objectives. Sloan Manage Rev 10: 53–59 Khouja M (1999) The single-period (news-vendor) problem: Literature review and suggestions for future research. Omega 27(5):537–553 Lau HS (1980) The newsboy problem under alternative optimization objectives. J Oper Res Soc 31:525–535 Lau HS, Lau AH (1997) Reordering strategies for a newsboy-type product. Eur J Oper Res 103: 557–572 Lau AH, Lau HS (1998) Decision models for single-period products with two ordering opportunities. Int J Prod Econ 55:57–70 Li S, Zhu Z, Huang L (2009a) Supply chain coordination and decision making under consignment contract with revenue sharing. Int J Prod Econ 120(1):88–99 Li J, Chand S, Dada M, Mehta S (2009b) Managing inventory over a short season: models with two procurement opportunities. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 11(1):174–184 Milner JM, Kouvelis P (2005) Order quantity and timing flexibility in supply chains: the role of demand characteristics. Manage Sci 51(6):970–985 Nahmias S, Schmidt C (1984) An efficient heuristic for the multi-item newsboy problem with a single constraint. Nav Res Logistics Q 31:463–474 Pan K, Lai KK, Liang L, Leung SCH (2009) Two-period pricing and ordering policy for the dominant retailer in a two-echelon supply chain with demand uncertainty. Omega 37:919–929 Pasternack BA (1985) Optimal pricing and return policies for perishable commodities. Mark Sci 4(2):166–176 Serel D (2009) Optimal ordering and pricing in a quick response system. Int J Prod Econ 121(2):700–714 Taylor TA (2002) Supply chain coordination under channel rebates with sales effort effects. Manage Sci 48(8):992–1007 Wang SD, Zhou YW, Wang JP (2010) Supply chain coordination with two production modes and random demand depending on advertising expenditure and selling price. International Journal of Systems Science, 2010, 41(10):1257–1272 Webster S, Weng ZK (2008) Ordering and pricing policies in a manufacturing and distribution supply chain for fashion products. Int J Prod Econ 114(2):476–486 Weng ZK (2004) Coordinating order quantities between the manufacturer and the buyer: a generalized newsvendor model. Eur J Oper Res 156:148–161 Whitin TM (1955) Inventory control and price theory. Manage Sci 2:61–68 Wong WK, Qi J, Leung SYS (2009) Coordinating supply chains with sales rebate contracts and vendor-managed inventory. Int J Prod Econ 120(1):151–161 Zhou Y, Li DH (2007) Coordinating order quantity decisions in the supply chain contract under random demand. Appl Math Model 31(6):1029–1038
.
Part III
Channel Power, Bargaining and Coordination
.
Bargaining in a Two-Stage Supply Chain Through Revenue-Sharing Contract Jing Hou and Amy Z. Zeng
Abstract We focus on a bargaining problem between one supplier and one retailer that are coordinated by a revenue-sharing contract. The suppler is assumed to have the ability to influence the retailer’s profit by setting his/her target inventory level, which in turn determines the lead time. We examine the cases under which either the supplier or the retailer is dominant in the bargaining process. The key contract parameter, the acceptable range of the revenue-sharing fraction for the two players, and the maximum amount of monetary bargain space are obtained under explicit and implicit information, respectively. Numerical illustrations of the contracts for various scenarios are given to shed more insights. Keywords Dominance and bargaining • Nonlinear optimization • Supply chain coordination • Supply contracts
1 Introduction Revenue sharing mechanism has been applied extensively in various industries, such as internet service (e.g., He and Walrand 2005), airline (e.g., Zhang et al. 2010), and virtual enterprises (e.g., Chen and Chen 2006) – to name a few, as an efficient vehicle to achieve coordination, because it is relatively straightforward
J. Hou (*) Business School, Hohai University, Nanjing, Jiangsu 211100, China e-mail: [email protected] A.Z. Zeng School of Business, Worcester Polytechnic Institute, Worcester, MA 01609, USA e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_14, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
347
348
J. Hou and A.Z. Zeng
for the decision makers to implement and manage the contract. The primary objective of the revenue-sharing contract is to align the two parties’ interests and actions by having the retailer share a portion of his/her revenue with the supplier. As a result, the supplier’s effort and willingness to collaborate should increase. Two desirable outcomes are expected from the revenue-sharing mechanism, namely higher profit level for the entire chain, and a “win-win” situation for each chain member. The classic problem of a revenue-sharing contract is how to determine the revenue-sharing fraction for better coordination outcomes. This contract parameter is determined under various decision-making configurations, one of which can be characterized by the power inequality of negotiation in the bargaining process. In a two-stage supply chain consisting of a single manufacturer (or supplier) and a single retailer, if the supplier has the ability to influence the retailer’s decision on revenue-sharing fraction, then he/she may receive larger increase in profit resulted from the coordination mechanism. On the other hand, if the retailer is dominant, then the revenue-sharing fraction may be set to satisfy the retailer’s requirements. The major contribution of this paper lies in the area where we obtain the key parameters of the revenue-sharing contract and the bargaining space of a singlesupplier-single-retailer supply chain with the consideration of a dominant player. The retailer’s profit depends upon the lead time that is affected by the supplier’s finite target inventory level. The contract requires the supplier to hold larger inventory level to achieve system optimization and also a “win–win” condition for two players. The dominant player (either the supplier or the retailer) in the bargaining process requires more increase in profit. In both situations, the ranges of the revenue-sharing fraction as well as the maximum monetary value that the two parties can bargain are obtained. The impacts of the explicit and implicit information about the supplier’s inventory holding cost on the decisions are also examined. As will be discussed in the literature review, the problem studied in this paper has not been fully addressed in the literature. Our numerical examples show that significant improvements can be accomplished by the proposed contract and the bargaining method. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 summarizes the literature related to revenue-sharing contract and the different ways of distributing the profit among the supply chain entities. In Sect. 3, we review the results from basic centralized and decentralized optimizations from our previous work, which will provide foundation for subsequent analysis. Section 4 examines the joint revenue-sharing and bargaining decisions between the two parties by taking into account of dominance and the kind of knowledge the retailer has about the supplier’s inventory holding cost structure. The ranges of the key contract parameter and monetary bargain space are derived and numerical examples are given. Finally, we provide concluding remarks and directions for future research in Sect. 5.
Bargaining in a Two-Stage Supply Chain Through Revenue-Sharing Contract
349
2 Literature Review Revenue-sharing contracts have attracted considerable attention. An extensive literature review can be found in Cachon and Lariviere (2000) and Yao et al. (2008). We herein focus on most recent examples of studies that have been published in the literature. Giannoccaro and Pontrandolfo (2004) propose a revenuesharing model that aims at coordinating a three-stage supply chain. The model increases the system efficiency as well as the profits of all the chain members by fine tuning the contract parameters. In analyzing a special two-stage supply chain where the revenue decreases with the lead time and increases with inventory, Gupta and Weerawat (2006) design a revenue-sharing contract to maximize the centralized revenue by choosing an appropriate inventory level. Chen et al. (2007) study the performance of the supply chain with one supplier and multiple buyers under deterministic price-sensitive customer demand. Yao et al. (2008) investigate a revenue-sharing contract for coordinating a supply chain comprising one manufacturer and two competing retailers who face stochastic demand before the selling season. Linh and Hong (2009) discuss how the revenue sharing fraction and the wholesale price are to be determined in revenue sharing contract in order to achieve channel coordination and a win–win outcome for a single retailer and a single wholesaler. Giannoccaro and Pontrandolfo (2009) model the negotiation process among the supply chain actors by adopting agent-based simulation, taking into account the contractual power and the collaboration among the SC actors. A number of researchers have recently demonstrated the effectiveness of revenue sharing contract in supply chain coordination by comparing or integrating it with other contract types. For example, Li and Hua (2008) and Li et al. (2009) have examined the coordination effectiveness of consignment contract with revenue sharing for decentralized supply chains. Bellantuono et al. (2009) present a model in which the supply chain partners participate in two different programs – a revenue sharing contract between the supplier and the retailer, and an advanced booking discount program offered by the retailer to the customers. Pan et al. (2010) discuss and compare the results of a wholesale price contract or a revenue-sharing contract under different channel power structures to check whether it is beneficial for manufacturers to use revenue-sharing contracts under different scenarios. Ouardighi and Kim (2010) compare the possible outcomes under a wholesale price contract and a revenue-sharing contract when studying a non-cooperative dynamic game in which a single supplier collaborates with two manufacturers on design quality improvements for their respective products. Lin et al. (2010) compare the revenue sharing contract with the insurance contract, under which the supplier shares the risk of overstock and under-stock with the retailer, improving the efficiency of the supply chain with a newsvendor-type product. In sum, the studies in this category do not consider revenue-sharing as a single coordination mechanism; rather as part of the supply chain collaboration methodology or an alternative to other contracts.
350
J. Hou and A.Z. Zeng
Bargaining and cooperation have been always playing a key role in profit allocation in a supply chain. For example, Jia and Yokoyama (2003) propose a scheme based on Game theory to decide the profit allocation of each independent power producers in the coalitions rationally and impartially. Guardiola et al. (2007) study the coordination of actions and the allocation of profit in supply chains under decentralized control in which a single supplier supplies several retailers with goods for replenishment of stocks. Nagarajan and Sosˇic´ (2008) use cooperative bargaining models to find allocations of the profit pie between supply chain partners. And the problem of how to split the additional profit among the supply chain entities in a revenue-sharing contract has been the subject of many recent researchers. In a study by Chauhan and Proth (2005) where the customer demand depends upon the retail price, a new approach is proposed to maximize the centralized profit by sharing the profit proportional to the risk among the partners. In the work of Jaber and Osman (2006), a simple profit-sharing contract is proposed in such a way that the profit is distributed proportionally to each partner’s investment amount. Rhee et al. (2010) propose a new way of generalizing contract mechanisms to multi-stage settings, where one supply chain entity takes the lead in negotiating a single contract with all other entities simultaneously. Two special cases are discussed – one in which all entities receive the same absolute increase in profit; and one in which all members receive the same relative increase in profit. In addition, Sucky (2006) considers the bargaining problem of a two-stage supply chain where the buyer has no access to the supplier’s complete information. To reduce the system-wide cost, the order quantity is treated as a variable and the coordination mechanism with the buyer being dominant is derived and compared with that under complete information. Inspired by the work of Rhee et al. (2010), our research assumes that either the supplier or the retailer is dominant in the bargaining process and requires more increase in profit. We derive the accepted range of revenue sharing fraction by both parties as well as the associated bargain space. In this paper we restrict our attention to a supply chain that consists of one supplier and one retailer, which are separate and independent organizations, actively seeking favorable opportunities to coordinate. We extend the study of Hou et al. (2009) by considering the situations under which one of the two supply chain members is dominant in the bargaining process. For both cases, we develop the key contract parameters and discuss the range of the monetary amount that can be shared between the two parties under explicit and implicit information about the supplier’s inventory cost, respectively.
3 The Basic Models We study the coordination issue between a supplier and a retailer in a two-stage supply chain that produces and sells one single product. The basic assumptions for this paper are identical to those made in our previous study (Hou et al. 2009) and are
Bargaining in a Two-Stage Supply Chain Through Revenue-Sharing Contract
351
briefly summarized here. The demand rate is known as l and the demand process is stationary and follows Poisson distribution. The supplier’s production cost is cs per unit and average unit inventory holding cost is h. The retailer’s unit cost is denoted as cr. Furthermore, the retailer’s unit profit of the final product, p, is assumed to be sensitive to the lead time. Similar to the study by Gupta and Weerawat (2006), we study the situation under which the supplier has the ability to influence the retailer’s average unit revenue p by setting his/her target inventory level b and by knowing the relationship between the lead time L and the target inventory level through the following expression: pðbÞ ¼ p0 bLðbÞ
(1)
where the parameter, b, is a scale factor, and p0 is the retailer’s largest possible unit revenue achieved in an ideal situation with the highest acceptable sales price by the end-users and the supplier’s shortest lead time. Both parameters ðb; p0 Þcan be estimated and hence can be assumed to be known. Since the retailer’s order lead time is determined by the time the supplier spends on production, transportation, and transaction, it is evident that the more inventory available at the supplier’s site, the shorter the lead time will be. Intuitively, the retailer’s average lead time is a decreasing function of the supplier’s target inventory level, that is, L0 ðbÞ < 0. The lead time is also limited by various factors besides the supplier’s target inventory level; for example, when the lead time is less influenced by the inventory, it is more determined by the other factors such as transportation time and order processing time. Hence, as the inventory level increases, the change rate of the lead time decreases. Therefore, the lead time, L(b), demonstrates the properties of a function that is decreasing but convex with respect to the inventory level (b), which means that L0 ðbÞ < 0 and L00 ðbÞ > 0. The assumed convexity of the lead-time function does simplify the subsequent analyses, but is also general enough to include many possible types of relationships between the inventory and lead time. Besides, we make an assumption that when there is no stock available at the supplier’s site, i.e., the lead time reaches its maximum, the customer will lower the acceptable price to an extent that the unit profit for the retailer becomes zero. As a result, the specific expression of L(b) is given as follows: LðbÞ ¼ lmax kbm ¼ p0 =b kbm ;
8 k > 0; 0 < m 1:
(2)
Where k is interpreted as a scale factor, and m is a known exponent. The values of both can be estimated based on sales history. In addition, lmax is the maximum lead time if there is no stock available when an order is placed, and LðbÞ > 0 holds for all values of b. In what follows, we first review the optimal planning parameters obtained from our previous study (Hou et al. 2009), which will be used as a basis for extensions in this paper.
352
3.1
J. Hou and A.Z. Zeng
The Centralized Planning Model
The goal of a centralized supply chain is to set the target inventory level so that the chain’s total expected profit, P0rþs , calculated in (3), is maximized. P0rþs ¼ lbkbm hb lðcs þ cr Þ
(3)
The first part of formula (3) is the revenue obtained by selling the final products. The second part is the inventory holding cost occurred at the supplier’s, while the last one indicates the supplier’s production cost and the retailer’s cost. It is easy to show that (3) is a concave function with respect to b and the supplier’s optimal inventory level is found as follows: b0
¼
h lbmk
1 m1
(4)
Note that the profit given at the above inventory quantity reaches to the highest point for the supply chain.
3.2
The Decentralized Profit-Sharing Model
In a decentralized supply chain, both players act independently and make decisions to maximize their respective profits. In this situation, the retailer determines a fraction (a) to share the sales revenue with the supplier, and then the supplier decides his/her target inventory level (b) based on the given revenue-sharing fraction. Denote (a*, b1*) as the optimal decisions and ðPr ; Ps Þ as the profits for the retailer and the supplier respectively, we summarize the results of this situation obtained by Hou et al. (2009) as follows: a ¼ m b1
Ps ðhja
¼
h lbm2 k
h ¼ mlbk lbm2 k
; b1 Þ
Pr ðhja
; b1 Þ
(5)
1 m1
m m1
< b0
h
(6)
h lbm2 k
h ¼ ð1 mÞlbk lbm2 k
m m1
1 m1
lcs
lcr
(7)
(8)
Bargaining in a Two-Stage Supply Chain Through Revenue-Sharing Contract
353
It is seen that the two methods provide somewhat different results. The objective now is to find an acceptable set of (a, b) to enhance the profitability of the supplier and the retailer. Note that a complete list of symbols and notations used throughout the paper is provided in Appendix 1.
4 The Bargaining Decision Under Dominance It is intuitive that a higher fraction of revenue offered by the retailer could motivate the supplier to hold a larger inventory, and as a result, a larger amount of revenue for the supply chain. Therefore, we want to see how they can work together to determine the revenue-sharing fraction so that the profits of both parties can increase to the levels they are able to achieve in a decentralized supply chain. The analysis will be performed in the following two situations (1) The supplier is the leader in the bargaining process, and we use the subscript “s” to label related notation, and (2) The retailer is the leader, and we use subscript “r” for all relevant symbols. Whoever is dominant in the supply chain requires larger increased profit from the new revenue sharing contract. Both situations are analyzed with explicit information and implicit information about the supplier’s inventory holding cost, h, respectively.
4.1 4.1.1
Supplier-Dominant Bargaining With Explicit Information
As the target inventory level of the supplier is set, which is b0 shown in (4), we only need to identify the new revenue-sharing fraction that will enable such an inventory quantity. Since increased inventory level causes higher inventory holding cost for the supplier but results in more revenue for the retailer, the dominant member (supplier) would require larger benefit from the coordination. Thus, we will first determine the new revenue-sharing fraction a in the presence of explicit information on the supplier’s inventory cost, h, and then discuss the range of the monetary amount that can be shared between the dominant supplier and the retailer. In a supplier-dominant supply chain, the range of a is given in the following statement: Proposition 4.1. In a supplier-dominant supply chain, to attract the two-stage supplier to hold a larger inventory level b0 and to achieve higher profits for both parties than those in the case of decentralized planning, the retailer’s new share of revenue, a, has the following range of values:
354
J. Hou and A.Z. Zeng
1 2m m 1 1 m m m1m m1m þ 2m1m þ 1 < as < 1 þ m1m m1m ; 2
8 0 < m < 1 (9)
Moreover, the range reaches the maximum when m ¼ 0.25. Proof. See Appendix 2. We refer to the right hand side of (9) as the upper limit of a, that is, 1
m
1m m1m ; aU s ¼1þm
(10)
and the left hand side of (9) as the lower limit, aLs ¼
1 2m m 1 m m1m m1m þ 2m1m þ 1 : 2
(11)
Now that the range of the revenue-sharing fraction is determined, we examine the range of monetary value that the retailer could share with the supplier. We denote such a monetary space as ð0; DPÞ, and give the values of the space in the following statement. Observation 4.1. In a supplier-dominant two-stage supply chain, there exist two possible scenarios when the monetary value for the two parties to share is found. The two scenarios are differentiated by a specific value of m* that is determined by the input parameters, ðl; b; k; h; cr cs Þ, as follows: Case (i): If 0 < m m* [except some values in m < m* when cr > cs, which fall into Case (ii)], then the range of the monetary amount that can be shared between the two parties is given by ð0; DPs1 Þ, where m DPs1 ¼ 0:5Ph ð1 mÞ 1 ð1 þ mÞm1m :
(12)
Case (ii): If m < m < 1 [plus those values of m < m* when cr > cs in Case (i)], there exists a revenue-sharing fraction, ah , where aLs < ah < aU s , at which the two parties’ new profits are identical: ah ¼
1 þ m lmðcs cr Þ : þ 2 2hb0
(13)
Therefore, a monetary quantity that allows the supplier’s new profit to be no less than the retailer’s is found as ð0; DPs2 Þ, where m
DPs2 ¼ Ph ðm 1Þðm1m 0:5Þ 0:5lðcs cr Þ
(14)
Note that in both (12) and (14), the factor, Ph , has the following expression:
h Ph ¼ lbk lbmk
m m1
(15)
Bargaining in a Two-Stage Supply Chain Through Revenue-Sharing Contract
355
Proof. See Appendix 3. It is seen from Observation 4.1 that retailer’s new revenue sharing fraction to attract the supplier to hold a higher inventory quantity falls into an interval, which is also true for the dollar amount. Hence, the final choice of the revenue-sharing fraction will be reached through bargaining between the two parties.
4.1.2
With Implicit Information
The supplier’s inventory cost, h, plays a critical role in decision making. In reality, the supplier may choose not to reveal the actual value of h to the retailer because he either considers it a piece of private information or has difficulty estimating the exact value. As such, the supplier may only tell the retailer a range of his cost structure in such a way that h1 < h < h2 . We call such a situation where the retailer has no specific value about the supplier’s cost structure as “decision-making under implicit information”. In this section, we will examine how to obtain the range of the revenue-sharing fraction and the impacts of the key input parameters on such a decision-making situation. Given the range of the supplier’s cost structure, h 2 ½h1 ; h2 , it is not difficult to show that the two parties’ profit functions are monotonically decreasing with the growth of the cost. Therefore, h1 and h2 represent the best and worst scenario, respectively, and we will only need to consider the new value of the contract parameter at these two limits. Suppose that the upper limit, h2, can be written as a function of the lower limit, that is, h2 ¼ ð1 þ dÞh1 ; where d > 0:
(16)
Table 1 reports two sets of the supplier’s inventory quantities based on the ; b results obtained from the previous sections: b 01 02 in centralized planning, and b11 ; b12 in decentralized coordination, as well as the profit functions of the two parties. Proposition 4.2. In a supplier-dominant two-stage supply chain, to coordinate with the supplier under the case of implicit information where the supplier provides an interval of the inventory cost, h1 h h2 , the retailer would select a revenuesharing fraction from the following range, aLs a aU s , where aLs ¼
1 2m m 1 m m1m m1m þ 2m1m þ 1 ; 2 1
m
1m m1m ; aU s ¼1þm
8 0<m<1
8 0 < m < 1:
However, the monetary bargain space to be negotiated between the two parties differs in the following way:
356
J. Hou and A.Z. Zeng
Table 1 Parameters in the gaming under implicit information Parameters hi, i ¼ 1, 2 a ¼ m a 1 1 m1 m1 b1 h1 h2 b11 ¼ ; b12 ¼ ; b11 > b12 2 2 lbm k lbm k 1 1 b0 h1 m1 h2 m1 b01 ¼ ; b02 ¼ ; b01 > b02 lbmk lbmk m m1 Retailer’s profit hi Pr ðhi ; a ; b1i Þ ¼ ð1 mÞlbk lcr lbm2 k m m1 hi Pr ðhi ; ai ; b0i Þ ¼ ð1 aÞlbk lcr lbmk m 1 m1 m1 Supplier’s profit hi hi Ps ðhi ; a ; b1i Þ ¼ mlbk hi ; lcs km2 bl km2 bl m 1 m1 m1 hi hi Ps ðhi ; ai ; b0i Þ ¼ albk hi lcs lbmk lbmk
Case (i): 0 < m m* [except some values of m < m* when cr > cs, which fall into Case (ii)]: As the supplier’s unit inventory holding cost range expands, which is captured by d (h2 h1 ¼ dh1 ), the gap between the maximum amount of income, ½1 GsDP , that the retailer would share with the supplier increases with d " ½1 GsDP ðdÞ
1 1 1þd
¼ As1
# m 1m
; where
m As1 ¼ 0:5ð1 mÞ 1 ð1 þ mÞm1m lbk
h1 lbmk
(17) m m1
(18)
Case (ii): m < m < 1 [plus some values of m < m* when cr > cs in Case (i)]: There exists a revenue-sharing fraction, ah , where aL < ah < aU , at which the two parties’ new profits are identical: ah ¼
1þm lmðcs cr Þ : þ 2 2hb0
(19)
Furthermore, as the supplier’s cost interval increases, the gap between the ½2 maximum amount of income, GsDP , that the retailer could share with the supplier increases with d " ½2 GsDP ðdÞ
¼ As2
1 1 1þd
# m 1m
; where
(20)
Bargaining in a Two-Stage Supply Chain Through Revenue-Sharing Contract
m
As2 ¼ ðm 1Þðm1m 0:5Þ lbk
h1 lbmk
m m1
:
357
(21)
Proof. See Appendix 4. As clearly stated in Proposition 4.2, it is interesting to see that even if the supplier provides an interval of the cost information rather than a specific value, the range of the fraction of revenue that the retailer will offer to encourage the retailer to hold larger quantity of inventory level remains the same; however, the amount of monetary value to be shared with the supplier varies as the range of the supplier’s cost value widens.
4.2
Retailer-Dominant Bargaining
The preceding section studies the key decision-making parameters when the supplier is dominant. In this section, we examine how the same parameters are determined in the opposite situation – the retailer is the dominator.
4.2.1
With Explicit Information
In this retailer-dominant supply chain in which the retailer has the explicit data about the inventory holding cost, h, we have found that the range of the revenuesharing fraction, a, can be described in the following proposition. Proposition 4.3. In a retailer-dominant two-stage supply chain, to attract the supplier to hold a larger inventory level b0 and to achieve higher profits for both parties than those in the case of decentralized planning, the retailer’s new share of revenue, a, satisfies the following range:
1 2m 2m m 1 m þ m1m m1m < ar < 0:5 m m1m m1m þ 2m1m þ 1 ; 8 0 < m < 1 (22)
Proof. See Appendix 2. Denote the right hand side of (22) as the upper limit of ar , that is, 2m m 1 L 1m m1m þ 2m1m þ 1 ; aU ¼ a ¼ 0:5 m m r s
(23)
and the left hand side of (22) as the lower limit, 1
2m
aLr ¼ m þ m1m m1m :
(24)
358
J. Hou and A.Z. Zeng
Comparing the conclusions in Proposition 4.3 with those in Proposition 4.1, we can see that the range of the revenue-sharing fraction remains unchanged; i.e., L U L aU r ar ¼ as as , and whoever is the leader, the range of the fraction reaches the maximum at m ¼ 0.25. The range of monetary value that the retailer could share with the supplier if the retailer is the leader is discussed in the following statement. Observation 4.2. In a retailer-dominant supply chain, two possible scenarios exist when finding the monetary amount for the two parties to share. The difference is dependent upon a specific range of (m1*, m2*) that is determined by the input parameters, ðl; b; k; h; cr cs Þ; as follows: Case (i): If m 2 = ðm1 ; m2 Þ and cr > cs , or cr cs , the range of the monetary amount that can be shared between the two parties is given by ð0; DPr1 Þ, where m DPr1 ¼ 0:5Ph ð1 mÞ 1 ð1 þ mÞm1m
(25)
Case (ii): If m 2 ðm1 ; m2 Þ and cr > cs , then there exists a revenue-sharing fraction, ah , where aLr < ah < aU r , at which the two parties’ new profits are identical. Therefore, a monetary quantity that allows the retailer’s new profit to be no less than the supplier’s is found as ð0; DPr2 Þ, where 1
2m
DPr2 ¼ Ph ð0:5 0:5m m1m þ m1m Þ þ 0:5lðcs cr Þ:
(26)
Proof. See Appendix 5. According to Observation 4.1 and 4.2, in the case where the supplier is dominant, only when cr–cs > d and m < m* can the supplier’s profit always be larger than the retailer’s (as shown in Appendix 3). This means that, to gain an advantage over the retailer, the supplier must lower his/her unit production cost (cs) to be less than the retailer’s unit cost (cr), and the supplier’s inventory level has minimal impact on the lead time, which is captured by the parameter, m. These two requirements are fairly stringent, and hence, it will be more difficult for the supplier to bargain. When the retailer is dominant, the condition under which the retailer’s profit is always higher than the supplier’s requires that only cr < cs is true. This means that the retailer only needs to ensure his/her unit cost (cr), lower than the supplier’s unit production cost (cs). This constraint is less stringent than that in the other case, and thus, it is easier for the retailer to gain advantage. The reason for this phenomenon is that, to achieve supply chain optimization, increased inventory level causes higher inventory holding cost for the supplier but results in higher revenue for the retailer, and thus makes it easier for the retailer to obtain higher profit than the supplier.
4.2.2
With Implicit Information
With the supplier’s holding cost information switching from a single value to an interval, the properties of the contract parameters in the retailer-dominant decision making are given in Proposition 4.4.
Bargaining in a Two-Stage Supply Chain Through Revenue-Sharing Contract
359
Proposition 4.4. In a retailer-dominant two-stage supply chain, to coordinate with the supplier under the case of implicit information where the supplier provides an interval of his inventory cost, h1 h h2 , the retailer would select a revenuesharing fraction from the following range, aLr a aU r , where 1
2m
aLr ¼ m þ m1m m1m ;
8 0<m<1
2m m 1 1m m1m þ 2m1m þ 1 ; aU r ¼ 0:5 m m
8 0<m<1
However, the monetary bargain space to be negotiated between the two parties differs in the following way: (i) When m 2 = ðm1 ; m2 Þ and cr > cs , or cr cs , and as the supplier’s average unit inventory holding cost range increases, the gap between the maximum amount ½1 of income, GrDP , that the retailer would share with the supplier increases with d " ½1 GrDP ðdÞ
where
¼ Ar1
1 1 1þd
m 1m
Ar1 ¼ 0:5ð1 mÞ 1 ð1 þ mÞm
# m 1m
;
h1 lbk lbmk
(27)
m m1
;
(28)
and (ii) When m 2 ðm1 ; m2 Þ and cr > cs , then there exists a revenue-sharing fraction, ah , where aLr < ah < aU r , at which the two parties’ new profits are identical: ah ¼
1 þ m lmðcs cr Þ þ 2 2hb0
Furthermore, as the supplier’s cost interval increases, the gap between the ½2 maximum amount of income, GrDP , that the retailer could share with the supplier increases with d " # m 1m 1 ½2 ; (29) GrDP ðdÞ ¼ Ar2 1 1þd where
m h1 m1 1 2m Ar2 ¼ 0:5 0:5m m1m þ m1m lbk : lbmk
Proof. See Appendix 4.
(30)
360
J. Hou and A.Z. Zeng
4.3
Numerical Examples
We provide two numerical examples to illustrate the range of a and the impact of the supplier’s holding cost range on the amount of revenue the retailer would share L U with the supplier. One Lexample shows the situation when ar < ah < as , and the U L U other considers ah 2 as ; as or ar ; ar . The values of the cost parameters, whose dimensions are all $/unit, for both cases are: b ¼ 2; l ¼ 500; k ¼ 0:5; h1 ¼ 0:5 Example 1. m ¼ 0.4, cr ¼ 6; cs ¼ 5. Based on these given parameters, we can easily derive values of a set of parameters when h1 ¼ 0.5 as follows: the L U as ; as ¼ ð0:6023; 0:6743Þ; aLr ; aU a ¼ 0:4; r ¼ ð0:5302; 0:6023Þ; b0 ¼ 21; 715; b1 ¼ 4; 716; Pr ðh1 ; a ; b1 Þ ¼ $5; 842; and Ps ðh1 ; a ; b1 Þ ¼ $1; 037: Furthermore, we have found that ah ¼ 0:6908; which exceeds the larger upper limit 0.6743, implying that the two members’ profits will never be the same within the sharing-fraction range. We then have calculated the two parties’ new profits, Pr ðh1 ; a; b0 Þ and Ps ðh1 ; a; b0 Þ, against the range of a (from 0.5302 to 0.6743), and display the results in Fig. 1. The profit values in the case of decentralized planning are also shown for benchmarking purpose. Note that the amount of capital that can be shared or bargained, DPs , for the dominant supplier and DPr for the dominant retailer are both about $1,954, which are also labeled in Fig. 1. 12000
10000
Pr (h1,a, b1*) 8000
P
Pr (h1,a *, b1* )
6000
DPs =
4000
Ps (h1,a,b*0 )
$1,954 DPr = $1,954
2000
Ps (h1,a *, b1* )
0 0.53 L
ar
0.56
0.6 U
0.64 L
ar, as a
Fig. 1 Example 1 – profits of the two parties: m ¼ 0.4; k ¼ 0.5; cr ¼ 6; cs ¼ 5
0.67 U
as
Bargaining in a Two-Stage Supply Chain Through Revenue-Sharing Contract
361
Fig. 2 The gap between the maximum amount of income for h1 < h < h2. (m ¼ 0.4, cr ¼ 6; cs ¼ 5)
With h1 fixed, we vary the range of h by increasing d from 0 to 1 at an increment of 0.2, and then calculate the maximum amount of revenue in dollars that could be bargained between the two parties. The results are shown in Fig. 2, which implies that as the upper limit of the supplier’s cost increases, the gap between the maximum amounts of income increases. Furthermore, the values of the gaps between supplier-dominant and retailer-dominant situations are identical; in particular, the gap is about $289,000 when h2 increases to twice as much as of h1 (i.e., d ¼ 1). 25; cs ¼ 5. Similarly, we have: a ¼ 0:45; aLs ; aU Example 2. m ¼ 0.45, s ¼ Lcr ¼ ð0:6463; 0:7138Þ; ar ; aU b0 ¼ 66; 684; b1 ¼ 15; 613; r ¼ ð0:5788; 0:6463Þ; Pr ðh1 ; a ; b1 Þ ¼ $8; 704; and Ps ðh1 ; a ; b1 Þ ¼ $7; 042: Unlike the previous example, ah ¼ 0:6575 is within aLs ; aU s ¼ ð0:6463; 0:71383Þ: The results are depicted in Fig. 3. Clearly, the amount of monetary capital that can be shared or bargained for the dominant supplier, DPs ¼ $4; 174; is smaller than for the dominant retailer, DPr ¼ $5; 003: Figure 4 shows the gap between the maximum amounts of income for this example. Unlike the previous case, this example sees a dramatic difference between the value of the gaps for supplier-dominant bargaining and retailer-dominant bargaining (About $764,000 when h2 increases to 200% of h1). This implies that the larger the bargain space (DP) is, the faster the gap between the maximum amounts of income ðGDP ðdÞÞ increases with the range of the inventory holding cost information ðdÞ. As such, the supplier would want to provide his cost information as specifically and exactly as possible in order to receive more sharing from the retailer.
362
J. Hou and A.Z. Zeng
Fig. 3 Example 2 – the profits of the two parties: m ¼ 0.45; k ¼ 0.5; cr ¼ 25; cs ¼ 5
Fig. 4 The gap between the maximum amount of income for h1 < h < h2 (m ¼ 0.45, cr ¼ 25; cs ¼ 5)
5 Concluding Remarks This paper studies the bargaining problem in a supplier–retailer supply chain based on revenue sharing. We assume that the retailer’s unit revenue is sensitive to the lead time, which is affected by the supplier’s target inventory level. A revenue-sharing
Bargaining in a Two-Stage Supply Chain Through Revenue-Sharing Contract
363
based coordination mechanism is constructed to select the supplier’s target inventory level and the revenue-sharing fraction to maximize the entire supply chain profit and to achieve a “win–win” condition. We obtain the range of the monetary amount that can be shared between the two parties under the situation where either the supplier or the retailer is dominant in the bargaining process. The impact of the supplier’s cost structure is also examined. This research leads to some subtle and important implications that can guide practices. First of all, the range of the revenue-sharing fraction that can be accepted by both parties remains the same in supplier-dominant and retailer-dominant situations. Secondly, in addition to the retailer’s unit cost (cr) and the supplier’s unit production cost (cs), the monetary amount that can be shared between the two parties depends heavily on the input parameter, m, the exponent associated with the supplier’s inventory level (b), which affects the supplier lead time, which in turn affects the profits of the two parties. Thirdly, in a retailer-dominant situation, it is easy for the retailer to obtain higher profit than the supplier; on the other hand, if the supplier is dominant, then it is hard for the supplier to gain such benefit. Finally, the format of the supplier’s cost structure (a single value versus an interval) does not affect the range of the revenue-sharing fraction that the retailer would use to coordinate the supplier. Furthermore, the larger the bargain space is, the faster the gap between the maximum amounts of capital increases with the range of the cost information. Several directions for future research can stem from our paper. First, given the optimal range of revenue-sharing fraction, how to distribute the additional profit among the supply chain entities would be an interesting issue. Second, the situation where the retailer chooses not to reveal his/her actual revenue to the counterpart is a problem that the supplier may encounter in the bargaining process. Finally, it will be worthwhile to investigate the supplier’s inventory decision if the supplier has a capacity constraint, as well as to consider the average lead time as a general function of the supplier’s inventory level. Acknowledgment This work is partially supported by the Scientific Research Foundation of Graduate School of Southeast University (YBJJ1003). We are also thankful for the helpful suggestions provided by the anonymous referees.
Appendix 1: The List of Symbols Used in the Paper l cs h cr L p
Demand rate (unit) Unit production cost of the supplier ($/unit) Average unit inventory holding cost of the supplier ($/unit) Unit cost of the retailer ($/unit) Lead time Final product’s unit profit of the retailer ($/unit)
364
p0 b b0 b1* P0rþs Pr Ps a* a aL aU ah ½ h 1 ; h2 DPs DPr GsDP
GrDP
J. Hou and A.Z. Zeng
The largest possible unit profit of the retailer ($/unit) Target inventory level of the supplier (unit) Supplier’s optimal target inventory level in a centralized supply chain (unit) Supplier’s optimal target inventory level in a decentralized supply chain (unit) Total expected profit of the supply chain Retailer’s profit function Supplier’s profit function Retailer’s optimal revenue sharing fraction in a decentralized supply chain New revenue-sharing fraction to attract the supplier to hold a larger inventory level (b0 ) and to achieve higher profits for both parties, where aL < a < a U Lower bound of the revenue-sharing fraction Upper bound of the revenue-sharing fraction Revenue-sharing fraction at which the two parties’ new profits are identical Range of the supplier’s inventory holding cost, where h2 ¼ ð1 þ dÞh1 and d > 0 Range of the monetary amount that can be shared between the two parties in a supplier-dominant supply chain Range of the monetary amount that can be shared between the two parties in a retailer-dominant supply chain Gap between the maximum amount of income that the retailer would share with the supplier in a supplier-dominant supply chain with implicit information Gap between the maximum amount of income that the retailer would share with the supplier in a retailer-dominant supply chain with implicit information
Appendix 2: This Appendix Contains the Proof for Proposition 4.1 and 4.3 If the retailer provides a higher share of revenue, a > a , to induce the supplier to hold an inventory level close to b0 , the value of the new revenue sharing fraction should satisfy the following requirements: Pr h; a; b0 > Pr h; a ; b1 ;
(31)
Bargaining in a Two-Stage Supply Chain Through Revenue-Sharing Contract
Ps h; a; b0 > Ps h; a ; b1 :
365
(32)
These two requirements ensure that the profits of both the two parties are increased so they would be willing to cooperate. If the dominant supplier gains more increase in profits, then Ps h; a; b0 Ps h; a ; b1 > Pr h; a; b0 Pr h; a ; b1
(33)
Else if the retailer is the leader, then Ps h; a; b0 Ps h; a ; b1 < Pr h; a; b0 Pr h; a ; b1
(34)
We first consider the case when the supplier is the leader. Since Pr ðh; a; b0 Þ
h ¼ ð1 aÞlbk lbmk
m m1
lcr ;
(35)
and Ps ðh; a; b0 Þ ¼ albk
h lbmk
m m1
1 m1 h h lcs lbmk
(36)
We see that the requirement in (31) implies that the fraction for revenue sharing, a, should take on the following range: 1 m a < 1 þ m1m m1m :
(37)
Similarly, we can derive another range of a based on the requirement in (32) as follows: 1 2m a > m þ m1m m1m :
(38)
And the range of a based on the requirement in (33) should be: 2m m 1 a > 0:5 m m1m m1m þ 2m1m þ 1
(39)
2m m 1 1 2m g1 ðmÞ ¼ 0:5 m m1m m1m þ 2m1m þ 1 m þ m1m m1m 1 m 2m m 1 and g2 ðmÞ ¼ 1 þ m1m m1m 0:5 m m1m m1m þ 2m1m þ 1 , it is easy m 2m to find that gðmÞ ¼ g1 ðmÞ ¼ g2 ðmÞ ¼ 0:5 1 m m1m þ m1m . Given the range Suppose
of m, 0 < m < 1, by plotting the value of g (m) to m (as seen in Fig. 5), we could
366
J. Hou and A.Z. Zeng m 0.01 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 0.55 0.6 0.65 0.7 0.75 0.8 0.85 0.9 0.95
0.08 0.07 0.06 0.05
g(m)
0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0
m = 0.25 0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
m
g (m) 0.0178 0.0490 0.0667 0.0753 0.0790 0.0797 0.0784 0.0757 0.0719 0.0675 0.0625 0.0571 0.0513 0.0453 0.0391 0.0327 0.0263 0.0198 0.0132 0.0066
Fig. 5 The plot of g(m) against m
prove that g1 ðmÞ ¼ g2 ðmÞ>0 holds for all values of m within (0, 1), and the function reaches the maximum when m ¼ 0.25. Thus, in this supplier-dominant supply chain, to entice the supplier to hold a larger inventory level b0 ; the retailer’s new share of revenue, a, which meets the requirements in (31), (32) and (33), should satisfy the following range: 2m m 1 1 m 0:5 m m1m m1m þ 2m1m þ 1 < a < 1 þ m1m m1m ;
8 0 < m < 1 (40)
Moreover, the range of a just equals g(m), which reaches the maximum (roughly about 0.0797) when m ¼ 0.25. If the retailer is the leader, since the proof is similar to that above, it is not repeated here. Hence, the proof for the proposition is complete.
Appendix 3: This Appendix Contains the Numerical Proof for Observation 4.1 The bargain space in terms of monetary value is the amount of capital shifted from the retailer to the supplier (as the supplier is the leader in the game, and thus has higher profit level). Hence, the bargain space, ð0; DPÞ, can be determined by the change of profit for the retailer as his share of revenue increases from aLs to aU s .
Bargaining in a Two-Stage Supply Chain Through Revenue-Sharing Contract
367
From Pr h; ah ; b0 ¼ Ps h; ah ; b0 , the fraction ah at which the two parties’ profits become identical can be derived as: ah ¼
1 þ m lmðcs cr Þ : þ 2 2hb0
(41)
We need to make sure that aL < ah < aU ; that is, to satisfy the following requirement, 1 þ m lmðc c Þ 1 2m m 1 1 m s r < 1 þ m1m m1m : m m1m m1m þ 2m1m þ 1 < þ 2 2 2hb0 (42) After some algebra, (42) indicates that the following relationship is required: f1 ðmÞ ¼
lmðcs cr Þ 1 2m m 1 m1m m1m þ 2m1m > 0 2hb0 2
f2 ðmÞ ¼
1 m lmðcs cr Þ 1 m >0 þ m1m m1m 2 2 2hb0
(43)
Since (43) does not offer a closed-form format of m, and 0 < m < 1, we rely on a numerical analysis again to see when the requirement of (43) can be met. The functions, f1(m) and f2(m), are plotted against m and the result are shown in Figs. 6–13 according to three different situations, with the basic parameters setting as l ¼ 500, k ¼ 0.5, b ¼ 2; h ¼ 1.
0.5
0.4
f1(m)
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
Fig. 6 The plot of f1(m) against m for cr ¼ cs
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
m
0.8
1
368
J. Hou and A.Z. Zeng 0.2 0.1
f2(m)
0 -0.1 -0.2 -0.3 -0.4 -0.5
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
m Fig. 7 The plot of f2(m) against m for cr ¼ cs
0.5
0
f1(m)
-0.5
-1
-1.5
-2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
m Fig. 8 The plot of f1(m) against m for cr > cs (m* ¼ 0.36)
Case 1: cs ¼ cr As shown in Fig. 6, for all m within (0, 1), f1 ðmÞ > 0 holds; while it is seen clearly that when m > 0:5; the value of the function f2 ðmÞ is positive. Therefore, if the input parameter, m, is greater than 0.5 (but less than 1), it is possible for the two parties’ new profits to be identical when the retailer increases his share of revenue from aL to ah , but not yet to aU . Based on the above results, we see that there are two scenarios when the supplier and retailer are coordinating to improve their respective profit from that resulted in the decentralized planning situation (1) if 0 < m < 0.5, then the retailer’s profit is
Bargaining in a Two-Stage Supply Chain Through Revenue-Sharing Contract
369
2.5
2
f2(m)
1.5
1
0.5
0
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
m Fig. 9 The plot of f2(m) against m for cr > cs ðl ¼ 500; k ¼ 0:5; b ¼ 2; h ¼ 1; cs ¼ 5; cr ¼ 10Þ
0.1 0.05 0
f1(m)
-0.05 -0.1 -0.15 -0.2 -0.25 -0.3
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
m Fig. 10 The plot of f1(m) against m for cr > cs (m* ¼ 0.46)
always higher than the supplier’s at aL a aU ; ðiiÞ if 0:5 m < 1: then the two parties reach the same profit level when the revenue-sharing fraction, a ¼ ah ðaL < ah < aU Þ. We now calculate the bargain space for each scenario. In the first scenario where 0 < m < 0.5, the bargain space, DPs1, is the differ ence between the retailer’s profits at the following two points: aL ; b0 and aU ; b0 . Referring to (8) and (11), we can calculate the difference as follows:
370
J. Hou and A.Z. Zeng 0.35 0.3 0.25
f2(m)
0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 -0.05
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
m Fig. 11 The plot of f2(m) against m for cr > cs ðl ¼ 500; k ¼ 0:5; b ¼ 2; h ¼ 1; cs ¼ 5; cr ¼ 6:5Þ
2.5
2
f1(m)
1.5
1
0.5
0
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
m Fig. 12 The plot of f1(m) against m for cr < cs (m* ¼ 0.52)
DPs1 ¼ Pr h; aL ; b0 Pr h; aU ; b0 m m m1 m1 (44) h h ¼ ð1 aL Þlbk ð1 aU Þlbk : lbmk lbmk m m1 h , and substituting aL in (11) to (44), we can be Denoting Ph ¼ lbk lbmk further simplify (44) to the following format:
Bargaining in a Two-Stage Supply Chain Through Revenue-Sharing Contract
371
0.5 0
f2(m)
-0.5 -1 -1.5 -2 -2.5
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
m Fig. 13 The plot of f2(m) against m for cr < cs ðl ¼ 500; k ¼ 0:5; b ¼ 2; h ¼ 1; cs ¼ 9; cr ¼ 5Þ
m DPs1 ¼ 0:5Ph ð1 mÞ 1 ð1 þ mÞm1m :
(45)
In the second scenario where 0:5 m < 1: the two parties’ profits approach to identical before the retailer’s revenue-sharing fraction reaches the upper limit. Since it is unfavorable for the supplier’s profit to be lower than the retailer’s, the monetary bargain space, DPs2 can be computed as DPs2 ¼ Pr h; ah ; b0 Pr h; aU ; b0 m m m1 m1 h h ð1 aU Þlbk ¼ ð1 ah Þlbk lbmk lbmk m
1
¼ Ph ð0:5 0:5m þ m1m m1m Þ 0:5lðcs cr Þ:
(46)
Case 2: cr > cs There is a specific m*, when m > m*, both f1 ðmÞ and f2 ðmÞ are positive. Then the monetary bargain space, DP s2 , is the difference between the retailer’s profits at the following two points: aL ; b0 and ah ; b0 , which can be computed as 1
m
DPs2 ¼ Ph ð0:5 0:5m þ m1m m1m Þ 0:5lðcs cr Þ
(47)
A. When cr – cs > d, where d is determined by other parameters of l; b; k; h, such m* is increasing with the distance between cr and cs, but not necessary larger or smaller than 0.5. For instance, if l ¼ 500, k ¼ 0:5, b ¼ 2, cs ¼ 5, h ¼ 1, then d is about 2, the values of m* are:
372
J. Hou and A.Z. Zeng
cr m*
6 0.11
7 0.25
10 0.36
15 0.42
20 0.45
25 0.47
And in this case when m < m*, the value of the function positive but f1 ðmÞ is f2 ðmÞis 2m m 1 lmðcs cr Þ 1 1m m1m þ2m1m þ1 < negative; i.e., the relationship of 1þm þ < mm 2hb 2 2 0
m
1
1þm1m m1m holds. That means the retailer’s profit is always smaller than supplier’s. Therefore, the bargain space L is the difference U between the retailer’s a ;b a ;b0 : DPs1 ¼0:5Ph ð1mÞ and profits at the following two points: 0 m 1ð1þmÞm1m . B. When cr – cs < d, m* is near 0.5 as the distance between cr and cs is really small. Using the same basic parameters above, m* is 0.47 for cr ¼ 6, and 0.46 for cr ¼ 6.5. But when m < m*, f2 ðmÞ f1 ðmÞ is negative for some values of m, and can be also positive for other values If nega within this range. m tive, then the bargain space is DPs1 ¼ Ph 12 ð1 mÞ 1 ð1 þ mÞm1m ; otherwise, 1 m DPs2 ¼ Ph ð0:5 0:5m þ m1m m1m Þ 0:5lðcs cr Þ. * Case 3: cr < cs . There is a specific m 0.5; its value is increasing slowly with the value of cs – cr. For instance, l ¼ 500, k ¼ 0:5, b ¼ 2, h ¼ 1, cr ¼ 5 the values of m* are: cs m*
6 0.5
7 0.51
8 0.51
9 0.52
10 0.52
11 0.53
13 0.53
15 0.54
20 0.54
When m < m*, the value of the function f2 ðmÞ is negative, while f1 ðmÞ 1 2m m 1 is positive. That is the relationship of m m1m m1m þ 2m2m þ 1 < 1 þ 2 1 m l mðCs Cr Þ þ holds. The retailer’s profit is always larger than m1m m1m < 1þm 2 2hb 0
supplier’s. Similar to m < 0.5, the bargain space is: case 1 when m DPs1 ¼ Ph 12 ð1 mÞ 1 ð1 þ mÞm1m . When m > m*, both f2 ðmÞ and f1 ðmÞ
lmðcs cr Þ are positive, then at ah ¼ 1þm , the two parties reach the same profit 2hb0 2 þ level. The monetary bargain space, DP2 , is the difference between the retailer’s profits at the following two points: aL ; b0 and ah ; b0 , which can be computed as 1 m DPs2 ¼ Ph ð0:5 0:5m þ m1m m1m Þ 0:5lðcs cr Þ. The proof for this observation is then complete.
Appendix 4: This Appendix Shows the Proof for Proposition 4.2 and 4.4 Since the proof for deriving the range of the revenue-sharing fractions is similar to that in Hou et al. (2009) and Appendix 1, it is not repeated here. Rather, we examine the monetary value that the retailer can share with the supplier. The results are summarized in Table 2 for Proposition 4.2 and Table 3 for Observation 4.4, respectively. It is seen that given a range of h½h1 h h1 ð1 þ dÞ instead of
Bargaining in a Two-Stage Supply Chain Through Revenue-Sharing Contract
373
Table 2 The maximums of shared monetary amount and gaps when the supplier is dominant (2) m < m < 1 (1) 0 < m < m L U h1 DPs11 ¼ Pr h1 ; as ; b01 Pr h1 ; as ; b01 DPs21 ¼ Pr h2 ; ah ; b01 Pr h2 ; aU s ; b01 m m m1 m1 h1 h1 lðcs cr Þ F1 ðmÞ F2 ðmÞ ¼ lbk ¼ lbk lbmk lbmk 2 L U U h2 DPs12 ¼ Pr h2 ; as ; b02 Pr h2 ; as ; b02 DPs22 ¼ Pr h2 ; ah ; b02 Pr h2 ; as ; b02 m m h2 m1 h2 m1 lðcs cr Þ F1 ðmÞ F2 ðmÞ ¼ lbk ¼ lbk 2 lbmk lbmk Gap G½1 ðdÞ ¼ DPs11 DPs12 DP " # m 1m 1 ¼ DPs11 1 1þd 1 m F1 ðmÞ ¼ ð1 mÞ 1 ð1 þ mÞm1m 2
½2
GDP ðdÞ ¼ DPs21 DPs22 " # m 1m 1 ¼ DPs21 1 1þd 1 1 1 m F2 ðmÞ ¼ m þ m1m m1m 2 2
Table 3 The maximums of shared monetary amount and gaps when the retailer is dominant (2) m 2 ðm1 ; m2 Þ and cr >cs (1) m 2 = ðm1 ; m2 Þ and cr > cs , or cr cs L U h1 DPr11 ¼ Pr h1 ; ar ; b01 Pr h1 ; ar ; b01 DPr21 ¼ Pr h1 ; ah ; b01 Pr h1 ; aLr ; b01 m m m1 m1 h1 h1 lðcs cr Þ F3 ðmÞ F4 ðmÞ þ ¼ lbk ¼ lbk 2 lbmk lbmk h2 DPr12 ¼ Pr h2 ; aLr ; b02 Pr h2 ; aU DPr22 ¼ Pr h2 ; ah ; b02 Pr h2 ; aLr ; b02 r ; b02 m m m1 m1 h2 h2 lðcs cr Þ F3 ðmÞ F4 ðmÞ þ ¼ lbk ¼ lbk lbmk lbmk 2
Gap G½1 ðdÞ ¼ DPr11 DPr12 DP " # m 1m 1 ¼ DPr11 1 1þd m F3 ðmÞ ¼ 0:5ð1 mÞ 1 ð1 þ mÞm1m
½2
GDP ðdÞ ¼ DPr21 DPr22 " # m 1m 1 ¼ DPr21 1 1þd 1 2m F4 ðmÞ ¼ 0:5 0:5m m1m þ m1m
one value, the gap between the shared monetary values at the two limits is a function of d. Let f ðdÞ ¼ 1
1 1þd
m 1m
:
(48)
As Hou et al. (2009) has proved, f ðdÞ increases as the range of h widens (i.e., h2 becomes bigger). The proof for Proposition 4.2 and 4.4 is then complete.
374
J. Hou and A.Z. Zeng
Appendix 5: This Appendix Shows the Numerical Proof for Observation 4.2 Similar to Appendix 3, from Pr h; ah ; b0 ¼ Ps h; ah ; b0 , the fraction ah at which the two parties’ profits become identical can be derived as: ah ¼
1 þ m lmðcs cr Þ þ : 2 2hb0
(49)
We need to make sure that
1 þ m lmðc c Þ 1 1 2m 2m m 1 s r < þ m m1m m1m þ 2m1m þ 1 : m þ m1m m1m < 2 2hb0 2 (50) After some algebra, (50) indicates that the following relationship is required: lmðcs cr Þ 1 1 1 2m 1m 1m >0 mþm m f1 ðmÞ ¼ 2hb0 2 2 lmðc c Þ 1 2m m 1 s r f2 ðmÞ ¼ >0 (51) m1m m1m þ 2m1m 2 2hb0
Since (51) does not offer a closed-form format of m, and 0 < m < 1, we rely on a numerical analysis again to see when the requirement of (51) can be met. The functions, f1(m) and f2(m), are plotted against m and the result are shown in Figs. 14–19 according to three different situations, with the basic parameters setting as l ¼ 500; k ¼ 0.5, b ¼ 2; h ¼ 1. 0.5
0.4
f1(m)
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
m Fig. 14 The plot of f1(m) against m for cr ¼ cs
0.8
1
Bargaining in a Two-Stage Supply Chain Through Revenue-Sharing Contract
375
0
-0.1
f2(m)
-0.2
-0.3
-0.4
-0.5
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
0.6
0.8
1
m Fig. 15 The plot of f2(m) against m for cr ¼ cs 0.5
0
f1(m)
-0.5
-1
-1.5
-2
0
0.2
0.4
m Fig. 16 The plot of f1(m) against m for cr > cs (m* ¼ 0.36)
Case 1: cs ¼ cr As shown in Fig. 14, for all m within (0, 1), f1 ðmÞ > 0 and f2 ðmÞ < 0 1 2m 2m m 1 holds; therefore, m þ m1m m1m Þ < 12 m m1m m1m þ 2m1m þ 1Þ < 1þm 2 þ lmðcs cr Þ L the retailer’s profit is always higher than the supplier’s at a a aU ; 2hb 0
and the bargain spaceDP1 , is the difference between the retailer’s profits at the following two points: aL ; b0 and aU ; b0 . DPr1 ¼ Pr h; aL ; b0 Pr h; aU ; b0 m m m1 m1 h h L U ð1 a Þlbk : (52) ¼ ð1 a Þlbk lbmk lbmk
376
J. Hou and A.Z. Zeng
Fig. 17 The plot of f2(m) against m for cr > cs. ðl ¼ 500; k ¼ 0:5; b ¼ 2; h ¼ 1; cs ¼ 5; cr ¼ 10Þ
2
1.5
f2(m)
1
0.5
0
-0.5
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
m
Fig. 18 The plot of f1(m) against m for cr < cs
2.5
2
f1(m)
1.5
1
0.5
0
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
m m m1 h Denoting Ph ¼ lbk lbmk , and substituting aL in (11) to (52), we can be further simplify (52) to the following format:
1 m DPr1 ¼ Ph ð1 mÞ 1 ð1 þ mÞm1m : 2
(53)
Case 2: cr > cs There is a specific range of (m1*, m2*), only when m is within this range, both f1 ðmÞ and f2 ðmÞ are positive, and the monetary bargain space DP1 is
Bargaining in a Two-Stage Supply Chain Through Revenue-Sharing Contract Fig. 19 The plot of f2(m) against m for cr < cs ðl ¼ 500; k ¼ 0:5; b ¼ 2; h ¼ 1; cs ¼ 9; cr ¼ 5Þ
377
0
-0.5
f2(m)
-1
-1.5
-2
-2.5
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
m
DPr2 ¼ Pr h; ah ; b0 Pr h; aL ; b0 m m m1 m1 h h L ¼ ð1 a Þlbk ð1 ah Þlbk lbmk lbmk 1 1 lðcs cr Þ 1 2m ¼ Ph m m1m þ m1m þ 2 2 2
(54)
Both values of m1* and m2* are increasing with the distance between cr and cs. And the interval between the two values is determined by other parameters of l; b; k; h. For instance, if l ¼ 500, k ¼ 0:5, b ¼ 2, cs ¼ 5, h ¼ 1, the range of (m1*, m2*) are: cr m*
6 (0.03, 0.11)
7 (0.21, 0.25)
10 (0.32, 0.36)
15 (0.38, 0.42)
20 (0.41, 0.45)
25 (0.43, 0.47)
But when m is outside this small range, f2 ðmÞm f1 ðmÞ is negative, and the bargain space is DPr1 ¼ 0:5Ph ð1 mÞ 1 ð1 þ mÞm1m . Case 3: cr < cs As seen from (51), the value of f1 ðmÞ increases with (cs – cr) and f2 ðmÞ decreases with (cs – cr), with other parameters unchanged. From Case 1 we know that, when cs ¼ cr, for all m within (0, 1), f1 ðmÞ > 0 and f2 ðmÞ < 0 holds; therefore, when cr < cs , we also have f1 ðmÞ > 0 and f2 ðmÞ < 0 for all m within (0, 1) (as shown in Figs. 18 and 19). Therefore, similarto case 1, the monetary bargain m space can be computed as DPr1 ¼ 0:5Ph ð1 mÞ 1 ð1 þ mÞm1m . The proof for this observation is then complete.
378
J. Hou and A.Z. Zeng
References Bellantuono N, Giannoccaro I, Pontrandolfo P, Tang CS (2009) The implications of joint adoption of revenue sharing and advance booking discount programs. Int J Prod Econ 121(2):383–394 Cachon G, Lariviere MA (2000) Supply chain coordination with revenue sharing contracts: strengths and limitations. Manage Sci 51(1):30–44 Chauhan SS, Proth JM (2005) Analysis of a supply chain partnership with revenue sharing. Int J Prod Econ 97(1):44–51 Chen J, Chen JF (2006) Study on revenue sharing contract in virtual enterprises. J Syst Sci Syst Eng 15(1):95–113 Chen K, Gao C, Wang Y (2007) Revenue-sharing contract to coordinate independent participants within the supply chain. J Syst Eng Electron 18(3):520–526 Giannoccaro I, Pontrandolfo P (2004) Supply chain coordination by revenue sharing contracts. Int J Prod Econ 89(2):131–139 Giannoccaro I, Pontrandolfo P (2009) Negotiation of the revenue sharing contract: an agent-based systems approach. Int J Prod Econ 122(2):558–566 Guardiola LA, Meca A, Timmer J (2007) Cooperation and profit allocation in distribution chains. Decis Support Syst 44(1):17–27 Gupta D, Weerawat W (2006) Supplier–manufacturer coordination in capacitated two-stage supply chains. Eur J Oper Res 175(1):67–89 He L, Walrand J (2005) Pricing and revenue sharing strategies for internet service providers. Paper presented in Proceedings of IEEE international conference on computer communications (INFOCOM), Miami, FL Hou J, Zeng AZ, Zhao L (2009) Achieving better coordination through revenue sharing and bargaining in a two-stage supply chain. Comput Ind Eng 57(1):383–394 Jaber MY, Osman IH (2006) Coordinating a two-level supply chain with delay in payments and profit sharing. Comput Ind Eng 50(4):385–400 Jia NX, Yokoyama R (2003) Profit allocation of independent power producers based on cooperative Game theory. Int J Electr Power Energy Syst 25(8):633–641 Li S, Hua Z (2008) A note on channel performance under consignment contract with revenue sharing. Eur J Oper Res 184(2):793–796 Li S, Hua Z, Huang L (2009) Supply chain coordination and decision making under consignment contract with revenue sharing. Int J Prod Econ 120(1):88–99 Lin Z, Cai C, Xu B (2010) Supply chain coordination with insurance contract. Eur J Oper Res 205 (2):339–345 Linh CT, Hong Y (2009) Channel coordination through a revenue sharing contract in a two-period newsboy problem. Eur J Oper Res 198(3):822–829 Nagarajan M, Sosˇic´ G (2008) Game-theoretic analysis of cooperation among supply chain agents: Review and extensions. Eur J Oper Res 187(3):719–745 Pan K, Lai KK, Leung SCH, Xiao D (2010) Revenue-sharing versus wholesale price mechanisms under different channel power structures. Eur J Oper Res 203(2):532–538 Ouardighi FE, Kim B (2010) Supply quality management with wholesale price and revenuesharing contracts under horizontal competition. Eur J Oper Res 206(2):329–340 Rhee B, Veen JAA, Venugopal V, Nalla VR (2010) A new revenue sharing mechanism for coordinating multi-stage supply chains. Oper Res Lett 38(4):296–301 Sucky E (2006) A bargaining model with implicit information for a single supplier–single buyer problem. Eur J Oper Res 171(2):516–535 Yao Z, Stephen CH, Leung KKL (2008) Manufacturer’s revenue-sharing contract and retail competition. Eur J Oper Res 186(2):637–651 Zhang A, Fu X, Yang HG (2010) Revenue sharing with multiple airlines and airports. Transp Res B Methodol 8–9(2):944–959
Should a Stackelberg-Dominated Supply-Chain Player Help Her Dominant Opponent to Obtain Better System-Parameter Knowledge? Jian-Cai Wang, Amy Hing Ling Lau, and Hon-Shiang Lau*
Abstract A manufacturer (Manu) supplies a product to a retailer (Reta). The uncertain knowledge of the dominant player (which may be either Manu or Reta) about a system parameter is represented by a subjective probability distribution. At the time when the dominant player is designing the supply or purchase contract, should the dominated player help the dominant player to improve his imperfect system-parameter knowledge? Can the dominant player induce the dominated player to share her superior knowledge by using (or by threatening to use) sophisticated “channelcoordinating” contract formats? It is likely that one would surmise from the literature that the answer to both questions is “yes”. However, this chapter shows that very often the correct answer is “no”. Specifically, for the basic cost and market parameters, we show that the dominated player is (1) always motivated to mislead the dominant player to have a biased mean value for his subjective distribution; and (2) motivated, over a wide range of likely conditions, to increase the variance of the dominant player’s subjective distribution. Moreover, the dominant player cannot narrow this range of confusion-encouraging conditions by using a more sophisticated contract format such as a “menu of contracts.” Our results highlight the need to develop arrangements that can actually motivate a dominated player to share knowledge honestly.
*
Authors contributed equally; names arranged in reverse alphabetical order
J.-C. Wang School of Business, University of Hong Kong, Pokfulam, Hong Kong and School of Management and Economics, Beijing Institute of Technology, Beijing, China e-mail: [email protected] A.H.L. Lau School of Business, University of Hong Kong, Pokfulam, Hong Kong e-mail: [email protected] H.-S. Lau* (*) Department of Management Sciences, City University of Hong Kong, Kowloon Tong, Hong Kong e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_15, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
379
380
J.-C. Wang et al.
Keywords Supply chain contract design • Information sharing
1 Introduction 1.1
Problem Statement
In considering human/organizational interactions, two common notions appear to be intuitively plausible at first glance: 1. It is often “beneficial” to share knowledge and strive for a “bigger pie” for all. 2. There is often some way a player can benefit himself by hiding/distorting the information he is supposed to provide to the other player. Unfortunately, these two notions suggest opposite actions; i.e., sharing knowledge honestly versus hiding/distorting information. Much of the supply chain literature is motivated by the first notion. This chapter emphasizes the validity of the second notion, contrary to what one might surmise from the large supply chain literature on information sharing and channel coordination. Specifically, we consider a supply chain with an upstream “manufacturer” (a male called “Manu”) and a downstream “retailer” (a female called “Reta”). We will consider separately the situations where the dominant player is (1) Manu; and (2) Reta. To facilitate explanation, the first part of this chapter will concentrate on the case in which the dominant player is Manu. Manu will then specify the supply contract. Manu is uncertain about one of the system parameters (say, x), and perceive it as a random variable x~ with subjective probability distribution Fx(•). Reta knows x perfectly, and recognizes that Manu’s x~-knowledge will influence how Manu will specify the supply contract to be offered to Reta. Our question is: from Reta’s perspective, what are the ideal characteristics (or “quality”) of Manu’s x~-perception that would lead Manu to specify a contract that is most advantageous to Reta? The spirit of the current supply chain “movement” suggests that Reta should help to improve the quality of Manu’s x~-perception. In contrast, this chapter summarizes our research results (Wang et al. 2008, 2009) showing that, in most situations, the opposite is true – regardless of what contract format Manu would implement.
1.2 q p C(q)
Summary of Basic Symbols and Relationships The quantity supplied by Manu to Reta and sold by Reta to the retail market The unit retail price set by Reta A supply contract designed and offered by Manu to Reta, requiring Reta to pay Manu $C(q) if Reta wants Manu to supply her q units
Should a Stackelberg-Dominated Supply-Chain Player
m, c x~ PM , P R, P I PC PM, PR PMsub, PRsub
381
The unit variable cost of Manu and Reta, respectively and k (m þ c) A generic random variable with support [xmin, xmax], standard deviation sx, and coefficient of variation kx. x~’s mean is denoted by either mx or x (i.e., bold letter) The profit of, respectively, Manu, Reta, and the “integrated firm” Total channel profit, equals (PM + PR) Expected profit of, respectively, Manu and Reta The subsistence profit of, respectively, Manu and Reta
Reta incurs a unit retail-processing cost c and gets to set the unit retail price p and the purchase quantity q. Given a supply contract C(q) specified by Manu and the (p, q)-decision set by Reta, Manu’s and Reta’s profits are: For Manu : PM ¼ CðqÞ mq; For Reta : PR ¼ ðp cÞq CðqÞ:
(1)
Both players know that for any p Reta sets, the market demand is given by the linear demand curve: q ¼ a bp;
(2)
where parameters (a,b) reflect the basic market-demand characteristics. In this model, Reta’s decision variables are (p,q), and Manu’s decisions are (1) C(q)’s format; and (2) the numerical values of C(q)’s parameters. Besides m, Manu’s “environmental variables” (or “system parameters”) are {a, b, c}. Manu’s knowledge of one of these is imperfect, and perceives it as a random variable (i.e., a~, b~ or c~), with cumulative distribution function (cdf) Fa(•), Fb(•) or Fc(•), respectively.
2 Review and Overview Figure 1 depicts the decision/action sequence of our scenario. At time point A, the dominated player (“Reta” in the current scenario) anticipates that the systemparameter information s/he provides may influence how the dominant player (“Manu”) will specify the supply contract. At time point B the dominant player specifies the supply contract.
2.1
Positioning in the Literature
There exists now a huge literature on supply chain coordination and cooperation; see, e.g., Cachon (2003) and Chen (2003) for excellent reviews. Among others, the following two notions are likely to be learnt from this literature:
382
J.-C. Wang et al.
Reta contemplates the format of Manu’s Fx(•) that will be most beneficial to Reta.
Manu specifies C(q), using his knowledge Fx(•) on x. ˜
Reta orders q units from Manu.
Reta sets the retail price p and sells her stock.
time axis Point A
Point B
Point C
Fig. 1 Schematic diagram of action sequence showing time points A–C
Notion (A): At time point B depicted in Fig. 1, the dominant player with imperfect knowledge of system parameter (say, “a”) can use a series of increasingly sophisticated contract formats to increasingly improve his (and the supply chain’s) expected profit. See, e.g., Corbett et al. (2004), and Liu and C¸etinkaya (2009) about supply chain contract design under “stochastic” and “asymmetric” knowledge scenarios. Notion (B): At time point C depicted in Fig. 1 (after C(q) has been specified), if a player at one supply-chain echelon has better knowledge of the system’s environmental parameters than the player at the other echelon, the better-informed player can often improve the supply chain’s performance by sharing his/her superior information – i.e., the “bigger pie” notion (see, e.g., Lee et al., 2000, Wu and ¨ zer 2010). Note that in our stripped-down cost model Cheng 2008, and Liu and O defined by (1) and (2), by time point C it is too late for Reta to improve channel profit by sharing her superior information with Manu. Our paper extends the earlier related studies in the following aspects: 1. While the overwhelming majority of earlier related studies consider questions ¨ zer raised at time points B or C in Fig. 1 (see, e.g., Ha 2001; Lau and Lau 2005; O and Wei 2006), we consider a question raised at time point A. 2. We use the simplest possible two-echelon structure, summarized by (1) and (2). There is no manufacturing capacity consideration, production lead time, logistics cost, forecasting issue, knowledge transmission cost, etc. Thus, we have removed as much as possible those factors that are most readily identified as motivations for Reta to conceal her superior {a,b,c}-knowledge. The purpose is to minimize any likely confounding effects by factors not directly related to our questions. Among many others, Tirole (1988), Corbett et al. (2004), and Liu and C¸etinkaya (2009) also employ this stylized structure. Regarding Aspect (1) stated above, only a few other supply-chain contractdesign studies have also focused on time point A. For example, Li (2002) examined the following problem: At time point A, are the dominated players willing to sign an information-sharing contract with the dominant player before they learn the true information, noting that once information sharing is agreed, the private information obtained later must be revealed truthfully.
Should a Stackelberg-Dominated Supply-Chain Player
383
That is, although the contract-signing action is at time point A, the possible information acquisition and sharing occurs after time point A. Another example is Taylor and Xiao (2010), who investigated, from the dominant-player’s perspective, which format of Fx(•) would be optimal. In contrast, our study takes the perspective of the dominated player. We now reiterate the difference between our questions and the questions answered in most of the related earlier studies. Consider first the situation where Manu is the dominant player. The earlier studies showed that (1) Manu can use increasingly sophisticated contract formats to give himself increasingly higher expected profits; (2) under a specified supply contract (with specified contract parameter values), often Manu and the channel (and sometimes also Reta) will benefit if Manu becomes better informed about certain system parameters (such as a, b, or c). In contrast, our questions are: 1. Before Manu has finalized a supply contract, is Reta motivated to help Manu to become better informed about certain system parameters? 2. Can Manu motivate Reta to help him become better informed by telling Reta that he will use increasingly more sophisticated supply contract formats? This chapter will show that, under a wide range of plausible situations (hereafter “Situation A”), Reta prefers Manu to be more (rather than less) uncertain about the system’s parameter(s). Moreover, the range of “Situation A” cannot be narrowed significantly by using more sophisticated contract formats. Also, Reta is always motivated to bias Manu’s subjective distributions. For Reta, our results mean that, contrary to what she is likely to conclude from the current supply-chain literature, she should NOT share knowledge honestly but should mislead Manu before Manu finalizes his contract; we also showed what kind of Manu-misperception Reta should aim for. For Manu (and hence the researchers), our results mean that, again contrary to what one might conclude from the literature, the various sophisticated channel coordinating contract formats are unable to induce Reta to share information honestly. Our results therefore also establish the need to find new ways to motivate Reta to share knowledge. To facilitate understanding, the wording in the preceding two paragraphs is for the situation where Manu is the dominant player. For the situation where Reta is the dominant player, simply interchange the terms “Manu” and “Reta”.
2.2
Overview of the Chapter
Sections 3–5 will consider the dominant-Manu case. Section 6 outlines the dominantReta case. The main results are summarized in the concluding Sect. 7.
384
J.-C. Wang et al.
3 The Case of a Dominant Manu: Structure of the Problem 3.1
Supply Contract Formats Considered
We consider four C(q)-formats that Manu may impose (listed below in the order of increasing level of “sophistication”): 1. Price-only contract, label [w]. This is the simplest C(q) format: Manu charges Reta a wholesale price w for each unit she buys from Manu. 2. Franchise Fee contract, label [FF]. Manu requires Reta to pay a specified franchise fee FFM; he then supplies Reta the product at cost (i.e., m/unit). 3. Two-Parts Tariff contract, label [2P]. Manu requires Reta to pay a lump-sum fee L and also charges Reta a wholesale price w for each unit she buys from Manu. 4. Menu of Contracts, label [MC]. Assume for the time being that Manu knows deterministically all parameters except a, and [amin, amax] is the finite support of the subjective probability distribution of Manu’s perceived a˜. The format of Manu’s [MC] is then{[w(adec), L(adec)]|amin adec amax}; i.e., Manu informs Reta that if Reta declares the demand curve’s a-value to be adec, Manu will charge Reta a unit wholesale price w(adec) plus a lump-sum payment L(adec). That is, w(adec) and L(adec) are functions of adec. Among others, Myerson (1979) has shown that, for a given Manu’s initial state of stochastic a-knowledge, Manu can design a w(adec) and a L(adec) such that Reta is forced to reveal the real a-value as adec at time point C of Fig. 1; the resultant [MC] then gives Manu the highest expected profit he can get among all possible contract formats (specified at Point B). Similarly, if Manu knows deterministically all parameters except b or c, the format of Manu’s [MC] will be, respectively, {[w(bdec), L(bdec)]| bmin bdec bmax} or {[w(cdec), L(cdec)]|cmin cdec cmax}. The above four C(q)s are the most popularly considered contract formats. There are of course other formats besides these four. However, as will be justified in Sect. 4.5, considering these four is sufficient to support the conclusions we will be presenting in this chapter.
3.2
Characterizing Manu’s Subjective Distributions
Consider, for example, Manu’s subjective distribution on a˜, with cdf Fa(•), mean ma and standard deviation sa. We consider two aspects of the “quality” of Manu’s a˜-perception: its “bias” (ma a) and its “uncertainty” sa. Manu’s a˜-perception is “perfect” if both bias and uncertainty equal zero. Earlier related studies such as Ha (2001) and Corbett et al. (2004) had to restrict the imperfectly-known parameter’s subjective distribution to be uniform in order to obtain meaningful analytical results. We follow this approach and also obtain analytical results by assuming a uniform Fa(•). We then go one more step and
Should a Stackelberg-Dominated Supply-Chain Player
385
investigate the effects of assuming a more versatile distribution for Fa(•). The gamma distribution is chosen because it can take on a much wider range of coefficients of variations and skewnesses compared to (say) the popular exponential, Erlang or normal (which are special cases of the gamma). For our model, numerical results using a gamma Fa(•) reveal some important behavior unobservable under a uniform-Fa(•) assumption. Of course, the gamma numerical results also confirm the major uniform-based analytical results. In the following sections, numerical results under the gamma assumption will be presented first because they are easier to understand, analytical results for the uniform assumption are then used to provide further support.
3.3
Overview and Preview for the Dominant-Manu Case
Sections 4 and 5 consider, respectively, uncertainties in “a” and “c”. Since fairly similar results are obtained for all three parameters {a, b, c}, we present detailed results only for “a”, while results for “b” are completely omitted. Our results can be briefly summarized as follows: Regardless of what contract format Manu will use, Reta should always try to inflate mb and mc but deflate ma. Regarding the uncertainties, Reta does not want Manu’s (sa, sb, sc) to be too low, but also not too high. To emphasize, Reta’s preferences towards Manu’s m and s are quite different. Regarding the “error” (in m), Reta wants it to be as large as possible (as long as it is in the right direction). Regarding “uncertainty” s, Reta does not want Manu to be either too certain or too uncertain about his estimate. Our conclusions also mean that both Reta and Manu should behave in ways that are quite different from what one might surmise from the current supply chain literature; particularly, they are in stark contrast to the “all or nothing” result in Taylor and Xiao (2010).
3.4
Summary of Basic Benchmark Results
Detailed derivations of the results summarized in this subsection can be found in, e.g., Corbett et al. (2004) and Lau and Lau (2005). Under an “integrated firm” where Manu and Reta are merged into one entity, it is known that the optimal (p,q) decisions and the attainable channel profit are: pI ¼ ða þ bkÞ=ð2bÞ; qI ¼ ða bkÞ=2; and PI ¼ ða bkÞ2 =ð4bÞ; recall k ðm þ cÞ:
(3)
If Manu and Reta are two separate players, each with deterministic knowledge of all the parameters, then the dominant Manu knows that, for any w-value he declares
386
J.-C. Wang et al.
in a [w]-contract, The players’ profits and Reta’s responses (on retail-price and purchase-quantity) are: ðPM Þw ¼ ðw mÞ½a bðw þ cÞ=2; ðPR Þw ¼ ½a bðw þ cÞ2 =ð4bÞ; pw ¼ ða þ bc þ bwÞ=ð2bÞ; qw ¼ ða bc bwÞ=2:
) (4a)
Recognizing the above, Manu maximizes his profit by setting w ¼ ða þ bkÞ=ð2bÞ;
(4b)
leading to the following optimal profits for the players and the channel: PR ¼ ða bkÞ2 =ð16bÞ; PM ¼ ða bkÞ2 =ð8bÞ; PC ¼ PM þ PR ¼ 3ða bkÞ2 =ð8bÞ:
(4c)
Equations (3) and (4) show that PC* < PI*; i.e., [w] does not “coordinate the channel.” In contrast, it is known that, with deterministic parameter knowledge, either [FF] or [2P] enables Manu to not only coordinate the channel (i.e., achieve PC* ¼ PI*), but also acquire absolute power in deciding Reta’s share of ПI* (subject of course to the condition PR PRsub). In the deterministic knowledge context [MC] is irrelevant because it degenerates into [2P]. If Manu does not know all the parameters deterministically, it is known that no contract format enables Manu to achieve the same total channel profit as ПI*. However, in most “stochastic” or “asymmetric” knowledge scenarios, [w], [FF] and [2P] enable Manu to achieve progressively higher expected profit for himself. Ultimately, [MC] is the most powerful contract format for Manu – i.e., an optimized [MC] enables Manu to obtain the largest expected profit for himself. Relative to [w], we will refer to [FF], [2P] and [MC] collectively as “coordination encouraging” contract formats.
4 Dominant Manu is Uncertain About the Market Size a In this section, we will consider in Sect. 4.1 how Reta wants Manu to perceive “a” when both sides know that Manu will offer a price-only ([w]) contract. Then, in Sects. 4.2–4.4 we will consider how Reta wants Manu to perceive “a” when both sides know that Manu will offer, in turn, a franchise fee contract ([FF]), a two-part tariff contract ([2P]) and a menu of contract ([MC]). Under each contract, we first tabulate the numerical results for the situation where Manu’s a priori subjective knowledge of parameter “a” is gamma-distributed; this tabulation enables us to illustrate the main pattern of behavior we are emphasizing in this chapter. This pattern is then confirmed by analytical results we are able to derive for the situation
Should a Stackelberg-Dominated Supply-Chain Player
387
where Manu’s a priori subjective knowledge of parameter “a” is uniformdistributed. Our results consistently show that (1) Reta always prefers Manu to perceive (incorrectly) a deflated ma; moreover, over a wide range of plausible conditions, Reta prefers Manu to be more uncertain about a (i.e., higher sa); and (2) Manu cannot narrow or alter Reta’s range of confusion-preferring conditions by implementing (or threatening to implement) a more sophisticated contract format (e.g., [MC]) instead of a simpler one (e.g., [w]).
4.1
The Price-Only Contract [w]
4.1.1
Problem Statement: Manu’s Knowledge of “a” is Inferior to Reta’s
Manu perceives a˜ with subjective cdf Fa(•). Thus, after setting w, (4a) indicates that ~ M(perM) ¼ (w m)[a˜ b(w þ c)]/2 and Manu will perceive his own profit to be P ~ R(perM) ¼ [a˜ b(w þ c)]2/(4b). Manu will perceive Reta’s profit to be P recognizes that Reta will “play” only if Reta’s profit exceeds PRsub; i.e., Manu ~ R(perM) PRsub; or, equivalently, when a˜ b0 , perceives that Reta will play if P 0 where b ¼ b(w + c) þ √(4bPRsub) is the “cutoff value” (see Ha 2001 for a more ~ M(perM)] under a detailed explanation). Thus, Manu’s problem of maximizing E[P stochastically-perceived a˜ can be written as: ð amax fðw mÞ½a bðw þ cÞ=2g dFa ðaÞ; where b ¼ maxðamin ; b0 Þ: (5) max w
b
Thus, Manu will set the unit wholesale price at w*, where w* is the solution to (5). Then, Reta knows, from her perspective, that if Manu perceives a˜ with cdf F(a), her profit (as perceived by herself) is, PR(perR) ¼ [areal b(w* þ c)]2/(4b). This PR(perR)-expression shows that a higher PR(perR) is brought by a lower w*. Reta’s (and hence our) question is therefore: what kind of a Manu-perceived Fa(•) will lead to a lower w* – hence a higher PR(perR)? 4.1.2
Numerical Results
Table 1 presents the PR(perR)-values for different combinations of c-values and ka-values (or, equivalently, sa-values); recalling that kx x~’s coefficient of variation. Values of other parameters are set at: areal ¼ ma ¼ 5, b ¼ 1, ПRsub ¼ [ma b (c þ m)]2/24, and a˜ is gamma distributed. Without loss of generality, we set m ¼ 1 throughout this chapter. To obtain the PR(perR)-values, first solve (5) numerically for w*, then compute PR(perR) ¼ [areal b(w* þ c)]2/(4b). Table 1 shows that, for any given c-value (i.e., along each c column), PR(perR) decreases as sa increases in the lower (grayed) region where sa is “sufficiently large,” but PR(perR) increases as sa increases in the upper (non-grayed) region where sa is “sufficiently small.” A “Boundary B” separates the grayed and non-grayed regions (or “Situations”).
388
J.-C. Wang et al.
Table 1 ПR(perR) under a price-only contract ([w])
Gamma-distributed a˜, ma ¼ 5, b ¼ 1, and ПRsub ¼ (ma bk)2/(24b) 2.5
ΠR(perR)
2 [w] [FF] [2P] [MC]
1.5 1 0.5 0
2.5
3
3.5
4
4.5
5
5.5
6
6.5
7
7.5 ma
Fig. 2 PR(perR) under gamma-distributed a˜: sa ¼ 0.4, areal ¼ 5, b ¼ 1, c ¼ 1, and PRsub ¼ 0
In other words, over a significant range of plausible conditions, Reta is motivated to increase Manu’s uncertainty in a˜. We have repeated Table 1 computations using a grid system of different combinations of values of the parameters ma, b and ПRsub; their results confirm the pattern illustrated in Table 1 (the same verification approach has been used in all subsequent numerically illustrated patterns to be reported in this chapter). Table 1’s characteristics will be discussed again in greater detail in Sect. 4.1.4 after supporting analytical results are presented below. The “filled diamond” line in Fig. 2 illustrates, for a typical set of (sa, areal, b, c, ПRsub)-parameter values, how PR(perR) increases as ma decreases under a [w] contract. That is, Reta always prefers Manu to perceive (incorrectly) a deflated ma. 4.1.3
Analytical Proofs
The behavior depicted in Table 1 (and other effects) are derived analytically in Appendix 1 of Wang, Lau and Lau (hereafter “WLL”) (2008) for the case of a uniform F(a). The main results are summarized as Lemmas 1A to 1C. Note that one does not need to read these analytical results (and their counterparts in Sects. 4.2.3, 4.3.3 and 4.4.3) in order to follow the basic arguments of this chapter.
Should a Stackelberg-Dominated Supply-Chain Player
389
Corresponding to the slanting “Boundary B” in Table 1, WLL’s (2008) Appendix 1 shows that, for the case of a uniform F(a), there are four “regions” or “Situations,” separated by three boundaries defined as follows. First, the boundary functions saWA, saWB and saWC are derived in (A6), (A9) and (A10) of WLL’s (2008) Appendix A. For example, one boundary function is: pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi saWB ¼ fma bk 5 bPRsub þ
qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi 2 pffiffiffi ½ma bk bPRsub þ 8bPRsub g=ð4 3Þ : (6)
Second, these boundary functions delineate the following four Situations: 1. 2. 3. 4.
Situation Ia: when sa saWA Situation Ib: when saWA < sa saWB Situation II: when saWB < sa saWC Situation III: when sa > saWC
Lemma 1A (Manu’s optimal w-decision). Depending on the “Situation,” Manu’s w* is: Situation Ia (when sa saWA): w* ¼ [ma b(c m)]/(2b). pffiffiffi pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi Situation Ib (when saWA < sa saWB): w ¼ ½ma 3sa bc 2 bPRsub =b: Situation II (when saWB < sa saWC):
w ¼
pffiffiffi 2ðma þ 3sa bcÞ þ bm
qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi pffiffiffi 2 ½ma þ 3sa bk þ 12bPRsub =ð3bÞ:
Situation III (when sa > saWC): PR(perR) is less than PRsub, hence no trade occurs. Lemma 1B (Effect of sa on PR(perR)). Since (4) shows that PR(perR) increases as w decreases, one can obtain the following conclusions by simply observing the w*-expressions given in Lemma 1A above: In Situation Ia, w* and hence PR(perR) is constant w.r.t. sa. In Situation Ib, w* decreases and hence PR(perR) increases as sa increases. In Situation II, w* increases and hence PR(perR) decreases as sa increases. Lemma 1C (Effects of ma and PRsub on PR(perR)). Effect of ma: in all Situations, w* increases as ma increases; i.e., PR(perR) decreases as ma increases. Hence Reta is always motivated to mislead Manu into perceiving a smaller ma. Effect of PRsub: in all Situations, w* decreases and hence PR(perR) increases as PRsub increases. Hence Reta is always motivated to convince Manu to recognize an inflated PRsub.
4.1.4
Discussion
Although this chapter is not meant to consider PRsub, the effect of PRsub stated in Lemma 1C is worth noting. On one hand, its Lemma-1C effect appears intuitively reasonable once it is stated; on the other hand, earlier models incorporating PRsub
390
J.-C. Wang et al.
have always assumed that Manu knows and accepts PRsub as it is. Lemma 1C suggests that setting PRsub is an issue that warrants deeper investigations. We return now to our main issue: Manu’s is a˜-knowledge, which we quantify in two aspects: bias (ma a) and uncertainty sa. Reta’s Preference on ma, or a˜ ’s Bias A higher a-value implies a higher “base demand.” Thus, our Lemma-1C result means that Reta will always try to mislead Manu into perceiving as low a ma-value as possible. This is neither counter-intuitive nor intuitively obvious. It is not surprising that a dominated player will want the dominant player (something like a “boss”) to perceive the operating environment as “tougher” than it actually is. Reta’s Preference on sa, or a˜ ’s Level of Uncertainty In contrast to ma’s effects, we show here that sa’s (or, equivalently, ka’s) effects are quite counter-intuitive. Lemma 1B indicates that PR(perR) is a quasi-concave function of sa, attaining its maximum at saWB. This, of course, is the sa (or ka) effect illustrated graphically by Table 1, where the grayed area below Boundary B (the line “══”) corresponds to Situation II, and the white area above Boundary B corresponds to Situation Ib. It can be easily seen from the derivations in Appendix 1 that Situation Ia does not arise if a˜’s probability distribution has a long right-hand tail (as in a gamma distribution), hence Table 1 does not exhibit a Situation-Ia area – in contrast to Lemma-1’s uniform-distribution results. Under Situation Ib, Reta prefers Manu’s sa to be higher; i.e., instead of sharing her a-information, she is actually motivated to confuse Manu and muddy Manu’s a˜-knowledge. This is contrary to the increasingly popular supply chain notion of mutually beneficial information sharing. Nevertheless, Table 1 also depicts that the Situation-Ib area is always above the Situation-II area; i.e., Reta is motivated to increase sa when sa is “too low,” but to reduce sa when sa is “too high” – thus, this aspect of sa’s counter-intuitive effects does fit the intuitively attractive notion of “everything in moderation.” We now study how large the Situation-I area is relative to the Situation-II area. This is facilitated by Table 1’s numerical results. Consider first the case of a uniformly distributed a˜. Define kaBB as the ka-value of Boundary B. Assuming the simpler case of PRsub ¼ 0, (6) indicates that p kaBB ¼ ½1 ðbk=ma Þ=ð2 3Þ; i.e., kaBB should be less that [1/(2√3)], or 0.29. Table 1 depicts, for situations with non-zero PRsub and gamma-distributed (instead of uniform-distributed) a˜, kaBBvalues that are significantly less than 0.29. Thus, for the Table 1 column with c ¼ 1, kaBB 0.12. At this c-value, assuming that ma ¼ areal, (3) gives pI* ¼ (areal + bk)/(2b) ¼ (5 + 2)/2 ¼ 3.5, where k ¼ m+c ¼ 2. Hence the theoretical
Should a Stackelberg-Dominated Supply-Chain Player
391
optimal markup over cost is M ¼ (pI* k)/k ¼ 0.75, which is near the lower end of realistic M values, considering that this is the combined gross profit margin of both Manu and Reta. Thus, columns to the right of the “c ¼ 1” column in Table 1 represent less realistic conditions because they are not sufficiently profitable, whereas columns to the left of the “c ¼ 1” column in Table 1 represent increasingly profitable conditions. In other words, for most realistic combinations of system-parameter values, “Situation I” applies when ka is between 0 and (very roughly) 0.2. Thus, while Situation I is not entirely negligible, it is probably not as prevalent as Situation II. Note, however, that this conclusion will be contradicted in Sect. 5, where knowledge uncertainty in “c” (instead of “a”) is considered.
4.2 4.2.1
The Franchise Fee Contract [FF] Problem Statement: Manu’s Knowledge of “a” is Inferior to Reta’s
We stated in Sect. 3.1 that, under [FF], Manu charges Reta a lump-sum fee FFM but supplies her at cost; i.e., m/unit. If Manu perceives a˜, he then perceives Reta’s profit as, from (3), h i ~ R ðperMÞ ¼ ða~ bkÞ2 =ð4bÞ FFM : P (7a) Since Manu knows that Reta will “play” only if her profit is at least PRsub, ~ R(perM) ¼ PRsub” gives “b” (the “cut-off” a-value below which Reta solving “P “quits”) as pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi (7b) b ¼ bk þ 2 ½bðPRsub þ FFM Þ: Hence Manu’s problem is to set FFM to maximize ð amax FFM dFa ðaÞ:
(8)
maxðamin ;bÞ
From Reta’s perspective, if Manu charges FFM, her profit (as perceived by herself) is PR(perR) ¼ (areal bk)2/(4b) FFM. Thus, Reta prefers a Manuperceived Fa(•) that leads to a lower FFM, and hence a higher PR(perR).
4.2.2
Numerical Results
As counterpart to Table 1, Table 2 presents the PR(perR)-values for different combinations of c-values and ka-values (or, equivalently, sa-values) under [FF] when a˜ is gamma distributed. Values of the other parameters (i.e., ma, b, m and ПRsub) are as for Table 1. The sa-effects on PR(perR) depicted by Table 2 are very
392
J.-C. Wang et al.
similar to those depicted by Table 1. The position of “Boundary B” (marked “══”) remains largely unchanged when one moves from Table 1 to Table 2. That is, implementing [FF] instead [w] does not alter or narrow the range of conditions under which Reta prefers Manu’s sa to be larger.
4.2.3
Analytical Proofs
The behavior depicted in Table 2 (and other effects) are derived analytically in WLL’s (2008) Appendix B for the case of a uniformly-distributed a˜. The main results are summarized as Lemmas 2A to 2C; they parallel Lemmas 1A to 1C given in Sect. 4.1.3 for [w]. Lemma 2A (Manu’s optimal FFM decision). The boundary values saFB and saFC used below are defined in (B4) and (B5) of WLL’s (2008) Appendix B. Then, depending on the “Situation,” Manu’s FFM* is: Situation I (when sa saFB): FFM ¼ ðma
pffiffiffi 3sa bkÞ2 =ð4bÞ PRsub :
Situation II (when saFB < sa saFC): qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi pffiffiffi pffiffiffi 2 FFM ¼ fma þ 3sa bk þ ½ma þ 3sa bk þ 12bPRsub g2 =ð36bÞ PRsub :
(9)
(10)
Situation III (when sa > saFC): PR(perR) is less than PRsub, hence no trade occurs. Lemma 2B (Effect of sa on PR(perR)). Since Sect. 4.2.1 showed that PR(perR) increases as FFM decreases, one easily obtains the following conclusions by observing the FFM-expressions given in Lemma 2A above: In Situation I, FFM* decreases and hence PR(perR) increases as sa increases. In Situation II, FFM* increases and hence PR(perR) decreases as sa increases. Therefore, PR(perR) is a quasi-concave function of sa, with its maximum at saFB. Lemma 2C (Effects of ma and PRsub on PR(perR)). The effects of ma and PRsub on PR(perR) under [FF] are identical to those stated in Lemma 1C for the [w] contract. Table 2 ПR(perR) under a Franchise fee contract ([FF])
Gamma-distributed a˜, ma ¼ 5, b ¼ 1, and ПRsub ¼ (ma bk)2/(24b)
Should a Stackelberg-Dominated Supply-Chain Player
4.3 4.3.1
393
The Two-Part Tariff Contract [2P] Problem Statement: Manu’s Knowledge of “a” is Inferior to Reta’s
As stated in Sect. 3.1, under [2P], Manu charges Reta a lump-sum fee L on top of a unit wholesale price w. Similar to the arguments given in Sects. 4.1.1 and 4.2.1 for [w] and [FF], Manu’s problem under [2P] can be formulated as: ð amax ½a bðw þ cÞ þ L dFa ðaÞ; ðw mÞ (11) max w;L;b b 2 subject to
4.3.2
½b bðw þ cÞ2 L PRsub ; amin b amax : 4b
(12)
Numerical Results
As counterpart to Tables 1 and 2, Table 3 presents the PR(perR)-values for different combinations of c- and sa-values under [2P] when a˜ is gamma-distributed. Again, the sa-effects on PR(perR) depicted by Table 3 are very similar to those depicted by Tables 1 and 2, and the comments made in Sect. 4.2.2 for [FF] are also applicable here. 4.3.3
Analytical Proofs
The behavior depicted in Table 3 (and other effects) are derived analytically in WLL’s (2008) Appendix C for the case of a uniform F(a). The main results are summarized as Lemmas 3A to 3C; they parallel Lemmas 1A to 1C given in Sect. 4.1.3 for [w] and Lemmas 2A–2C given in Sect. 4.2.3 for [FF]. Similar to Lemma 1A, the Situation’s boundary functions saTA, saTB and saTC are derived in (C12), (C9) and (C13) of WLL’s (2008) Appendix C. Lemma 3A (Manu’s optimal [2P] decisions for w and L). Depending on the “Situation,” Manu’s optimal [2P] decisions for w and L are: Situation I (when sa min(saTA,saTB)): Table 3 ПR(perR) under a two-part tariff contract ([2P])
Gamma-distributed a˜, ma ¼ 5, b ¼ 1, and ПRsub ¼ (ma bk)2/(24b)
394
J.-C. Wang et al.
pffiffiffi pffiffiffi 3sa =b þ m; and L ¼ ðma 2 3sa bkÞ2 =ð4bÞ PRsub :
(13)
Situation IIa (when min(saTA,saTB) < sa saTB): pffiffiffi pffiffiffi w ¼ 3sa =b þ m; and L ¼ ðma 2 3sa bkÞ2 =ð4bÞ PRsub :
(14)
w ¼
Situation IIb (when saTB < sa saTC): qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi pffiffiffi pffiffiffi 2 w ¼ 4ðma þ 3sa bcÞ þ 11bm ðma þ 3sa bkÞ þ 60bPRsub =ð15bÞ; (15a) L ¼
pffiffiffi ma þ 3sa bk þ
qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi pffiffiffi 2 ðma þ 3sa bkÞ þ 60bPRsub =ð100bÞ PRsub : (15b)
Situation III (when sa > saTC): PR(perR) is less than PRsub, hence no trade occurs. Lemma 3B (Effects of sa on PR(perR)). In Situation I, PR(perR) increases as sa increases. In Situation IIa and Situation IIb, PR(perR) decreases as sa increases. Therefore, PR(perR) is a quasi-concave function of sa, with its maximum at min (saTA, saTB). (Note that contrary to its counterparts Lemmas 1B and 2B, Lemma 3B cannot be obtained by merely observing the results given in Lemma 3A; it is derived in WLL’s Appendix 3). Lemma 3C (Effects of ma and PRsub on PR(perR)). The effects of ma and PRsub on PR(perR) under [2P] are identical to those stated in Lemmas 1C and 2C for [w] and [FF].
4.4 4.4.1
A Menu of Contract [MC] Brief Explanation of the Menu of Contracts ([MC]) Format
As explained in Myerson (1979) and Corbett et al. (2004), it is possible for Manu to specify functions w(adec) and L(adec) such that Reta is forced to declare the real a-value as adec, and that the resultant [MC] is the contract format that gives Manu the highest expected profit for a given state of stochastic a-knowledge (see Sect. 3.1).
4.4.2
Numerical Results
As counterpart to Tables 1–3, Table 4 presents the PR(perR)-values for different combinations of c- and sa-values under [MC] when a˜ is gamma distributed. Again, the sa-effects on PR(perR) depicted by Table 4 are very similar to those depicted by
Should a Stackelberg-Dominated Supply-Chain Player
395
Tables 1–3, and the comments made in Sects. 4.2.2 and 4.3.2 for [FF] and [2P] are also applicable here. 4.4.3
Analytical Proofs
The behavior depicted in Table 4 (and other effects) can be proven analytically for the case of a uniformly-distributed a˜. The substance of what amounts to “Lemma 4A” (i.e., the counterpart of Lemmas 1A, 2A and 3A) are detailed in WLL’s Appendix D. Lemmas 4B to 4C stated below are counterparts of the earlier Lemmas 1B/1C, 2B/2C and 3B/3C. Lemma 4B. The definitions of the following critical values saMA, saMB and saMC are given in (D14), (D12) and (D15) of WLL’s Appendix D. Then, depending on the “Situation,” the effects of sa on Reta’s PR(perR) are: Situation I (sa min(saMA,saMB)): PR(perR) increases as sa increases. Situation IIa (min(saMA,saMB) < sa saMB): PR(perR) decreases as sa increases. Situation IIb (saMB < sa saMC): PR(perR) decreases as sa increases. Situation III (sa > saMC): PR(perR) is less than PRsub, hence no trade occurs. Lemma 4C. PR(perR) decreases as ma increases and increases as PRsub increases.
4.5
Summary and Discussion for the Scenario of Asymmetric a-Knowledge
Each of Sects. 4.1–4.4 showed that, given that Reta already knows the contract format Manu will use (be it [w], [FF], [2P] or [MC]), there is a “Situation-I” set of conditions under which Reta prefers Manu’s a-uncertainty to be higher when Manu is trying to determine the Manu-profit-maximizing parameter values of the supply contract. Furthermore, the expanse of Situation I remains largely unchanged for different contract formats. Since [w] ([MC]) is the simplest (most powerful) supply contract format a dominant Manu can impose, it is reasonably safe to assume that other plausible contract formats will also exhibit such a “Situation-I” behavior Table 4 PR ðperRÞ under a menu of contracts ([MC])
Gamma-distributed a˜, ma ¼ 5, b ¼ 1, and PRsub ¼ ðma bkÞ2 =ð24bÞ
396
J.-C. Wang et al.
(we have actually confirmed this for a few other contract formats such as “quantity discount” and “(maximum) resale price maintenance”). Therefore, combining Sects. 4.1–4.4 enables us to conclude that, even if Reta does not know what contract format Manu will use, there is still a roughly constant set of conditions under which she prefers Manu to be less certain about a when Manu is formulating the supply contract. However, as explained in Sect. 4.1.4, these Situation-I conditions are probably not more prevalent than the Situation-II conditions (this conclusion will be contradicted in Sect. 5, where instead of “a,” Manu does not know “c” deterministically). However, Reta is always motivated to mislead Manu into believing an inflated value of PRsub but a deflated value of ma. The analytical derivations and numerical computations presented here have been done under the assumption that Reta knows a perfectly. However, it can be easily shown that the same conclusions are obtained if one assumes that Reta also knows a only as a random variable a˜0 (which is likely to be different from Manu’s perceived a˜). For example, under [w], (4) gives Reta’s expected profit as E[PR(perR)] ¼ E [a˜0 b(w* + c)]2/(4b), a moment’s reflection would reveal that a lower w* leads to a higher E[PR(perR)]. Combining this conclusion with Lemma 1A leads again to Lemma 1B. The same argument applies to Lemmas 2 and 3 (for [FF] and [2P]). [MC] presents greater difficulties, since now one has to derive a different set of [MC]’s [w(adec), L(adec)], given that Manu realizes that Reta also knows a only as a random variable. This is because, unlike [w], [FF] and [2P], Reta’s knowledge plays a role in Manu’s design of [MC]. In other words, extending our results, one can prove easily that, regardless of whether Reta herself is well informed of the parameter (say) a, a “Situation I” exists under [w], [FF] and [2P], where Reta prefers Manu to be less certain about a. While our analytical results cannot be similarly extended for [MC], it seems reasonable to conjecture that the same conclusion can be extended to [MC]. In other words, there exists a “Situation I” under which Reta prefers Manu’s sa to be larger, regardless of Reta’s own knowledge of a.
5 Dominant Manu is Uncertain About Reta’s Unit Cost c 5.1
Reta’s Preference on sc, or c’s Level of Uncertainty
We follow the same approach used in Sects. 3 and 4. First, as in a˜’s case, we are able to obtain analytical solutions (obtainable from the authors) for the case of uniformly-distributed c~ (i.e., the counterparts of Lemmas 1–4). We also obtained numerical solutions for the case of gamma-distributed c~, which not only reveal more characteristics than the uniformly-distributed-~ c analytical solutions, but are also much easier to understand. Since the c~-results here have much in common the ~ we will omit for brevity sake the [FF] numerical results. earlier results for a˜ and b, Thus, Tables 5–7 correspond to, respectively, Tables 1, 3 and 4 of Sect. 3 for [w],
Should a Stackelberg-Dominated Supply-Chain Player
397
[2P] and [MC]. In the following paragraphs we point out the similarities to and emphasize the differences from the results presented earlier for a˜. The following similarities between Tables 5–7 and the earlier tables can be observed: 1. There is a Situation-I (Situation-II) area where kc is sufficiently low (high) and Reta prefers Manu to be more (less) uncertain about c~. The low/high-kc areas are graphically separated by a “Boundary B” (the line “══”) in the tabulated numerical data. 2. The position of Boundary B does not change substantially when Manu’s contract changes from the simplest format (i.e., [w]) to the most sophisticated and powerful (i.e., [MC]). The significant difference between this section’s c-uncertainty results (i.e., Tables 5–7) and the earlier a-uncertainty results (i.e., Tables 1–4) is in the k-magnitude at which Boundary B is located. In short, the Situation-I area is now much more prevalent than in the cases of uncertainties in a (and in b, detailed in WLL 2008). To elaborate, consider the Table 5 column with a ¼ 5. As explained in Sect. 4.1.4, we have, from (2), pI* ¼ [a + b(mc + m)]/(2b) ¼ (5 + 2)/2 ¼ 3.5, and the markup over cost is M ¼ (pI* k)/k ¼ 0.75. That is, the profitability here is the same as the column of c ¼ 1.0 in Table 1 discussed in Sect. 4.1.4. However, whereas Boundary B in Table 1’s “c ¼ 1” column occurs at around ka ¼ 0.13, Boundary B in Table 5’s “a ¼ 5” column occurs at around kc ¼ 0.5. Noting that the maximum possible k-value for a uniformly distributed random variable is 0.577, a Boundary-B location at kc ¼ 0.5 means that Situation I (the area above Boundary B) covers a very high proportion of likely uncertainty levels in Manu’s c~. Columns to the right of “a ¼ 5” in Table 5 represent low-profitability conditions that are less likely to occur. Moving to the left, the “a ¼ 10.0” column in Table 5 corresponds to a markup-over-cost (M) of 2 – an M-value not unrealistic high. However, at this M-level, Situation II does not arise until kc is as high as 0.95. Thus, ~ contrary to the conclusions reached in the preceding section for a˜ (and for b, detailed in WLL 2008), Table 5 shows that when Manu is uncertain about c, then
Table 5 ПR(perR) under a price-only contract ([w])
Gamma-distributed c~, mc ¼ 1, b ¼ 1, and ПRsub ¼ [a b(mc þ m)]2/(24b)
398
J.-C. Wang et al.
Table 6 ПR(perR) under a two-part tariff ([2P])
Gamma-distributed c~, mc ¼ 1, b ¼ 1, and ПRsub ¼ [a b(mc þ m)]2/(24b)
Table 7 ПR(perR) under a menu of contracts ([MC])
Gamma-distributed c~, mc ¼ 1, b ¼ 1, and ПRsub ¼ [a b(mc þ m)]2/(24b)
in the majority of plausible conditions Reta is motivated to increase Manu’s c-uncertainty. Incidentally, Table 5 shows the necessity of considering both uniform and gamma distributions in this chapter; i.e., under some a-values “Situation II” can only arise when kc exceeds 0.577, thus Situation II cannot be adequately illustrated using only the uniform distribution. Therefore, to facilitate direct comparisons, Tables 1–7 are all compiled using gamma-distributed distributions. In Tables 6 and 7, Boundary B is slightly higher than its position in Table 5. However, it does not alter the conclusions reached in the preceding paragraph based on [w] and in the preceding sections based on a- and b-uncertainties – i.e.: 1. Over a range of plausible conditions (Situation I), Reta prefers Manu to be more uncertain about c. Also, Manu cannot significantly narrow or alter the range of Situation I by using a more sophisticated contract format (e.g., [MC]) instead of a simpler one (e.g., [w]). 2. Contrary to uncertainties in demand (i.e., sa and sb), under c-uncertainty Situation I becomes more prevalent than Situation II.
Should a Stackelberg-Dominated Supply-Chain Player
5.2
399
Reta’s Preference on mc (or c’s bias) and PRsub
It can be easily proven that Reta will always try to mislead Manu into perceiving a higher mc (numerically illustrated in Fig. 3) and a higher PRsub. This effect matches intuition.
6 The Case of a Dominant Reta While WLL (2008) considered dominant-Manu scenarios, WLL (2009) considered the following dominant-Reta cost/profit model: For Manu : PM ¼ ðw mreal Þ q; Reta’s profit PR ¼ ðp wÞ q; where q ¼ a bp:
(16)
Referring to Fig. 1, the dominant Reta knows Manu’s mreal only stochastically as ~ and we investigate, from Manu’s perspective, what are the ideal characteristics m, ~ (or “quality”) of Reta’s m-perception that would lead Reta to specify a contract that is most advantageous to Manu. As in the preceding Sects. 3–5, we assume that Reta may implement any one of the four following contract-formats (1) price-only [rSU]; (2) [FF]; (3) [2P]; and (4) [MC]. Note that (1) [rSU] is [w]’s mirror image for the dominant-Reta scenario; and (2) a Reta-imposed [MC] involves more difficult calculations than a Manu-imposed [MC]. We developed procedures in WLL (2009) for determining, for each of the four contract formats, the parameter values that will optimize Reta’s expected profit. Using these optimizing procedures, we identified conditions under which Manu is motivated to share or distort asymmetrical information on the system parameters m and PMsub. These conditions are summarized as Points E–G in Sect. 7. 1.2 1 ΠR(perR)
0.8
[w] [FF] [2P] [MC]
0.6 0.4 0.2 0
mc 0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
1
1.1
1.2
1.3
1.4
1.5
Fig. 3 PR(perR) under gamma-distributed c~: sc ¼ 0.4, creal ¼ 1, a ¼ 5, b ¼ 1, and PRsub ¼ 0
400
J.-C. Wang et al.
7 Concluding Summary We consider a very basic two-echelon supply chain system defined by the profit functions and demand curve given in (1), (2) and (16). At the initial stage (time point A in Fig. 1), the dominant player has not specified a supply contract, and has a stochastic perception of the value of one of the system’s parameters – i.e., one of {a,b,c} in the dominant-Manu case, or “m” in the dominant-Reta case. Sections 3–5 cover the dominant-Manu case, where we investigated how Reta would prefer Manu to perceive {a,b,c} and whether Reta is (or can be) motivated to improve the quality of Manu’s perception. We found that: (A) Regardless of how simple or sophisticated Reta’s contract format is, Reta is always motivated to mislead Manu into perceiving an inflated mc and an inflated PRsub. (B) Reta is always motivated to mislead Manu into perceiving a deflated ma-value but an inflated mb-value. (C) Reta is motivated to increase sx (where “x” is one of {a,b,c}) when sx is “too low,” but to reduce sx when sx is “too high” – i.e., “everything in moderation”. (D) Over a very substantial range of plausible and “desirable” (i.e., “profitable”) conditions, Reta is motivated to increase the uncertainty level (s) of Manu’s perception of {a,b,c}. Moreover, this range of confusion-preferring conditions cannot be narrowed by using (or threatening to use) more sophisticated contract formats such as a “menu of contracts” at time point B. Point A appears intuitively obvious after it is pointed out, even though it does not appear to have been explicitly recognized in the literature. Point B is neither intuitively obvious nor counter-intuitive. Points C and D are counter-intuitive and also appear to contradict some popularly held notions. Results (C) and (D) on Reta’s s-preference can be viewed from two directions. First, the current emphasis on supply chain coordination and collaboration might induce one to “guess” that a rational Reta would want to improve the quality (i.e., reduce the s) of Manu’s perception of (a,b,c), particularly when a coordination-encouraging contract is to be implemented. On the other hand, the existence of information rent might induce one to “guess” that Reta would not want to help Manu for free. Our results show that both guesses are half right (and half wrong). Thus, one can argue, coming from the “supply chain” angle, that it is counter-intuitive that the prospect of a coordination-encouraging contract has no effect on motivating Reta to reduce Manu’s s on (a,b,c). From the opposite direction, one might also argue that it is counter-intuitive that there is a range of conditions under which Reta would be interested in improving Manu’s s “for free.” Section 6 covers the dominant-Reta case, where we investigated how Reta would want Manu to perceive {m} and whether Reta is (or can be) motivated to improve the quality of Manu’s perception. Very similar to our dominant-Manu findings reported in Sects. 3–5, we found that:
Should a Stackelberg-Dominated Supply-Chain Player
401
(E) Regardless of how simple or sophisticated Reta’s contract format is, Manu is always motivated to mislead Reta into perceiving an inflated mm and an inflated Manu’s subsistence profit level PMsub. (F) Manu is motivated to increase sm when sm is “too low,” but to reduce sm when sm is “too high” – i.e., “everything in moderation” (see Sect. 3.3). (G) Over a significant range of likely conditions, Manu is motivated to increase rather than reduce sm – i.e., to worsen rather than improve the degree of ~ certainty/confidence Reta feels about her initial m-perception before Reta designs her contracts. Manu is motivated to reduce the uncertainty of Reta’s ~ m-perception only in a relatively narrower range of conditions that can be roughly characterized as “low profitability.” Point E appears to be intuitively obvious after it is pointed out. Point F is not very counter-intuitive, but Point G is counter-intuitive and contradicts some popularly held notions.
References Cachon GP (2003) Supply chain coordination with contract. In: de Kok AG, Graves C (eds) Handbooks in operations research and management science, vol 11, Supply chain management: design, coordination, and operation. Elsevier, Amsterdam Chen FR (2003) Information sharing and supply chain coordination. In: de Kok AG, Graves C (eds) Handbooks in operations research and management science, vol 11, Supply chain management: design, coordination, and Operation. Elsevier, Amsterdam Corbett CJ, Zhou D, Tang CS (2004) Designing supply contracts: contract type and information asymmetry. Manage Sci 50:550–559 Ha AY (2001) Supplier-buyer contracting: asymmetric cost information and cutoff level policy for buyer participation. Nav Res Log 48:41–64 Lau AHL, Lau HS (2005) Some two-echelon supply-chain games: improving from deterministicsymmetric-information to stochastic-asymmetric-information. Eur J Oper Res 161:203–223 Lee HL, So KC, Tang CS (2000) The value of information sharing in a two-level supply chain. Manage Sci 46:626–643 Li L (2002) Information sharing in a supply chain with horizontal competition. Manage Sci 48:1196–1212 Liu XC, C ¸ etinkaya S (2009) Designing supply contracts in supplier vs buyer-driven channels: the impact of leadership, contract flexibility and information asymmetry. IIE Trans 41:687–701 ¨ zer O ¨ (2010) Channel incentives in sharing new product demand information and robust Liu H, O contracts. Eur J Oper Res 207(3):1341–1349 Myerson RB (1979) Incentive compatibility and the bargaining problem. Econometrica 47:61–73 ¨ zer O ¨ , Wei W (2006) Strategic commitments for an optimal capacity decision under asymmetric O forecast information. Manage Sci 52:1238–1257 Taylor TA, Xiao W (2010) Does a manufacturer benefit from selling to a better-forecasting retailer? Manage Sci 56(9):1584–1598 Tirole J (1988) The theory of industrial organization. MIT, Cambridge, MA Wang JC, Lau HS, Lau AHL (2008) How a retailer should manipulate a dominant manufacturere’s perception of market and cost parameters. Int J Prod Econ 116:43–60 Wang JC, Lau HS, Lau AHL (2009) When should a manufacturer share truthful manufacturing cost information with a dominant retailer? Eur J Oper Res 197:266–286 Wu YN, Cheng TCE (2008) The impact of information sharing in a multiple-echelon supply chain. Int J Prod Econ 115:1–11
.
Supply Chain Coordination Under Demand Uncertainty Using Credit Option S. Kamal Chaharsooghi and Jafar Heydari
Abstract In this chapter, a coordination scheme based on the credit option for the simultaneous coordination of order quantity (Q) and reorder point (s) in a two-stage supply chain (SC) is developed. A decentralized SC including one buyer and one supplier is investigated. The buyer faces demand uncertainty and uses a continuous (s, Q) inventory model. It is shown that joint decision making for both s and Q is profitable for the whole SC. However, in centralized decision making the buyer always loses, whereas the supplier greatly profits. A credit option is proposed as a coordination scheme to encourage the buyer to accept the coordinated decisions. In the proposed model, the buyer can benefit from late payments that are subject to commitment to the jointly agreed s and Q. The lower and upper bounds for the credit period are calculated. The proposed scheme shares the benefits of coordinated decision making based on the bargaining power of each member. Numerical experiments showed that the proposed model can achieve channel coordination. Keywords Coordination • Credit option • Order quantity • Reorder point • Supply chain • Uncertainty
1 Introduction The supply chain concept is based on collaboration and coordination between all companies involved in producing, distributing, and delivering the right product at the right time for the consumers. From this viewpoint, all members involved in an SC must make their decisions in accordance with overall SC benefits. In the past, S.K. Chaharsooghi Industrial Engineering Department, Tarbiat Modares University, Tehran, Iran e-mail: [email protected] J. Heydari (*) Industrial Engineering Department, Shiraz University of Technology, Shiraz, Iran e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_16, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
403
404
S.K. Chaharsooghi and J. Heydari
companies competed with each other, whereas today, supply chains are racing against each other. The success of an SC depends on the willingness of the potential customers, which requires collaboration and coordination between all members in reducing the sale price, improving product quality, and delivering the right services to the customers. Due to the continuity of decisions in an SC, a wrong decision at one stage (e.g., a local optimum) can lead to additional costs for other members; thus, the SC can be greatly hindered in accomplishing its mission. Therefore, each SC member should make decisions regarding other members rather than only their own profitability. For example, the buyer (or retailer) has the authority to make inventory decisions, such as how much to order (order quantity) or when to order (reorder point). However, these decisions, in addition to influencing the buyer’s profitability, affect the supplier’s costs by changing its inventory-system inputs. Customers’ expectations are currently increasing; these include a high-quality product at the lowest price, quick delivery, and after-sale services. This increase of customer expectations, along with the many competitors in the market, has forced SC members to collaborate to meet the demands of customers at a higher level than their competitors. Thus, to increase customer loyalty and expand market share, each SC member should make appropriate decisions such that the overall SC costs are reduced and the customers’ expectations are met in the best possible manner. Additionally, uncertainties such as external factors outside of the SC members’ control can significantly affect the decisions made by SC partners (Chaharsooghi and Heydari 2010a). These uncertainties may include but are not limited to demand (quantity), supply (time), and price (changes). In facing uncertainties, there are two general strategies: first, if the uncertainties can be manipulated (by paying the relevant costs), shaper strategies are used, e.g., shaping market demand by offering a discount; second, if the uncertainty cannot be reshaped, it is then necessary to implement appropriate plans (e.g., increasing safety stocks) to face future uncertainties, known as adaptor strategies (Gupta and Maranas 2003). Member coordination is a key idea in the formation of the supply chain concept; in almost all definitions of the supply chain, coordination plays a critical role. Coordination in SC means that all decision makers in the SC make their decisions in alignment with other partners such that they globally optimize decision criteria. Sometimes, this alignment between decision makers requires members to set their decision variables far from their local optima; therefore, to encourage these members to accept the global optimum, a set of incentive schemes should be offered. Anything that is capable of encouraging an SC member to participate in the coordination model can be identified as an incentive scheme, e.g., quantity discounts, return policies (buy-back contracts), quantity flexibility, revenue sharing contracts, and credit options (delayed payment). The main focus of this chapter is on the credit option as an innovative scheme for facilitating SC coordination under demand uncertainty. The use of credit is very common in current business environments and plays an important role as a form of financing, particularly in developing countries (Sarmah et al. 2008). Although credit trading has been studied traditionally from the viewpoint of financing, from the operations-management viewpoint, using credit can reduces a company’s
Supply Chain Coordination Under Demand Uncertainty Using Credit Option
405
operating costs. In today’s business transactions, suppliers frequently allow credit for fixed time periods to encourage buyers to increase the size of their orders (Huang 2010). Allowing credit for a specific time period is advantageous for the buyer from several points of view. First, under a credit contract, the buyer does not have to pay the supplier immediately and therefore it is possible to pay the supplier from future earnings. Therefore, low-capital buyers can enter the business. Second, as the major portion of inventory holding costs is associated with investment depreciation, using credit therefore reduces these costs. In other words, delayed payment reduces the amount of capital invested in stock for the duration of the credit period (Huang 2010). Third, the unpaid balance can be invested during the credit period and create additional earnings. In general, before the end of the delay period, the retailer can sell the goods and accumulate revenue and earn interest (Huang 2007). In this chapter, we consider the benefit of credit from the second point of view. In this chapter, a two-stage, serially-connected SC is investigated. The downstream uses a continuous inventory-review system (s,Q). Based on this inventory-review system, the downstream places its order of size Q when its inventory level drops to the reorder point s. In the traditional mode, both Q and s are determined by the downstream so that minimize its costs. In the coordinated mode, unlike in the traditional mode, both downstream and upstream jointly determine these decision variables. Our analyses show that the simultaneous coordination of order quantity and reorder point is profitable for the supply chain as whole. Although the profit of the entire chain is increased, the buyer’s profitability is affected due to the deviation from its local optimum. To compensate for the downstream loss, an incentive scheme based on a credit option is proposed. According to the implemented credit option, the downstream can delay payments for purchased and delivered goods for a certain time, which is known as the credit period. Because a major part of inventory costs is due to investment depreciation on warehouses, a delay in payment can reduce these costs in the downstream site. The credit option is applied successfully as an innovative scheme to simultaneously coordinate both order quantity and reorder point in the supply chain. By implementing the credit option in the SC, the profitability of both members is increased over that before accepting the coordination model. Therefore, the participation of all members in the model is guaranteed. The lower and upper bounds for the credit period are determined based on the downstream and upstream profitabilities. Finally, the exact value of the credit period is calculated based on the bargaining power of each member. In this case, the profits of the coordination model are shared according to the bargaining power of the members. The main contribution of this chapter is the development of a model for the simultaneous optimization of order quantity and reorder point in a supply chain under demand uncertainty. We show that offering delayed payment can encourage the buyer to change its decisions to fall in line with the SC-optimal decisions. Delayed payment has been previously considered mostly for deterministic situations; in this study, we show that delayed payment is capable of coordinating an SC under a demand uncertainty. This chapter is organized as follows. In Sect. 2, a brief literature review is provided. SC model development in decentralized, centralized, and coordinated
406
S.K. Chaharsooghi and J. Heydari
decision making is described in Sect. 3. Section 4 presents the numerical experiments. Finally conclusions are given in Sect. 5.
2 Literature Review Recently, SC coordination has attracted the attention of many researchers as well as practitioners around the world. Moving toward the development of supply chain management, the coordination issue has become a critical field of study. Various coordination models have been proposed in the literature. In this section, we focus on the recent studies in this area. Effective SC management requires the coordination of all SC members, including suppliers, manufacturers, distributors, and retailers, in delivering goods to the customers (Xu et al. 2001). Coordination mechanisms aim to find the optimum solution for the entire chain and then encourage chain members to accept this solution (Giannoccaro and Pontrandolfo 2004). Coordination can be considered in different functions of an SC such as inventory control, logistics, transportation, and forecasting, (Arshinder et al. 2008). Most of the research on SC coordination to date has considered the order quantity as the core parameter, while other parameters also exist that must be coordinated (Chaharsooghi and Heydari 2010a). In the centralized SC, there is one central planner who makes decisions and controls all members and therefore makes decisions that maximize the profit of the whole SC, whereas in decentralized, uncoordinated SC, each member maximizes its own profit (Chen et al. 2010). To coordinate a decentralized SC, various coordination contracts have been proposed in the literature, including quantity discounts (Tsai 2007; Shin and Benton 2007; Li and Liu 2006), buyback policies (Xiao et al. 2010; Ding and Chen 2008; Yao et al. 2008), revenue sharing (Van der Rhee et al. 2010; Hou et al. 2009; Li et al. 2009; Chauhan and Proth 2005), credit options (Chaharsooghi and Heydari 2010b; Jaber and Osman 2006; Sarker et al. 2000), and insurance contracts (Lin et al. 2010). The philosophy of all coordination contracts is the fair sharing of risk among partners. Cachon (2003) conducted a comprehensive literature review on SC-coordination contracts. In the following, the most popular coordination models are examined. Sharing downstream overstocking risk is the main concern of order-quantity coordination models. In a multi period setting, quantity-discount models – the most popular coordination models – have been developed. In quantity-discount models, the upstream encourages the downstream to change its order size by offering a quantity discount. Here, the problem is how to set the discount parameters such that the downstream has enough incentive to participate and, conversely, so that upstream profitability is not seriously affected. Various discount models have been introduced in the literature for various problem settings. For example, coordinating a three-level SC using quantity discounts has been investigated (Munson and Rosenblatt 2001; Jaber et al. 2010). A linear quantity-discount model to coordinate an SC including one manufacturer and multiple retailers after a demand disruption
Supply Chain Coordination Under Demand Uncertainty Using Credit Option
407
has been developed (Chen and Xiao 2009). A quantity-discount model in a twostage SC, in which the demand rate depends on the retailer’s stock level, has also been developed, and it was shown that this model could achieve channel coordination (Zhou et al. 2008). Return policies are also of interest to researchers in the SC-coordination field. In single-period inventory systems (or seasonal sales), unsold items at the retailer’s site at the end of the period pose a risk for the retailer. Return policies are adopted by upstream members to convince retailers to place their orders based on the wholly optimal solution. The effect of e-marketplaces on return polices in an SC when the returned product can be sold in the e-marketplace has been studied (Choi et al. 2004). Flexible return policies in a three-level SC have been proposed, and it was shown that this policy could achieve channel coordination (Ding and Chen 2008). The impact of price-sensitive demand on return polices has also been investigated and various situations were modeled (Yao et al. 2008). The effect of demand-information asymmetry on full return polices was investigated, and it was found that, under some conditions, it is possible that the upstream can lose profitability whereas the downstream always benefits from a return policy (Yue and Raghunathan 2007). Another coordination contract is the credit option or delayed payment, the main concern of this work. In trade, using credit or delayed payment means late payment for a purchased and delivered product. Credit trade has some advantages for the credit users (buyers) and is very common in business today. From the perspective of inventory control, one important advantage of the use of credit is the reduction of inventory-holding costs (Chaharsooghi and Heydari 2010b). A credit option was successfully applied for coordinating the base stock level and review period in a two-stage SC with periodic inventory model (Moses and Seshadri 2000). The optimal pricing and ordering policies with delayed payment, which are dependent on order size in a single-location inventory system, have been calculated, wherein it was assumed that a fixed and predetermined credit period is a function of order quantity and demand is a function of selling price (Shinn and Hwang 2003). The optimal cycle time of a single-location inventory model when delayed payment was allowed by the vendor and the credit period is not a decision variable has also been calculated (Chung et al. 2005); this model has been enhanced by optimizing the retailing price in addition to the cycle time (Teng et al. 2005). Subsequently, the model was further complemented to consider a partially permissible delay in payment when the order size is smaller than a predetermined quantity (Huang 2007). The above studies all considered the case of deterministic demand without shortages; Chung and Huang (2009) complemented the previous works by considering delayed payment in a single-location inventory system when shortages are allowed. This study was later extended to an economic production-quantity framework with a finite replenishment rate (Hu and Liu 2010). Most of the abovementioned studies in the field of delay in payments considered single-location inventory systems, whereas in supply chain management the problem is extended to multilocation inventory systems. Delay in payments has been successfully used to coordinate the order quantity in a deterministic environment
408
S.K. Chaharsooghi and J. Heydari
(Jaber and Osman 2006). The optimal replenishment cycle and replenishment frequency in a two-stage SC under a credit option have been determined and the delay period calculated (Chen and Kang 2007). Sarmah et al. (2007) introduced a coordination model based on a credit option in a two-stage serial SC in which each party has its individual profit target. Afterwards, the coordination of singlemanufacturer and multiple heterogeneous buyers by considering transportation costs when demand is known and constant was investigated, and the coordinated production and replenishment cycle are determined (Sarmah et al. 2008). In another report, the effect of delayed payment, the inflation rate, and the depreciation rate on the inventory system when the supplier provides a permissible payment delay for the purchaser were discussed, and the optimal payment period and replenishment cycle were derived (Chang et al. 2009). Lead-time reduction in a two-stage supply chain with a permissible payment delay has been investigated, and the optimum inventory policy along with the optimum lead-time length has been calculated (Huang et al. 2010a). In the last study, the credit period was considered to be an input parameter of the system. The same authors further developed this work from a mathematical modeling viewpoint, in which the capital investment in reducing the order-processing time is a logarithmic function of ordering costs (Huang et al. 2010b). In this chapter, a credit-option model is proposed as an incentive scheme for coordinating one buyer and one supplier. In comparison with the previous works in the field of SC coordination and delay in payments contracts, this study can be distinguished in two aspects. First, the proposed model considers the coordination of two principal inventory decisions, i.e., order quantity and reorder point, simultaneously. Second, in the proposed model the credit option is investigated as an incentive scheme in the continuous inventory-review system in which the customer demand is stochastic. In the proposed model, the buyer uses an (s,Q) inventory system and the decision variables are order quantity and reorder point. By offering a credit period, the supplier encourages the buyer to select these decision variables such that the expected total SC costs are minimized. The coordinating parameter “Credit period” is determined such that both parties have sufficient incentive to participate in the model.
3 Model Development The investigated supply chain is a two-stage SC with one actor at each level, namely, buyer and supplier. The buyer faces the stochastic demand of the customers and uses a continuous inventory-review system (s,Q), in which an order of size Q is placed with the supplier when the buyer’s inventory level drops to the reorder point s. The placed order Q is delivered to the buyer after a stochastic lead time. In this model, the mean and variance of lead-time demand (LTD) is known. Both s and Q are buyer decision variables. The received customer orders must be responded to immediately; otherwise, the unfulfilled demand will be backlogged and must be realized as soon as possible.
Supply Chain Coordination Under Demand Uncertainty Using Credit Option
409
The supplier problem is how to replenish stocks such that is able to respond to the buyer’s orders. It is assumed that when a supplier places the replenishment order, the order is delivered immediately and instantaneously. In this situation, it has been proven that optimal size of a supplier order is an integer multiple of the buyer’s order quantity (Rosenblatt and Lee 1985). The following notation is used in this chapter: D Q1 Q2 h1 h2 A1 A2 B k m sL s
Expected demand per year Buyer’s order quantity (decision variable) Supplier’s order quantity, which is function of the buyer’s order quantity given by Q2 ¼ nQ1, where n is an integer (decision variable) Buyer’s unit inventory holding cost per year Supplier’s unit inventory holding cost per year Buyer’s ordering cost per replenishment Supplier’s ordering cost per replenishment Shortage cost per unit at buyer’s site Safety factor (decision variable) Expected lead time demand Standard deviation of demand during lead time Buyer’s reorder point, which is function of the safety factor k
It is assumed that the lead-time demand has a normal distribution. Therefore, for any given value of k, the reorder point s will be m + ksL (Silver et al. 1998), where ksL is the safety stock (SS).
3.1
Traditional Decision Making
In the traditional decision-making model, each SC member determines its authorized decision variables (k and Q1 for buyer and Q2 for supplier) by considering its own cost function such that it minimizes its own costs, regardless of other chain members. In this situation, each SC member should solve a traditional singlelocation inventory problem. In their textbook example of a single-location inventory model, Silver et al. (1998) calculate the optimized buyer’s order quantity and reorder point simultaneously. The expected buyer’s annual cost function, including expected annual ordering, holding and shortage costs, is calculated as follows: ðk; Q1 Þ ¼ A1 D=Q1 þ h1 ð0:5Q1 þ ksL Þ þ ðBDGu ðkÞsL Þ=Q1 TCTraditional 1
(1)
where Gu(k) is defined as: 1 ð
Gu ðkÞ ¼ k
1 u2 ðu kÞ pffiffiffiffiffiffi e 2 du 2p
(2)
410
S.K. Chaharsooghi and J. Heydari
The expected shortages per replenishment cycle are represented by Gu ðkÞsL . The buyer’s expected annual shortage costs can be calculated by multiplying the expected shortages per replenishment cycle by the expected number of replenishments per year, D/Q1, and the unit shortage cost B. Silver et al. (1998) propose an iterative procedure to find the optimum value of k and Q1 simultaneously. Meanwhile, the supplier solves its inventory problems by itself. As mentioned earlier, it has been proven that supplier cost will be minimized when Q2 is an integer multiple of Q1. The supplier expected annual-cost function, including expected annual ordering and holding costs, is: ðnÞ ¼ A2 D=ðnQ1 Þ þ 0:5h2 ðn 1ÞQ1 TCTraditional 2
(3)
In the real world, due to changing market behavior, the upstream members do not hold high inventory levels. It is assumed the supplier’s order quantity nQ1 should not exceed 1 year of customer demand, except in special cases (where Q1 is greater than D, in which case n is set at 1). Therefore, if D/Q1 is smaller than one then n ¼ 1; otherwise, the optimal value of n can be obtained by evaluating the integers in the interval [1, D/Q1]. In the traditional decision-making mode, buyer and supplier each make their decisions independently based on their own expected cost functions, i.e., (1) and (3), respectively.
3.2
Centralized Decision Making
In the centralized decision-making mode, there is one SC manager who controls all the businesses in the chain and makes decisions on Q1, k, and n based on the expected total profitability of the SC. The solution thus determined (i.e., the optimal values of the decision variables in the centralized mode) the globally optimum solution. The expected annual cost function (TC) for the whole chain is the sum of buyer and supplier expected cost functions (1) and (3): TCðk; Q1 ; nÞ ¼ ½nA1 þ A2 þ nBGu ðkÞsL D=ðnQ1 Þ þ 0:5½h1 þ ðn 1Þh2 Q1 þ h1 ksL
(4)
Considering the fact that the sum of convex functions must also be convex, to prove the convexity of TC with respect to Q1 and k, it is sufficient to prove the and TCTraditional . In the literature, it has been noted that convexity of TCTraditional 1 2 Traditional is a convex function of Q1 and k (Silver et al. 1998, p. 326). Also, TC1 is not a function of k and, therefore, this is sufficient to prove it is a TCTraditional 2 convex function of Q1. Because @ 2 TCTraditional =@Q21 ¼ 2A2 D=ðnQ31 Þ > 0, TCTraditional 2 2 is a convex function with respect to Q1 and k. Hence, TC is also a convex function with respect to Q1 and k.
Supply Chain Coordination Under Demand Uncertainty Using Credit Option
411
Using the first-order condition, the following equations are obtained: Q1 ¼ ½2DðnA1 þ A2 þ nBGu ðkÞsL Þ=ðn½h1 þ h2 ðn 1ÞÞ1=2 Fu ðkÞ ¼
1 ð
k
1 h1 Q 1 u2 pffiffiffiffiffiffi :e 2 :du ¼ DB 2p
(5)
(6)
where Fu ðkÞ is the probability that a standard normal variable u takes on a value of k or larger or, correspondingly, the probability of a stock-out within the replenishment lead time. Also, similarly to the traditional decision-making mode, it is assumed that a supplier’s order quantity nQ1 should not exceed 1 year of customer demand except in special cases where Q1 > D. An iterative procedure that converges to the optimal solution is proposed as follows. Initialization: Set n as low as possible (n ¼ 1). Step 0: Set Gu ðkÞ ¼ 0. Step 1: Calculate Q1 using (5). Step 2: Calculate k using (6). Step 3: Repeat steps 1 and 2 iteratively until Q1 and k converge (the difference between two successive values reaches a sufficiently small value) then calculate TC using (4). Step 4: If n bD=Q1 c, then n ¼ n þ 1; go to Step 0. Step 5: Each combination of s, Q1, and n that results in a lower value of TC is the optimal solution (the obtained optimal values are denoted by the superscript “*”). In this procedure, the previous simpler procedure proposed by Silver et al. (1998) (corresponding to steps 0–3 of the proposed procedure) constitutes the middle of the newly proposed procedure. Due to the convex nature of the functions involved, convergence of the above procedure is ensured. Using the proposed procedure, the optimal values of decision variables will be obtained. The target point of the coordination model is to achieve this operational plan with a decentralized chain structure. To achieve channel coordination, the final values of the decision variables resulting from the coordination model must be equal to those of the centralized decision-making model. Indeed, coordination mechanisms should serve to create sufficient incentive for chain members to set their decision variables equal to the values obtained in the centralized model.
3.3
Coordinated Decision Making
Coordination mechanisms aim to encourage members to make decisions that are in line with those of the centralized SC, i.e., those of the globally optimum solution.
412
S.K. Chaharsooghi and J. Heydari
In most cases, when the SC has a decentralized structure, setting the decision variables to optimal centralized values incurs losses for some members. In these cases, using an incentive scheme to fairly share the benefits of a coordination model is vital. At best, a coordination mechanism can increase SC profitability up to that of the centralized decision-making model; this is called channel coordination. Channel coordination is achieved if the expected total SC costs in the coordinated model are reduced to the centralized SC costs. Also, the coordination mechanism should be desirable for all members (Giannoccaro and Pontrandolfo 2004) to ensure that the model is applied. A model is desirable for a member when the application of the model does not reduce the member’s profit to less than that before applying the model. In this chapter, to coordinate both order quantity and reorder point simultaneously, a coordination mechanism based on a credit option is proposed. In this model, the buyer can take advantage of a payment delay subject to commitment to the jointly determined values of the decision variables. Based on the proposed model, the buyer must change its operational decisions regarding s and Q1 from its local optimum to the global optimum to access the benefit of delayed payment for purchased goods proposed by the supplier. Inventory holding cost is associated with cost factors such as leasing the warehouse space, staffing wages, overhead costs, and capital invested in stock. Although the cost of holding inventory is not fully due to capital invested in stock, this capital comprises the majority of inventory holding costs. The use of credit reduces the buyer’s inventory holding costs because it reduces the amount of capital invested in stock for the duration of the credit period (Huang et al. 2010a; Teng et al. 2005). Also, using a credit option has several other advantages for the buyer exploiting delayed payment which are not considered in this study; for instance, a credit user can accumulate sales revenue and earn interest by investing in external projects or depositing the earnings in an interest-bearing account during the credit period (Hu and Liu 2010; Chung et al. 2005). From the SC-coordination perspective, a credit option can convince the buyer to commit to the jointly agreed-upon replenishment rules by decreasing its inventory costs. By comparing the previously investigated traditional and centralized decisionmaking structures, it is possible to extract the operational coefficients for both buyer and supplier. By applying these operational coefficients to the local optimal solution (the values of the decision variables obtained in the traditional model), each party can extract the globally optimum solution. The buyer’s order-quantity coordinator coefficient can be defined as KQ ¼ Q1 =Q1 , where Q1 is the globally optimum value of the buyer’s order quantity that is obtained from the centralized decision-making model and Q1 is the local optimal value of the buyer’s order quantity calculated from the traditional decision-making model. Similarly, the buyer’s safety-factor coordinator coefficient is defined as Kk ¼ k =k and the supplier’s coordinator coefficient for the decision variable n is defined as Kn ¼ n =n. However, applying these defined coordinator coefficients is not possible without necessary arrangements. In fact, by applying the above coefficients, the buyer will
Supply Chain Coordination Under Demand Uncertainty Using Credit Option
413
lose due to deviation from its local optimum. To compensate for the incurred losses, the supplier proposes that the buyer purchases on credit. As mentioned earlier, using credit has several advantages for the buyer; their most important is reducing the expected inventory holding costs. As the majority of inventory holding cost is related to the capital invested in stock, this cost will be imposed only when the payment is cleared; therefore, delayed payment can reduce inventory holding costs. The portion of expected inventory holding costs due to capital invested in stock differs among various industries. For the model be applicable across different industries, we define this portion as a parameter in the proposed model. It is considered that b% of the expected inventory holding cost is related to the capital invested in stock and, therefore, the credit option can compensate these costs for the buyer in the Credit period (CP). From the mathematical point of view, during the credit period the buyer’s expected annual inventory holding costs are reduced by the coefficient (100 b)%. Figure 1 shows the buyer’s reduced inventory holding costs associated with the capital invested in stock after applying the credit option. Several replenishment cycles for both the buyer and supplier and their inventory positions by assuming n ¼ 3 are illustrated in Fig. 1. As shown here, the buyer places an order of size Q1 with the supplier when its inventory position drops to the Buyer Inventory Position
s µ
Q1
Q1
LT
LT
Q1
Q1
LT
LT
LT
Q1
SS=k.σL
CP
Supplier Inventory Position
CP
CP
First batch delivery
CP
Third batch delivery
Second batch delivery
CP
Time
Fifth batch delivery
Fourth batch delivery
Q1
Q1
2Q1
2Q1
Q1
Settle the bill for first batch Shipping first batch
Settle the bill for second batch
Shipping second batch
Q1
Settle the bill for third batch
Shipping third batch
Settle the bill for fourth batch
Shipping fourth batch
Settle the bill for fifth batch
Shipping fifth batch
Time
Shipping sixth batch
Fig. 1 Inventory positions for the buyer (top) and supplier (bottom) and sequence of events in several replenishment cycles
414
S.K. Chaharsooghi and J. Heydari
reorder point s. The placed order is received just after the stochastic lead time LT. Due to the stochastic nature of lead time demand, a shortage may occur. After receiving a placed order, the waiting customers and new customers are served from the recently arrived batch of product (Q1) and revenue is earned. Without the credit option, the buyer must settle the bill at the time of receipt of each order. In the case where a credit option is proposed by the supplier, the buyer settles the payment at the end of the credit period CP. The amount of capital invested in stock for each unit of inventory during the credit period is zero. As b% of the inventory holding cost is associated with capital invested in stock, the cost of holding each unit during the credit period will be reduced. In Fig. 1, the area under the curve is divided into two parts. The hatched area represents the credit duration. In other words, at the beginning of each solid area in Fig. 1, the buyer pays the supplier for the previously delivered batch, CP time units ago. During the CP, the buyer earns revenue from selling the goods which have not yet been paid for. The inventory holding costs in the hatched area of Fig. 1 are reduced by the coefficient (100 b)% with respect to the solid area. Thus, the credit-option contract reduces the buyer’s inventory holding costs during the credit period. If this cost reduction compensates for the increased cost of changing from traditional to centralized decision making, then the buyer will participate. A longer credit period means a greater reduction in the buyer’s expected costs. From the buyer’s perspective, extending credit period is more advantageous. There is a lower bound for credit period, below which the participation is not beneficial for the buyer (when the extra savings from the delay in payment is less than extra cost imposed by accepting the centralized solution). Conversely, adjusting the credit period as low as reasonably possible is more beneficial for the supplier. In the credit period, payment has been not made to the supplier for product sold. Due to the time value of money, delaying the payments only up to a certain period is economical for the supplier. Therefore, from the supplier perspective, there is an upper bound for the credit period; when the delay time exceeds this upper bound, the participation will not be advantageous for the supplier. Figure 2, shows the concept of credit time interval and the preferences of both parties. As shown in Fig. 2, if the credit period becomes very low, the buyer will lose and will not participate, whereas if the credit period becomes very high the supplier will lose. Thus, there is an interval for the credit period between these lower and upper bounds; the appropriate CP lies within it. The bargaining power of members with
Low
Credit Period
High
Fig. 2 The interest of two parties in adjusting the credit period, CP
Supply Chain Coordination Under Demand Uncertainty Using Credit Option
415
each other is the measure for adjusting the coordinator variable CP. As all the inventory-system variables are determined for traditional and coordinated models, the only remaining decision variable is coordinator variable CP. Hereinafter, the Q1, k, and n denote locally optimal values of the decision variables in the traditional model and Q1 , k*, and n* denote globally optimal values of the decision variables in the centralized model, which are absolutely determined and known.
3.3.1
Condition for Buyer to Participate (Lower Bound for Credit Period)
In proposing the credit option to the buyer, the supplier intends to share the earned profits. In fact, the use of credit transfers part of the inventory costs to the supplier and therefore leads to a reduction in the buyer’s expected costs. As mentioned earlier, the buyer’s expected costs consist of three parts: expected ordering, holding inventory, and shortage costs. Using credit affects the second part; i.e., inventory holding costs. As in the traditional inventory model, it is possible to calculate the expected holding inventory costs before applying the credit option by calculating the area under the buyer’s inventory-level curve, which is ðQ1 =2Þ þ k:sL , where the first term is the average cycle inventory and the second term is the safety stock level. By applying the unit inventory-holding costs h1 to the derived value, the buyer’s expected annual inventory holding costs are calculated [see (1)]. To calculate the buyer’s expected annual inventory holding costs after applying the credit option, it is necessary to calculate the area under the buyer’s inventory-level curve based on Fig. 1. The hatched area in Fig. 1 is affected by the coefficient (1 b) while the solid area is not. As a result, the expected annual inventory holding costs will be: Inventory holding costs n ¼ h1 ðKQ Q1 DðCPÞÞ2 =2KQ Q1 þ ð1 bÞðCPÞðD D2 ðCPÞ=2KQ Q1 ÞðCPÞ þKk ksL ð1 bDðCPÞ=KQ Q1 Þ As can be seen in the above equation, the coordinator coefficients KQ and Kk are applied to the variables Q1 and k, respectively; note that Q1 and k in the above relation refer to the optimal values obtained from the traditional model. Finally, the buyer’s expected annual cost function after applying the credit option can be expressed as follows: TCCoordinated ðCPÞ 1
" D ðKQ Q1 DðCPÞÞ2 D2 ðCPÞ þ h1 þ ð1 bÞðD ÞðCPÞ ¼ A1 2KQ Q1 K Q Q1 2KQ Q1 D D þKk ksL ð1 bCP Þ þ ðBGu ðKk kÞsL Þ K Q Q1 KQ Q 1
(7)
416
S.K. Chaharsooghi and J. Heydari
where the three terms denote the expected ordering cost, the expected inventory holding cost and the expected shortage cost, respectively. In the cost function (7), the buyer agrees to apply the coordinator coefficients KQ and Kk to the local optimum values of Q1 and k; in turn, the supplier accepts the delay in payments according to the credit period (delay period) CP. The only decision variable in (7) is CP. The buyer participates (i.e., applies the coordinator coefficients in the case of using credit) if and only if buyer costs do not rise after participation. In mathematical terms, TC after participation (7) must be smaller than the buyer’s expected cost in the traditional model (1). By comparing the buyer’s expected cost functions before and after the credit-option contract, a lower bound for CP can be calculated. Proposition 1. The minimum credit period that convinces the buyer to participate is: CPmin
1 ¼ ðKQ Q1 þ Kk ksL Þ D
rffiffiffiffiffiffiffi 2W D2
(8)
where W¼
ðKQ Q1 þ Kk ksL Þ2 1 h A1 Dð1 KQ Þ þ BDsL ½Gu ðKk kÞ Gu ðkÞKQ : 2 bh1 i Q1 2 ðKQ 1Þ þ h1 KQ kQ1 sL ðKk 1Þ (9) þh1 KQ 2
Proof. Set TCTraditional ðk; Q1 Þ TCCoordinated ðCPÞ; by simple mathematical opera1 1 tions it is verified that this inequality will be satisfied if and only if pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi CP D1 ðKQ Q1 þ Kk ksL Þ 2W=D2 . The right side of the resulting expression gives CPmin, which is the lowest value for the CP that encourages the buyer to participate. In fact, when CP is adjusted to CPmin, the expected total cost for the buyer after accepting the coordinator coefficients KQ and Kk is then equal to the expected total cost for buyer before accepting the coordination. If CP is adjusted to a value less than CPmin, the total cost imposed on the buyer after accepting the coordinator coefficients will then be greater than the traditional-model costs, and the buyer will therefore not participate in the plan.
3.3.2
Condition for Supplier to Participate (Upper Bound for Credit Period)
The supplier is the proposer of the credit option to the buyer. If the offer leads to disadvantages for the supplier, it will basically never occur. In this section, the costs imposed on the supplier by proposing credit are calculated and compared to the costs saved from the coordination model. When the supplier’s earned value is
Supply Chain Coordination Under Demand Uncertainty Using Credit Option
417
greater than the cost of convincing the buyer, supplier participation is then guaranteed. The difference between the supplier’s expected cost function in the coordinated and traditional models indicates the earned value of the supplier in moving from the traditional to coordinated model. In the coordinated model, in addition to the expected ordering and holding costs, the supplier is faced with another cost factor: the cost of convincing the buyer. The buyer’s convincing cost is related to the time value of money. The supplier receives payment CP units of time later; thus, with a known interest rate, it is easy to calculate this cost. Also note that all the costs by the supplier for convincing the buyer are delivered by the buyer; therefore, another simple method for calculating the convincing cost is the calculation of the hatched area in Fig. 1 over 1 year multiplied by the imposed cost coefficient bh1. Finally, the supplier’s expected annual cost function after proposing the credit option is: TCCoordinated ðCPÞ ¼ A2 D=ðKn KQ nQ1 Þ þ 0:5h2 KQ Q1 ðKn n 1Þ 2 þ bh1 DðCPÞ KQ Q1 0:5DðCPÞ þ Kk ksL =KQ Q1
(10)
where the first term is the expected ordering costs, the second term is the expected inventory holding costs and the third term is the expected cost of convincing the buyer. The supplier participates in the plan if and only if its cost after participation (10) is smaller than the cost before participation (3). By comparing the supplier’s expected cost functions before and after the credit-option contract, the following proposition establishes an upper bound for CP. Proposition 2. The maximum allowable credit period which is acceptable for the supplier is: CPmax
1 ¼ ðKQ Q1 þ Kk ksL Þ D
rffiffiffiffiffiffiffi 2M D2
(11)
where M¼
2DA2 ð1 KQ Kn Þ þ h2 KQ Kn nQ1 2 ð1 KQ n½1 Kn KQ Þ 2Kn nbh1 þ 0:5ðKQ Q1 þ Kk ksL Þ2
(12)
Proof. Set TCTraditional ðnÞ TCCoordinated ðCPÞ; by simple mathematical operations 2 2 it is verified that this inequality will be satisfied if and only if CP D1 ðKQ Q1 þ pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi Kk ksL Þ 2M=D2 . The right side of the achieved expression gives CPmax, the highest value for the CP that is acceptable for the supplier. When CP is adjusted to CPmax, the expected total cost to the supplier after proposing the credit option is then equal to its expected total cost in the traditional model. If the CP is adjusted to higher than CPmax, the total cost imposed on the supplier by proposing the credit option will be greater than in the traditional model, and the supplier will therefore refuse to participate.
418
3.3.3
S.K. Chaharsooghi and J. Heydari
Equitable Credit Period
Channel coordination will be achieved by setting the credit period to a value between CPmin and CPmax. If CP is set to CPmin, then all the benefits are acquired by the supplier. In fact by setting CP ¼ CPmin, the buyer’s expected cost after coordination will be equal to the buyer’s expected cost in the traditional model. In this state, there is no change in profitability for the buyer by accepting the plan, and all the advantages are therefore gained by the supplier. Indeed, by setting the CP to CPmin, the buyer’s profitability will merely not be reduced. Conversely, if CP is set to CPmax, then all the benefits are gained by the buyer. The interval [CPmin, CPmax] is a continuous interval and therefore in selecting the credit period from this interval there are infinite options. But what point must be selected? Or, similarly, what is the criterion for setting CP? The answer to these questions is related to the power of each member versus the other. Recalling Fig. 2, the member with more power can set the CP. In the business environment this power is called “bargaining power”. The bargaining power is defined as the total advantage which one can obtain in a negotiation. In this section, the coordinator variable CP is determined based on the bargaining power of SC members. In this way, the share of benefits obtained by each member will be fairly distributed. We define a as the bargaining power of the buyer versus the supplier and therefore (1 a) is the bargaining power of the supplier versus the buyer. It is clear that a is between 0 and 1. By increasing the value of a to near 1, the bargaining power of the buyer increases. As a result, by increasing a, the expected earnings of the buyer are increased and vice versa. To calculate the credit period, it is necessary to calculate the extra earnings resulting from applying the proposed coordination model and share them between the two parties by adjusting the CP. The extra profit by applying the coordination scheme is: DTC ¼ TCðk; Q1 ; nÞ TCðk ; Q1 ; n Þ ¼ ½nA1 þ A2 þ nBGu ðkÞsL D=ðnQ1 Þ þ 0:5½h1 þ ðn 1Þh2 Q1 þ h1 ksL ½Kn nA1 þ A2 þ Kn nBGu ðKk kÞsL D=ðKn nKQ Q1 Þ 0:5½h1 þ ðKn n 1Þh2 KQ Q1 h1 Kk ksL
(13)
where Q1, k, and n are the (locally) optimal values of the decision variables in the traditional decision-making model, and Q1 , k*, n* are the optimal values of the decision variables in the centralized model, which are created by applying the coordinator coefficients KQ, Kk, and Kn, respectively, to the local optimum values. a According to the buyer–supplier bargaining power relationship, ðaþð1aÞÞ 100% of DTC should be obtained by the buyer and rest is retained by the supplier. From the mathematical point of view, the buyer’s expected cost after coordination must be smaller than the buyer’s expected cost in traditional mode by of the factor aDTC.
Supply Chain Coordination Under Demand Uncertainty Using Credit Option
TCTraditional ðk; Q1 Þ TCCoordinated ðk ; Q1 ; CPÞ ¼ aDTC 1 1
419
(14)
By substituting (1) and (7) into (14), the exact value of CP based on the buyer’s bargaining power a is found as follows: sffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi# " 1 KQ Q1 aDTC Þ ðKQ Q1 þ Kk ksL Þ 2ðW CP ¼ D bh1
(15)
The channel coordination is achievable, If one value from (15) is obtained within the interval [CPmin, CPmax]. By applying the calculated CP, the supplier’s share of ð1aÞ the extra benefits will be ðaþð1aÞÞ 100%.
4 Numerical Experiments In this section, the performance of the introduced coordination scheme is measured by conducting a set of numerical examples. Also, the effect of uncertainties on the coordination model is examined by testing the model with various degrees of uncertainty. Table 1 shows the data set for the numerical experiments. After running the three models (traditional, centralized and coordinated) based on the Table 1 data set, the results shown in Table 2 were obtained. As shown in Table 2, the TC resulting from the coordinated decision-making model is equal to that of the centralized model. Therefore, the proposed coordination model can achieve channel coordination. Also, applying the model is desirable for both members due to the reduction of expected costs for each member with respect to the traditional model. By shifting from traditional to centralized decision making, the expected total SC cost can be reduced from the 885.89 to 814.03, an ~8.1% improvement. Nevertheless, this shift is not applicable due to the increase in the buyer’s expected costs (from 561.95 to 607.37). The credit-option scheme resolves this problem by fairly sharing the acquired benefits between members. As shown in Table 2, in the coordinated model, both members’ costs are reduced with respect to the traditional model and the total expected cost of the SC is also equal to the centralized model. The trend of the changes in the decision variables and the performance criteria were also tracked by increasing the uncertainty. The standard deviation of the leadtime demand (LTD) is the measure of uncertainty, and we can call it the degree of uncertainty. Figure 3 shows the total SC cost improvement resulting from the coordinated model with respect to traditional decision making with various degrees of uncertainty. As shown in Fig. 3, the proposed model can create an appropriate cost saving for an SC greater than 5% with all degrees of uncertainty. This improvement in total SC cost shows the ability of the coordination model for adjusting the decision
420
S.K. Chaharsooghi and J. Heydari
Table 1 Numerical experiment data
Table 2 The results of running the numerical examples
Parameters D h1 h2 B A1 A2 m sL a b
Traditional decision making Decision variables Q1 123.48 s 77 n 1 CP (day) N/A
Performance criteria 561.95 TC1 TC2 323.94 TC 885.89
Values 500 4 3 5 50 80 80 20 0.6 0.4
Centralized Coordinated decision making decision making 193.57 69.93 1 N/A
193.57 69.93 1 CPmin ¼ 21.24 CPmax ¼ 65.22 CP ¼ 45.35
607.39 206.64 814.03
518.84 295.19 814.03
12
% Improvement
10 8 6 4 2 0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 LTD standard deviation
Fig. 3 SC cost improvement of coordinated decision making compared to the traditional model
Supply Chain Coordination Under Demand Uncertainty Using Credit Option
421
200 Q1-Traditional
180
Q1-Coordinated Product unit
160
s-Traditional s-Coordinated
140 120 100 80 60
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 LTD standard deviation
Fig. 4 Coordinated buyer’s order quantity and reorder point versus traditional buyer’s order quantity and reorder point
variables. The proposed credit option encourages the buyer to decide on the variables Q1 and s jointly. Thus, the globally optimum solution can be achieved. Figure 4 illustrates the values of the buyer’s order quantity and reorder point before and after implementing the credit option. As shown here, the proposed model adjusts the buyer’s order quantity to a point higher than in traditional decision making while the reorder point is adjusted to less than in the traditional model. Note that in Fig. 4 the coordinated Q1 and s are equal to Q1 and s in centralized decision making. Figure 5 shows the buyer’s expected costs with the various degrees of uncertainty. As shown by the buyer’s expected cost curve, the cost in the coordinated model is lower than traditional and centralized models. As shown in Fig. 5, without conducting the credit option, the buyer’s expected cost increases (in going from the centralized to traditional model) and the buyer declines to participate. In fact, in coordinated decision making the buyer takes advantage of the delay in payment and therefore its cost is reduced compared to the centralized decision-making structure. Because the buyer suffers the uncertainties, as uncertainty increases the buyer’s expected costs also increase but the efficiency of the coordination model is not affected; i.e., channel coordination is achieved in all cases. Figure 6 shows the changes in the supplier’s expected costs versus the degree of uncertainty; also illustrated is a comparison between the three decision-making models from the supplier’s cost viewpoint. As shown here, the supplier’s expected cost increases in the coordinated model with respect to centralized decision making. The main cause of this increase is the proposal of the credit option to the buyer. Although the supplier’s expected cost in the coordinated model is greater than in the centralized model, it is always less than in the traditional model (see Fig. 6); therefore, the participation of the supplier is assured.
422
S.K. Chaharsooghi and J. Heydari 700 Traditional 650
Centralized Coordinated
Buyer's cost
600 550 500 450 400
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 LTD standard deviation
Fig. 5 Buyer’s expected costs versus degree of uncertainty (comparison between traditional, centralized and coordinated decision making)
400
350
Supplier's cost
300
250
200 Traditional 150
Centralized Coordinated
100
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 LTD standard deviation
Fig. 6 Supplier’s expected costs versus degree of uncertainty (comparison between traditional, centralized and coordinated decision making)
The change in the coordinator variable CP versus the degree of uncertainty is illustrated in Fig. 7. The credit period is reduced by increasing uncertainty. In summary, by increasing uncertainty, the expected costs of the supply chain will increase, but the proposed coordination model can reduce the cost as much as possible, and channel coordination is achievable by applying the model.
Supply Chain Coordination Under Demand Uncertainty Using Credit Option
423
100 CP-min
90
CPmax
Credit Period (day)
80
Fair CP
70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30
LTD standard deviation
Fig. 7 Credit periods with different degrees of uncertainty.
5 Concluding Remarks Supply chain coordination has two main aspects (1) what decisions need to be coordinated, and (2) how to coordinate them. In this chapter, a scheme based on a credit option for the simultaneous coordination of order quantity and reorder point in a two-stage SC under uncertainty was introduced. The presented scheme has the ability to achieve channel coordination. In this scheme, the buyer can use the advantage of delayed payment that is subject to commitment to the globally optimum decisions. Using a credit option, the supplier shares the extra benefits with the buyer. Surplus sharing is fairly distributed based on the members’ bargaining power. This study indicates that the simultaneous coordination of order quantity and reorder point is advantageous and the credit option can be used as a coordination scheme in achieving such advantages under demand uncertainty. The experimental results indicate the model effectiveness (achieving channel coordination) and suitability (dividing the benefits fairly). In addition, the numerical experiments show the advantages of the proposed model with various degrees of demand uncertainty. Although the credit option, or delay in payments, is a well-known mechanism both in financing and operations-management literature, its application under uncertainty has rarely been examined. This study shows the capability of the credit option as a supply chain coordination scheme under demand uncertainty. Compared to the existing literature in the field of SC coordination under uncertainty, this study can be viewed as an opening statement toward implementing the credit option as an SC-coordination scheme under uncertainty which is capable of aligning the objectives of the SC members with the supply chain goal. In comparison with the
424
S.K. Chaharsooghi and J. Heydari
existing studies on the use of credit option in deterministic settings, this study enlarges the application area of credit option toward stochastic environments. The main limitation of the proposed model regards the structure of the investigated SC. The model is limited to a one-buyer, one-supplier configuration. The proposed model can be extended in future work by considering more SC tiers and a networked SC structure. In addition, all developments of the basic creditoption model in the deterministic environment, considering factors such as inflation, partial credit, and deteriorating products, can be investigated in future work.
References Arshinder K, Kanda A, Deshmukh SG (2008) Supply chain coordination: perspectives, empirical studies and research directions. Int J Prod Econ 115:316–335 Cachon GP (2003) Supply chain coordination with contract. In: Graves S, de Kok T (eds) Handbooks in operations research and management science. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 229–340 Chaharsooghi SK, Heydari J (2010a) Optimum coverage of uncertainties in a supply chain with an order size constraint. Int J Adv Manuf Technol 47:283–293 Chaharsooghi SK, Heydari J (2010b) Supply chain coordination for the joint determination of order quantity and reorder point using credit option. Eur J Oper Res 204(1):86–95 Chang CT, Wu SJ, Chen LC (2009) Optimal payment time with deteriorating items under inflation and permissible delay in payments. Int J Syst Sci 40(10):985–993 Chauhan SS, Proth JM (2005) Analysis of a supply chain partnership with revenue sharing. Int J Prod Econ 97(1):44–51 Chen LH, Kang FS (2007) Integrated vendor–buyer cooperative inventory models with variant permissible delay in payments. Eur J Oper Res 183:658–673 Chen K, Xiao T (2009) Demand disruption and coordination of the supply chain with a dominant retailer. Eur J Oper Res 197:225–234 Chen H, Chen Y, Chiu CH, Choi TM, Sethi S (2010) Coordination mechanism for the supply chain with lead time consideration and price-dependent demand. Eur J Oper Res 203:70–80 Choi TM, Li D, Yan H (2004) Optimal returns policy for supply chain with e-marketplace. Int J Prod Econ 88:205–227 Chung KJ, Huang CK (2009) An ordering policy with allowable shortage and permissible delay in payments. Appl Math Model 33:2518–2525 Chung KJ, Goyal SK, Huang YF (2005) The optimal inventory policies under permissible delay in payments depending on the ordering quantity. Int J Prod Econ 95:203–213 Ding D, Chen J (2008) Coordinating a three level supply chain with flexible return policies. Omega 36(5):865–876 Giannoccaro I, Pontrandolfo P (2004) Supply chain coordination by revenue sharing contracts. Int J Prod Econ 89:131–139 Gupta A, Maranas CD (2003) Managing demand uncertainty in supply chain planning. Comput Chem Eng 27:1219–1227 Hou J, Zeng AZ, Zhao L (2009) Achieving better coordination through revenue sharing and bargaining in a two-stage supply chain. Comput Ind Eng 57(1):383–394 Hu F, Liu D (2010) Optimal replenishment policy for the EPQ model with permissible delay in payments and allowable shortages. Appl Math Model 34:3108–3117 Huang YF (2007) Economic order quantity under conditionally permissible delay in payments. Eur J Oper Res 176:911–924 Huang CK (2010) An integrated inventory model under conditions of order processing cost reduction and permissible delay in payments. Appl Math Model 34:1352–1359
Supply Chain Coordination Under Demand Uncertainty Using Credit Option
425
Huang CK, Tsai DM, Wu JC, Chung KJ (2010a) An integrated vendor–buyer inventory model with order-processing cost reduction and permissible delay in payments. Eur J Oper Res 202:473–478 Huang CK, Tsai DM, Wu JC, Chung KJ (2010b) An optimal integrated vendor–buyer inventory policy under conditions of order-processing time reduction and permissible delay in payments. Int J Prod Econ 128(1):445–451. doi:10.1016/j.ijpe.2010.08.001 Jaber MY, Osman IH (2006) Coordinating a two-level supply chain with delay in payments and profit sharing. Comput Ind Eng 50(4):385–400 Jaber MY, Bonney M, Guiffrida AL (2010) Coordinating a three level supply chain with learningbased continuous improvement. Int J Prod Econ 127(1):27–38 Li J, Liu L (2006) Supply chain coordination with quantity discount policy. Int J Prod Econ 101(1):89–98 Li S, Zhu Z, Huang L (2009) Supply chain coordination and decision making under consignment contract with revenue sharing. Int J Prod Econ 120(1):88–99 Lin Z, Cai C, Xu B (2010) Supply chain coordination with insurance contract. Eur J Oper Res 205:339–345 Moses M, Seshadri S (2000) Policy mechanisms for supply chain coordination. IIE Trans 32(3):245–262 Munson CL, Rosenblatt MJ (2001) Coordinating a three-level supply chain with quantity discounts. IIE Trans 33(5):371–384 Rosenblatt MJ, Lee HL (1985) Improving profitability with quantity discounts under fixed demand. IIE Trans 17:388–395 Sarker BR, Jamal AMM, Wang S (2000) Supply chain models for perishable products under inflation and permissible delay in payment. Comput Oper Res 27(1):59–75 Sarmah SP, Acharya D, Goyal SK (2007) Coordination and profit sharing between a manufacturer and a buyer with target profit under credit option. Eur J Oper Res 182:1469–1478 Sarmah SP, Acharya D, Goyal SK (2008) Coordination of a single-manufacturer/multi-buyer supply chain with credit option. Int J Prod Econ 111:676–685 Shin H, Benton WC (2007) A quantity discount approach to supply chain coordination. Eur J Oper Res 180(2):601–616 Shinn SW, Hwang H (2003) Optimal pricing and ordering policies for retailers under order-sizedependent delay in payments. Comput Oper Res 30:35–50 Silver EA, Pyke DF, Peterson R (1998) Inventory management and production planning and scheduling, 3rd edn. Wiley, New York Teng JT, Chang CT, Goyal SK (2005) Optimal pricing and ordering policy under permissible delay in payments. Int J Prod Econ 97:121–129 Tsai JF (2007) An optimization approach for supply chain management models with quantity discount policy. Eur J Oper Res 177(2):982–994 Van der Rhee B, van der Veen JAA, Venugopal V, Nalla VR (2010) A new revenue sharing mechanism for coordinating multi-echelon supply chains. Oper Res Lett 38(4):296–301 Xiao T, Shi K, Yang D (2010) Coordination of a supply chain with consumer return under demand uncertainty. Int J Prod Econ 124(1):171–180 Xu K, Dong Y, Evers PT (2001) Towards better coordination of the supply chain. Transp Res E 37:35–54 Yao Z, Leung SCH, Lai KK (2008) Analysis of the impact of price- sensitivity factors on the returns policy in coordinating supply chain. Eur J Oper Res 187:275–282 Yue X, Raghunathan S (2007) The impacts of the full returns policy on a supply chain with information asymmetry. Eur J Oper Res 180:630–647 Zhou YW, Min J, Goyal SK (2008) Supply-chain coordination under an inventory-level-dependent demand rate. Int J Prod Econ 113:518–527
.
Supply Chain Coordination Under Consignment Contract with Revenue Sharing Sijie Li, Jia Shu, and Lindu Zhao
Abstract The balance of power between manufacturers and retailers is shifting, and consignment contract with revenue sharing has been widely applied in many industries, especially in on-line marketplaces. In this chapter we consider a supply chain with an upstream manufacturer and a downstream retailer where a singleperiod product is produced and sold. The manufacturer chooses the delivery quantity and the retail price, and the retailer sets the revenue shares. Utilizing Nash bargaining model, a cooperative game model is developed to implement profit sharing between the manufacturer and the retailer to achieve their cooperation. When the manufacturer and the retailer are assumed to be risk-neutral, under a very mild restriction on the demand distribution, the decentralized supply chain can be perfectly coordinated, and both players can earn more in the proposed cooperative setting. Furthermore, the impacts of supply chain system parameters on the optimal supply chain decisions and the supply chain performance are investigated in this chapter. Keywords Consignment contract with revenue game • Supply chain coordination • Uncertainty
sharing
•
Cooperative
S. Li (*) • L. Zhao Institute of Systems and Engineering, Southeast University, Nanjing, Jiangsu, People’s Republic of China e-mail: [email protected]; [email protected] J. Shu Department of Management Science and Engineering, School of Economics and Management, Southeast University, Nanjing, Jiangsu, People’s Republic of China e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_17, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
427
428
S. Li et al.
1 Introduction In the traditional supply chain and distribution channel, the upstream seller, acting as the leader, has the ownership and price control of goods, and the downstream buyer often acts as the follower. The leader-follower scheme essentially implies that the supply chain member as the leader is dominant in the supply chain and distribution channel. The “dominant” implies that a supply chain member has the power of controlling/influencing another member’s actions and decisions. However, in the current market-oriented economy, the balance of power between manufacturers and retailers is shifting in industries as diverse as pharmaceuticals, consumer packaged goods, hardware, apparel, and furniture (Kumar 1996). Porter (1974) has confirmed the existence of retailer power in consumer goods industries, and defined it as the ability of a retailer to influence a manufacturer’s product differentiation. The supply chain with dominant retailer in the context of marketing and distribution channels has arguably been more pronounced in many academic researches and empirical analyses (e.g., Hua and Li 2008; Lau et al. 2008; Chen and Xiao 2009; Li et al. 2010). Consignment contract with revenue sharing has been widely applied in various industries, such as rental (Dana and Spier 2001; Mortimer 2004), retailing and auction (Wang et al. 2004b; G€ um€ us¸ et al. 2008) and procurement of industrial materials (Cachon 2001; Cachon and Lariviere 2001; Gerchak and Wang 2004). It is essentially a real realization of the power shifting in supply chain channel, and especially popular in on-line marketplaces, such as Amazon.com, Alibaba.com, eBay.com, etc. Under such a contract, ownership of the goods is retained by the supplier and price is also usually determined solely by the supplier. For each item sold, the retailer will deduct an agreed percentage from the selling price, remit the balance to the vendor and no money changes hands until the item is sold (Bolen 1978). Under the consignment contract with revenue sharing, the downstream retailer has more market power and acts as the leader in the supply chain channel, which means that the retailer is dominant over the supplier. In this chapter, we investigate the supply chain decisions and coordination under the consignment contract with revenue sharing. The centralized and decentralized supply chain structures are generally involved in supply chain organizations (Giannoccaro and Pontrandolfo 2004). In the centralized structure, the supply chain operates on the basis of centrally made decisions. In the decentralized structure, each firm makes its own decisions, based on its own knowledge, almost regardless of the rest of the supply chain (Bose and Pekny 2000). The coordination mechanism is an important issue in designing a contract for a decentralized supply chain. Cachon (2003) defined supply chain coordination as follows: A contract is said to coordinate the supply chain if the set of supply chain optimal actions is a Nash equilibrium, i.e., no firm has a profitable unilateral deviation from the set of supply chain optimal actions. This definition is concentrated on the decentralized supply chain since a centralized supply chain is perfectly coordinated. For a decentralized supply chain, if the decisions result in supply chain channel profit
Supply Chain Coordination Under Consignment Contract with Revenue Sharing
429
that is equal to the total profit achieved in a centralized supply chain, the decentralized supply chain is called perfect coordination or channel coordination (Bernstein and Federgruen 2003; Cachon 2004; Wang et al. 2004b). Many researches have addressed the supply chain coordination problem for the consignment contract with revenue sharing. These researches demonstrated that the decentralized supply chain cannot be perfectly coordinated under the consignment contract with revenue sharing. Cachon and Lariviere (2001) analyzed contracts of vendor management inventory (VMI) with revenue sharing, in which the manufacturer facing an uncertain demand offers various contracts to a component supplier. They demonstrated that the decentralized system provides less capacity than the integrated system, which means that the supply chain is not perfectly coordinated. Cachon (2003) studied coordination in a supply chain with one supplier and one retailer, and several different contract types were shown to coordinate the supply chain, such as buy back contracts, revenue sharing contracts, quantity flexibility contracts, sales rebate contracts and quantity discount contracts. They did not consider the consignment contract, and the supply chain is coordinated by an adjusting parameter l, which can loosely be interpreted as the retailer’s share of the supply chain’s profit. Wang et al. (2004b) modeled the decision making of the two firms in a supply chain as a non-cooperative game, and showed that the decentralized channel profit is always lower than the centralized channel profit under the proposed consignment contract. Li and Liu (2008) presented a coordination decision policy, in which a price discount policy is developed to allocate the expected increased profits between two sides of the supply chain; however the decentralized supply chain cannot be perfectly coordinated. Furthermore, many researches also showed that the consignment contract cannot perfectly coordinate the decentralized supply chain (e.g., Dong and Xu 2002; Choi et al. 2004; Cachon 2004). There are also some researches on perfectly coordinating the decentralized supply chain. Cachon (2001) proposed an approach of fixed transfer payments from the supplier to the retailer. Gerchak and Wang (2004) suggested a twoparameter contract (revenue-sharing plus surplus-subsidy) for an assembly system with multiple suppliers and one manufacturer. These coordination mechanisms can be regarded as an implementation of channel profits sharing by a transfer payment. In this chapter, we consider a two-echelon supply chain with an upstream manufacturer and a downstream retailer under the consignment contract with revenue sharing, and two specific demand function forms: additive and multiplicative demand cases (Petruzzi and Dada 1999; Wang et al. 2004b). The manufacturer produces a single-period product at a constant marginal cost. He has only one chance at production before the start of the selling season and sells his products through the retailer. The retailer does not pay the manufacturer upon receipt of the items but shares the sales revenue on units sold. The market demand for the singleperiod product is assumed to be price sensitive and uncertain. In this supply chain setting, the manufacturer chooses the delivery quantity and the retail price to be sold in the market, and the retailer sets the revenue shares.
430
S. Li et al.
Utilizing Nash bargaining model (Nash 1950), we propose the cooperative game models to describe the relationship of payment bargaining between the manufacturer and the retailer and determine the optimal consignment contract with revenue sharing, i.e., the revenue sharing agreement attached with the equilibrium payment scheme. By the fair bargaining between the manufacturer and the retailer instead of adding the additional decision parameters or conditions, we explore the coordination mechanism for the decentralized supply chain under the consignment contract with revenue sharing. Compared with the existing researches on perfect coordination by Cachon (2001) and Gerchak and Wang (2004), the proposed coordination mechanism is more moderate and achievable by a Nash equilibrium contract. Following the measurement of the retailer’s dominance defined by Hua and Li (2008), we also investigate the retailer’s dominance in the two-echelon supply chain under the consignment contract with revenue sharing. Under a very mild restriction on the demand distribution function, we find that the cooperative game between the manufacturer and the retailer has unique Nash equilibrium solution, the manufacturer and the retailer can earn more by their cooperation and the decentralized supply chain is perfectly coordinated. By the theoretical and numerical analyses, we also explore supply chain system parameters (e.g., price-elasticity index, supply chain cost and demand uncertainty) how to affect the supply chain’s optimal decisions and the supply chain performance. This chapter is organized as follows. The assumptions and model are described in Sect. 2. In Sect. 3, the decisions of the centralized supply chain under the consignment contract with revenue sharing are characterized. The cooperative game models to coordinate the decentralized supply chain are provided in Sect. 4, and the impacts of supply chain system parameters on the supply chain performance are also discussed in this section. Detailed numerical results and managerial implications are contained in Sect. 5 and the last section concludes our work.
2 Model Assumptions and Descriptions We consider a two-echelon supply chain consisting of a risk-neutral manufacturer and a risk-neutral retailer, in which a single-period product is produced and sold in market with uncertain and price-sensitive (or price-dependent) demand. The price-sensitive demand is stochastic and can be modeled either in an additive or multiplicative fashion (Petruzzi and Dada 1999; Wang et al. 2004b). The manufacturer produces the single-period product at a constant marginal cost, and the product is sold at a retail price. The retailer incurs a constant cost at the retail stage. In economics and finance, marginal cost is the change in total cost that arises when the quantity produced changes by one unit, and it is typically increasing because of diminishing marginal productivity. Although the increasing marginal costs are common in the practical production deployment (Robert 1997; McAdams and Malone 2005), the constant marginal costs can appear, such as in the stage of
Supply Chain Coordination Under Consignment Contract with Revenue Sharing
431
proportional returns (Rowntree 1941). In literature, it is common that, without loss of generality, the marginal costs for both manufacturer and retailer are typically assumed to be constant (Lariviere and Porteus 2001; Li 2002; Wang et al. 2004b; Hua and Li 2008). Because the costs incurred by the manufacturer and the retailer are constant, the costs incurred by the manufacturer and the retailer can be regarded as a cost sharing agreement.
2.1
Notations and Assumptions
We first introduce the following notations and assumptions to develop the proposed model.
2.1.1
Notations
p D e f() F() h(x) g(x) cM cR c a q r y(p) z Pc(p,q) ðpc ; zc Þ Pd;M Pd;R Pe;M Pe;R
Product’s retail price per unit Price-sensitive demand, i.e., D(p) Random variable with a finite mean value of m and standard deviation value of s Probability density function (PDF) of e ¼ 1 FðÞ Cumulative distribution function (CDF) of e, FðÞ f(x)/[1 F(x)], the failure rate function of demand distribution ¼xh(x), the generalized failure rate function of demand distribution Manufacturer’s marginal production cost Retailer’s marginal cost at the retail stage for inventory handling, shelf-space usage, etc. cM + cR, the total supply chain cost per unit Retailer’s cost share that is incurred at the retail stage, and 1 a is manufacturer’s cost share that is incurred at the production stage Manufacturer’s production quantity for the single-period product Retailer’s revenue share for per unit sold Deterministic and decreasing function of p that captures the dependency between demand and price Stocking factor of inventory Total expected profit of supply chain for any chosen retail price p and production quantity q Supply chain decisions for the centralized supply chain Manufacturer’s expected profit functions in non-cooperative situation Retailer’s expected profit functions in non-cooperative situation Manufacturer’s expected profit functions in cooperative situation Retailer’s expected profit functions in cooperative situation
432
S. Li et al.
ðpd ; zd ; rd Þ ðpe ; ze ; re Þ
Supply chain decisions at non-cooperation Supply chain decisions at cooperation
We add superscript “ values.
2.1.2
*
” to the relative variables to represent their optimal
Assumptions
1. The price-sensitive demand D has the functional forms of D(p) ¼ y(p)e in the multiplicative demand case and D(p) ¼ y(p) + e in the additive demand case. 2. The random variable e is supported on [A, B] with B A 0. 3. F() is strictly increasing, differentiable on [A, B], and F(A) ¼ 0, F(B) ¼ 1 (i.e., there is always some demand in market). 4. y(p) takes the form of y(p) ¼ apb (a > 0, b > 1) in the multiplicative case, and takes the form of y(p) ¼ a bp (a > 0, b > 0) in the additive case. The representations of y(p) are common in the literature, with the former representing an iso-price-elastic demand curve and the later representing a linear demand curve (Lau and Lau 2003; Khouja and Robbins 2005; Hua et al. 2006); see Petruzzi and Dada (1999) for an excellent review and extensions. In the formulation of y(p) ¼ apb, the parameter b is the price-elasticity index of (expected) demand. The larger the value of b, the more sensitive the demand is to a change in price. If the price-elasticity index is greater than 1, then a product is defined as price elastic; if the price-elasticity index is 1 or less, then a product is defined as inelastic. We focus on price-elastic products by assuming b > 1. In the linear demand case, the demand function is quite different from the iso-priceelasticity and multiplicative model. For example, it does not preserve the isoprice-elasticity property. Its price-elasticity index of the (expected) demand is given by bp/(a bp + m). The parameter b here is an indicator of the price “sensitivity” of demand and is closely related to the price-elasticity index. Specifically, the price-elasticity index is increasing in b at any price p. So, one can consider the parameter b as a surrogate of the price-elasticity index. 5. At the end of the selling season, the unsold units bear no salvage value or disposal cost and the unsatisfied demand incurs no loss-of-goodwill cost (i.e., shortage penalty). For the single-period or short life-cycle products, the assumptions of zero salvage value or holding cost and zero loss-of-goodwill cost are appropriate reflections of reality (Goto et al. 2004; Wang et al. 2004a). 6. The demand distribution has the strictly increasing failure rate (IFR) property: h0 (x) > 0, i.e., dh(x)/dx > 0. The IFR assumption is not restrictive because it captures most common distributions, such as the normal, uniform, as well as the gamma and Weibull families, subject to parameter restrictions (Barlow and Proschan 1975). According to Lariviere and Porteus (2001), IGFR (increasing generalized failure rate) is implied by IFR condition (there are IGFR distributions that are not IFR).
Supply Chain Coordination Under Consignment Contract with Revenue Sharing
2.2
433
The Model
In a decentralized supply chain, the manufacturer produces the product and then sells it to consumers through the retailer under a consignment contract. The consignment contract with revenue sharing adopted by the firms in the supply chain is the outcome of a bargaining process. The manufacturer and the retailer agree to negotiate to make a contract, and both firms accept the shares of the channel profit dictated by the negotiation process, which is subject to individual rationality. Under the consignment contract with revenue sharing, the retailer offers the manufacturer a revenue sharing contract which stipulates the product sold, he keeps r share of the revenue for per unit sold, and remits the rest, i.e., 1 r, to the manufacturer. In the non-cooperative situation, the two firms follow a Stackelberg (i.e., leaderfollower) game: The retailer, acting as the leader, offers the manufacturer a take-itor-leave-it contract, which specifies the percentage allocation of sales revenue between herself and the manufacturer. The manufacturer, acting as a follower, chooses how many units of the product to produce and the retail price. The manufacturer accepts the contract as long as he can earn a positive profit. According to the research of Wang et al. (2004b), we have the optimal decisions in the non-cooperative situation, which is depicted in Table 1. Firms will have market power as buyers, typically, when they have a dominant position in the market, and they use this power to extract favorable prices, terms and/or conditions from suppliers. There is few definition and measurement on the retailer dominance. Loewenstein et al. (2005) investigated the conversational dominance in negotiation by experimental and statistical method. The conversational dominance is measured by three basic measures: deception (misrepresentation of preferences and capabilities), extreme offers (offers outside the range specified for an issue), and quantitative arguments. Dukes et al. (2006) measured the bargaining power by the parameter in the generalized Nash bargaining model to Table 1 The optimal decisions for decentralized supply chain at non-cooperation Demand Iso-price-elastic Linear Condition F is IGFR F is IFR z
Þ ¼ ðb 1Þ½zd Lðzd Þ Fðz d bzd
ð1 rd Þ½a þ zd Lðzd Þ ð1 aÞbc ð1 rd Þ½a þ zd Lðzd Þ þ ð1 aÞbc
ð1 aÞc a þ zd Lðzd Þ þ 2ð1 rd Þ 2b 2 1 þ Fðzd Þ 1 þ rd aðb 2Þ þ 1 þ 2a ð1 aÞ ð1 aÞ rd ¼ r 1 Fðzd Þ 1 rd ba 2 2ðr aÞ½1 þ Fðzd Þ þ d ¼0 Iðrd ; zd Þ Note: Iðrd ; zd Þ ¼ ð1 rd Þ½1 Fðzd Þ2 ð1 rd Þf ðzd Þ½a þ zd Lðzd Þ ð1 aÞbcf ðzd Þ; a < rd < 1 ð1 aÞbc=ða þ AÞ
p
pd ¼
bczd 1a ðb 1Þ½zd Lðzd Þ 1 rd
Fðzd Þ ¼ pd ¼
434
S. Li et al.
represent the manufacturer’s relative bargaining power. Canie¨ls and Gelderman (2007) observed the supplier dominance in the strategic quadrant of the Kraljic matrix, which is measured as the difference between supplier’s dependence and buyer’s dependence. In this chapter, we assume that the manufacturer and the retailer are devoted to pursue the long-range relationship, their bargaining and deal is repeated many times and both players must consider not only their short-term gains but also their longterm payoffs. Therefore, the expected profits are their suitable objectives in the business operations. The retailer’s dominance in a supply chain is defined as: d rm ¼
PR PM PR
ðif PR PM 0Þ;
(1)
in (1), drm denotes the retailer’s dominance over the manufacturer. PM and PR are the manufacturer’s and the retailer’s expected profits, respectively. The retailer’s dominance does not have a generalized description and definition in the existing researches, such as qualitative analysis and statistical hypothesis testing. The proposed measure of retailer’s dominance provides a clear and closed-form definition to describe the relative power or dominance between the manufacturer and the retailer. We employ cooperative game models in multiplicative and additive demand cases to show how to design an equilibrium contract and how to perfectly coordinate the decentralized supply chain through a cooperative bargaining process. The purpose of cooperation is to actually determine a channel profit allocation scheme between the manufacturer and the retailer. It should be noted that not all optimal profit sharing schemes are acceptable, neither the manufacturer nor the retailer would be willing to accept less profit at cooperation than at noncooperation. An optimal payment scheme ðPe;M ; Pe;R Þ at cooperation is called acceptable if DPe;M ¼ Pe;M Pd;M 0, and DPe;R ¼ Pe;R Pd;R 0, then the acceptable decision set Z can be defined as n o Z ¼ ðp; z; rÞjDPe;M ðp; z; rÞ ¼ Pe;M Pd;M 0; DPe;R ðp; z; rÞ ¼ Pe;R Pd;R 0 : (2) Equation (2) means that the optimal decisions ðpe ; ze ; re Þ belong to a point set, and the set of optimal decisions satisfies the individual rationality, which implies that both players earn more profits by their cooperation in the decentralized supply chain, i.e., DPe;M ðp; z; rÞ ¼ Pe;M Pd;M 0 and DPe;R ðp; z; rÞ ¼ Pe;R Pd;R 0. Suppose the manufacturer’s utility function of DPe;M is u1 ðÞ and the retailer’s utility function of DPe;R is u2 ðÞ. Then according to Nash bargaining model, the optimal bargaining payment scheme is obtained by solving the following problem: max u1 ðDPe;M Þ u2 ðDPe;R Þ:
ðp;z;rÞ2Z
(3)
Supply Chain Coordination Under Consignment Contract with Revenue Sharing
435
Based on the assumption that both the manufacturer and the retailer are riskneutral, the cooperative game model (3) can be formulized as max ðPe;M Pd;M ÞðPe;R Pd;R Þ:
ðp;z;rÞ2Z
(4)
We next study the manufacturer-retailer relationships and coordination decisions for the decentralized supply chain by conducting the proposed cooperative game model. We also investigate the impacts of demand uncertainty and supply chain cost share on the retailer’s dominance.
3 Decisions in Centralized Supply Chain We first characterize the optimal decision to the centralized supply chain, in which the retail price and the production quantity for the product are simultaneously chosen by a central decision-maker to maximize the total expected profit of supply chain, and this optimal decision has to be made before demand realization. For the single-period product problem, we have Pc ðp; qÞ ¼ cq þ pE½minfq; Dg:
3.1
(5)
The Iso-Price-Elastic Demand Case
For the iso-price-elastic demand model, DðpÞ ¼ yðpÞ e and yðpÞ ¼ apb , we then have Pc ðp; qÞ ¼ cq þ pE½minfq; yðpÞ eg:
(6)
Following Petruzzi and Dada (1999), we define z q=yðpÞ. This transformation of variables provides an alternative interpretation of the stocking decision: if z > e, then leftovers occur; if z < e, then shortages occur. Then, the problem of choosing a retail price p and a production quantity q is equivalent to choosing a retail price p and a stocking factor z, and (6) is equivalent to (7) Pc ðp; zÞ ¼ yðpÞfp½z LðzÞ czg; Rz where yðpÞ ¼ apb , and LðzÞ ¼ A ðz xÞf ðxÞdx. Wang et al. (2004b) provided the optimal decision ðpc ; zc Þ for the centralized supply chain with the iso-price-elastic demand: if F is IGFR, the centralized supply chain has unique optimal decision ðpc ; zc Þ, where zc is uniquely determined by Þ bczc c Þ ¼ ðb1Þ½zc Lðz ; pc ¼ ðb1Þ½z Lðz Fðz Þ : c bz c
c
c
436
3.2
S. Li et al.
The Linear Demand Case
For the linear demand model, DðpÞ ¼ yðpÞ þ e and yðpÞ ¼ a bp. Since p c, it is assumed that a bc þ A 0 to ensure the non-negative demand when the product is priced at cost, i.e., p ¼ c. By substituting DðpÞ ¼ yðpÞ þ e and yðpÞ ¼ a bp into (5), the expected profit function of the centralized supply chain can be written as Pc ðp; qÞ ¼ cq þ pE½minfq; yðpÞ þ eg:
(8)
As the iso-price-elastic demand model, z q yðpÞ is defined as the stocking factor, then (8) can be rewritten as Pc ðp; zÞ ¼ ðp cÞða bpÞ þ p½z LðzÞ cz:
(9)
The following theorem is about the optimal decision ðpc ; zc Þ to the iso-priceelastic demand case. Theorem 1. For any fixed z 2 ½A; B, if 2h2 ðzÞ þ dhðzÞ=dz > 0, the centralized supply chain has a unique optimal decision ðpc ; zc Þ, where zc is uniquely deteraþz Lðz Þbc
mined by Fðzc Þ ¼ aþzc Lðzc Þþbc , and pc ðzc Þ ¼ c
c
aþzc Lðzc Þþbc . 2b
Proof. For any fixed z 2 ½A; B, it follows from (9) that @Pc ðp; zÞ ¼ a þ bc 2bp þ ½z LðzÞ ¼ 0; @p and @Pc ðp; zÞ ¼ p½1 FðzÞ c ¼ 0: @z By solving the above equations, we can obtain the feasible solution ðpc ; zc Þ aþzc Lðzc Þbc and pc ðzc Þ ¼ bcþaþz2bc Lðzc Þ . satisfying Fðzc Þ ¼ aþz c Lðzc Þþbc c Lðzc Þbc We next prove that zc is the unique solution to Fðzc Þ ¼ aþz aþzc Lðzc Þþbc . Let GðzÞ ¼ ½a þ z LðzÞ½1 FðzÞ bc½1 þ FðzÞ, then we have dGðzÞ 1 FðzÞ ; ¼ f ðzÞ a þ z LðzÞ þ bc dz hðzÞ 0 d2 GðzÞ f ðzÞ dGðzÞ f ðzÞ dhðzÞ 2 ½1 FðzÞ 2h ¼ ðzÞ þ : þ 2 dz2 f ðzÞ dz h ðzÞ dz d2 GðzÞ > 0, then It is obvious that, if 2h2 ðzÞ þ dhðzÞ dz dz2 dGðzÞ=dz¼0 < 0, which implies that GðzÞ itself is a unimodal function.
Supply Chain Coordination Under Consignment Contract with Revenue Sharing
437
Therefore zc is the unique solution since GðzÞ is continuous on ½A; B, GðAÞ ¼ a þ A bc > 0 and GðBÞ ¼ 2bc < 0. It follows from (9) that @ 2 Pc ðp; zÞ ¼ 2b; @p2
@ 2 Pc ðp; zÞ ¼ pf ðzÞ and @z2
@ 2 Pc ðp; zÞ ¼ 1 FðzÞ: @z@p
We then have 2 2 @ 2 Pc ðp; zÞ @ 2 Pc ðp; zÞ @ Pc ðp; zÞ ¼ 2bpf ðzÞ ½1 FðzÞ2 : @p2 @z2 @z@p
(10)
Equation (10) implies that ðpc ; zc Þ is the optimal solution to (9) if 2bpf ðzÞ ½1 FðzÞ2 > 0 at
ðpc ; zc Þ:
(11)
c Þþbc Substituting pc ¼ aþzc Lðz into (11), and we have 2b
ÞfFðz c Þ hðzc Þ½a þ zc Lðzc Þ þ bcg < 0: Fðz c Because GðzÞ is a unimodal function, GðAÞ > 0 and GðBÞ < 0, therefore c Þ hðzc Þ½a þ zc Lðzc Þ þ bc < 0, which means dGðzÞ=dz < 0 at z ¼ zc , and Fðz 2 that (11) can be met if 2h ðzÞ þ dhðzÞ=dz > 0. @ 2 Pc ðp;zÞ So we can have the following principal minors at ðp ; z Þ: < 0, 2 c c @p ðpc ;zc Þ 2
2 2 2 2 @ Pc ðp;zÞ @ Pc ðp;zÞ @ Pc ðp;zÞ @ Pc ðp;zÞ < 0, and > 0, then the Hessian 2 2 2 @z @p @z @z@p ðp ;z Þ c
ðpc ;zc Þ
c
matrix of Pc ðp; zÞ is negative definite at ðpc ; zc Þ Thus, if 2h2 ðzÞ þ dhðzÞ=dz > 0, there is a unique optimal contract ðpc ; zc Þ to the centralized supply chain. □ It is obvious that, if F is IFR, i.e., dhðzÞ=dz > 0, 2h2 ðzÞ þ dhðzÞ=dz > 0 for 8z 2 ½A; B. Theorem 1 indicates that it does not need any requirement on parameters other than the demand distribution itself to determine the optimal consignment contract with revenue sharing for the centralized supply chain. The following proposition describes how the optimal decision ðpc ; zc Þ changes with the supply chain system parameters b and c. Proposition 1. If 2h2 ðzÞ þ dhðzÞ=dz > 0, then (i) zc is decreasing in b, and is also decreasing in c. (ii) pc is decreasing in b, and its monotone property in c depends on b. Proof. (i) According to Theorem 1, we have Gðzc Þ ½a þ zc Lðzc Þ½1 Fðzc Þ bc½1 þ Fðzc Þ ¼ 0
438
S. Li et al.
From the chain rule and differentiation of implicit functions, we have dzc c½1 þ Fðzc Þ ¼ : db @Gðzc Þ=@zc From the proof of Theorem 1, GðzÞ is a unimodal function, GðAÞ > 0 and GðBÞ < 0, and zc is the unique solution to Gðzc Þ ¼ 0, then @Gðzc Þ=@zc < 0. Therefore, if 2h2 ðzÞ þ dhðzÞ=dz > 0, dzc =db < 0, which means that zc is decreasing in b. For the same reason zc is also decreasing in c. (ii) From the chain rule and differentiation of implicit functions, we have dpc @pc @pc dzc ¼ þ : db @b @zc db Since pc ðzc Þ ¼
aþzc Lðzc Þþbc , 2b
we have
@pc a þ zc Lðzc Þ < 0 and ¼ @b 2b2
@pc 1 Fðzc Þ ¼ > 0: @zc 2b
Then dpc =db < 0, which means that pc is decreasing in b. From the chain rule and differentiation of implicit functions, we also have dpc @pc @pc dzc ¼ þ : dc @c @zc dc @p
@p
1Fðz Þ
dz
b½1þFðz Þ
c so It can be derived that @cc ¼ 12 , @zc ¼ 2b c and dcc ¼ @Gðz Þ=@z , c c c dpc Lðzc Þ dc ¼ 2 @Gðzc Þ=@zc , where Lðzc Þ ¼ Fðzc Þ þ bchðzc Þ 1. Because @Gðzc Þ=@zc < 0, the sign of dpc /dc isn determined by Lðz oc Þ.
1þFðzC Þ , Vc LðzC Þ
Since 1 FðzVc Þ ¼ bc aþz
1þFðz Þ
c Lðzc Þ ¼ bc hðzc Þ aþz Lðz Þ , which means c
c
aþz Lðz Þbc
that sign of Lðzc Þ is determined by zc . According to Fðzc Þ ¼ aþzc Lðzc Þþbc , zc is c c uniquely determined by b for any fixed c. □ Therefore, the monotone property of pc in c depends on b. Proposition 1 shows that, the price-elasticity index b affects the optimal stocking factor and the optimal retail price in the linear demand case as it does in the multiplicative demand case, but the effects of the total supply chain cost per unit c in the optimal stocking factor and the optimal retail price are different in the isoprice-elastic and the linear demand cases.
Supply Chain Coordination Under Consignment Contract with Revenue Sharing
439
4 Decentralized Supply Chain Coordination In this section, we investigate the coordination decisions for the decentralized supply chain in multiplicative and additive demand cases.
4.1
The Iso-Price-Elastic Demand Case
For the decentralized supply chain, we define the stocking factor of inventory as z q=yðpÞ. Hence the problem of choosing p, q and r is equivalent to choosing p, z and r. The manufacturer’s and the retailer’s expected profits can be written as Pe;M ðp; z; rÞ ¼ ð1 aÞcq þ ð1 rÞpE½minðq; DÞ
(12)
¼ yðpÞfð1 rÞp½z LðzÞ ð1 aÞczg; Pe;R ðp; z; rÞ ¼ acq þ rpE½minðq; DÞ ¼ yðpÞfrp½z LðzÞ aczg:
(13)
Substituting (12) and (13) into the cooperative game model (4), and we have the following conclusion from its first-order and second-order conditions. Theorem 2. For any fixed z 2 ½A; B, if F is IGFR, the cooperative game model (4) has a unique game equilibrium solution ðpe ; ze ; re Þ, where ze is uniquely determined by Þ ¼ ðb 1Þ½ze Lðze Þ ; Fðz e bze
pe ¼
(14)
bcze ; ðb 1Þ½ze Lðze Þ
(15)
and re ¼ ðb aÞb ½2ðb 1Þa þ 1 þ
ðb 1Þb1 ½ðb 2Þa þ 1 2bðb aÞb
:
(16)
Proof. By solving the first order conditions of cooperative game model (4) in the iso-price-elastic demand case, we have the feasible solutions ðpe ; ze ; re Þ, which are determined by the following equations, e Þ ¼ ðb 1Þ½ze Lðze Þ ; Fðz bze
440
S. Li et al.
pe ¼
bcze ; ðb 1Þ½ze Lðze Þ
and re ¼ ðb aÞb ½2ðb 1Þa þ 1 þ
ðb 1Þb1 ½ðb 2Þa þ 1 2bðb aÞb
:
Following the proof of Theorem 1 in Wang et al. (2004b), there is a unique ze 2 e Þ ¼ ðb1Þ½ze Lðze Þ . Then, the feasible solution ðp ; z ; r Þ is ðA; BÞ satisfying Fðz e e e bze unique. From the second order conditions, the optimality conditions of the cooperative game model (4) are equivalent to (see, Gottfried and Weisman 1973): e Þ2 bcze f ðze Þ < 0; pe ½Fðz D ¼ Pe;M Pd;M ¼ Pe;R Pd;R > 0: From the proof of Theorem 1 in Wang et al. (2004b), 1 bze hðze Þ < 0 if F is IGFR. bcze e Þ Þ ¼ ðb1Þ½ze Lðz and pe ¼ ðb1Þ½z Lðz Since Fðz Þ , we then have pe Fðze Þ ¼ c; e bze e e thus, Þ2 bcz f ðz Þ ¼ cFðz Þ½1 bz hðz Þ < 0: pe ½Fðz e e e e e e Þ2 bcz f ðz Þ < 0 always holds if F is IGFR. It means that pe ½Fðz e e e From the optimal decision ðpd ; zd ; rd Þ and the unique feasible solution ðpe ; ze ; re Þ, we have D ¼ Pe;M Pd;M ¼ Pe;R Pd;R ¼ aczd ðpd Þb
ðb aÞb þ ðb 1Þb1 ½bða 2Þ þ 1 2ðb 1Þbþ1
:
Let gðaÞ ¼ ðb aÞb þ ðb 1Þb1 ½bða 2Þ þ 1, it can be verified that g0 ðaÞ ¼ b½ðb 1Þb1 ðb aÞb1 < 0, and lim gðaÞ ¼ 0. a!1
Because 0 < a < 1 and g0 ðaÞ < 0, so we have gðaÞ > 0. This implies that D > 0, and D ¼ Pe;M Pd;M ¼ Pe;R Pd;R > 0 holds. According to the above proofs, the unique feasible solution ðpe ; ze ; re Þ is optimal to the cooperative game model (4) if F is IGFR. □ From the proof of Theorem 2, the unique equilibrium solution ðpe ; ze ; re Þ always meets the acceptable decision condition Z when the demand distribution F is IGFR.
Supply Chain Coordination Under Consignment Contract with Revenue Sharing
441
This reveals that both the manufacturer and the retailer are better off at cooperation than at non-cooperation. Form the proof procedures of Theorem 2, if d½zhðzÞ=dz ¼ hðzÞ þ zdhðzÞ=dz > 0, the supply chain members can obtain more profits from their cooperation than those from non-cooperation, i.e., Pe;M > Pd;M , Pe;R > Pd;R ; and their incremental profits are equal, i.e., Pe;M Pd;M ¼ Pe;R Pd;R . The following proposition characterizes the optimal decision in the cooperative situation, its relationship to the optimal decision in the non-cooperative situation and to the optimal decision of the centralized supply chain. Proposition 2. In the decentralized supply chain with the iso-price-elastic demand model, (i) ze is independent of re , c, or a, and pe is independent of re or a. (ii) ze ¼ zc ¼ zd . (iii) pe ¼ pc < pd . (iv) re only depends on b and a, and re < rd . Proof. (i) From Theorem 2, we have ze is independent of re , c, or a, and pe is independent of re or a. (ii) Since there is a unique solution z to z bzFðzÞ þ ðb 1ÞLðzÞ ¼ 0, and compar e Þ d Þ c Þ Þ ¼ ðb1Þ½zc Lðz Þ ¼ ðb1Þ½zd Lðz e Þ ¼ ðb1Þ½ze Lðz with Fðz and Fðz , ing Fðz c d bzc bzd bze then ze ¼ zc ¼ zd . bcze bczc (iii) Since pe ¼ ðb1Þ½z Lðz Þ and pc ¼ ðb1Þ½z Lðz Þ , then pe ¼ pc . From Theorem e e c c 1 and Theorem 2 in Wang et al. (2004b), pc < pd . Then, pe ¼ pc < pd . (iv) It is obvious that re only depends on b and a. We have re
rd
" # 2ðb 1Þa þ 1 ðb 1Þb1 aðb 2Þ þ 1 ¼ 1 þ b1 2b ba 2bðb aÞ <
2ðb 1Þa þ 1 1 2b aðb 2Þ þ 1 þ : 2b 2b ba
Since rd ¼ aðb2Þþ1 < 1, we have ba re rd <
2ðb 1Þa þ 1 1 2b ðb 1Þða 1Þ þ ¼ < 0: 2b 2b b
Then, re < rd . □ Proposition 2 indicates that the optimal stocking factor ze is equal to that of the decentralized supply chain in non-cooperative situation and also equals that of the centralized supply chain. The optimal retail price pe is equal to that of the centralized supply chain, and is always less than that of the decentralized supply
442
S. Li et al.
chain in non-cooperative situation. The optimal revenue share re is less than that of the decentralized supply chain in non-cooperative situation. These mean that, in the condition of satisfying demand, the consumers can benefit from the supply chain cooperation (i.e., lower retail price) and the manufacturer’s dominance are improved (i.e., higher profit share) as well as the supply quantity cannot be affected. It follows from Parts (ii) and (iii) of Proposition 2 that the decentralized supply chain with the iso-price-elastic demand model is perfectly coordinated under the equilibrium consignment contract with revenue sharing ðpe ; ze ; re Þ. Substituting ðpc ; zc Þ into (7), we have Pc ¼
ac ðp Þb zc : b1 c
(17)
By substituting ðpe ; ze ; re Þ into (12) and (13) respectively, we have the manufacturer’s and the retailer’s profits in the decentralized supply chain: Pe;M ¼
Pe;R ¼
ðb aÞb ðb 1Þb1 ½ðb 2Þa þ 1 2ðb aÞb ðb aÞb þ ðb 1Þb1 ½ðb 2Þa þ 1 2ðb aÞb
Pc ;
(18)
Pc :
(19)
Then the retailer’s share of the channel profit can be calculated as b¼
Pe;R 1 ðb 1Þb1 ½ðb 2Þa þ 1 þ ¼ : Pe;M þ Pe;R 2 2ðb aÞb
(20)
Proposition 3. With the iso-price-elastic demand model, the retailer’s profit share b (i) is increasing in a for any given b > 1, and decreasing in b for any given a. b1 as a ! 0 and 1 as a ! 1, and never be below 0.5. (ii) approaches 12 þ ðb1Þ 2bb (iii) approaches
1þaeð1aÞ 2
as b ! 1 and 1 as b ! 1, and never be below 0.5.
Proof. (i) From (20), we have increasing in a, and
db da
½ðb2Þaþb ¼ ðb1Þ > 0, which implies that b is 2ðbaÞbþ1 b
db ðb 1Þb1 ðb aÞ½aðb 2Þ þ 1 að1 aÞðb 1Þ b1 : ¼ þ log db ðb aÞ½aðb 2Þ þ 1 ba 2ðb aÞbþ1 að1aÞðb1Þ þ log Let lðbÞ ¼ ðbaÞ½aðb2Þþ1
b1 ba , we have
Supply Chain Coordination Under Consignment Contract with Revenue Sharing
l0 ðbÞ ¼
ð1 aÞ2 ðb 1Þðb aÞ2 ½ðb 2Þa þ 12
443
ðbÞ;
where ðbÞ ¼ ½bðb 5Þ þ 5a2 þ 2½bðb 1Þ 1a þ b. For ðbÞ, we have 0 ðbÞ ¼ 1 þ að4b þ 2ba 5a 2Þ > ð3a þ 1Þð1 aÞ > 0 for b > 1, hence, ðbÞ > ð1Þ ¼ a2 2a þ 1 > 0. Therefore we have l0 ðbÞ > 0 for b > 1. Since lim lðbÞ ¼ 0, lðbÞ < 0 for b > 1. b!1 Thus, db=db < 0, which implies that b is decreasing in b. (ii) From (20), we have 1 ðb 1Þb1 1 lim b ¼ þ > ; a!0 2bb 2 2 and 1 ðb 1Þ lim b ¼ þ ¼ 1: 2 2ðb 1Þ
a!1
(iii) From (20), we have b¼
Pe;R 1 ðb 1Þb1 ½ðb 2Þa þ 1 þ ¼ ; Pe;M þ Pe;R 2 2ðb aÞb
then 1 ð1 aÞ ¼ 1; lim b ¼ þ b!1 2 2ð1 aÞ and lim b ¼ 12 þ lim eb log½ba lim b1
b!1
b!1
b!1
n
ðb2Þaþ1 2ðbaÞ
o
ð1aÞ
¼ 12 þ e
a
2
> 12 .
□
Proposition 3 illustrates the behavior of the retailer’s profit share b. It is showed that the retailer can always extract more than 50% of the channel profit even if he does not incur any portion of the channel cost. From (20), the retailer’s and the manufacturer’s profit shares are not affected by demand uncertainty. Following the measurement of the retailer’s dominance defined in (1), at the isoprice-elastic demand case, the retailer’s dominance is as follows: drm ¼
2ðb 1Þb1 ½ðb 2Þa þ 1 ðb aÞb þ ðb 1Þb1 ½ðb 2Þa þ 1
:
(21)
444
S. Li et al.
The following Proposition 4 describes the impacts of supply chain parameters b and a on the retailer’s dominance. It indicates that the retailer is always dominant over the manufacturer in the decentralized supply chain, and is the same as the meanings of Proposition 3, i.e., the retailer can always extract more than 50% of channel profit. Proposition 4. With the iso-price-elastic demand model, the retailer’s dominance d rm (i) is increasing in a for any given b > 1, and decreasing in b for any given a. 2 (ii) approaches 1þðb1Þ 1b b > 0 as a ! 0 and 1 as a ! 1. b a
(iii) approaches e 2ae + aea > 0 as b ! 1 and 1 as b ! 1. Proof. (i) From (21), we have ddrm 2ðb 1Þbþ2 ðb aÞb1 ½ðb 2Þa þ b ; ¼ 2 da fðb 1Þðb aÞb þ ðb 1Þb ½ðb 2Þa þ 1g and ddrm 2ðb 1Þbþ1 ðb aÞb ½aðb 2Þ þ 1lðbÞ ; ¼ 2 db fðb 1Þðb aÞb þ ðb 1Þb ½ðb 2Þa þ 1g where lðbÞ ¼
að1 aÞðb 1Þ b1 : þ log ðb aÞ½aðb 2Þ þ 1 ba
Since b > 1 and 0 < a < 1, ðb 2Þa þ b ¼ ðb 1Þa þ ðb aÞ > 0, then ddrm =da > 0. From the proof of Proposition 3, lðbÞ < 0 for 8b > 1, then dd rm =db < 0: (ii) From (21), we have lim d rm ¼
a!0
2ðb 1Þb1 bb
b1
þ ðb 1Þ
¼
2 1 þ ðb 1Þ1b bb
;
and lim d rm ¼ 1:
a!1
(iii) From (21), we have lim drm ¼ 1,
e
b!1 2aea + aea .
and
lim d rm ¼ lim
b!1
b!1 1þ
2 ðbaÞb ðb1Þb1 ½ðb2Þaþ1
¼
2 1þ lim
ðbaÞb
lim
ðb1Þ
b!1 ðb1Þb b!1 ðb2Þaþ1
¼ □
Supply Chain Coordination Under Consignment Contract with Revenue Sharing
445
Proposition 4 implies that the retailer dominance d rm is always greater than zero, that is to say that the retailer is dominant over the manufacturer in the decentralized supply chain under the consignment contract with revenue sharing. From (21), the retailer dominance is not affected by demand uncertainty, and is related to supply chain parameters b and a in the iso-price-elastic demand case.
4.2
The Linear Demand Case
In the linear demand case, the stocking factor of inventory is defined as z ¼ q y(p), then the problem of choosing p, q and r is equivalent to choosing p, z and r. The manufacturer’s and the retailer’s expected profit functions are Pe;M ðp; zÞ ¼ ð1 aÞcq þ ð1 rÞpE½minfq; Dg ¼ ð1 rÞp½a bp þ z LðzÞ ð1 aÞc½a bp þ z; Pe;R ðp; zÞ ¼ acq þ rpE½minfq; Dg ¼ rp½a bp þ z LðzÞ ac½a bp þ z:
(22)
(23)
Substituting (22) and (23) into the cooperative game model (4), and solving the optimal problem of cooperative game model (4), we have the following conclusion. Theorem 3. For any fixed z 2 ½A; B, if F is IFR, the cooperative game model (4) has a unique game equilibrium solution ðpe ; ze ; re Þ, where ze is uniquely determined by Fðze Þ ¼
a þ ze Lðze Þ bc ; a þ ze Lðze Þ þ bc
(24)
pe ðze Þ ¼
a þ ze Lðze Þ þ bc ; 2b
(25)
and Þ ð1 aÞð2r 1Þ Fðz Þ 2a 1 r a z z þ Lðz Þ Lðz Þ 1 Fðz e d e d e d d d : þ re ¼ þ Þ bc 2 Fðze Þ 2ð1 rd Þ 4 1 rd Fðz d (26) Proof. By solving the first order conditions of cooperative game model (4) in the linear demand case, we can have the feasible solutions, which are determined by the following equations:
446
S. Li et al.
Fðze Þ ¼
a þ ze Lðze Þ bc ; a þ ze Lðze Þ þ bc
(27)
pe ðze Þ ¼
a þ ze Lðze Þ þ bc ; 2b
(28)
and e Þ ð1 aÞð2r 1Þ Fðz Þ 2a 1 r a z ze þ Lðz Þ Lðze Þ 1 Fðz d d d d d re ¼ þ : Þ þ 4 2 Fðze Þ 2ð1 rd Þ 1 rd bc Fðz d (29) According to Theorem 1, if 2h2 ðzÞ þ dhðzÞ=dz > 0, there is a unique optimal e Lðze Þbc solution ze 2 ðA; BÞ satisfying Fðze Þ ¼ aþz aþze Lðze Þþbc . Because zd and rd are unique, (27)–(29) determine a unique feasible solution ðpe ; ze ; re Þ if dhðzÞ=dz > 0. It is known that, if the Hessian matrix of cooperative game model is a negative definite matrix at ðpe ; ze ; re Þ, ðpe ; ze ; re Þ is the optimal solution to the cooperative game model (4). The Hessian matrix is a negative definite matrix at ðpe ; ze ; re Þ if the following two conditions are satisfied (see, Gottfried and Weisman 1973): ½1 Fðze Þ2 2bpe f ðze Þ < 0;
(30)
Pe;M Pd;M ¼ Pe;R Pd;R > 0:
(31)
Let Rðpe ; ze Þ ¼ 2bpe f ðze Þ ½1 Fðze Þ2 , (28) gives 1 Fðze Þ : Rðpe ; ze Þ ¼ f ðze Þ a þ ze Lðze Þ þ bc hðze Þ
(32)
From the proof of Theorem 1, we have GðzÞ ¼ ½a þ z LðzÞ½1 FðzÞ bc ½1 þ FðzÞ is a unimodal function if 2h2 ðzÞ þ dhðzÞ=dz > 0. dGðzÞ Sincen GðAÞ ¼ a þ A bc > 0 and GðBÞ ¼ 2bc < 0, o dz < 0, i.e., f ðze Þ a þ ze Lðze Þ þ bc
1Fðze Þ hðze Þ
z¼ze
< 0.
Therefore, Rðpe ; ze Þ > 0, and (30) holds if 2h2 ðzÞ þ dhðzÞ=dz > 0. From the first order optimality conditions, it can be derived that Pe;M Pd;M ¼ Pe;R Pd;R ¼
ðPe;M þ Pe;R Þ ðPd;M þ Pd;R Þ : 2
From Table 1, we have 1a ½a þ zd Lðzd Þ½1 Fðzd Þ gbc½1 þ Fðzd Þ ¼ 0, where g ¼ 1r > 1. d
Supply Chain Coordination Under Consignment Contract with Revenue Sharing
447
Let Yðzd Þ ¼ ½a þ zd Lðzd Þ½1 Fðzd Þ gbc½1 þ Fðzd Þ; then dYðzd Þ 1 Fðzd Þ ; ¼ f ðz Þ a þ z Lðz Þ þ gbc d d d dzd hðzd Þ and 0 d2 Yðzd Þ f ðzd Þ dYðzd Þ f ðzd Þ dhðzd Þ 2 ½1 Fðz : ¼ þ Þ 2h ðz Þ þ d d f ðzd Þ dzd h2 ðzd Þ dzd dzd 2 If 2h2 ðzÞ þ dhðzÞ dz > 0, then d2 Yðzd Þ f ðz Þ ¼ h2 ðzd Þ ½1 Fðzd Þ½2h2 ðzd Þ þ dhðzd Þ=dzd < 0, dz 2 d
dYðzd Þ=dzd ¼0
which
d
implies that Yðzd Þ is a unimodal function. 1a and g ¼ 1r Recall that a < rd < 1 ð1aÞbc , so we have YðAÞ ¼ a þ A aþA d
gbc > 0. Since Yðzd Þ is continuous on ½A; B, and YðBÞ ¼ 2gbc < 0, thus zd is the unique solution to Yðzd Þ ¼ 0 and @Yðzd Þ=@zd < 0. dz bc½1þFðz Þ From the implicit function rule, we have dgd ¼ @Yðz Þ=@zd < 0. d d By observing Table 1, we have lim zd ¼ ze . g!1 Therefore, ze > zd if g > 1. It can be directly observed that Pc , Pd;M þ Pd;R and Pe;M þ Pe;R have the same function form. According to Theorem 1, Pc achieves its maximum if and only if ðzc ; pc Þ ¼ ðzc ; pc Þ. It can also be observed from their expressions that ðze ; pe Þ ¼ ðzc ; pc Þ, thus ðze ; pe Þ is the unique optimal solution to Pe;M þ Pe;R . Because ze > zd , so we have Pe;M þ Pe;R > Pd;M þ Pd;R , and (31) holds. Therefore, the optimal solution ðpe ; ze ; re Þ determined by (24)–(26) is the Nash equilibrium solution to the cooperative game model (4) if dhðzÞ=dz > 0. □ In Theorem 3, zd and rd are the optimal stocking factor of inventory and the optimal revenue share of the decentralized supply chain in the linear demand case respectively, see Table 1. From the proof of Theorem 3, the unique equilibrium solution ðpe ; ze ; re Þ always meets the acceptable decision condition Z if the demand distribution F is IFR. This also reveals that both the manufacturer and the retailer are better off at cooperation than at non-cooperation in the linear demand case, i.e., Pe;M > Pd;M and Pe;R > Pd;R , which is the same as that in the iso-price-elastic demand case. Since the expressions of pe and ze are the same as those of pc and zc respectively, we have the following properties about pe and ze according to Proposition 1: if F is IFR, then ze is decreasing in b , and is also decreasing in c; pe is decreasing in b, and may be increasing, constant or decreasing in c. The following Proposition 5 characterizes the characters of the optimal decision in the cooperative situation, its relationship to the optimal decision in the noncooperative situation and to the optimal decision of the centralized supply chain.
448
S. Li et al.
Proposition 5. In the decentralized supply chain with the linear demand model, (i) ze and pe do not depend on re or a, but depends on b and c; re depends on b, c and a. (ii) pe ¼ pc . (iii) ze ¼ zc > zd . Proof. (i)–(ii) They can be easily verified from the expressions of ðpd ; zd ; rd Þ, ðpe ; ze ; re Þ and ðpc ; zc Þ. (iii) The uniqueness of ze and zc gives ze ¼ zc . According to the proof of Theorem 3, we have ze > zd . Therefore ze ¼ zc > zd . □ It follows from Parts (ii) and (iii) of Proposition 5 that ðpe ; ze Þ ¼ ðpc ; zc Þ, which means that the decentralized supply chain with the linear demand model is perfectly coordinated under the consignment contract with revenue sharing ðpe ; ze ; re Þ. Since it is difficult to provide the closed forms of the manufacturer’s and the retailer’s expected profits, we cannot describe the impacts of parameters b, c and demand uncertainty s on supply chain decisions, b and drm analytically. We perform numerical studies to investigate the impacts.
5 Numerical Analysis To better illustrate the ideas in this chapter, we develop a numerical sample for the linear demand case. In the numerical studies, we assume that e ~ N(10,5), a ¼ 100, c ¼ 1.0. Given a ¼ 0.25, the optimal solutions can be obtained by applying Theorem 3 at a given b. The manufacturer’s and the retailer’s expected profits can then be computed numerically as well as the retailer’s profit share and dominance. When b varies from 1 to 80, the computational results are reported in Table 2. As shown in Propositions 3 and 4, we let a ¼ 0 and a ¼ 0.999 to analyze the behaviors of the retailer’s profit share b and dominance drm as a ! 0 and a ! 1, respectively. The computational results are reported in the following Tables 3 and 4. Results in Tables 2–4 show that, in the linear demand case, the revenue share r, the retail price p and the production quantity q is decreasing in b for any given a. Furthermore, the retailer’s profit share b and dominance drm are also decreasing in b for any given a, these observations are similar to Propositions 3 and 4 in the isoprice-elastic demand case. From Propositions 3 and 4, the retailer can always extract more than 50% of the channel profit in the iso-price-elastic demand case; however, in the linear demand case, the manufacturer can earn more than the retailers. For example, as shown in Table 3, when b > 36.07 (it corresponds to the italic and bold face), the retailer’s profit share is less than 0.5 and its dominance is negative. Table 4 shows that the retailer’s profit share and dominance approach 1 as a ! 1, which is similar to the
Supply Chain Coordination Under Consignment Contract with Revenue Sharing
449
Table 2 The optimal solutions in linear demand case, e ~ N(10,5), a ¼ 100, c ¼ 1.0, a ¼ 0.25 b
zd
1 13.518 5 11.247 10 10.057 15 9.255 20 8.616 25 8.064 30 7.566 40 6.656 50 5.792 80 2.804
rd pd 0.950 62.325 0.863 13.621 0.790 7.198 0.731 4.991 0.681 3.863 0.637 3.175 0.597 2.710 0.527 2.119 0.466 1.757 0.321 1.195
ze 20.491 16.804 14.835 13.520 12.490 11.618 10.849 9.491 8.262 4.402
re pe qe Pe;M Pe;R b drm 0.827 55.738 64.753 479.028 2,507.213 0.840 0.809 0.705 11.522 59.194 134.528 412.508 0.754 0.674 0.627 5.997 54.865 70.754 174.030 0.711 0.593 0.572 4.155 51.195 45.651 99.750 0.686 0.542 0.530 3.233 47.830 31.959 64.644 0.669 0.506 0.496 2.680 44.618 23.333 44.656 0.657 0.477 0.466 2.312 41.503 17.441 32.002 0.647 0.455 0.417 1.850 35.492 10.054 17.353 0.633 0.421 0.377 1.572 29.638 5.800 9.572 0.623 0.394 0.290 1.151 12.295 0.681 0.963 0.586 0.293
Table 3 The optimal solutions in linear demand case, e ~ N(10,5), a ¼ 100, c ¼ 1.0, a ¼ 0 b
zd
rd
pd
ze
re
pe
Pe;M
qe
Pe;R
b
drm
1.00 13.173 0.940 63.061 20.491 0.740 55.738 64.753 729.604 2,256.637 0.756 0.677 5.00 10.867 0.833 13.857 16.804 0.582 11.522 59.192 194.331 352.705 0.645 0.449 10.00 9.664 0.741 7.337 14.835 0.482 5.997 54.867 100.420 144.365 0.590 0.304 15.00 8.858 0.667 5.090 13.520 0.413 4.155 51.200 64.203 81.198 0.558 0.209 20.00 8.217 0.603 3.940 12.490 0.360 3.233 47.822 44.675 51.928 0.538 0.140 25.00 7.667 0.545 3.237 11.618 0.315 2.680 44.610 32.470 35.519 0.522 0.086 30.00 7.172 0.493 2.760 10.849 0.278 2.312 41.503 24.183 25.260 0.511 0.043 36.07 6.616 0.434 2.354 10.003 0.238 2.001 37.830 17.205 17.205 0.500 0.000 40.00 6.272 0.399 2.154 9.491 0.215 1.850 35.492 13.863 13.544 0.494 0.024 50.00 5.421 0.316 1.781 8.262 0.165 1.572 29.638 7.965 7.407 0.482 0.075 80.00 2.501 0.107 1.200 4.402 0.051 1.151 12.295 0.933 0.712 0.433 0.309
Table 4 The optimal solutions in linear demand case, e ~ N(10,5), a ¼ 100, c ¼ 1.0, a ¼ 0.999 b
zd
rd
pd
ze
re
pe
qe
Pe;M
Pe;R
b
d rm
15.00 20.00 25.00 30.00 40.00 50.00 80.00
13.459 12.449 11.590 10.827 9.478 8.253 4.398
0.999 0.999 0.999 0.999 0.999 0.999 0.999
4.163 3.238 2.684 2.314 1.851 1.573 1.151
13.520 12.490 11.618 10.849 9.491 8.262 4.402
0.999 0.999 0.999 0.999 0.999 0.999 0.999
4.155 3.233 2.680 2.312 1.850 1.572 1.151
51.200 47.822 44.610 41.503 35.492 29.638 12.295
0.048 0.052 0.044 0.036 0.022 0.013 0.001
145.353 96.551 67.945 49.407 27.385 15.359 1.644
1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00
1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00
results in Propositions 3 and 4. One issue should be illuminated in Table 4, when b is small (e.g., b 10), the manufacturer’s profit is negative at cooperation, and then the manufacturer and the retailer will not bargain to cooperate. For more detailed illustrations of impacts of price sensitivity b on the retailer’s profit share and dominance, we give another example that e ~ N(10,5), a ¼ 100, c ¼ 1.0 and a ¼ 0.5. The optimal solutions of the supply chain and the expected profits of the manufacturer and the retailer are then computed numerically as well as
450
S. Li et al.
Table 5 The optimal solutions in linear demand case, e ~ N(10,5), a ¼ 100, c ¼ 1.0, a ¼ 0.5 b
zd
10.00 11.161 20.00 8.804 30.00 7.060 40.00 5.527 50.00 4.046 60.00 2.506
rd 0.838 0.760 0.702 0.656 0.617 0.583
pd 6.994 3.731 2.611 2.039 1.690 1.454
ze 17.809 14.036 11.381 9.167 7.140 5.137
re 0.760 0.690 0.643 0.608 0.580 0.557
pe 6.079 3.258 2.318 1.847 1.563 1.373
qe 57.015 48.878 41.852 35.293 28.972 22.761
Pe;M Pe;R 45.662 206.125 21.219 77.024 11.777 37.986 6.879 20.388 4.012 11.052 2.240 5.720
b 0.819 0.784 0.763 0.748 0.734 0.719
drm 0.778 0.725 0.690 0.663 0.637 0.608
Table 6 The optimal solutions in linear demand case, e ~ N(10,5), a ¼ 100, c ¼ 1.0, b ¼ 10.0 a
zd
0.01 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.50 0.75 0.99
9.678 9.735 9.810 9.888 9.970 10.057 10.586 11.424 14.112
rd 0.743 0.751 0.760 0.770 0.780 0.790 0.843 0.905 0.992
pd 7.332 7.312 7.285 7.258 7.229 7.198 7.019 6.758 6.118
ze 14.835 14.835 14.835 14.835 14.835 14.835 14.835 14.835 14.835
re 0.488 0.511 0.541 0.570 0.598 0.627 0.763 0.890 0.998
pe 5.997 5.997 5.997 5.997 5.997 5.997 5.997 5.997 5.997
qe 54.8650 54.8650 54.8650 54.8650 54.8650 54.8650 54.8650 54.8650 54.8650
Pe;M 99.192 94.315 88.293 82.357 76.510 70.754 43.491 19.222 0.168
Pe;R 145.592 150.469 156.491 162.427 168.275 174.030 201.293 225.562 244.616
b 0.595 0.615 0.639 0.664 0.687 0.711 0.822 0.921 0.999
drm 0.319 0.373 0.436 0.493 0.545 0.593 0.784 0.915 0.999
the retailer’s profit share and dominance. The computational results are reported in Table 5. Table 5 shows that the impacts of price sensitivity b on the manufacturer’s and the retailer’s expected profits, the retailer’s profit share and dominance are the same to those shown in Table 2. For analyzing the impacts of parameter a on the supply chain decisions, the retailer’s profit share and the retailer’s dominance, we next set b ¼ 10.0. When a varies from 0.01 to 0.99, the computational results are listed in Table 6. From Table 6, the revenue share r is increasing in a, however, for any given b > 0, the retailer’s cost share a has no impact on the production quantity q and the retail price p, i.e., the production quantity q and the retail price p are constant in a. As shown in Fig. 1, the retailer’s profit share b and dominance drm are increasing in a for any given b > 0. These observations are similar to Propositions 3 and 4 in the iso-price- elastic demand case. It can also be found that the retailer’s dominance is more sensitive in the price-elasticity index and the retailer’s cost share. To analyze the effects of demand uncertainty on the supply chain decisions and performance, we let b ¼ 10.0, a ¼ 0.25 and s varies from 5 to 50. Applying Theorem 3, we obtain the optimal solutions, the expected profits of supply chain members, the retailer’s profit share and dominance for any given demand uncertainty level s. Table 7 shows the computational results when the demand uncertainty varies.
Supply Chain Coordination Under Consignment Contract with Revenue Sharing
451
1.20 1.00 0.80 0.60 0.40 0.20 0.00
0.01
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.20
Retailer's profit share
0.25
0.50
0.75
0.99
Retailer's dominance
Fig. 1 The impacts of cost share on retailer’s profit share and dominance
Table 7 The optimal solutions in linear demand case, e ~ N(10,s), a ¼ 100, c ¼ 1.0, b ¼ 10.0, a ¼ 0.25 s
zd
5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50
10.057 10.563 11.478 12.749 14.335 16.201 18.317 20.658 23.203 25.934
rd 0.790 0.780 0.772 0.765 0.758 0.752 0.747 0.743 0.739 0.736
pd 7.198 7.146 7.139 7.153 7.187 7.238 7.305 7.386 7.480 7.586
ze 14.835 19.845 25.102 30.581 36.272 42.166 48.258 54.541 61.008 67.654
re 0.627 0.610 0.596 0.583 0.571 0.561 0.551 0.542 0.534 0.527
pe 5.997 6.156 6.369 6.591 6.819 7.052 7.290 7.533 7.782 8.036
qe 54.8650 58.2850 61.4120 64.6710 68.0820 71.6460 75.3580 79.2110 83.1880 87.2940
Pe;M 70.754 80.113 92.161 105.197 119.070 133.795 149.410 165.954 183.463 201.972
Pe;R 174.030 179.027 188.322 198.603 209.582 221.281 233.749 247.031 261.162 276.177
b 0.711 0.691 0.671 0.654 0.638 0.623 0.610 0.598 0.587 0.578
drm 0.593 0.553 0.511 0.470 0.432 0.395 0.361 0.328 0.298 0.269
Results in Table 7 show that, in the linear demand case, the production quantity and the retail price will increase in the demand uncertainty, and the retailer’s and the manufacturer’s expected profits is also increasing. These mean that the more demand uncertainty will lead to high expected profits for the manufacturer and the retailer because of the high risk in the market. As shown in Fig. 2, the retailer’s profit share b and dominance drm are decreasing in s for any given a > 0 and b > 0, which indicate that higher demand uncertainty will cut the retailer’s profit share and dominance in the decentralized supply chain. It is also can be found that the retailer’s dominance is more sensitive than the retailer’s profit share in the demand uncertainty. Comparing the optimal decisions at cooperation with those at non-cooperation in the above numerical analyses, it is found that the supply chain channel will supply more product quantity with lower retailer price in the market at cooperation. This means that the supply chain members can earn more profit by their cooperation and the consumers also obtain benefits from the supply chain cooperation.
452
S. Li et al. 0.80 0.70 0.60 0.50 0.40 0.30 0.20 0.10 0.00
5
10
15
20
25
Retailer's profit share
30
35
40
45
50
Retailer's dominance
Fig. 2 The impacts of demand uncertainty on retailer’s profit share and dominance
6 Conclusion In this chapter, we investigate the coordination of a decentralized supply chain consisting of an upstream manufacturer and a downstream retailer, in which a single-period product is produced and sold in the retail market. The bargaining process between the supply chain members is governed by a consignment contract with revenue sharing. We present a cooperative model utilizing Nash bargaining model with two demand cases: the iso-price-elastic demand and the linear demand. In the proposed model, the retailer is the leader and the manufacturer is the follower in the non-cooperative game, and the two players are willing to cooperate if their profits at cooperation are no less than those at non-cooperation. They bargain and try to make an equilibrium agreement on the retail price, production quantity and revenue share. The research shows that the cooperative game between the manufacturer and the retailer has a unique equilibrium solution under a very mild restriction on the demand distribution. Under the equilibrium contract, the decentralized supply chain can be perfectly coordinated and both the manufacturer and the retailer are better off. It is found that the retailer’s profit share and dominance is increasing in retailer’s cost share for any given price elasticity, decreasing in price elasticity for any given retailer’s cost share. The retailer can always extract more than 50% of the channel profit even if he does not incur any portion of the channel cost in the multiplicative demand case; however, the manufacturer can earn more than the retailer by their cooperation in the linear demand case. Acknowledgements The research is supported by National Natural Science Foundation of China (No.71001024; No.70801014), Program for New Century Excellent Talents in University of China (NCET-09-0292) and PhD Programs Foundation of Ministry of Education of China (No.20100092120042).
Supply Chain Coordination Under Consignment Contract with Revenue Sharing
453
References Barlow RE, Proschan F (1975) Statistical theory of reliability and life testing probability models. Holt, Rinehart, and Winston, New York Bernstein F, Federgruen A (2003) Pricing and replenishment strategies in a distribution system with competing retailers. Oper Res 51(3):409–426 Bolen WH (1978) Contemporary retailing. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ Bose S, Pekny JF (2000) A model predictive framework for planning and scheduling problems: a case study of consumer goods supply chain. Comput Chem Eng 24:329–335 Cachon GP (2001) Stock wars: inventory competition in a two echelon supply chain. Oper Res 49(5):658–674 Cachon GP (2003) Supply chain coordination with contracts. In: Graves S, de Kok T (eds) Handbooks in operations research and management science: supply chain management. North-Holland, Amsterdam Cachon GP (2004) The allocation of inventory risk in supply chain: push, pull, and advancepurchase discount contracts. Manage Sci 50(2):222–238 Cachon GP, Lariviere MA (2001) Contracting to assure supply: how to share demand forecasts in a supply chain. Manage Sci 47(5):629–646 Canie¨ls MCJ, Gelderman CJ (2007) Power and interdependence in buyer supplier relationships: a purchasing portfolio approach. Ind Mark Manage 36:219–229 Chen KB, Xiao TJ (2009) Demand disruption and coordination of the supply chain with a dominant retailer. Eur J Oper Res 197(1):225–234 Choi KS, Dai JG, Song JS (2004) On measuring supplier performance under vendor-managedinventory programs in capacitated supply chains. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 6(1):53–72 Dana JD, Spier KE (2001) Revenue sharing and vertical control in the video rental industry. J Ind Econ 49(3):223–245 Dong Y, Xu KF (2002) A supply chain model of vendor managed inventory. Transp Res E 38(2):75–95 Dukes AJ, Gal-Or E, Srinivasan K (2006) Channel bargaining with retailer asymmetry. J Mark Res 43:84–97 Gerchak Y, Wang Y (2004) Revenue-sharing vs. wholesale-price contracts in assembly systems with random demand. Prod Oper Manage 13(1):23–33 Giannoccaro I, Pontrandolfo P (2004) Supply chain coordination by revenue sharing contracts. Int J Prod Econ 89(2):131–139 Goto JH, Lewis ME, Puterman ML (2004) Coffee, tea, or . . .?: a Markov decision process model for airline meal provisioning. Transp Sci 38(1):107–118 Gottfried BS, Weisman J (1973) Introduction to optimization theory. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ G€ um€us¸ M, Jewkes EM, Bookbinder JH (2008) Impact of consignment inventory and vendor managed inventory for a two-party supply chain. Int J Prod Econ 113(2):502–517 Hua ZS, Li SJ (2008) Impacts of demand uncertainty on retailer’s dominance and manufacturerretailer supply chain cooperation. Omega Int J Manage Sci 36(5):697–714 Hua ZS, Li SJ, Liang L (2006) Impact of demand uncertainty on supply chain cooperation of single-period products. Int J Prod Econ 100(2):268–284 Khouja M, Robbins SS (2005) Optimal pricing and quantity of products with two offerings. Eur J Oper Res 163(3):530–544 Kumar N (1996) The power of trust in manufacturer-retailer relationships. Harv Bus Rev 74(6):92–109 Lariviere MA, Porteus EL (2001) Selling to the newsvendor: an analysis of price-only contract. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 3(4):293–305 Lau AHL, Lau HS (2003) Effects of a demand-curves shape on the optimal solutions of a multiechelon inventory/pricing model. Eur J Oper Res 147(3):530–548
454
S. Li et al.
Lau AHL, Lau HS, Wang JC (2008) How a dominant retailer might design a purchase contract for a newsvendor-type product with price-sensitive demand. Eur J Oper Res 190(2):443–458 Li L (2002) Information sharing in a supply chain with horizontal competition. Manage Sci 48(9):1196–1212 Li JL, Liu LW (2008) Supply chain coordination with manufacturer’s limited reserve capacity: an extended newsboy problem. Int J Prod Econ 112(2):860–868 Li J, Sheng ZH, Liu HM (2010) Multi-agent simulation for the dominant players’ behavior in supply chains. Simul Model Pract Theory 18(6):850–859 Loewenstein J, Morris MW, Chakravarti A, Thompson L, Kopelman S (2005) At a loss for words: dominating the conversation and the outcome in negotiation as a function of intricate arguments and communication media. Organ Behav Hum Dec 98:28–38 McAdams D, Malone TW (2005) Internal market for supply chain capacity allocation. Working Paper, MIT Sloan School of Management, Cambridge, MA Mortimer JH (2004) Vertical contracts in the video rental industry. Working paper, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA Nash JF (1950) The bargaining problem. Econometrica 18(2):155–162 Petruzzi NC, Dada M (1999) Pricing and the newsvendor problem: a review with extensions. Oper Res 47(2):183–194 Porter M (1974) Consumer behavior, retailer power and market performance in consumer goods industries. Rev Econ Stat 56:419–436 Robert D (1997) Durable-goods monopoly, increasing marginal cost and depreciation. Economica 64(253):137–154 Rowntree RH (1941) Note on constant marginal cost. Am Econ Rev 31(2):335–338 Wang HW, Guo M, Efstathiou J (2004a) A game-theoretical cooperative mechanism design for a two-echelon decentralized supply chain. Eur J Oper Res 157(2):372–388 Wang Y, Jiang L, Shen ZJ (2004b) Channel performance under consignment contract with revenue sharing. Manage Sci 50(1):34–47
Part IV
Technological Advancements and Applications in Supply Chain Coordination
.
DEAL: A Heuristic Approach for Collaborative Planning in Detailed Scheduling J. Benedikt Scheckenbach
Abstract Aroused by ongoing globalization, the division of labor steadily increases and future competition will likely take place between whole supply chains and not only between single companies. This compels suppliers and manufacturers to better coordinate their production plans in order to save production and holding costs. Despite this necessity, the willingness to share sensitive production data such as cost factors or resource availability has remained very limited. Usually the companies consider these data as vital to their business. However, today’s production planning models and solvers used in industry are of monolithic type and require full visibility of data in order to compute a solution. Hence, they cannot be used to tackle supply-chain-wide planning problems involving different companies. In recent years, “Collaborative Planning” as a joint decision making process under information asymmetry has received increased attention. The majority of present research in this field breaks with the monolithic approach but assumes that planning problems can be solved to optimality. On the contrary, industry struggles in operational business with large detailed scheduling problems that are only solvable by heuristics – violating this fundamental assumption. However, being computed only shortly before execution, badly aligned detailed schedules most obviously demand a coordinated solution. We propose a decentralized evolutionary algorithm (DEAL) for coordinating large-sized detailed schedules that does not demand the exchange of sensitive data but only transmits delivery dates and ordinal rankings. Experimental results prove that DEAL computes in the same time solutions of similar quality as monolithic heuristics are able to.
This work originated from a joint research project between the University of Hamburg, Institute for Logistics and Transport and the SAP AG Walldorf, Germany. Today, the author works as Supply Chain Consultant at Bayer Technology Services GmbH, Germany. J.B. Scheckenbach (*) Cranachstr. 16, 50733 Koeln, Germany e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_18, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
457
458
J.B. Scheckenbach
Keywords Collaborative planning • Detailed scheduling • Evolutionary algorithm • SAP APO
1 Introduction In the last decades, advanced planning systems (APS) have been put forward by industry and academia to solve supply chain (SC) planning problems. To cope with the complexity of the planning problems, APS are typically organized in a hierarchical manner. That is, on a mid-term level so-called master planning centrally calculates rough cut plans, generating enterprise-wide material quantity targets for subsequent production planning and detailed scheduling, which are then applied for each production site separately. Production planning is concerned with translating material quantity targets into concrete production activities, whereas detailed scheduling is about computing a good sequence and a feasible resource assignment for the activities. As detailed schedules per plant have to respect superordinated rough cut plans on enterprise level, APS inherently employ a hierarchical form of coordination. The problem with the above approach is that it is not applicable to companies that are interdependent on delivered items but legally separate organizations. A superordinated decision-making process fails because of the missing central entity and the reluctance of SC members to disclose sensitive data, such as production and holding cost or resource availability. As a remedy, successive planning strategies are employed today, a typical example is upstream planning. In upstream planning, the more powerful downstream entity calculates its production plan first, generating demand for subsequent upstream entities. Most of today’s “collaboration” systems, such as vendor-managed inventory, are actually implementations of successive planning strategies. From a mathematical perspective the interorganizational optimization problem is split into separate interdependent subproblems. The subproblems are then solved sequentially, whereas already-solved subproblems define the constraints for yet unsolved subproblems. For example, suppose a manufacturer setting up his production plan according to current demand and forecasts. By doing this, the manufacturer creates the demand for his suppliers that have to plan their production accordingly. However, successive planning pays no respect to the suppliers’ actual production capacities. Hence, successive planning strategies lead to suboptimal results, which often will result in wasted production capacity, larger safety stocks, decreased service levels or increased production costs. In recent years, academia has put forward advanced coordination mechanisms that try to attain the results of hierarchical coordination (or centralized planning) without requiring the parties to exchange sensitive data. Subsuming the different approaches, the term Collaborative Planning (CP) has emerged as a new research area. From a practical perspective, CP mechanisms have to cope with three difficulties: First, they should support complex operational planning problems. Second, the exchange of sensitive data must be avoided. Third, the mechanisms are required to be incentive compatible to prevent opportunistically acting partners
DEAL: A Heuristic Approach for Collaborative Planning in Detailed Scheduling
459
from supplying systematically biased input that changes overall results to their advantage. It is very difficult to consider all three requirements to the fullest. This, and the still-prevailing paradigm of successive planning have hampered the introduction of CP mechanisms in practice. This work presents a decentralized evolutionary algorithm (DEAL) for aligning detailed schedules of several suppliers delivering to one manufacturer. In such a setting, production processes of the manufacturer cannot start until the suppliers have provided the necessary items. Being computed only shortly before execution, badly aligned detailed schedules most obviously demand a coordinated solution. Restricting to the limited scope of detailed scheduling allows to fulfill the above requirements to a degree acceptable for practical implementations. This work is organized as follows. Section 2 provides a brief summary of stateof-the-art CP approaches. In Sect. 3, the term “detailed scheduling” is further clarified by presenting the optimization problem underlying our further discussion. Section 4 introduces evolutionary algorithms. Section 5 presents the proprietary SAP metaheuristic to solve detailed scheduling problems – the so-called Production Planning and Detailed Scheduling (PP/DS) Optimizer. Building on this background, DEAL is presented in Section 6. Finally, we discuss experimental key results in Sect. 7 followed by concluding remarks in Sect. 8.
2 Literature Review on Collaborative Planning According to Stadtler (2007) Collaborative Planning (CP) can be defined as: . . . a joint decision making process for aligning plans of individual SC members with the aim of achieving coordination in light of information asymmetry.
Information asymmetry is a term stemming from game theory and describes the state where no SC member possesses all the information or preferences of other SC members. There exist several definitions for coordination, depending on the exact field of research. Roughly, literature can be divided into analytical and operational models. Analytical models employ very restrictive assumptions that allow a rigorous mathematical treatment. Here, coordination is often defined as optimal solution and Nash equilibrium. In contrast, the complexity of operational models might not even allow to numerically compute the optimal solution in reasonable time. Here, many authors speak of coordination, if the initial situation could be at least improved. The next two subsections provide a brief overview of the two approaches.
2.1
Analytical Models
Regarding analytical models, a large body of literature is concerned with multiechelon systems. Such a system includes several stages (e.g., representing supplier and manufacturer sites) to be coordinated.
460
J.B. Scheckenbach
Static multi-echelon systems rely on restrictive assumptions, such as static demand in a single-item, single-production-stage scenario and aim at finding the optimal trade-off between the holding and fixed-order costs. The difficulty lies in the assumption that different costs accrue for each echelon. For example, large orders might be beneficial to suppliers, because of potential savings in order processing costs. However, a manufacturer might prefer more frequent, smaller orders due to high inventory cost (cf. Bhatnagar and Chandra 1993). If the manufacturer is the more powerful party, the supplier’s problem is to persuade the manufacturer to change his order policy by making concessions such as price discounts or compensation payments. Reviews of contributions assuming complete information are provided by Goyal and Gupta (1989) and Thomas and Salhi (1998). Papers that explicitly deal with incomplete information include Sucky (2006), Fransoo et al. (2001), and Corbett and de Groote (2000). Stochastic multi-echelon systems assume a stochastic demand distribution, generally with negligible fixed-order costs; and are concerned with retrieving the optimal safety stock for a given service level. For a single stage facing stochastic demand, the optimal safety stock is a quantile of the demand distribution. Research dates back to 1960, with the paper of Clark and Scarf (1960) who derive an exact algorithm for a serial multi-echelon system. Diks et al. (1996) and van Houtum et al. (1996) give an overview about relevant literature since then. Also contract theory focuses on the analytical investigation of the relationship between a supplier and a buyer of a good. Most of the literature in contract theory is about determining optimal contract parameters given the functional form of a contract, cf. Cachon (2003). As a main result, multi-echelon systems and contract theory provide the insight that lower system-wide costs can be achieved if some SC members provide compensation payments to create incentives for other members to accept a coordinated solution. Auction theory analyzes price-settling mechanisms under pure market conditions. There exist two possibilities for applying an auction mechanism to SC planning. First, the SC partners can be determined by an auction. A typical example is the choice of third-party logistics providers. However, it is questionable if market conditions really exist within an SC: Here, the choice for partners is usually a strategic one, binding a manufacturer to a supplier for a longer time period, cf. Stadtler (2007). Second, auction mechanisms can be employed for choosing the best interorganizational plan out of a set of alternatives. The typical proceeding is that the auctioneer grasps total visibility of resources and sells resource capacity to competing bidding agents, representing, for example, different company divisions. A survey can be found in Wellman and Walsh (2001). Most research focuses on incentive compatibility. In an incentive compatible mechanism, players fare best when they truthfully reveal any private information requested, i.e. truth-telling is a dominant strategy (cf. Myerson 1979). Incentive compatibility can be achieved by introducing compensation payments demanding each player to pay the opportunity cost that his presence introduces to all the other players. Auction mechanisms only focus on the problem of selecting the optimal
DEAL: A Heuristic Approach for Collaborative Planning in Detailed Scheduling
461
production schedule but does not address the construction of candidate schedules under information asymmetry. A proposal on order quantities or delivery times can also be interpreted as a good offered from one SC member to the other. While each player knows his internal value of the good, he is assumed to have only limited information (in the form of a probability function) of his antagonist’s valuation. For such cases of information asymmetry, publications related to Bargaining theory analyze the efficiency of equilibrium strategies. Chatterjee and Samuelson (1983) provide such an analysis for a bilateral monopoly. Within a nonrecurring sealed-bid double auction, a buyer and a seller of an indivisible good simultaneously reveal their offers. If trading takes place (the buyer’s offer is higher than the seller’s claim) a settlement is computed according to an a priori known mechanism (e.g., by splitting the difference between both offers equally). Though the seller’s and buyer’s actual values of the good are assumed to be private knowledge, a probability distribution of likely values is supposed to be common knowledge. Being rational players, buyer and seller implement “best response strategies,” giving a price offer dependent on the own value and the counterpart’s probability distribution. These interlinked strategies lead to a Nash equilibrium. Related contributions have been put forward by Harsanyi and Selten (1972), Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983), Samuelson (1984), and Radoport and Fuller (1995). Bargaining theory provides interesting analytical insights into strategies leading to Nash equilibria and the related efficiency of the employed price-settlement mechanisms, i.e., the percentage of mutual beneficial agreements that can be actually attained by bargaining under the employed mechanism. However, most approaches assume the parties’ probability distributions of the value of the good to be public knowledge. It is questionable if this assumption can be justified for practical purposes. As auction theory, bargaining theory is not concerned how the good is created. In general, analytical models provide mathematical insight about optimal properties of coordination mechanisms, such as incentive compatibility. However, restrictive assumptions complicate a direct application to practical planning problems of an operational type.
2.2
Operational Models
In contrast to analytical models, operational models explicitly focus on generating production plans under information asymmetry. Using a metaheuristic, Fink (2004, 2006) investigates a supplier-manufacturer scenario where the sequence of delivery influences the quality of the related production plans. A central algorithm (assumed to be common knowledge) repeatedly proposes randomized delivery sequences to be accepted or rejected. The last jointly accepted delivery sequence is the final outcome of the coordination process. To sustain a fair outcome, both SC members are required to accept a certain percentage of the proposals, forcing them to also accept worse proposals.
462
J.B. Scheckenbach
The internal acceptance probabilities are calculated according to a cooling scheme taken from Simulated Annealing. Though proposing purely randomized delivery sequences by a third party can be considered as a very fair approach, it might be regarded as inefficient in a real-world environment, where evaluating each proposal takes a considerable amount of time due to the size of the problems. An important aspect of CP mechanisms is security. Security can be defined by means of a trusted mediator (cf. Li and Atallah 2006). Assume an idealized mechanism, where each SC member supplies sensitive information to the trusted mediator, the mediator solves the global problem and reports back the individual solutions without disclosing private information to other SC members. A mechanism is said to be secure if any adversary interacting in the real mechanism can do no more harm than in the ideal scenario. The idea of security can be illustrated by a simple example. Assume three parties A, B, and C and each party holding a stock of items, e.g., A has three items, B has five items and C has two items in stock. Suppose that the parties aim at computing the sum of items without revealing how much items each single party has in stock. A secure sum algorithm can be set up as follows. Party A adds a random number, say 7, to its stock and transmits the sum of 10 to B. B adds its five items and transmits the sum of 15 to C. In turn, C adds 2 and transmits the sum of 17 to A. Eventually, A subtracts the initial random number and the correct sum of stock, i.e. ten items, has been computed. However, no party knows the exact number of items of any other party. Similar, though more complex, secure multiparty algorithms are available for other algebraic operations and different number of parties. These algorithms can be regarded as “one-way functions,” functions that are easy to evaluate but hard to invert (cf. Yao 1982). In simple terms, each protocol takes shares of the input and produces shares of the output (cf. Kerschbaum and Deitos 2008). Each SC member can encrypt his input with a private key, such that it cannot be decrypted by other parties without the private key, whereas the function can still be evaluated despite the encrypted values. Li and Atallah (2006) present a decentralized secure Simplex method for two parties. Atallah et al. (2003) present secure allocation protocols that prevent a disclosure of bidders’ sensitive information during auctions. Being a sophisticated encryption method, secure multiparty computation itself is not incentive compatible and does not prevent users from supplying systematically biased input. Operational planning problems are often formulated as linear problems (LP) or mixed-integer linear problems (MILP) and the solution is computed by an LP/ MILP-solver. Lagrangian relaxation (LR) is a common decomposition technique (cf. Conejo et al. 2006; Williams 1999) for problems having a sparse coefficient matrix, where most of the non-zero coefficients can be ordered into a block-angular structure. Consider the linear programming problem min
x1 ;x2 ;...;xn
n X j¼1
cj xj
(1)
DEAL: A Heuristic Approach for Collaborative Planning in Detailed Scheduling n X
s.t:
dij xj b fi
8i ¼ 1; . . . ; q
463
(2)
j¼1 n X
aij xj ¼ bi
8i ¼ 1; . . . ; m
(3)
j¼1
0 b xj
8j ¼ 1; . . . ; n;
(4)
where constraints (2) have a decomposable structure in n blocks. In the particular case of n ¼ 2, the problem can be written as 0 1 x½1 T T @ A; c½1 j c½2 min x½1 ;x½2 x½2 where the superindices in brackets refer to partitions, subject to 0
D½1 B B B B @ A½1
1 j 0 ½1 1 b C C x @ A b j D½2 C C ½2 A x ¼ j A½2
1 f ½1 B C C B B f ½2 C: C B @ A b 0
The problem can be decomposed by “dualizing” the coupling constraints 3. That is, adding them to the objective function. The problem 1–4 can be rewritten as " max
l1 ;l2 ;...;lm
s.t:
n X
min
x1 ;x2 ;...;xn
dij xj b fi
n X j¼1
cj xj
m X i¼1
li bi
n X
!# aij xj
j¼1
8i ¼ 1; . . . ; q
j¼1
0 b xj 0 b li
8j ¼ 1; . . . ; n; 8i ¼ 1; . . . m
where l1, l2, . . ., lm denote the Lagrangian multipliers. The idea of LR is to iteratively solve the inner minimization problem while updating the multipliers until the procedure has converged to a satisfying solution. Since the inner problem has a true block-angular constraint structure, it can be partitioned accordingly and solved separately. Subgradient procedures are frequently used to iteratively increase multiplier values in proportion to their constraint violation in the primal problem.
464
J.B. Scheckenbach
Many SCM problems have a block-angular constraint matrix consisting of the intra-company constraints of each SC member, connected by inter-company material-flow-balance constraints. Subgradient methods only require realized material flows to update the multipliers, not the information of domain-internal production constraints. Hence, LR inherently supports scenarios with information asymmetry and is used by many authors to solve inter-company planning problems information asymmetry, cf. Kutanoglu and Wu (1999), Kutanoglu and Wu (2006), Ertogal and Wu (2000), Nie et al. (2006) and Walther et al. (2008). Multiplier values are dual information. Another possibility is to exchange primal information, target right-hand side (rhs) values for decision variables included in the coupling constraints, cf. Jung et al. (2005). Dudek and Stadtler (2005) decomposes the problem by fixing the material flow from a supplier and a manufacturer to certain values by setting the related rhs values. At the beginning, upstream planning is used to compute the initial “supply pattern.” Then the SC members alternatingly propose supply quantities and associated cost increases trying to compute reasonable proposals by approximating its antagonist’s cost changes within the local objective function. This is realized by penalizing the deviation from the currently confirmed supply quantities. The penalty coefficients are calculated on the basis of the antagonist’s cost reports. Thus, only effective proposals – that is, supply patterns with the highest trade-off of decrease of internal cost and increase of approximated “external” cost – are computed. After coordination, the worse-off player needs to be compensated by the player experiencing an improvement in its local objective function. Above approaches share the drawback that the adherence to imposed multipliers, rhs values or penalties cannot be monitored. An SC member can simply increase its local objective value by relaxing these bounds. Also the introduction of compensation payments does not necessarily ensure incentive compatibility. In a setting where the set of alternatives is already known to all players (as assumed for most analytical models), incentive compatibility in the sense of choosing the best interorganizational solution from a set of alternatives might be ensured by compensation payments. However, the situation is different if the reported values are also used for constructing new solutions. During construction, the future outcome of the search process is not determined yet. Thus, players are tempted to exaggerate their reported costs for receiving a higher compensation payment in order reap a good piece of the savings pie (as long they have the possibility for doing so). If an SC member reports exaggerated costs, its own objective gets a larger influence. At the end, those solutions will get explored that are, ceteris paribus, close to the locally optimal solution of the exaggerating domain obscuring the true global optimum with maximum saving. A possible solution to this problem is to decouple compensation payments from the coordination process. Albrecht (2010) suggests to compute a lumpsum (based on historical information) a priori to jointly constructing the solution. Under this premise the search process fosters truth telling of costs of intermediate solutions, since cheating obscures the true global optimum leading to an outcome where all partners are worse-off. For operational models of a certain structure, Albrecht
DEAL: A Heuristic Approach for Collaborative Planning in Detailed Scheduling
465
(2010) proves that his mechanism is able to attain the global optimum within a finite number of proposal exchanges. Summarizing the above literature, coordination mechanism must support complex planning problems of operational type under information asymmetry, must not lead to a disclosure of sensitive data and must be incentive compatible. The difficulty lies in equally considering all the three aspects: For example, multi-echelon systems and contract theory support incentive compatibility but require very restrictive assumptions and simplified models. Secure multiparty computation is able to deal with complex models but is not incentive compatible. With the exception of Albrecht (2010), this critique also holds for coordination schemes relating to mathematical decomposition techniques. Moreover, although critical information is not explicitly exchanged, operational mechanisms relying on cost reporting provide opportunistically acting players the possibility to infer sensitive data by systematically probing other SC members. Thus, even if the mechanisms do not directly require the exchange of sensitive data, they are insecure in protecting these data. Practical requirements introduce further difficulties. If we assume planning problems to be NP-hard, the solution with maximum global saving is not guaranteed to be found in a reasonable amount of time – violating a fundamental assumption of many incentive compatible mechanisms. Moreover, in most approaches, the value of each generated alternative is measured as the difference to an initial solution. However, SC members are usually not of equal power in practice. A powerful party might be tempted to create bad initial settings for the weaker parties if there is the possibility to gain future compensation payments from the weaker parties’ “cost decrease” through coordination. For example, a (powerful) manufacturer could initially order items very early, resulting in huge overtime costs for the supplier and additional storage costs for the manufacturer, whereas storage costs are assumed to be less than overtime costs. Now, the coordination mechanism will search for a solution that avoids these costs. In the example, it is likely that such a solution will be found (since the costs have been generated by purpose) and that the coordinated solution will come with a higher cost decrease for the supplier than for the manufacturer. Hence, if savings are split “fairly”, the supplier will have to compensate the manufacturer. Thus, the manufacturer used his power to generate an additional margin at the expense of his supplier. Concluding, even if a mechanism was incentive compatible given a set of assumptions, its application in practice might suffer from a violation of some of these assumptions. Furthermore, real-world optimization usually requires considerable fine-tuning of parameters and data belonging to a company’s specific optimization problem. It is likely that companies would not accept a coordination mechanism that required a major change of the parameters or even abandoned their long-time tested and approved planning system. Moreover, companies often have specific planning problems that cannot be tackled by out-of-the-box solutions. In practice, the landscape of optimization tools is hence very heterogeneous and several software companies compete with different optimization methods with proprietary intrafirm developments. Finding a real-world setting with homogeneous optimization tools is unlikely. Hence, the coordination mechanism should rather treat the underlying
466
J.B. Scheckenbach
solver as a black box. As will be discussed later, most models for production planning share commonalities in their structure. Our intention is to construct a coordination mechanism that dynamically changes the input data relating to common model structures but not the solver itself. Different solvers can then be supported by adapting the interface for changing the data.
3 The Resource-Constrained Project-Scheduling Problem The Resource-Constrained Project-Scheduling Problem (RCPSP) belongs to the class of NP-hard problems (cf. Blazewicz et al. 1983; Neumann et al. 2001) and represents a generalizations of different scheduling problems, such as job-shop or flow-shop problems. In our study, the RCPSP forms the underlying scheduling problem of each SC member. We present its basic problem definition below in order to provide the extension to collaborative planning in Sect. 6. We introduce the following definitions. The planning interval is defined as the 2 N0 consisting of several periods with a given discrete time interval ½0; . . . ; T period length (e.g., seconds), in which all activities start and end. An activity j refers to a single production activity (e.g., the assembly of parts). An activity has a start and a duration dj 0, defining the finish date fdj ¼ sdj + dj. date sdj 2 ½0; . . . ; T The set of all activities is referred to as J. Moreover, there exists a set R of renewable resources. Each resource r has a constant capacity of ar units that is renewed every period t ∈ T. When executed, an activity j places a constant resource usage ujr on resource r throughout its duration. The time for executing an activity is bounded by its release date rdj. The activities have to be executed in a predefined partial order, the so-called activity-precedence relation. For convenience, we introduce the sets Pj ¼ {i ∈ J | i is the immediate predecessor of j} and Sj ¼ {i ∈ J | i is the immediate successor of j}. An instance of the RCPSP is then given by • • • • •
A planning interval ½0; . . . ; T, A set of activities J, A set of renewable resources R, A precedence relation given by Pj or Sj for each activity j, respectively, The precedence and capacity constraints sdj r rdj sdj r fdi fdj ¼ sdj þ dj X j2Jjsdj b t b fdj
ujr b ar
8j 2 J
(5)
8j 2 J; i 2 Pj
(6)
8j 2 J
(7)
r2R 8t 2 ½0; . . . ; T;
• An objective function that shall be minimized or maximized.
(8)
DEAL: A Heuristic Approach for Collaborative Planning in Detailed Scheduling
467
4 Evolutionary Algorithms Because of the extensive run times of mixed integer approaches and their complex implementation, many researchers have turned to metaheuristics. The term metaheuristic usually describes a generic optimization principle that is widely applicable to many different problem domains. Very often, the basic idea behind a metaheuristic is inspired by nature. Evolutionary algorithms (EAs) are stochastic iterative optimization heuristics inspired by natural evolution. Starting with a set of candidate solutions (population), in each iteration (generation), promising solutions are selected as potential parents (mating selection), and new solutions (individuals) are constructed by mixing information from the parents (crossover) and slightly modifying them (mutation). The resulting offspring are then inserted into the population, replacing some old or less fit solutions (environmental selection). By continually selecting good solutions for reproduction and then creating new solutions based on the knowledge represented in the selected individuals, the solutions “evolve” and become better and better adapted to the problem to be solved, just like in nature, where the individuals become better and better adapted to their environment through the means of evolution. In line with Deb (2001), an EA can be outlined as follows, t 0 initialize population: P(t) evaluate P(t) repeat select mating pool: M(t) s(P(t)) c(M(t)) construct offspring: M0 (t) evaluate P(t) \ M0 (t) update: P(t + 1) u(P(t) \ M0 (t)) t t+1 until terminated, with t denoting the generation counter, P(t) the population at generation t, and s, c and u representing the different genetic operators for selection, construction and update. For a more detailed introduction to EAs, the reader is referred to Eiben and Smith (2003).
5 The SAP Production Planning and Detailed Scheduling Optimizer SAP offers the PP/DS Optimizer as proprietary tool to solve RCPSPs of extended complexity, including multiple modes, setup times, precedence relations with maximum time constrains, varying capacity profiles and different objectives. Here, the
468
J.B. Scheckenbach
above problem definition shall suffice. As objective we consider lateness minimization. In practice, soft-constrained due dates per activity ddj are often used to model customer preferences. In a simple way the objective can be put mathematically as Minimize
X
max fdj ddj ; 0 :
j2J
Due to the combinatorial complexity of the RCPSP, approaches for computing exact solutions (cf. Manne 1960; Blazewicz et al. 1996; Herroelen et al. 1998; Brucker and Knust 2000; Klein 2000; Neumann et al. 2001; Damay et al. 2007) are only applicable to small-sized problems of minor practical relevance. In line with the research of Hartmann and Kolisch (2000); Hartmann (2002); Alcaraz and Maroto (2001); Kolisch and Hartmann (2006), the PP/DS Optimizer employs an EA based on an activity sequence encoding and a serial schedule generation schemes (SSGS). An SGSS consists of |J| stages in each of which an activity is scheduled at the earliest precedence- and resource-feasible time. SSGS can be used to construct active schedules. Informally spoken, an active schedule is a schedule where no activity can be started earlier without delaying the start of another activity. It has been proved that for regular performance measures, such as lateness minimization, the optimal schedule lies within the set of all active schedules (cf. Sprecher et al. 1995; Neumann et al. 2001). Employing different SGSS as decoding functions, the PP/DS Optimizer uses several mutation and crossover operators to find the best sequence of activities. In other words, the search is not carried out in the space of all possible schedules (spanned by all start dates sdj not violating precedence and capacity constraints), but in the space of all sequences; using SGSS to evaluate the fitness of candidate sequences. Being a metaheuristic, the PP/DS Optimizer does not guarantee to find the optimal schedule. Thinking about compensation payments, it is hard to relate lateness to real monetary terms (cf. Stadtler 2005, p. 585). Especially on an operational level, machine-, workforce- and material-related costs are usually considered as sunk costs from an accountancy perspective. Using lateness costs, we primarily aim at seeking schedules that make optimal use of the available resources. As a detailed discussion of the PP/DS Optimizer would be beyond the scope of this paper, the interested reader is referred to Engelmann (1998) and Scheckenbach (2010). Earliness as a non-regular performance measure precludes the use of SSGS; the optimal schedule no longer lies within the set of all active schedules. However, from a practical point of view, the minimization of earliness is important to reduce holding costs. The strategy is then to modify the schedule constructed by SSGS in a subsequent right-alignment step. We define a right-aligned schedule as a schedule where no activity can be finished later without advancing some other activity, or violating the constraints, or increasing the objective function. Right-alignment considers activities from “right” to “left” (relating to their positions in a Gantt chart) and shifts each activity to the latest possible date. Also SAP provides a rightalignment algorithm.
DEAL: A Heuristic Approach for Collaborative Planning in Detailed Scheduling
469
6 DEAL: A Decentral Evolutionary Algorithm This section presents a decentral evolutionary algorithm (DEAL) for aligning detailed schedules of n suppliers and one manufacturer. The algorithm works decentrally in the sense that a top-level evolutionary algorithm iteratively changes local problem instances that are solved locally and separately by the PP/DS Optimizer of each SC member. By doing this, each SC members evolves a population of candidate schedules. The top-level metaheuristic controls the composition of local schedules to global feasible schedules and the evolution of local populations, without demanding the exchange of sensitive data. We start by formulating the interorganizational problem in Subsection 6.1. Subsections 6.2 and 6.3 are about constructing candidate solutions. A solution relates to a composition of local schedules, feasible from an SC-wide perspective. In Subsection 6.4 we address the evaluation of solutions, the selection of the mating pool and the update of the population. Subsection 6.5 presents means to further speed up the search process.
6.1
The Interorganizational Problem
We assume each SC member having its unique set of resources. We further assume the activities between the different SC members to be connected by precedence constraints. That is, some activities of the manufacturer can only be started after the suppliers’ preceding activities have been finished, neglecting transportation times. Moreover, we assume that there is no cyclic dependency between the SC members. Thats is, neither suppliers nor manufacturer deliver to other suppliers taking part in coordination. Nevertheless, suppliers and manufacturer might delivery to external sinks and might be supplied by external sources, not participating in coordination. We extend our previous RCPSP formulation by defining • ddj as static, non-varying due date of activity j relating to external sinks, • rdj as static, non-varying release date of activity j relating to external sources, • e as index of an SC member (agreeing on the notation that the manufacturer is e ¼ 0 and suppliers are e > 0) and E as the set of all SC members, • Je J as the set of activities j of SC member e, Je, • Re as the set of resources r of e, • Pej as the set of predecessors within the problem of SC member e, • Sej as set of successors within the problem of SC member e, activities directly depending • JU0 as the set of manufacturer’s upstream-related on the suppliers’ delivery, i.e. JU0 ¼ j 2 J 0 j9i 2 J e ^ i 2 Pej with e 2 Enf0g , activities directly influencing • JDe as the set of supplier e’s downstream-related the manufacturer’s problem, i.e. JDe ¼ j 2 J e j9i 2 J 0 ^ i 2 S0j .
470
J.B. Scheckenbach
We assume the set of all jobs to be distributed between the SC members e, i.e. 8e 2 E : J e J; [ J e ¼ J; e2E
8e; f 2 E; e 6¼ f : J e \ J f ¼ ;: The same is true for resources. The intra-company RCPSPs of supplier and manufacturer interlink as follows. Finish dates of suppliers and static, nonvarying, release dates rdj determine the manufacturer’s release dates; expressed by including the following equations in the manufacturer’s RCPSP formulation. ( ) rdj ¼ max
max
k2Pej ;e2Enf0g
ðfdk Þ; rdj
8j 2 JU0
(9)
A supplier’s due dates of downstream-relating activities are defined by ( ddj ¼ min
min ðpdk Þ; ddj k2S0j
) 8j 2 JDe ; e 2 Enf0g;
(10)
where pdk denote proposed dates, send by the manufacturer to the supplier during coordination.
6.2
Initialization
During initialization, the manufacturer proposes dates that “myopically” optimize his intradomain problem. To do this, all release dates rdj are first set to their static, non-varying values rdj . Based on this relaxed problem, the manufacturer applies the PP/DS Optimizer for a predefined amount of time, resulting in a solution consisting of start dates sdj and finish dates fdj, j ∈ J0. The proposed dates pdj are then derived from the manufacturer’s related right-aligned schedule. Each supplier receives those proposed dates relating to his scheduling problem. The suppliers translate the proposed dates into downstream-related due dates using Equations 10, apply the PP/DS Optimizer to solve their own scheduling problems and report the realized finish dates back to the manufacturer. Applying (9), the manufacturer in turn converts these finish dates into upstream-related release dates and recalculates his schedule once again using the PP/DS Optimizer. The outcome is a feasible, though suboptimal, SC-wide schedule. After the above procedure, remaining candidates are computed according to the principles discussed in the next section, until the initial population has reached its size. Note that the strategy “propose everything as early as possible” does not provide an initial advantage to the manufacturer, since the suppliers’ capacity is limited
DEAL: A Heuristic Approach for Collaborative Planning in Detailed Scheduling
471
(the RCPSP does not provide an option for overtime). Rather than absolute values, relative trade-offs between the proposed dates communicate the manufacturer’s preferences.
6.3
Construction
The construction of a new candidate solution is done analogously to initialization with the difference that the manufacturer tries to compute promising proposed dates based on the current population. To sustain an evolutionary process, the manufacturer should only change the most conflicting dates, otherwise construction would be similar to initialization. Different operators have been studied on the basis of this general idea. In the following, we will highlight a few examples, a detailed discussion can be found in Scheckenbach (2010). Proposed dates can be calculated by propagating the manufacturer’s due dates to upstream-related activities by means of backward passes. A backward pass propagates the upper bounds from the end of the horizon backward starting with pddn ¼ ddn : for j ¼ jJ 0 j; . . . ; 1; pddj ¼ min ddj ; min pddh dh jh 2 Sj where the manufacturers activities are assumed to be numbered according to a topological sorting (i.e. i < j, if i ∈ Pj, and pddj denotes the propagated due date. Proposed dates are then calculated as pdj ¼ pddj dj ; 8j 2 JU0 . Dates calculated by backward passes communicate the manufacturer’s minimal requirements (neglecting capacity constraints) to the suppliers. For most coordination problems, this strategy is too simple, since bottlenecks arise because of limited capacity and suboptimal activity sequences. An alternative is to generate an intermediate problem instance i by partially relaxing release dates in the manufacturer’s problem. By applying the PP/DS Optimizer to the intermediate instance, the manufacturer searches for better sequences of activities. The proposed dates are then derived from the start dates of the related right-aligned schedule. One possibility to calculate the set of release dates to relax is to take the history of coordination into account. With respect to an existing solution p, we define ðpÞ ðpÞ ðpÞ ðpÞ the amount of correction of activity j 2 JU0 as Dj ¼ rdj pdj , whereas rdj denotes the release date that results from the suppliers counterproposals ðpÞ (cf. Equation 9) to the proposed date pdj during constructing of solution p. The ðpÞ amount of correction Dj measures the suppliers’ ability to fulfill the manuðpÞ facturer’s proposals. Note that Dj can also become negative if a supplier exceeds the manufacturer’s requirements. Intuitively, a further relaxation of release dates of activities with a large positive amount of correction is not promising, as at least one of the suppliers is apparently not able to fulfill the resulting proposed dates. Instead ðpÞ we restrict the critical set to those activities with a low Dj . For the first a percent of
472
J.B. Scheckenbach ðpÞ
ðiÞ
activities with low Dj we set rdj ¼ rdj and for the remaining 1 a percent ðpÞ ðiÞ ðpÞ with high Dj we set rdj ¼ sdj . Lateness to ultimate customers is then reduced by applying the PP/DS Optimizer to the relaxed problem instance. The proposed dates are derived from the start dates of the subsequently right-aligned schedule, whereas right-alignment is not allowed to increase lateness, as discussed in Sect. 5. Another possibility is to shift weakly connected components. Imagine an undirected graph, where activities define the nodes and precedence relations the edges. Usually, this graph can be decomposed into several disjunct weakly connected components. Relaxing release dates of all activities belonging to the same component might have a larger effect on the lateness criterion than doing so for arbitrary selected activities. For each component C J, the maximum difference between finish date and propagated due date is computed as ðpÞ ðpÞ mdC ¼ max fdj pddj : j2C
We might aim at relaxing the release dates of the “most-delayed” activities contained in the first ba nC c components with largest maximum difference, where nC is the total number of components and a a further tuning parameter (the symbol b:c denotes the floor function). Crossover uses the information of several existing candidates to derive new proposed dates. For example, linear crossover can be used to compute proposed dates as ðpÞ
ðqÞ
rdj þ rdj ; 8j 2 JU0 ; pdj ¼ 2
(11)
where q and p denote two existing solutions from the mating pool. Instead of the former release dates, also proposed dates might be combined. Concluding, constructing a solution always takes the preferences of all SC members into account. First, the manufacturer proposes dates to the suppliers representing his most demanded corrections to an existing schedule. Second, the suppliers incorporate the manufacturer’s preferences into their objective function by adapting their downstream-related due dates, cf. Equation 10. However, the suppliers are not forced to comply to the manufacturer’s proposal and the SC-wide solution is based on their counterproposal. In particular, suppliers might not agree to delay any external customer. This goal can be expressed by giving the related delay a larger weight in the lateness objective before the start of coordination.
6.4
Evaluation, Selection and Update
Evaluating a candidate set of solutions is critical for advancing in the right search direction. In our approach, evaluating refers to the task of ranking the different SC-wide schedules in order to remove worst ones from the population and for
DEAL: A Heuristic Approach for Collaborative Planning in Detailed Scheduling
473
selecting the mating pool. Following the above discussion this ranking scheme must support incentive compatibility, at least from a practical perspective. If compensation payments are not taken into account, we refer to a coordination mechanism as practically incentive compatible if it does not put any SC member worse than in the initial, uncoordinated setting. However, such a deterioration is not necessarily measured by the objective function. Costs of a supplier can be decomposed into coordination-related and domain-related costs. Coordination-related costs are penalty costs resulting from the violation of due dates proposed by the manufacturer. Since these costs mainly anticipate the manufacturer’s decision problem, they cannot be claimed by the supplier in an accountancy sense.1 Hence, in addition to the objective function of the local optimization method, a supplier might have another evaluation function representing his preferences regarding the manufacturer’s proposals. A simple, practical evaluation function distinguishes between acceptable and unacceptable solutions. Unacceptable solutions result from a setting of due dates that leave a supplier’s local optimization method too little freedom to produce acceptable results. We define ue ðpÞ ¼
0; if the proposal p is acceptable, z 2 N; if the proposal p is not acceptable:
Integer z denotes a ranking of unacceptable solutions. The smaller z, the better the related solution from a supplier’s perspective. For each solution, the suppliers submit their ranking to the manufacturer. After having computed his ranking in a similar manner, the manufacturer can combine the single ratings by non-dominated sorting. Solution p is said to dominate q, if 8e 2 E : ue ðpÞ b ue ðqÞ and 9d 2 E : ue ðpÞ < ue ðqÞ: Non-dominated sorting clusters the population into subsets dominating each other. This allows to construct a global ranking g, i.e. individuals that are not dominated by other individuals get a g ¼ 1, individuals with g ¼ 2 are only dominated by individuals with g ¼ 1 and so on. Having this information, the manufacturer decides which solutions to select in the mating pool and which to remove from the population. Although he is free in his single decisions, the ultimate solution to be implemented is required to be accepted by all suppliers, i.e. 8e 2 Enf0g : ue ðpÞ ¼ 0. In each generation, m offspring are created out of a population of l individuals. An offspring is created by either applying a mutation or crossover operator. An individual to be mutated is chosen by tournament selection, cf. Deb (2001). That is, two individuals are randomly drawn from the parent generation, and the one with better ranking wins the 1
Nevertheless, coordination-related costs are in direct relation to domain-related costs. For example, setting a due date earlier might result in a solution with higher lateness of other orders of external clients.
474
J.B. Scheckenbach
tournament. The two individuals required for crossover are determined analogously by two tournaments. After constructing the offspring, the manufacturer sorts all individuals according to their global ranking. The manufacturer removes the worst m individuals from the population (environmental selection) and transmits this information to the suppliers who update their local populations accordingly. The above ranking has three advantages. First, the transmission of ordinal rankings disguises objective values considered as sensitive by the suppliers. The manufacturer has only limited possibilities for probing the suppliers to infer sensitive data. Although he knows that a solution is regarded by a supplier as better or worse than another solution, he does not know how much better or worse it is. Second, the dimensionality is reduced. The search process is not driven in dimensions were solutions are already acceptable for some suppliers (having a ranking of zero) but a multiobjective Goal Programming approach, as discussed in Deb (2001), is implemented instead. Third, and most important, suppliers have only limited possibilities for cheating. No suppliers can influence the trade-off between the local objectives by exaggerating his values, as such a trade-off does not exist in non-dominated sorting. Of course, suppliers can label actually acceptable solutions as unacceptable – but that is something they already can do today by reporting that present delivery dates cannot be maintained. In general, we assume that suppliers try to comply to delivery dates to the extent possible, as their status of being a reliable partner depends on it. Thus, we are tempted to label DEAL as a practically incentive compatible mechanism (however, not in a mathematical sense).
6.5
Means to Speed Up the Search Process
This section discusses means to further speed up the search process. First, the above coordination mechanism is characterized by periodic idle times. Suppliers wait for new manufacturer’s proposals to counter. Similarly, the manufacturer waits for counterproposal before the construction of a solution is continued. Today, computational power is a relatively cheap expense. As the single solutions are independent of each other, the coordination can be parallelized, allowing the manufacturer to compute several proposals in parallel, without waiting for counterproposals. Note that in such an environment the term generation becomes elusive – the focus is instead on a high workload in the systems. In contrast to classic EAs, individuals have different states. Intuitively, selection, construction and update operators can only be applied to the set of “complete” individuals. Second, a “warm reboot” was established. In a standard PP/DS run, different heuristics compute the initial activity sequences (e.g., the activities are sorted according to their propagated due dates). As DEAL holds a population of schedules, information of previous local PP/DS runs are available, however. Hence, we added the sequence of each schedule in the population to the set of initial standard sequences. Depending on the chosen due or release dates of the new offspring
DEAL: A Heuristic Approach for Collaborative Planning in Detailed Scheduling
475
this information might not prove useful and is sorted out during environmental selection of the PP/DS run. However, if the problem instances vary only slightly, using existing activity sequences avoids a computation “from scratch” and gives good results already at the beginning of the PP/DS run. Third, a self-adaption of operators for generating proposals can be set up. We regard the decision of selecting an operator as a dynamically changing optimization problem. For each operator o, we define a value to. The probability for choosing operator o out of the set of all operators O is computed as t Po : to o2O
After an operator has been applied, all values are decreased by a factor d ∈ (0;1), to d, 8o ∈ O. If an operator has been applied successfully (the child c is i.e. to better globally ranked than the parent p, its value increases by the relative ranking improvement: to
to þ
gðpÞ gðcÞ : gðpÞ
The value to can be interpreted as pheromone value in an ant-colonization optimization approach, cf. Merkle et al. (2002). Fourth, redundant computations are avoided. After deriving proposed dates for offspring c, the following redundancy checks apply: If another individual p in the manufacturer’s population exists, that is accepted by all suppliers (ne ðpÞ ¼ 0; 8e 2 ðpÞ ðcÞ Enf0g) with rdj b pdj ; 8j 2 JU0 , the manufacturer discards solution c immediately and does not transmit the proposed dates to the suppliers. After an individual has passed the first check, a second check is carried out by each supplier. For supplier e, an individual c is redundant, if there exists a local candidate schedule ðpÞ ðcÞ p with ne(p) ¼ 0 and ddj b ddj ; 8j 2 JDe . In such a case, the supplier skips the local PP/DS run and counterproposes again the release dates of individual p. Each supplier stores the information how manufacturer proposals relate to local schedules in a table. Obviously, this table has to be looked up for computing the correct ranks and needs to be adapted if the manufacturer transmits which individuals are to be deleted.
7 Experimental Key Results The description of DEAL and the SAP PP/DS Optimizer in the above sections were very limited due to the scope of this contribution. With this background a detailed discussion of experimental results would be a futile endeavor. Hence, this section
476
J.B. Scheckenbach
aims at a high-level presentation of key results only. More details are provided in Scheckenbach (2010). Two test data generators were used. The first one models the common procedure in practice. Given periodic demand patterns, available Bill-of-Materials, related resource capacity requirements and fixed lot sizes, a material requirements planning (MRP) algorithm calculates number and length of required production activities, precedence constraints and resource utilization. Usually the MRP run generates several lots to satisfy total demand of a finished good. As solely one Bill-ofMaterial per finished good is available, the generated activities show a repetitive structure akin to flow shop problems. The second test data generator is based on the work of Kolisch et al. (1992, 1995). Adding activity by activity, an algorithm randomly constructs an activity network and also randomly chooses the length, the resource requirements and the due dates of each activity. Restricting these decisions to be within certain bounds results in a test instance with predefined complexity measures. Having created a test instance by using one of the above generators, it is divided into the interconnected subinstances belonging to the different SC members. The division is carried out on the basis of a predefined assignment of resources to SC members. By respecting this assignment already during the generation of a test instance we assure that no cyclic dependency results between the different SC members (as assumed in Sect. 6.1). Independent of the chosen test data generator, the above procedure results in one fractioned test instance for the coordination mechanism and one integral benchmark instance to be “centrally” solved by a single PP/DS Optimizer. Several runs for different test instances with up to 10,000 activities have been carried out systematically to increase statistical confidence. Although the coordination mechanism has to cope with information asymmetry, neither a deterioration in solution quality nor run time could be observed with regard to the “central” solution. Several factors contributed to this result. First, proposed dates imply certain tradeoffs in the local optimization problem. Rather than the dates’ absolute values, these tradeoffs steer the local optimization methods. Hence, a crude alignment of delivery dates by DEAL seems to be sufficient – the exact setting of delivery dates is done subsequently by the local optimization methods themselves. Second, DEAL can be regarded as a decomposition method working problems that exhibit specific properties. For example, there are no cyclic dependencies between suppliers and manufacturer. It can be argued that DEAL makes use of these problem structures but not the generic PP/DS Optimizer. Third, the “warm reboot” property carries over information between several solutions. Avoiding an initialization from scratch allows to shorten runtimes of the locally applied PP/DS Optimizer without deteriorating the solution quality. In turn, shorter local runtimes allow more proposals to be exchanged. Due to the combinatorial complexity of the RCPSP, a frequent exchange of proposals is advantageous. Moreover it was observed that the warm reboot gets more effective as the process converges to a good setting of proposed or release dates, as previous activity sequences better fit to an offspring problem instance. Thus, the warm reboot
DEAL: A Heuristic Approach for Collaborative Planning in Detailed Scheduling
477
supports the seamless shift from the strategy “try as much proposed dates as possible” at the beginning of coordination to the strategy “generate the best schedules for a fixed setting of proposed dates” towards the end of coordination. Fourth, even for larger problem instances a good coordinated solution was found in reasonable time. Although complexity increases, larger problem instances usually allow more freedom of rescheduling, i.e., a crude alignment of proposed dates suffices. Moreover, larger problem instances apparently come with a greater probability that large parts of previous activity sequences can be used for the warm reboot. Fifth, it could be observed that larger population sizes lead to better results. This is a common property of EAs: Larger populations have a better chance of overcoming local optima, at the cost of a slower convergence, however. By computing and evaluating proposals in parallel, DEAL allows larger population sizes without prolonging runtime. To further clarify the test methodology, Fig. 1 exemplary shows the results for a medium-sized test instance, also including multiple modes and setup times. Two suppliers deliver to one manufacturer, but also have other customers that should not be harmed by coordination.2 The convergence of the centrally applied PP/DS Optimizer is shown by the solid graph.3 The graph shows the average delay of 700000
central, monolithic solution sequential coordination parallel coordination
sum of no-priority lateness
650000 600000 550000 500000 450000 400000 350000 300000 250000
1000
2000
3000 4000 5000 runtime in seconds
6000
7000
Fig. 1 Exemplary results of a test instance with more than 2,700 activities in total, two suppliers and one manufacturer. Shown is the lateness to the manufacturer’s ultimate customers of central and coordination solutions, average of 10 runs each
2 Cf. Scheckenbach (2010), par. 8.2.2.1 and 8.2.2.4 for a detailed description of the underlying business problem. 3 The initial 500 s are required for problem generation and initialization.
478
J.B. Scheckenbach
deliveries from the manufacturer to ultimate customers of ten different runs and of each run’s best-found solution at a specific point in time. It can be seen that the fitness of the initial population is gradually improved each generation, although the speed of improvement declines. The dashed graphs show the result of sequential and parallel coordination, respectively. An additional idle time can be observed required for the construction of the initial coordinated solution. For computing and evaluating a proposal, each partner runs his PP/DS Optimizer for 50 s. It should be highlighted that the graphs do not show the convergence of a local PP/DS run within these 50 s, but only the results of coordination, which explains the rather step-wise convergence. In order to compute acceptable solutions both suppliers prioritize the lateness to external customers in their local objective (cf. Sect. 6.3). Additionally the double-ranking scheme of Sect. 6.4 was implemented. Hence, improving acceptability can lead to a temporary increase in the lateness to the manufacturer’s customers (only the latter figure is drawn). It is worth mentioning, that all approaches led to acceptable solutions in the end of all runs, although the initial situation was not always accepted by the suppliers. Finally and most surprisingly, it can be seen that the parallel coordination (also employing a larger population size) does not only show better performance than the sequential coordination, but was also able to beat the central solution. It seems that the DEAL framework as a top-level metaheuristic was able to introduce new information that steered the overall search process in the right manner. Adjusting the due dates of the suppliers’ RCPSP instances by an evolutionary process and repeatedly solving these sub problems finally led to the good results. One might argue that the above results do not prove the effectiveness of DEAL but only the ineffectiveness of the PP/DS Optimizer. This is not true. First of all, it has to be mentioned that, for NP-hard planning problems, an optimal solution can usually not be computed in reasonable time. Moreover, one has to keep in mind that the PP/DS Optimizer was constructed to tackle RCPSPs of general type. For evaluating DEAL, we only consider a subset of all possible scheduling problems: problems, that exhibit regions that are only interdependent in a noncyclic manner. DEAL can be regarded as a specialized heuristic working on such problem structures. Hence, by decomposing the central scheduling problem, more detailed knowledge over the subproblems becomes available. According to the No Free Lunch Theorem of computer science, we have to expect that the results of a specialized heuristic are better than those of a general one.
8 Concluding Remarks When designing a coordination mechanism, three fundamental requirements have to be considered: Complex planning problems have to be supported, sensitive data must not be disclosed and incentive compatibility has to be guaranteed. To ensure the latter, most present approaches rely on compensation payments, payments made in an agreement by one or more parties to other parties to induce them to join the
DEAL: A Heuristic Approach for Collaborative Planning in Detailed Scheduling
479
agreement. Though this idea seems to be logical at first sight, compensation payments are not without problems. As argued, such payments may – if not properly designed within the mechanism – provide possibilities for cheating and probing the other partner to infer sensitive information instead of preventing them from doing so. The presented heuristic restricts to generating ultimate solutions that are acceptable to all SC members without compensation payments. Naturally, this decision prunes the search space, possibly making the global optimum unattainable. However, it is questionable if this is considered as a drawback from a practical point of view. Usually, compensation payments are hardly deducible from control costs of objective functions and for many practical problems the optimal solution is usually not attained anyway. Practical acceptability adds further requirements: The mechanism should handle multiple domains, different optimization engines and different optimization models. It should be scalable to large problems and able to handle degraded, suboptimal solutions. Moreover, due to the limited time before escalation, short-term scheduling most urgently demands coordination. We believe EAs to be the logical choice under such conditions. They are not restricted to a particular type of problem requiring only a black-box fitness computation and are, as a population-based approach, easy to parallelize. Essentially, the idea is to adjust the data of underlying planning problems by an evolutionary process, using local optimization engines for decoding. As only the local data, but not the related optimization models are changed, different optimization engines can be connected to our framework. With regard to detailed scheduling, most practically used heuristics build up on release and due dates. If the possibility of a warm reboot is given, many proposals can be exchanged as well. For evaluating different proposals, we disguised sensitive data and limited possibilities for cheating by transmitting only ordinal rankings (reflecting a proposal’s quality) between the partners. Concluding, we claim that DEAL fulfills the three requirements complexity, security and incentive compatibility – at least from a practical perspective.
References Albrecht M (2010) Supply chain coordination mechanisms. In: Lecture notes in economics and mathematical systems. Springer, Heidelberg Alcaraz J, Maroto C (2001) A robust genetic algorithm for resource allocation in project scheduling. Ann Oper Res 102:83–109 Atallah MJ, Deshpande V, Elmongui HG, Schwarz LB (2003) Secure supply-chain protocols. In: Proceedings of the IEEE International Conference on E-Commerce Bhatnagar R, Chandra P (1993) Models for multi-plant coordination. Eur J Oper Res 67:141–160 Blazewicz J, Domschke W, Pesch E (1996) The job shop scheduling problem: conventional and new solution techniques. Eur J Oper Res 93:1–33 Blazewicz J, Lenstra J, Rinnoy Kan AH (1983) Scheduling projects to resource constraints: classification and complexity. Discrete Appl Math 5:11–24
480
J.B. Scheckenbach
Brucker P, Knust S (2000) A linear programming and constraint propagationbased lower bound for the rcpsp. Eur J Oper Res 127:355–362 Cachon GP (2003) Supply chain coordination with contracts, Volume 11 of Handbooks in operations research and management science: Supply Chain Management, Chap. 6. NorthHolland, pp. 229–340 Chatterjee K, Samuelson W (1983) Bargaining under incomplete information. Oper Res 31(5):835–851 Clark AJ, Scarf H (1960) Optimal policies for a multi-echelon inventory problem. Manage Sci 6(4):475–490 Conejo AJ, Castillo E, Minguez R, Garcia-Bertrand R (2006) Decomposition techniques in mathematical programming. Springer, Berlin Corbett CJ, de Groote X (2000) A supplier’s optimal quantity discount policy under asymmetric information. Manage Sci 46(3):444–450 Damay J, Quilliot A, Sanlaville E (2007) Linear programming based algorithms for preemptive and non-preemptive rcpsp. Eur J Oper Res 182:1012–1022 Deb K (2001) Multi-objective optimization using evolutionary algorithms. Wiley, New York, NY Diks EB, de Kok AG, Lagodimos LAG (1996) Multi-echelon systems: a service measure perspective. Eur J Oper Res 95:241–263 Dudek G, Stadtler H (2005) Negotiation-based collaborative planning between supply chain partners. Eur J Oper Res 163:668–687 Eiben A, Smith J (2003) Introduction to evolutionary computing. Springer, Heidelberg Engelmann T (1998) Prozessflussoptimierung mit evolutionaeren algorithmen. Master’s thesis, Institut fuer angewandte Informatik und formale Beschreibungsverfahren, Universitaet Karlsruhe (TH) Ertogal K, Wu DS (2000) Auction-theoretic coordination of production planning in the supply chain. IIE Trans 32(10):931–940 Fink A (2004) Supply chain coordination by means of automated negotiations. In: Proceedings of the 37th Hawaii International Conference on System Science Fink A (2006) Multiagent based supply chain management, Chapter Supply chain coordination by means of automated negotiations between autonomous agents. pp 351–372 Fransoo JC, Wouters MJF, de Kok TG (2001) Multi-echelon multi-company inventory planning with limited information exchange. J Oper Res Soc 52:830–838 Goyal SK, Gupta YP (1989) Integrated inventory modelas: the buyer-vendor coordination. Eur J Oper Res 41:261–269 Harsanyi JC, Selten R (1972) A generalized nash solution for two-person bargaining games with incomplete information. Mangement Sci 18(5):80–106 Hartmann S (2002) A self-adapting genetic algorithm for project scheduling under resource constraints. Nav Res Logist 49:433–448 Hartmann S, Kolisch R (2000) Experimental evaluation of state-of-the-art heuristics for the resource-constrained project scheduling problem. Eur J Oper Res 127:394–407 Herroelen W, De Reyck B, Demeulemeester E (1998) Resource-constrained project scheduling: a survey of recent developments. Comput Oper Res 25(4):279–302 Jung H, Frank CF, Jeong B (2005) A production-distribution coordination model for third party logistics partnership. In: IEEE International Conference on Automated Science and Engineering Kerschbaum F, Deitos RJ (2008) Security against the business partner. In: Proceedings of the 2008 ACM workshop on Secure web services. Klein R (2000) Scheduling of resource-constrained projects. Kluwer, The Netherlands Kolisch R, Hartmann S (2006) Experimental investigation of heuristics for resource-constrained project scheduling: an update. Eur J Oper Res 174:23–37 Kolisch R, Sprecher A, Drexl A (1992) Characterization and generation of a general class of resource-constrained project scheduling problems. Technical Report 301, Insititut fr Betriebswirtschaftslehre, Universitt Kiel, Germany
DEAL: A Heuristic Approach for Collaborative Planning in Detailed Scheduling
481
Kolisch R, Sprecher A, Drexl A (1995) Characterization and generation of a general class of resource-constrained project scheduling problems. Manage Sci 41:1693–1703 Kutanoglu E, Wu SD (1999) On combinatorial auction and lagrangean relaxation for distributed resource scheduling. IIE Trans 31:813–826 Kutanoglu E, Wu SD (2006) Incentive compatible, collaborative production scheduling with simple communication among distributed agents. Int J Prod Res 44(3):421–446 Li J, Atallah M (2006) Secure and private collaborative linear programming. In: International conference on collaborative computing: networking, applications and worksharing Manne AS (1960) On the job-shop scheduling problem. Oper Res 8(2):219–223 Merkle D, Middendorf M, Schmeck H (2002) Ant colony optimization for resource constrained project scheduling. IEEE Trans Evol Comput 6(4):333–346 Myerson RB (1979) Incentive compatibility. Econometrica 47(1):61–73 Myerson RB, Satterthwaite MA (1983) Efficient mechanisms for bilateral trading. J Econ Theory 29:265–281 Neumann K, Schwindt C, Zimmermann J (2001) Project scheduling with time windows and scarce resources. Springer, Heidelberg Nie L, Xu X, Zhan D (2006) Collaborative planning in supply chains by lagrangian relaxation. In: Proceedings of the First International multi-symposiums on computer and computational science Radoport A, Fuller MA (1995) Bidding strategies in a bilateral monopoly with two-sided incomplete information. J Math Psychol 39:179–196 Samuelson W (1984) Bargaining under asymmetric information. Econometrica 52(4):995–1005 Scheckenbach B (2010) Collaborative planning in detailed scheduling. Ph.D thesis, University of Hamburg Sprecher A, Kolisch R, Drexl A (1995) Semi-active, active and non-delay schedules for the resource-constrained project-scheduling problem. Eur J Oper Res 80:94–102 Stadtler H (2005) Supply chain management and advanced planning – basics, overview and challenges. Eur J Oper Res 163:575–588 Stadtler H (2007) A framework for collaborative planning and state-of-the-art. OR Spectrum 31:5–30 Sucky E (2006) A bargaining model with asymmetric information for a single supplier-single buyer problem. Eur J Oper Res 171:516–533 Thomas PR, Salhi S (1998) A tabu search algorithm for the resource constrained project scheduling problem. J Heuristics 4:123–139 van Houtum GJ, Inderfurth K, Zijm WHM (1996) Materials coordination in stochastic multiechelon systems. Eur J Oper Res 95:1–23 Walther G, Schmid E, Spengler TS (2008) Negotiation based coordination in product recovery. J Prod Econ 111(2):334–350 Wellman MP, Walsh WE (2001) Auction protocols for decentralized scheduling. Game Econ Behav 35:271–303 Williams HP (1999) Model building in mathematical programming, 4th edn. Wiley, New York Yao A (1982) Protocols for secure computation. In: Proceedings of the 23rd Annual IEEE Symposium on Foundations of Computer Science
.
Inventory Record Inaccuracy, RFID Technology Adoption and Supply Chain Coordination H. Sebastian Heese
Abstract Most retailers suffer from substantial discrepancies between inventory quantities recorded in the system and stocks truly available to customers. Promising full inventory transparency, RFID technology has often been suggested as a remedy to this problem. We consider inventory record inaccuracy in a supply chain model, where a Stackelberg manufacturer sets the wholesale price and a retailer determines how much to stock for sale to customers. We first analyze the impact of inventory record inaccuracy on optimal stocking decisions and profits. Contrasting optimal decisions in a decentralized supply chain with those in an integrated supply chain, we find that inventory record inaccuracy exacerbates the inefficiencies resulting from double marginalization in decentralized supply chains. Assuming that RFID technology can eliminate the problem of inventory record inaccuracy, we determine the cost thresholds at which RFID adoption becomes profitable. We show that a decentralized supply chain benefits more from RFID technology, such that RFID adoption improves supply chain coordination. Keywords Inventory • Record inaccuracy • RFID • Supply chain coordination
1 Introduction The discrepancy between inventory records and the amount of product effectively available for sale to customers presents a key problem in retail operations. Based on extensive empirical studies, Raman et al. (2001) report they found 65% of inventory This chapter is based on the article “Inventory record inaccuracy, double marginalization and RFID adoption” by H.S. Heese, published 2007 in Production and Operations Management (volume 16, issue 5, pages 542–553). H.S. Heese Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, 1309 East Tenth Street, Bloomington, IN 47405, USA e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_19, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
483
484
H.S. Heese
records to be erroneous, i.e., the recorded inventory quantity did not match the quantity present at the store. Physical inventory deviated from inventory records by 35% on average, and about 16% of the product physically present at the store was not readily available to customers due to SKU misplacement. Transaction or scanning errors present yet another source of inventory record inaccuracies – all too often cashiers at the checkout use the number key to aggregate products with different flavors but the same price. Raman et al. (2001) conclude that “most retailers cannot, with any degree of precision, identify the number of units of a given item available at a store.” Since even the most sophisticated management system is handicapped if working with flawed data, the problem of lacking inventory record accuracy is often referred to as the missing link in retail execution and it has been estimated that the resulting lost sales and inventory costs reduce profits by more than 10% (Raman et al. 2001; Alexander et al. 2002). In this chapter we do not differentiate between the different sources of discrepancies between inventory records (system inventory or planned inventory) and inventory truly available for sale to customers (shelf inventory or available inventory). Since from the retailer’s perspective, the common underlying problem is the uncertainty of the inventory record, we will also use the term inventory uncertainty to refer to this problem. Among other developments in information technology, Radio-Frequency Identification (RFID) technology is being discussed as a powerful means to solve the problem of inventory uncertainty, among a plethora of other problems in supply chain execution. Enabling virtually full inventory transparency (both location and quantity) at any time, RFID technology, employed at the item-level, has indeed the potential to vastly improve retail execution (cf. McFarlane and Sheffi 2003). In recent years, several major retail chains have strongly promoted – or even mandated – RFID adoption by their suppliers, mostly at the pallet level. While RFID technology is suggested to enable substantial efficiency gains at the different stages of a supply chain, the associated costs are by no means negligible. Besides fixed costs related to the purchase and implementation of the necessary infrastructure, at this point especially the substantial cost of RFID tags seems to prohibit widespread use at the item level. Even if tag-costs decreased substantially, it is unlikely that item-level RFID adoption would be financially profitable at every retailer and for all products – it would likely start with more expensive items (cf. Want 2004). An optimal adoption decision needs to balance the value of full inventory transparency with the costs of RFID. In making this trade-off, it is important to distinguish the different incentives (benefits and costs) at the various stages of the supply chain. For example, adoption may be difficult if the retailer reaps most of the benefits, while the manufacturer bears most of the costs. More generally asked, how does the adoption decision of a decentralized supply chain differ from that of an integrated supply chain? We use the classic supply chain model of a single manufacturer, who as Stackelberg leader determines the wholesale price at which a product is sold to a retailer, who in turn determines how much to stock for sale to consumers (at an exogenous retail price). In making this stocking decision, the retailer faces
Inventory Record Inaccuracy, RFID Technology Adoption
485
uncertainty in customer demand as well as in inventory records. The latter source of uncertainty can be eliminated through RFID employment. We analyze the impact of inventory record inaccuracies on supply chain performance, and we investigate how double marginalization in a decentralized supply chain affects the different stages’ incentives to adopt RFID. While the possible implications of RFID technology on the supply chain are manifold, we focus on the improvements that result from having accurate inventory information. (With RFID all system inventory is available for sale to customers.) Poor execution at the retail level has been identified as the main driver of out-of-stock situations, which are a key problem in retailing (Andersen Consulting 1996; Gruen et al. 2002). While the benefit of such accuracy to the retailer is immediate, it is less clear, how RFID adoption affects the manufacturer, and the supply chain as a whole. Specifically, we address the following research questions: 1. How does inventory uncertainty affect stocking decisions compared to the standard case with accurate inventory records? 2. How does inventory uncertainty affect profits in a decentralized supply chain as compared to an integrated supply chain? 3. When do the manufacturer and the retailer individually benefit from RFID technology? 4. How does the RFID adoption decision in a decentralized supply chain differ from that of an integrated supply chain? We review the related literature in Sect. 2, and we introduce our base model in Sect. 3. Section 4 contains our model analysis and main results; we discuss the impact of inventory record inaccuracy on supply chain decisions and performance in an integrated and a decentralized supply chain (Sects. 4.1 and 4.2, respectively), before we contrast RFID adoption decisions for these two cases in Sect. 4.3. In Sect. 5, we conclude with a discussion of our results, limitations of our model, and suggestions for future research. All proofs are relegated to Appendix 1.
2 Literature Review The problem of inaccurate inventory records and misplaced SKUs at the retail level is widely discussed (e.g., Alexander et al. 2002; Raman et al. 2001; DeHoratius and Raman 2008). While most classic inventory models are based on the assumption of accurate inventory information, a subset of that research area considers the problem of inventory uncertainty under the term of yield uncertainty. An extensive review of this research stream is provided in Yano and Lee (1995). There is some very recent work that investigates optimal inventory management explicitly under inaccurate inventory records. Camdereli and Swaminathan (2010) consider the case where a fixed and known proportion of the retailer’s order quantity becomes unavailable for sale due to misplacement at the retailer. All misplaced products are recovered and salvaged
486
H.S. Heese
at the end of the period. They analyze the impact of such proportional loss on the retailer’s optimal order quantity. They compare the performance of a decentralized supply chain with that of a vertically-integrated supply chain and investigate how coordination can be achieved by means of buy-back and revenue-sharing contracts. DeHoratius et al. (2008) propose the maintenance of a probabilistic inventory record instead of the commonly used point estimate to account for the presence of inventory record inaccuracy. Sources of such inaccuracies are modeled through an additional random variable called invisible demand. They suggest a simple Bayesian procedure to periodically update the inventory record. In K€ok and Shang (2007), the phenomenon of inventory inaccuracy is represented through random errors that change the physical inventory level at the end of each period. These errors keep accumulating, until the inventory record is updated by means of a costly inspection. They propose a near-optimal joint inventory inspection and replenishment heuristic and find that order quantities should increase as the number of periods since the last inspection increases, to accommodate for the added uncertainty. The inspection frequency should be higher for items with high value and larger error variance relative to demand variance. While explicitly addressing the impact of inventory record inaccuracy on inventory management, none of the above articles quantifies the value of inventory accuracy or the problem of RFID adoption. ¨ zer (2007) argue that most of the existing Dutta et al. (2007) and Lee and O estimates of the value of RFID are at best educated guesses, often lacking any comprehensible basis. Since most of these estimates are overly optimistic, the ¨ zer (2007) suggest that results of implementation are often frustrating. Lee and O this discrepancy between wild value propositions and sobering results has created a credibility gap and they call for the academic community to provide solid models to enable more realistic estimates of the RFID value. Atali et al. (2009) consider a single stage inventory control problem, where inventory records are inaccurate due to three additional demand streams: shrinkage, misplacement, and transaction errors. By prioritizing the different demand streams, they derive upper and lower bounds on the optimal solution as well as a simple heuristic. They compare the costs under inventory record inaccuracy with those under perfect transparency to obtain what they call the value of inventory visibility, which represents an upper bound on the benefits of RFID technology. Sahin (2004) considers a single-stage inventory system with inventory record inaccuracy. Considering different possible sources of such inaccuracies as well as different mathematical forms to represent these relations, Sahin investigates the consequences of inaccurate inventory records and thereby provides a quantifiable value for Auto ID technology. Rekik et al. (2008, 2009) study product loss through misplacement or theft. They demonstrate the importance of explicitly considering this problem in the stocking decision and derive threshold cost values, at which RFID adoption would become cost-effective. Karaer and Lee (2007) study the value inventory visibility in a manufacturer’s reverse channel. Their findings suggest that RFID technology might enable
Inventory Record Inaccuracy, RFID Technology Adoption
487
substantial benefits if the product return flow is highly volatile, if the duration of the reverse channel process is long, and if a significant portion of the returned products needs to be reworked. While these four articles explore the problem of inventory control under inaccurate inventory information and explicitly consider the role of RFID technology in mitigating the problem of inventory inaccuracy, their focus lies on the value of inventory visibility at a single stage or firm. In contrast, our work specifically focuses on the consequences of inaccurate inventory records in the presence of double marginalization in a decentralized supply chain, contrasting RFID adoption incentives of the individual supply chain stages with that of the integrated firm. Kang and Gershwin (2005) use simulation to study the consequences of inventory record inaccuracies in a setting where the inventory management process is automated. They find that even small undetected losses can lead to severe disruptions and stock-outs, especially in lean systems. They suggest several approaches to mitigate this problem, including the adoption of Auto-ID technology. Even though Auto-ID technology in their model enables full inventory transparency, their results suggest that simple heuristics that compensate for the stock loss can achieve near-optimal performance – at much lower cost. Fleisch and Tellkamp (2005) simulate the consequences of inventory record discrepancies in a three-stage supply chain. They find that an elimination of such inaccuracies, which could for example be achieved by RFID technology, can substantially reduce supply chain cost and stock-outs. While the simulation models of Kang and Gershwin (2005) and Fleisch and Tellkamp (2005) present a valuable first step in analyzing the value of inventory visibility in a supply chain, they assume a vertically integrated supply chain and hence cannot derive any insights with respect to the value of RFID adoption in a decentralized supply chain. Using simulation to estimate of the value of RFID technology in a four-stage supply chain under different degrees of collaboration, Sari (2010) finds that RFID adoption to be most beneficial in environments with longer lead times and limited demand uncertainty. Rekik et al. (2005) consider a supply chain with one manufacturer and one retailer both in the presence of inventory inaccuracies and under full inventory transparency due to RFID implementation. Comparing these two settings, they derive the value of RFID technology and they determine tag cost threshold values for profitable adoption. Similar to Camdereli and Swaminathan (2010), Rekik et al. (2005) also investigate the inefficiencies due to double marginalization in a decentralized supply chain and derive coordinating buy-back contracts. Gaukler et al. (2007) investigate the impact of RFID technology on a vertically-integrated supply chain vis-a`-vis a decentralized supply chain with one manufacturer and one retailer. They capture possible discrepancies between shelf inventory (available to satisfy customer demand) and backroom inventory through a parameter y that represents the efficiency of the retailer’s replenishment process. More specifically, they define y as the conditional probability that, given ample backroom inventory, a customer will find the product available on the retail shelf. If true demand is normally distributed, so is the effective demand that can be satisfied from the shelf.
488
H.S. Heese
Assuming that neither the manufacturer nor the retailer include y in their decision making and that losing sales is the only penalty for empty shelves, the problem can be formulated as a standard newsvendor problem. Gaukler et al. (2007) analyze the benefits of full replenishment efficiency ðy ¼ 1Þ in a vertically-integrated supply chain and derive some insights into the threshold cost, at which RFID adoption would become profitable. While Rekik et al. (2005) and Gaukler et al. (2007) address problems that are similar to the one investigated in this article, their works differ in several important aspects. Most importantly, their research assumes that the impact of inventory record inaccuracy on the order yield is always negative, i.e., the retailer’s inventory available for sale is always less than ordered. However, it is reasonable to believe that inventory misplacements might eventually be corrected, implying available inventory that is larger than ordered in a specific period. Similarly, scanning errors will have a negative effect on the inventory records for some products and a positive for others (e.g., if scanning a vanilla yogurt as a strawberry yogurt). In such settings, RFID technology promises two potential benefits. On the one hand, it could help reduce the problem of shrinkage. On the other hand, RFID improves inventory transparency, reducing the uncertainty associated with inaccurate inventory records. We believe that these are two different value propositions, each of them important enough to merit attention. However, under the assumption that the source of inventory record inaccuracy always reduces order yield, the impact of inventory record inaccuracy can only be analyzed in the presence of such product losses, which are likely to have a confounding effect in estimating the value of RFID technology in achieving inventory transparency. The problem of uncertainty in inventory records cannot even be considered in a model where such inaccuracies are deterministic and known (as in Rekik et al. 2005). In our model, inventory record inaccuracies can be both positive or negative. Specifically, we capture this discrepancy between system inventory and available inventory by assuming that the ratio of the two follows a random variable. While this setup allows us to model shrinkage by assuming a mean below unity, we show that even in the absence of such losses, the mere uncertainty with respect to available inventory has a substantial impact on the supply chain. Gaukler et al. (2007) further assume that the retailer acted as if she was not aware of the inventory inaccuracy problem. This approach greatly simplifies the mathematical analysis, reducing it to a standard newsvendor problem. In our model, the retailer is conscious of the uncertainty with respect to inventory and she adjusts her orders accordingly, such that her execution problems also affect the manufacturer. As a consequence, in our setting both supply chain stages have an incentive to consider the costly adoption of RFID technology. Finally, the focus of Gaukler et al. (2007) is on the impact of RFID adoption on supply chain performance, rather than the adoption decision, while the question of how the adoption decision in a decentralized supply chain differs from that of an integrated supply chain is of central concern in our work.
Inventory Record Inaccuracy, RFID Technology Adoption
489
3 The Model In this section, we introduce our base model with its underlying assumptions. While we present the model for the integrated supply chain (which is analyzed in Sect. 4.1), the adjustments for the decentralized scenario (Sect. 4.2) are straightforward. A table with an overview of the notation is provided in Appendix 2. Generally, our model is based on the familiar newsvendor model. Given a starting inventory xn in period n, the decision maker needs to determine the optimal stocking quantity Qn in order to maximize expected (discounted) infinite-horizon profits. Demands in the different periods Dn are independent random variables with the identical support on ½0; D, density fD ðÞ and mean mD . A product is produced at cost c and offered for sale at a retail price r > c. We assume the firm has no market power and hence is a price-taker (i.e., the retail price r is exogenous). We do not explicitly consider penalty costs to capture the negative implications of shortages. Including such costs in our model would be straightforward and would not affect any of our insights. The key difference between our model and the standard newsvendor model with accurate inventory records is that the quantity available for sale to customers (shelf inventory) might differ from the planned stocking quantity. We assume that supply is reliable, so that such differences occur due to execution inefficiencies at the retailer, e.g., shrinkage, scanning errors, or SKU misplacement (cp. Sect. 1). Whereas some products might be lost forever due to theft, others might be physically present at the retailer (stored or lost in the backroom or on the wrong shelf), but not readily available for sale. However, in some periods these units can be made available to customers – since record inaccuracies are certainly not planned, such recoveries might come as a surprise and hence might actually increase available inventory beyond the planned stocking level. As a consequence, besides demand uncertainty, the decision maker faces uncertainty with respect to the validity of the inventory records. For example, let Q denote the number of units on the inventory record (and supposedly in the store) and let QA denote the number of units actually available for sales to the customers (on the right shelf). If inventory is misplaced, QA < Q. If those units are then found and placed at the right spot, it might also occur that QA > Q. On average, the available inventory should not be larger than the planned inventory, but it can be smaller, if there is shrinkage. Noting the obvious similarity to the problem of inventory management under yield uncertainty, we build on the model of Inderfurth (2004) and model the discrepancy between planned and available inventory in any given period through a stochastic multiplier Yn on ½0; Y with density fY ðÞ and mean mY 1. The random variable Y represents the ratio of available to recorded (planned) inventory, so on average there is no shrinkage if mY ¼ 1, while there is some loss if mY < 1. To achieve mathematical tractability in an environment complicated by uncertainty in inventory records, we assume that the ending inventory in each period is no larger than the desired stocking quantity of the next period (i.e., xn Qn ).
490
H.S. Heese
Following the seminal work of Veinott (1965), this assumption has frequently been used in the inventory literature to achieve tractability in multi-period settings with non-perishable inventory. This assumption is always satisfied in traditional inventory models with accurate inventory records, if cost parameters are stationary and demand is stochastically non-decreasing, since optimal stocking levels are non-decreasing over time and leftover inventory can never exceed the intended stocking quantity. However, this assumption is non-trivial in our setting, where stochastic order yield might lead to leftover inventory in excess of the intended stocking quantity. With the assumption that left-over inventory in any given period is less than the optimal stocking quantity of the following period, consecutive periods can be decoupled by assuming that there is a salvage value s on end-of-period leftover inventory, which is equal to the (discounted) unit cost of the following period minus a potential per-unit per-period holding cost. Hence, under this assumption, consecutive periods are independent and can be analyzed separately, so that the analysis of a multi-period inventory model with inventory holding cost can be reduced to a single-period analysis with the appropriate salvage value and zero starting inventory, without any loss of generality. While we base our following analysis on a single-period model, we ask the reader to keep in mind that our results and insights apply to any period of a multi-period horizon, and thus also for the corresponding multi-period problem. Let pðQÞ denote the supply chain’s expected profit if ordering Q.1 The finite To obtain a continuously differentiable support of fD ðÞ implies a discontinuity at D. representation of the problem, we distinguish two cases depending on whether the Y. 2 order quantity Q is smaller (case A) or larger (case B) than D= D Case A : Q Y
(1)
0YQ 1 ð pA ðQÞ ¼ cQ þ @ ðrD þ sðYQ DÞÞfD ðDÞdDAfY ðYÞdY ðY
ðY
0
B þ @ 0
D Case B : Q > Y 1
0
ðD
0
1
C rYQfD ðDÞdDAfY ðYÞdY
YQ
(2)
Analyzing a single-period model with zero starting inventory, we will use the terms order and stocking quantity interchangeably. 2 In the following, the cases where inequality conditions are satisfied with equality are assigned arbitrarily, without loss of generality.
Inventory Record Inaccuracy, RFID Technology Adoption
0YQ D=Q ð ð @
pB ðQÞ ¼ cQ þ 0
ðY þ D=Q D=Q ð
þ 0
491
1 ðrD þ sðYQ DÞÞfD ðDÞdDAfY ðYÞdY
0
0 D 1 ð @ ðrD þ sðYQ DÞÞfD ðDÞdDAfY ðYÞdY 0 B @
0
ðD
1 C rYQfD ðDÞdDAfY ðYÞdY
YQ
It is easy to confirm that the expected profit functions are strictly concave and to derive sufficient first-order conditions. However, analytical closed form expressions can only be obtained for special types of demand and yield distributions, for example the uniform and the exponential distribution (Inderfurth 2004). To obtain analytically tractable and crisp results, we assume that both yield and demand are uniformly distributed. Numerical studies based on normally distributed demand and yield largely confirmed our analytical results. With these assumptions, (1) and (2) can be simplified to the following expressions. Case A : Q
mD : mY
pA ðQÞ ¼ ðrmY cÞQ
ðr sÞmY 2 2 Q 3mD
Case B : Q >
mD : mY
pB ðQÞ ¼ ðr sÞmD ðc smY ÞQ
ðr sÞmD 2 1 Q 3mY
(3)
(4)
In the following section, we analyze how inventory record uncertainty affects stocking decisions and supply chain performance, focusing specifically on the impact of double marginalization in a decentralized supply chain. Assuming that the adoption of RFID technology implies additional per-unit costs, but leads to full inventory transparency (the problem then becomes a standard newsvendor problem), we derive closed form solutions for the RFID cost thresholds that make adoption profitable.
4 Analysis In this section, we investigate the consequences of inventory uncertainty and we contrast RFID adoption incentives of an integrated supply chain with those of a decentralized supply chain. We first determine the optimal decisions and supply chain profits for the integrated (Sect. 4.1) and for the decentralized supply chain
492
H.S. Heese
(Sect. 4.2). In Sect. 4.3, we derive and contrast the RFID cost thresholds for the two scenarios, below which adoption would be profitable. In the following, superscripts are used to indicate the concerned supply chain stage (M: manufacturer, R: retailer, SC: supply chain), and subscripts (1–4) are used to distinguish between the following four cases (1) an integrated supply chain with inaccurate inventory records, (2) an integrated supply chain with RFID, (3) a decentralized supply chain with inaccurate inventory records, and (4) a decentralized supply chain with RFID.
4.1
The Effect of Inventory Record Inaccuracy in an Integrated Supply Chain
We first derive the optimal order decisions and resulting profits for an integrated supply chain that experiences inventory record inaccuracies. This supply chain faces average procurement/production cost of c=mY and, for notational conveY nience, we use the parameter a ¼ rc=m rs to denote its critical fractile. Proposition 1. The optimal order quantity for the integrated supply chain under 3a otherwise. D, if a 23 , and Q1B ¼ p1ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi D, inventory inaccuracy is Q1A ¼ 4m 2mY
Y
¼ Correspondingly, expected profits are qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi ðrsÞðc=mY sÞ pSC , otherwise. 1B ¼ ðr sÞmD 2mD 3 pSC 1A
3ðrc=mY Þ2 4ðrsÞ
3ð1aÞ
mD , if a 23 , and
Reflecting the earlier distinction of two possible regimes [cp. cases A and B in (1) and (2)], we see that the rule for determining the optimal order quantity under inventory uncertainty differs depending on the specific value of the critical fractile ðaÞ.3 While the optimal order rule for small service levels (case A) has a similar structure as in the standard newsvendor problem, it is very different for larger critical fractiles (case B). Shrinkage (if mY < 1) generally has two conflicting effects on the optimal order quantity. On the one hand, one could expect shrinkage to increase the optimal order quantity to compensate for the expected loss in product. On the other hand, shrinkage increases the expected per unit production costs, with a decreasing effect on the target service level and hence the optimal order quantity. The net outcome of these two effects can be both positive or negative, depending on the specific values of the different cost parameters (see Lemma 1 in Appendix 1). For sufficiently high salvage value ðs > r=4Þ, both order quantities strictly increase in mY . If the salvage value is lower, Q1A is increasing-decreasing in mY , and Q1B is either decreasingincreasing (if s > c=2) or even strictly decreasing in mY ðs < c=2Þ. 3 While the specific value of two-thirds is characteristic of the uniform distribution, a threshold based stocking policy is likely for all demand distributions with finite support (see earlier discussion of the two cases). We observed similar threshold based stocking policies in numerical experiments for normally distributed demand and order yield.
Inventory Record Inaccuracy, RFID Technology Adoption 140
493
Q1B
120 100 80 60
Q1A
a = 2/3
40 20 0 20%
µY
100%
Fig. 1 Optimal order quantity of the integrated supply chain
Figure 1 illustrates the optimal order decisions and the contrast between the different stocking rules Q1A and Q1B for D ¼ 100, c ¼ 10, s ¼ 8, and r ¼ 50. Shrinkage lowers the critical fractile under inventory uncertainty, and increasing mY from 20 to 100% raises a from 0 to approximately 95%. Figure 1 demonstrates how the integrated supply chain’s optimal order quantity is raised for higher critical fractiles. Compared to the optimal order quantity for lower critical fractiles, the optimal order quantity for higher critical fractiles is always inflated to buffer against the comparatively high underage costs that might occur in the event of extremely low order yield (Q1B > Q1A , if a > 2=3). Lemma 1 in Appendix 1 proves that the validity of this observation is not limited to this specific numeric example. In this case, the threshold value a ¼ 2=3 corresponds to an average ratio between available inventory and system inventory of about mY ¼ 46%. It is interesting to analyze the optimal order quantity for the case without shrinkage (i.e., mY ¼ 1) and to compare it to the optimal order quantity Q^ for the corresponding newsvendor problem without inventory uncertainty (i.e., Y ¼ 1). It is well-known that Q^ ¼ aD and without shrinkage, deviations from this order quantity can only be due to the inherent inventory uncertainty. The results of Lemma 1 (see Appendix 1) show that without shrinkage ðmY ¼ 1Þ there is a threshold value 2=3 < a < 1, such that the optimal order quantity under inventory uncertainty is larger than the optimal order to the corresponding problem without inventory uncertainty, if and only if a > a, i.e., if the critical fractile is sufficiently large.4 For the specific example presented in Fig. 1, it can easily be verified that the optimal order quantity under inventory uncertainty is always higher than the optimal order quantity for the standard newsvendor problem without inventory uncertainty (Q^ ¼ aD increases from 0 to 95). Employing RFID technology has two effects on supply chain performance. On the one hand, this technology enables better (we assume perfect) inventory 4 This threshold value solves 12a2 ð1 aÞ ¼ 1, so a 89:6%. This threshold result has been mentioned in Inderfurth (2005).
494
H.S. Heese
transparency, such that all inventory is available for sale.5 It can be easily confirmed that such accuracy increases expected supply chain profits. On the other hand, there are costs associated with RFID technology. In practice, the cost of item-level RFID is largely driven by the cost of the tags. Correspondingly we assume that employment of RFID increases the per-unit cost by a fixed amount t.6 Assuming full inventory transparency under RFID, the supply chain in this scenario (subscript 2) faces the standard newsvendor problem (cf. Porteus 2002) and expected profits are ðQ
ðD
pRFID ðQÞ ¼ ðc þ tÞQ þ ðrD þ sðQ DÞÞfD ðDÞdD þ rQfD ðDÞdD 0
(5)
Q
Proposition 2 provides the optimal order quantity and expected profits for the integrated supply chain under RFID employment. Proposition 2. The optimal order of the integrated supply chain with RFID 2 yields maximum expected profit pSC ¼ ðrctÞ mD . D employment Q2 ¼ rct 2 rs rs Since inventory transparency increases expected profits, there must be a threshold value for the RFID costs, below which adoption is profitable. Before analyzing these cost thresholds (in Sect. 4.3), in the following section (Sect. 4.2) we derive the optimal decisions for a decentralized supply chain.
4.2
The Effect of Inventory Record Inaccuracy in a Decentralized Supply Chain
As in the previous section, we first study the optimal decisions and resulting supply chain performance for the case of inaccurate inventory records, and then analyze the setting with RFID technology. The previous section studied the decisions in an integrated supply chain; here we assume that the Stackelberg manufacturer sets a wholesale price, anticipating the retailer’s corresponding optimal stocking decision. While the manufacturer is not directly affected by the inventory record inaccuracy, he is so indirectly through the retailer’s adjustments in her order decision. In a setting were the retailer does not consider the inventory uncertainty in making her order decisions (as in Gaukler et al. 2007), the only reason for her to adjust her orders under RFID would be a change in the per-item cost. However, if the retailer 5
An implication of this assumption is that RFID adoption eliminates shrinkage. While this effect can be an important driver of RFID adoption, much of the following discussion focuses on the potential benefit of RFID technology in reducing inventory uncertainty, assuming there is no shrinkage ðmY ¼ 1Þ. However, unless noted otherwise, all results are also valid for the case with shrinkage ðmY < 1Þ. 6 To avoid trivial cases we assume t < r c.
Inventory Record Inaccuracy, RFID Technology Adoption
495
is aware of the inventory uncertainty problem and adjusts the order quantity accordingly, the impact of inventory uncertainty (or RFID adoption) on the manufacturer benefits is not immediately clear. Proposition 3 describes the equilibrium wholesale price and order decisions as well as resulting expected profits for the decentralized supply chain with inventory uncertainty. Proposition 3. In a decentralized supply chain with inventory inaccuracies, the Y and the retailer orders manufacturer charges a wholesale price w3 ¼ cþrm 2 2 3a D. Manufacturer, retailer and supply chain profits are pM ¼ 3mD ðrc=mY Þ , Q3 ¼ pR3
¼
8mY 3mD ðrc=mY Þ2 16ðrsÞ
3
and
pSC 3
¼
9mD ðrc=mY Þ2 16ðrsÞ
8ðrsÞ
, respectively.
Interestingly, we find that in the decentralized supply chain with endogenous wholesale pricing, the optimal order decision no longer follows the two different rules encountered in the previous section, where we distinguished between regimes A and B depending on the critical fractile a. While for high critical fractiles the retailer would still order according to a different function (similar to Q1B in Proposition 1), with the double marginalization (Spengler 1950) under endogenous wholesale pricing she simply never faces such high critical fractiles. Even if the supply chain as a whole had a higher critical fractile (a > 2=3), the manufacturer’s mark-up above cost always reduces the retailer’s critical fractile sufficiently to induce an order following the rule for regime A. It can easily be seen that, for a 2=3, double marginalization in the decentralized supply chain reduces the order quantity to 50% of the quantity that maximizes integrated supply chain profits (Q1A ). We know from Proposition 1 that the integrated supply chain follows a different stocking rule (Q1B ) for higher critical fractiles and it can be shown that Q1B > Q1A for a > 2=3 (see Lemma 1 in Appendix 1). Hence, under inventory uncertainty, the integrated supply chain inflates the order quantity for high critical fractiles (compared to case A). For a > 2=3, the decentralized supply chain keeps following the same rule (case A) and hence orders even less than half of what the integrated supply chain orders. As a result, we find that for products with high critical fractiles inventory inaccuracies exacerbate the problem of double marginalization in a decentralized supply chain. We now explore the benefits of RFID employment on the decentralized supply chain with double marginalization. Similar to Proposition 2, Proposition 4 provides the equilibrium decisions and resulting performance measures after RFID adoption for the decentralized supply chain. Proposition 4. In a decentralized supply chain with RFID technology, the manufacturer charges a wholesale price w4 ¼ rþcþt and the retailer orders Q4 ¼ 2 2 1 rct D. Manufacturer, retailer and supply chain profits are pM ¼ ðrctÞ mD , 2
pR4
rs Þ2 ¼ ðrct 4ðrsÞ
4
mD and
pSC 4
¼
3ðrctÞ2 4ðrsÞ
2ðrsÞ
mD , respectively.
Recall that the costs of RFID technology are borne by the manufacturer, but that he can, with endogenous wholesale pricing, pass some of these costs on to the
496
H.S. Heese
retailer. Comparing the wholesale prices before and after RFID adoption, we see YÞ , so the manufacturer’s surcharge on the wholesale price that w4 w3 ¼ tþrð1m 2 increases with the severity of the retailer’s pre-RFID shrinkage problem (it decreases in mY ). If there is no shrinkage at the retailer (i.e., if mY ¼ 1), the costs of RFID technology are split evenly. Consistent with the earlier observation, we find that the decentralized supply chain again orders exactly half of what the integrated supply chain would order. However, since there is only one stocking rule for the case with inventory transparency, here the impact of double marginalization on the optimal order quantity is consistent for all values of a. The fact that RFID adoption restores this proportionality of order quantities for high critical fractiles hints at the coordinating effect of RFID adoption. In the following section we derive and analyze the adoption thresholds for the integrated and the decentralized supply chain, and we show that the inventory transparency following RFID adoption might indeed improve supply chain coordination.
4.3
Double Marginalization and RFID Adoption
Proposition 5 provides the RFID cost threshold below which the integrated supply chain would find RFID adoption profitable. Proposition 5. An integrated supply chain would adopt RFID technology pffiffi for t < tA ¼ ðr cÞ 23 ðr c=mY Þ if a 23 , and for t < tB ¼ ðr cÞ rffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi qffiffiffiffiffiffiffi ðr sÞ 1 2 1a 3 , otherwise. As expected, we see that the benefit of RFID adoption differs depending on the balance of underage and overage costs, captured by the supply chain’s critical fractile a. It can be easily verified that both cost thresholds are positive, confirming the value of inventory transparency. The following Proposition 6 provides the analogue to Proposition 5 for the decentralized supply chain. Proposition 6. In a decentralized supply chain where the manufacturer set the wholesale price as a Stackelberg leader, both the retailer and the manufacturer are better off with RFID technology if and only if t < tA . Interestingly, we find that with endogenous wholesale pricing, the retailer’s and the manufacturer’s RFID adoption decisions are perfectly aligned, i.e., the retailer is better off under RFID adoption if and only if the manufacturer is better off. As a consequence, the (leading) manufacturer’s adoption decision is also optimal in terms of total supply chain profits. Surprisingly, Proposition 6 also shows that, if the critical fractile is relatively low ða 2=3Þ, the cost threshold of the decentralized supply chain is identical to that of the integrated supply chain. Consequently, the double marginalization in the
Inventory Record Inaccuracy, RFID Technology Adoption
497
decentralized supply chain in this case does not distort the evaluation of RFID. However, adoption decisions are different for higher critical fractiles ða > 2=3Þ, as described in the following Proposition 7, which provides one of the key insights of this chapter. Proposition 7. For a > 2=3, the cost threshold for profitable RFID adoption is strictly larger in a decentralized supply chain than in an integrated supply chain ðtA > tB Þ. No matter if the RFID adoption is undertaken by the manufacturer or mandated by the retailer, as long as the manufacturer is able to adjust wholesale prices as Stackelberg leader, for products with a sufficiently high critical fractile, the decentralized supply chain has a larger incentive to adopt RFID than the integrated supply chain, as it extracts a higher relative benefit from RFID technology. As a consequence, the performance gap due to double marginalization is decreased and RFID adoption improves supply chain performance. Figure 2 illustrates the difference between the two cost thresholds and contrasts the RFID adoption decisions of an integrated and a decentralized supply chain. For this graph, we use the same parameter values as in Fig. 1 (D ¼ 100, c ¼ 10, s ¼ 8, and r ¼ 50). Shrinkage in our model increases the expected procurement cost and thus has a significant impact on the supply chain’s critical fractile. For this specific example, the critical fractile a increases from 0 to approximately 95% as the average ratio of available-to-planned inventory mY increases from 20 to 100%. For settings with substantial shrinkage and relatively smaller critical fractiles under inventory uncertainty (a 2=3 for mY < 46%), we see that the incentives of the integrated and the decentralized supply chain are perfectly aligned ðtA ¼ tB Þ. The two threshold values are the same, even if the product would have a high critical fractile in the absence of shrinkage. However, for higher critical fractiles under inventory record inaccuracy, the decentralized supply chain extracts a higher value from RFID and finds RFID 40
8
35
tA
7 30
a=2/3
6
25 20
5 tA = tB
4
tA > tB
15
3 80%
10 5 0 20%
µY
Fig. 2 Cost thresholds for profitable RFID adoption
tB
100%
µY
100%
498
H.S. Heese
adoption profitable at a higher per-unit cost compared to the cost threshold of the integrated supply chain ðtA > tB Þ. In settings with very high shrinkage, the value of RFID as a tool to prevent such losses is substantial (for this specific numeric example we have tA ¼ tB ¼ 40 for mY ¼ 20%). In order to better illustrate the value of RFID in reducing the uncertainty in inventory records, in the small frame of Fig. 2, we contrast the threshold values for higher values of mY (from 80 to 100%). We see that the relative difference between the two thresholds might be substantial for such settings with minor shrinkage problems (higher mY ) – arguably the case in most real life instances. In the absence of shrinkage ðmY ¼ 1Þ, the integrated supply chain in this example would invest up to tB ¼ 3:67 per unit into RFID technology, whereas the decentralized supply chain would find RFID adoption profitable up to a significantly higher cost threshold of tA ¼ 5:36. Why does the decentralized supply chain gain proportionally the same from RFID adoption for relatively low critical fractiles ða 2=3Þ, but more if the critical fractile is higher ða > 2=3Þ? As discussed before, if the critical fractile is relatively low, both the decentralized and the integrated supply chain increase their orders by the same fraction ðQ3 =Q1A ¼ Q4 =Q2 ¼ 1=2Þ, and both supply chains make the same RFID adoption decision (Proposition 6). For higher critical fractiles however, the optimal order quantity for the integrated supply chain is proportionally larger under inventory inaccuracies (Q1B > Q1A , see Lemma 1 in Appendix 1). While both the integrated and the decentralized supply chain make the same proportional adjustments to their optimal order quantities when employing RFID in settings with relatively low optimal service levels, we see that with inaccurate inventory information for higher critical fractiles, the integrated supply chain inflates the optimal order quantity (cp. Fig. 1). Since the order quantities are proportionally the same for both supply chain structures with inventory transparency, the change after RFID adoption is proportionally larger for the decentralized supply chain, counteracting the problem of double marginalization. Note that improved supply chain coordination in our model is a result of individually rational RFID adoption decisions, and coordination was not an explicit objective at the outset. Clearly the performance of the decentralized supply chain could be further improved, for example by means of buy-back contracts. However, the focus of our research lies on RFID adoption decisions under inventory record inaccuracy. The general problem of supply chain coordination has been addressed by a wide body of research (see Cachon (2003) for a review).
5 Conclusion The discrepancy between inventory records and the amount of product effectively available for sale to customers presents a key problem in retail operations. Promising full transparency, RFID technology is often proposed as a remedy to this problem. However, RFID technology is not free of cost, so an optimal
Inventory Record Inaccuracy, RFID Technology Adoption
499
adoption decision needs to quantify the achievable benefits and balance them against these costs. We consider a simple supply chain model, where a Stackelberg manufacturer sets the wholesale price and a retailer determines how much to stock for sale to customers. Besides demand uncertainty, the retailer faces uncertainty with respect to her inventory records, i.e., she is uncertain by how much available stock differs from the planned stocking quantity. We first analyze how inventory record uncertainty affects optimal stocking decisions in an integrated supply chain. We find that in the presence of such inaccuracies, the optimal stocking rule can follow two different types, depending on the balance between underage and overage costs. For relatively low critical fractiles, the optimal stocking rule resembles the solution to the standard newsvendor problem without inventory inaccuracies. However, for higher critical fractiles, we find that the optimal stocking quantity for the integrated supply chain is increased to reduce the risk of costly stock-outs in the event that available inventory turns out to be much lower than system inventory. We then determine the optimal wholesale price and stocking decisions in the decentralized supply chain. We show that with endogenous wholesale pricing by a Stackelberg manufacturer, the manufacturer’s and the retailer’s RFID adoption decisions are perfectly aligned, i.e., the manufacturer is better off with RFID technology if and only if the retailer is better off. As a consequence, the manufacturer’s optimal RFID adoption decision is also optimal in terms of total supply chain profits. Interestingly, we find that with endogenous wholesale pricing, the critical fractile to the retailer is never sufficiently high to warrant an stocking quantity increase as encountered for the integrated supply chain. In the absence of inventory record uncertainty, both supply chains resort to stocking rules of the same structure and our findings are consistent with the classic result that the stocking quantity of the decentralized supply chain with double marginalization is half of that of the integrated supply chain. We show that this proportionality of stocking quantities is maintained under inventory record uncertainty, as long as the (integrated) supply chain’s critical fractile is sufficiently low. However, for higher critical fractiles the (integrated) supply chain’s optimal stocking quantity is increased. Since the decentralized supply chain with double marginalization fails to adjust stocking quantities sufficiently to maintain proportionality, we find that for relatively high critical fractiles, the double marginalization in a decentralized supply chain may exacerbate the negative consequences of inventory record inaccuracy. Analyzing the cost thresholds for profitable RFID adoption, interestingly we find that for low critical fractiles the incentives for RFID adoption in the decentralized supply chain are perfectly aligned with those in the integrated supply chain, such that both supply chains would find RFID technology attractive at the same cost. However, for products with higher critical fractiles, the relative benefit of RFID is larger for the decentralized supply chain and consequently adoption would become profitable at a strictly higher cost. The rationale behind this surprising finding lies in the decentralized supply chain’s failure to sufficiently increase stocking quantities
500
H.S. Heese
under inventory record inaccuracy. Since RFID adoption eliminates the need for such stocking quantity inflation and restores the proportionality of stocking quantities of the two supply chains, it mitigates the consequences of double marginalization and hence improves coordination of the decentralized supply chain.
Appendix 1: Additional Results and Proofs Lemma 1. (a) Q1A is increasing in mY for 0 < a 2=3, if s > r=4, and increasing-decreasing otherwise. (b) Q1B is increasing in mY (for 2=3 < a < 1), if s > r=4, decreasing if s < c=2, and decreasing-increasing otherwise. ^ and Q1B > Q^ , a > a, where 2=3 < a < 1. (c) If mY ¼ 1, then Q1A < Q, (d) If a > 2=3, then Q1B > Q1A . Proof of Lemma 1. 2c 2 3c 1A Part (a): @Q @mY > 0 , mY < r ; a 3 , mY rþ2s . Q1A is increasing in mY for 3c 2c r 0 < a 2=3, if rþ2s < r , s > 4 , and increasing-decreasing otherwise. c 2 3c 1B Part (b): @Q @mY > 0 , mY > 2s ; a > 3 , mY > rþ2s . Q1B is increasing in mY on 3c 2=3 < a < 1, if 2sc < rþ2s , s > 4r , decreasing if 2sc > 1 , s < 2c , and decreasingincreasing otherwise. 1 ffi < a , 12a2 ð1 aÞ > 1. Part (c) Q1A < Q^ by inspection; Q1B < Q^ , pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi 2 3ð1aÞ The left side of this inequality is decreasing in a(for a > 2=3). At a ¼ 2=3, it is equal to 16=9 > 1, and it is equal to zero at a ¼ 1. Hence there exists a 2 23 ; 1 , where the inequality is satisfied with equality. 3mD a 1 9a2 D ffi> Part (d) Q1B >Q1A , pmffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi 2mY , 3ð1aÞ > 4 (since both sides of the mY 3ð1aÞ □ inequality are positive) ,14ð3aþ1Þ ð23aÞ2 >0,a6¼23. Proof of Proposition 1. The optimal order quantities are derived in Inderfurth (2004). The resulting expected profits can be obtained by substituting these quantities into (3) and (4). □ Proof of Proposition 2. The optimal order quantity Q2 is the well-known critical fractile solution to the classic newsvendor model. The expected profits follow from □ substituting Q2 into the expected cost function (5) and simplification. Proof of Proposition 3. The retailer’s optimal order quantities are as given in 3 =mY Proposition 1, but with a critical fractile of a3 ¼ rwrs instead of a. The M manufacturer’s profit equals p3 ¼ ðw3 cÞQ3 . Two cases need to be distinguished 3 ¼ ðr þ 2sÞ m3Y to denote the depending on the resulting value of a3 . Use w
Inventory Record Inaccuracy, RFID Technology Adoption
501
3 (i.e., a3 2=3), a3 ¼ 2=3. For w3 w @ 2 pM @pM 3mD rw3A =mY 3mD 3A ðw3A Þ 3A ðw3A Þ ¼ ðw3A cÞQ3A ¼ ðw3A cÞ 2m < 0; @w ¼ ; @w3A 2 ¼ ðrsÞm rs 3A Y Y cþrmY 3 , a3 jw3A < 2=3 , 3ðc mY sÞ þ ðr sÞmY > 0. w3A > w For 0 ! w3A ¼ 2 ; qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi @pM ðw Þ mD 3B M rs 3B 3 (i.e., a3 > 2=3), p3B ¼ ðw3B cÞQ3B ¼ ðw3B cÞ m 3ðw3B =m sÞ; @w w3 < w ¼ 3B Y Y wholesale
price
at
which
pM 3A
qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
mD cþw3B 2smY 1 3ð1a3 Þ 2w3B 2smY mY M pM 3A a3 ¼2=3 ¼ p3B a3 ¼2=3
3 (both cases are equivalent at w 3 ). Since > 0 ! w3B ¼ w 3 , the optimal wholesale price is w3 ¼ w3A . and w3A > w
Substituting this optimal wholesale price gives the expressions in the Proposition.□ Proof of Proposition 4. The retailers optimal order quantity Q4 is the standard critical fractile solution to the newsvendor problem in (5) – the critical fractile 4 The manufacturer’s profit equals pM is rw 4 ¼ ðw4 ðc þ tÞÞQ4 ¼ rs . rw @ 2 pM @pM 4mD rþcþt 4 ðw4 Þ 4 ðw4 Þ 4 ðw4 ðc þ tÞÞ2mD rs ; @w4 ¼ 0 ! w4 ¼ 2 . @w4 2 ¼ ðpþrsÞ < 0; Substitution of the optimal wholesale price and simplification gives the expressions in the Proposition. □ 2
2
ðrctÞ 3ðrc=mY Þ SC Proof of Proposition 5. If a 23 : pSC 2 > p1A , rs mD > 4ðrsÞ mD p ffiffi ffi 2 2 , 4ðr c tÞ > 3ðr c=mY Þ , 2ðr c tÞ > 3ðr c=mY Þ (both sides are pffiffi Þ2 SC positive) , t < ðr cÞ 23 ðr c=mY Þ; If a > 23 : pSC , ðrct 2 > p1B rs mD > qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi Y sÞ ðr sÞmD 2mD ðrsÞðc=m 3 qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi qffiffiffiffiffiffi qffiffiffiffiffiffi rct2 12=3 1a 1a , rs > 1 2 3 1 2 3 > 1 2 ¼ 1=3 > 0 3
, rct rs >
rffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi qffiffiffiffiffiffiffi 12
1a 3
, t < ðr cÞ ðr sÞ
rffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi qffiffiffiffiffiffiffi 12
1a 3 .
□
M Proof of Proposition 6. The inequalities pR4 > pR3 and pM 4 > p3 (hence by definition SC SC also p4 > p3 ) can both easily be transformed to 4ðr c tÞ2 > 3ðr c=mY Þ2 , which is the same inequality as in the proof of Proposition 5 for case A. □ pffiffi Proof of Proposition 7. tA > tB , ðr cÞ 23 ðr c=mY Þ > ðr cÞ ðr sÞ rffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi rffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi qffiffiffiffiffiffiffi qffiffiffiffiffiffiffi pffiffi qffiffiffiffiffiffi 3 1a 1a a , 1 2 > 3 a2 (both sides of the > 1 2 3 , 1 2 1a 2 3 q3ffiffiffiffiffiffi 4 inequality are positive for a > 2=3) , 1 34 a2 > 2 1a 3 (both sides of the inequal 3 3 2 9 4 4 9 ð2 þ aÞ a 23 > ity are positive for a > 2=3) , 1 2 a þ 16 a > 3 43 a , 16
0 , a > 23 :
□
502
H.S. Heese
Appendix 2: Overview of Notation Symbol c r s t Y U½0; Y mY D U½0; D mD w Q p
a
Description Unit cost Unit revenue Unit salvage value RFID tag cost (per unit) Yield (random variable) Mean yield Demand (random variable) Mean demand Unit wholesale price (decision variable) Order quantity (decision variable) Expected profit Superscript (M ¼ manufacturer; R ¼ retailer; SC ¼ supply chain) Critical fractile for the supply chain
References Alexander K, Birkhofer G, Gramling K, Kleinberger H, Leng S, Moogimane D, Woods M (2002) Focus on retail: applying Auto-ID to improve product availability at the retail shelf. White paper, Auto-ID Center, MIT, Cambridge Anderson Consulting (1996) Where to look for incremental sales gains: the retail problem of outof-stock merchandise. The Coca-Cola Retailing Research Council, Atlanta ¨ zer O ¨ (2009) If the inventory manager knew: value of visibility and RFID under Atali A, Lee HL, O imperfect inventory information. Working paper, Stanford University, Stanford, CA Cachon GP (2003) Supply chain coordination with contracts. In: Graves S, de Kok T (eds) Handbooks in OR/MS: supply chain management: design, coordination and operation. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 229–239 Camdereli AZ, Swaminathan JM (2010) Misplaced inventory and radio-frequency identification (RFID) technology: information and coordination. Prod Oper Manage 19(1):1–18 DeHoratius N, Raman A (2008) Inventory record inaccuracy: an empirical analysis. Manage Sci 54(4):627–641 DeHoratius N, Mersereau A, Schrage L (2008) Retail inventory management when records are inaccurate. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 10(2):257–277 Dutta A, Lee HL, Whang S (2007) RFID and operations management: technology, value and incentives. Prod Oper Manage 16(5):646–655 Fleisch E, Tellkamp C (2005) Inventory inaccuracy and supply chain performance: a simulation study of a retail supply chain. Int J Prod Econ 95(3):373–385 Gaukler GM, Seifert RW, Hausman WH (2007) Item-level RFID in the retail supply chain. Prod Oper Manage 16(1):65–76 Gruen TW, Corsten DS, Bharadwaj S (2002) Retail out-of-stocks: a worldwide examination of extent, causes, and consumer responses. The Grocery Manufacturers of America, Washington, DC Inderfurth K (2004) Analytical solution for a single-period production-inventory problem with uniformly distributed yield and demand. Cent Eur J Oper Res 12:117–127
Inventory Record Inaccuracy, RFID Technology Adoption
503
Inderfurth K (2005) Incorporating demand and yield uncertainty in advanced MRP systems. In: Lasch R, Janker CG (eds) Logistik management – innovative logistikkozepte. Deutscher Universitaets-Verlag, Wiesbaden Kang Y, Gershwin SB (2005) Information inaccuracy and inventory systems: stock loss and stockout. IIE Trans 37(9):843–859 ¨ , Lee HL (2007) Managing the reverse channel with RFID-enabled negative demand Karaer O information. Prod Oper Manage 16(5):625–645 K€ ok AG, Shang KH (2007) Inspection and replenishment policies for systems with inventory record inaccuracy. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 9(2):185–205 ¨ zer O ¨ (2007) Unlocking the value of RFID. Prod Oper Manage 16(1):40–64 Lee HL, O McFarlane D, Sheffi Y (2003) The impact of automatic identification on supply chain operations. Int J Logistics Manage 14(1):1–17 Porteus EL (2002) Foundations of stochastic inventory theory. Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA Raman A, DeHoratius N, Ton Z (2001) Execution: the missing link in retail operations. Calif Manage Rev 43(3):136–152 Rekik Y, Jemai Z, Sahin E, Dallery Y (2005) Involving the performance of retail stores subject to execution errors: coordination versus Auto-ID technology. Technical report, LGI – Ecole Centrale Paris, Paris Rekik Y, Sahin E, Dallery Y (2008) Analysis of the impact of the RFID technology on reducing product misplacement errors at retail stores. Int J Prod Econ 112(1):264–278 Rekik Y, Sahin E, Dallery Y (2009) Inventory inaccuracy in retail stores due to theft: an analysis of the benefits of RFID. Int J Prod Econ 118(1):189–198 Sahin E (2004) A qualitative and quantitative analysis of the impact of the auto ID technology on the performance of supply chains. PhD thesis, LGI – Ecole Centrale Paris, Paris Sari K (2010) Exploring the impacts of radio frequency identification (RFID) technology on supply chain performance. Eur J Oper Res 207(1):174–183 Spengler JJ (1950) Vertical integration and antitrust policy. J Polit Econ 58(4):347–352 Veinott AF (1965) Optimal policy for a multi-product, dynamic, nonstationary inventory problem. Manage Sci 12(3):206–222 Want R (2004) RFID: a key to automating everything. Sci Am 290(1):56–65 Yano CA, Lee HL (1995) Lot sizing with random yields: a review. Oper Res 43(2):311–334
.
Possibilistic Mixed Integer Linear Programming Approach for Production Allocation and Distribution Supply Chain Network Problem in the Consumer Goods Industry Bilge Bilgen
Abstract In the consumer goods industry there is an ongoing trend towards an increased product variety and shorter replenishment cycle times. Hence, manufacturers seek a better coordination of production and distribution activities. Our study is motivated by the production-distribution problem encountered by a soft-drink company operating in consumer goods industry. The problem is to determine the optimal allocation of products and routing decisions for a multiechelon supply chain to minimize the total supply chain cost comprising of production, setup, inventory and distribution costs. A mixed integer linear programming (MILP) model is proposed to describe the optimization problem. However, a real supply chain operates in a highly dynamic and uncertain environment. The ambiguity of cost parameters is considered in the objective function of the model. The proposed approach uses the strategy of minimizing the most possible cost, maximizing the possibility of obtaining lower cost, and minimizing the risk of obtaining higher cost. Zimmermann’s fuzzy multi objective programming method is then applied for achieving an overall satisfactory compromise solution. The applicability of the proposed model is illustrated through a case study in consumer goods industry.
1 Introduction A supply chain system is comprised of all organizations that are involved in transforming raw materials to a final product. Supply chain management has received considerable attention from academicians and practitioners during the last several decades. In today’s world fast economic changes and the increasing pressure of market competition lead firms to focus on integrated supply chains. The coordination and integration of the production (supply), inventory, and distribution B. Bilgen Department of Industrial Engineering, Dokuz Eylul University, 35160 Izmir, Turkey e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_20, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
505
506
B. Bilgen
(demand) operations is widely perceived to be a route to obtain a competitive advantage. Arshinder et al. (2008) present a survey and classification of studies on supply chain coordination found in the literature. In the consumer goods industry the focus in production planning and scheduling is shifting from the management of plant-specific operations to a holistic view of the entire supply chain comprising value adding functions like purchasing, manufacturing and distribution. A closer coordination of production and distribution activities is required in order to avoid excessive inventories at the manufacturers’ warehouses. While traditionally minimizing production costs has been considered as the major objective, attention has shifted towards faster replenishment and improved logistical performance. Thus, finished product inventories are merely regarded as buffers between the manufacturing and the distribution stage of the supply chain. As a result, distribution costs have to be included in the overall objective function (Bilgen and Guenther 2010). The dynamic and complex nature of supply chain imposes a high degree of uncertainty in supply chain planning decisions and significantly influences the overall performance and effectiveness of the configuration and coordination of supply chain network (Klibi et al. 2010). The significance of accounting for uncertainty has prompted the researchers to address uncertain parameters in supply chain planning. Several authors have analyzed the sources of uncertainty present in a supply chain. In a recent review Peidro et al. (2009a) have presented an analysis of the literature on supply chain planning under uncertainty conditions by adopting quantitative approaches. In their review, some of the strengths and weaknesses of the approaches currently used have been pointed. Interested reader could refer to excellent reviews of Klibi et al. (2010) and Peidro et al. (2009a) regarding the review of supply chain network design problems under uncertainty, and review of quantitative models for supply chain planning under uncertainty, respectively. In this chapter, the optimal design and operation of a multi-product, multiperiod, multi-echelon, supply chain consisting of multiple manufacturers, multiple production lines and multiple distribution centers is considered. The problem is to assign products to the production lines, and to determine the routes to be traveled to coordinate the production and transportation routing operations so that the customer demand, capacity constraints, production, and inventory constraints are all satisfied, while the resulting cost (i.e. the sum of the production, inventory, setup, and transportation costs) over a given planning horizon is minimized. The problem is formulated as a MILP model. Because of price fluctuations in a dynamic market, assigning crisp values for parameters is no longer appropriate for dealing ambiguous decision problems. Possibility distribution offers an effectual alternative for proceeding with inherent ambiguous phenomena in determining cost parameters. Therefore, in this study a possibilistic MILP model is developed. The purpose of this study is twofold: first to develop more relatively sophisticated MILP model able simultaneously to form production and distribution network in the consumer goods industry, secondly to demonstrate the usefulness and significance of the fuzzy programming through a possibilistic programming approach.
Possibilistic Mixed Integer Linear Programming Approach for Production Allocation
507
The remainder of this chapter is organized as follows. The relevant literature is reviewed in Sect. 2. In Sect. 3 the key characteristics of the problem are outlined, and the model is described in detail. The proposed possibilistic mixed integer linear programming is elaborated in Sect. 4. The results of a numerical investigation which show the practical applicability of the developed possibilistic optimization model is presented in Sect. 5. Finally, concluding remarks and future directions for further studies are stated in Sect. 6.
2 Literature Review The efficient coordination of production and distribution systems becomes a challenging problem as companies move towards higher collaborative and competitive environments. In the academic literature, integrated production and distribution planning problem has been the subject of many studies during the last decade. For general in-depth description of the field of production and distribution planning in supply chain management, the reader is referred to Ereng€uc¸ et al. (1999), Sarmiento and Nagi (1999), Bilgen and Ozkarahan (2004), Stadler (2005), Chen and Vairaktarakis (2005) Arshinder et al. (2008), Peidro et al. (2010a), Chen (2010). Research effort on the supply chain coordination issues have been overwhelming and many fruitful research results have obtained. e.g. Chandra and Fisher (1994), Fumero and Vercellis (1999), Dhaenens-Flipo and Finke (2001), de Matta and Miller (2004), Park (2005), Lei et al. (2006), Cordeau et al. (2006), Eksioglu et al. (2007), Stadtler and Kilger (2008), Rizk et al. (2008), Elhedhli and Gzara (2008), Tsiakis and Papageorgiou (2008), and Bilgen and Guenther (2010). The models stated above assume the parameters that influence the design decisions to be deterministic. However, much of decision making in real world takes place in an environment where the objectives, constraints, or parameters are not known precisely. Several approaches take into account sources of uncertainty are arising in the area of supply chain management. These approaches can be roughly classified into analytic approaches, and simulation-based approaches (Guillen et al. 2005). On the other hand another classification is done by Peidro et al. (2009a) as analytic models, models based on artificial intelligence (AI), simulation based models and hybrid models. A number of researchers have proposed stochastic supply chain management models that are closer to real situations. Most research has modeled the supply chain uncertainty (e.g., uncertain demand) by probability distribution that is usually predicted from historical data. However, whenever statistical data is unreliable or even unavailable, stochastic models may not be the best choice. Fuzzy set theory may provide an alternative approach for dealing with the supply chain uncertainty (Lai and Hwang 1992a). Fuzzy set theory was proposed by Zadeh and has been found extensive applications in various fields such as operations research, management science, control theory and artificial intelligence. Fuzzy mathematical programming (FMP) is one of the most popular decision making approaches based on fuzzy set theory. Fuzzy sets theory has been
508
B. Bilgen
implemented in mathematical programming since 1970 when Bellman and Zadeh (1970) introduced the basic concepts of fuzzy goals, fuzzy constraints, and fuzzy decisions. Many of the developments in the area of FMP are based on this seminal paper. A detailed discussion of the FMP procedures can be found in (Lai and Hwang 1992a; Zimmermann 1996). In the context of FMP, two research directions that are being pursued are flexible programming, and possibilistic programming. Flexibility is modeled by fuzzy sets and may reflect the fact that constraints and goals are linguistically formulated. Some applications of flexible programming can be found in Tsai et al. (1997), Miller et al. (1997), and Mula et al. (2006). On the other hand there is uncertainty, corresponding to an objective variability in the model parameters (randomness), or a lack of knowledge of the parameter values (epistemic uncertainty). Epistemic uncertainty is concerned with ill-known parameters modeled by fuzzy intervals in the setting of possibility theory (Mula et al. 2007). Different applications of possibilistic programming approach can also be found in the literature. Hsu and Wang (2001) develop a possibilistic linear programming model to determine appropriate strategies regarding the safety stock levels for assembly materials, regulating dealers’ forecast demands, and number of key machines. Wang and Liang (2005) present a novel interactive possibilistic programming approach for solving the multi-product aggregate planning problem with imprecise forecast demand, related operating costs, and capacity. In a more recent work, Sakalli et al. (2010) develop a possibilistic aggregate production planning (APP) model for blending problem in a brass factory. In the proposed model, the Lai and Hwang’s fuzzy ranking concept is relaxed by using either-or constraints. The important works concerning application of possibilistic programming in SCM are presented by Wang and Shu (2005, 2007). Other applications of possibilistic programming in production and distribution planning problems can be found in Chen and Chang (2006), Mula et al. (2007), Liang (2008), Torabi and Hassani (2008a), Liang and Cheng (2009), Mula et al. € (2010), Kabak and Ulengin (2011). In recent years there is a significant growth in the study of production and distribution models using the FMP approach. In a pioneering study, Sakawa et al. (2001) have presented fuzzy programming for the production and transportation planning in the light of obscure estimation of parameters. Chen and Chang (2006) simultaneously handle multi-product, multi-echelon, and multi-period supply chain model with fuzzy parameters. And they propose a solution procedure that is able to calculate the fuzzy objective value of the fuzzy supply chain model. Subsequent research on FMP include by Aliev et al. (2007). They develop a fuzzy integrated multi-product, multi-period production and distribution planning model within supply chain. The model is formulated in terms of fuzzy programming and solution is provided by Genetic Algorithm (GA). Torabi and Hassani (2008a) develop a novel multi-objective possibilistic MILP model for a supply chain master planning problem consisting of multiple suppliers, one manufacturer and multiple
Possibilistic Mixed Integer Linear Programming Approach for Production Allocation
509
distribution centers. Their model integrates the procurement, production and distribution plans considering various conflicting objectives simultaneously as well as the imprecise nature of some impractical parameters such as market demands, cost/time coefficients, and capacity levels. In another study they develop a more comprehensive multi-objective supply chain master planning framework for a multi-echelon supply chain by extending their previous work. They propose a FGP model which is solved through a novel auxiliary crisp formulation (Torabi and Hassani 2008b). Liang (2008) presents an interactive fuzzy multi-objective linear programming (FMOLP) model for solving integrated production and transportation problem with multiple fuzzy goals in fuzzy environments. Liang and Cheng (2009) proposes a FMOLP model to simultaneously minimize total costs and total delivery time with reference to inventory levels, available machine capacity and labor levels at each source, as well as market demand and available warehouse space at each destination, and the constraint on total budget. More recently, Peidro et al. (2009b, 2010b) adopt two well-known fuzzy programming approaches to solve the tactical supply chain planning problem arises in the automobile industry. The fuzzy model integrally handles all the epidemistic uncertainty sources identified in tactical supply chain planning problem. The proposed model in their papers integrates procurement, production, and distribution planning activities into a multi-echelon, multi-product, multi-level and multi-period supply chain network. Bilgen (2010) apply flexible programming approach on the integrated production and distribution planning problem within consumer goods industry. The effects of different fuzzy operators on the model under different demand granularity levels are investigated. Jolai et al. (2010) consider a multi-objective, multi-product, and multi-period collaborative production and distribution planning model using Fuzzy Goal Programming (FGP) approach. A simple genetic algorithm, a particle swarm optimization (PSO) and hybrid GA are developed to solve the problem. Kabak and € Ulengin (2011) propose a possibilistic linear programming model to make strategic resource planning decisions in the SC context. In its current form, the proposed model is expected to provide an important guide to SC managers in preparing their strategic plans, taking into account the fuzziness of long-term plans. Table 1 summarizes the relevant studies. In this chapter, we present a novel model consisting of multiple production lines, multiple plants, and multiple distribution centers considering imprecise nature of the integrated production and distribution planning problem. Our study also extends this literature in terms of the model scope. It enhances the above mentioned studies by considering detailed distribution routing, minor and major setup time and costs, and assignments of products to production lines. Its main advantage lies in its ability to simultaneously coordinate production allocation and transportation operations of the entire planning horizon. The main contribution of this chapter is the integration of production allocation and distribution supply chain network problem through a possibilistic programming approach, accompanied by experiments on real data in consumer goods industry.
S S
M M M M
S
S M S
S
S
Chen and Chang (2006) Aliev et al. (2007)
Torabi and Hassani (2008a) Torabi and Hassani (2008b) Liang (2008) Liang and Cheng (2009)
Peidro et al. (2009b)
Mula et al. (2010) Jolai et al. (2010) Bilgen (2010)
€ Kabak and Ulengin (2011)
Proposed research
M
M
M M M
M
M M S S
M M
S
M
M
M M M
M
M M S M
M M
M
Number of products
M
S
M M M
M
M M S M
M M
S
Number of periods
T
S/T
T T T
T
T T S T
T T
T
Decision level
þ
þ
þ þ
þ
þ
þ
þ þ þ
þ þ
þ
þ
þ
Objective Constraints function
Source of uncertainty
S strategic, T tactical, O operational, S single, M multi, V vagueness, A ambiguity, H hypothetic
S
Sakawa et al. (2001)
Objective (S vs. M)
Number of echelons
Problem characteristics
Table 1 Literature on integrated production and distribution planning models using FMP
A A
þ þ
A V V
þ þ
A
þ
A A A A V A
þ þ
þ þ
V
Ambiguity vs. Parameters vagueness
Zimmermann’s approach Zadeh’s extentions principle Genetic algorithm Possibilistic programming FGP FMOLP FMOLP Chanas and Verdegay method Possibilistic programming FGP, GA, PSO Flexible programming Possibilistic programming Possibilistic programming
Solution approach
þ
þ
þ H þ
þ
H H þ þ
H þ
þ
Industrial application
510 B. Bilgen
Possibilistic Mixed Integer Linear Programming Approach for Production Allocation
511
3 Problem Description and Model Formulation Our study is motivated by the production-distribution problem encountered by a soft-drink company, which has to decide routinely the best way of delivering a set of orders to its customers over a multi-day planning horizon. Often it is not economical to install production equipment at each plant for the entire portfolio of products due to the high investment costs. Therefore, dedicated lines for the production of a specific range of products are established at each plant. Each individual plant has two production lines. No plant can produce the whole product range but just a part of the product range. Each production line at each individual plant can be viewed as a single stage process capable of producing several product groups. Setup costs are incurred at each plant whenever a production line changes production to a different product group. Each plant has an attached distribution center (DC) which serves as a buffer for the local production, and storage for products, which cannot be produced at the corresponding plant. Each DC has to be able to deliver the whole range of products. Products which cannot be produced in the corresponding plant must be delivered to a DC from another plant or another DC. Delivery takes place by means of homogenous vehicles with limited capacity. The distribution of goods from the plants to the DCs occurs in one of two ways: on a straight-and-back basis, i.e. there is only one DC on a given delivery vehicle’s path, which is the case if the customer requirements constitute a full truck load (FTL), or in a route involving multiple DCs on the route have individual requirements less than a truckload (LTL). For LTL multiple customers are served in a single route. In this case, transportation costs only depend on the transportation distance, not on the specific load. Usually, optimization models for production and distribution planning are based on the simplifying assumption that transportation costs are linear with respect to quantity and distance. This assumption, however, is not rectified in real transportation systems since most often different modes of transportation can be used. Particularly, in the consumer goods industry road transport is the most preferred mode in the distribution of finished goods due to its high flexibility (Guenther and Seiler 2009). The problem is to assign products to the production lines, and to determine the routes to be traveled to coordinate the production and transportation routing operations so that the customer demand, capacity constraints, production, and inventory constraints are all satisfied, while the resulting cost (i.e. the sum of the production, inventory, setup, and transportation costs) over a given planning horizon is minimized.
3.1
Problem Assumptions and Notation
The following considerations further define and delimit the problem: • The supply network consists of several plants which deliver the final products to various distribution centers.
512
B. Bilgen
• Each plant comprises several not necessarily identical production lines. Each line produces a given range of products. Multiple assignments of products to the lines are allowed. • For each product inventory balances at distribution centers are updated on a daily basis according to the production output from the various lines at the plants, the inbound and outbound transportation quantities, and the given external demand. • All vehicles used in LTL transportation are assumed to be identical. • No specific handling capacities and costs at distribution centers are considered. • Transportation activities are carried out within a single day. Nevertheless, lead times for long-distance transportation can be modeled simply by offsetting the time index of the respective decision variables. • Each vehicle can only travel according to pre-defined route with fixed operational cost. It is assumed that a vehicle can pick up products from a plant in a travel. Each vehicle is allowed to discharge cargo at most two distribution centers.
3.2
Model Formulation
The MILP model for the considered problem proposed by Bilgen (2010) is adopted as the basis of this work. It reflects major issues arising in the consumer goods industry, e.g. major and minor setups, daily demand assignments, use of different transportation modes etc. Nevertheless, its main features are also relevant for other types of industries. The sets, indices, parameters and variables used to formulate the problem mathematically are described below.
3.2.1
Notation
Sets I J Ji L P Lp IL W T Ji Rp Rw
Set of products (i ¼ 1,2,. . .,I) Set of product groups (j ¼ 1,2,. . .,J) Set of products that belong to group j Set of production lines (l ¼ 1,2. . .,L) Set of plants (p ¼ 1,2,. . .,P) Set of production lines at plant p Set of products that can be processed on line l Set of distribution centers (DC) (w ¼ 1,2,. . .,W) Set of time periods Set of product groups including product p Set of routes that begin with plant p Set of routes including distribution center w
Possibilistic Mixed Integer Linear Programming Approach for Production Allocation
513
Parameters PCapl ECapl diwt ail ai V tsil TSjl ~ l EC C~prod il C~SMin il C~SMaj
Capacity of production line l Extra capacity of production line l External demand of product i at DC w in period t Time consumed to produce product i on line l Factor for converting quantities of product i into unit loads, e.g. pallets Loading capacity of a vehicle Minor setup time of product i on line l Major setup time of product group j on line l Extra cost for using production line l Processing cost of product i on production line l
C~Inven iw C~LTL
Inventory holding cost of product i at DC w in time period t Transportation cost per vehicle on route r
Minor setup cost of product i on production line l Major setup cost of product group j on production line l
jl
r
Decision variables xilt elt yirwt qipwt Iiwt nrt zilt ujlt
Production volume for product i produced on production line l in time period t Extra capacity used on production line l in time period t Quantity of product i delivered to warehouse w via route r in time period t Quantity of product i shipped from plant p to DC w in time period t Inventory level of product i at DC w at the end of time period t The number of vehicle used on route r in time period t. (identical vehicles are used) 1, if product i is setup on line l in period t 0, otherwise 1, if product group j is setup on line l in period t 0, otherwise
3.2.2
Objective Function
Minimize XXX i2I l2L t2T
XXX i
w
t
od xilt þ C~Pr il
XXX
zilt þ C~SMin il
i2I l2L t2T
C~Inven iw Iiwt þ
XX
XXX j2J l2L t2T
ujlt þ C~SMaj jl
XX r
t
C~LTL r nrt
ðCapÞ EC~l elt
l2L t2T
(1)
514
B. Bilgen
The first term in objective function defines the production costs, the second and the third terms represent the minor and major setup costs for products, and product groups, respectively. Finally last three terms represent transportation ~ l , C~prod , cost of the system, and the inventory costs, and extra capacity costs. EC il SMin ~SMaj ~Inven ~LTL ~ Cil , Cjl , Ciw , Cr are imprecise coefficients.
3.2.3
Model Constraints
subject to X
ail xilt þ
X
i
tsil zilt þ
X
i
TSjl ujlt PCapl þ elt
8l; t
(2)
j
Constraints (2) are the time capacity constraints. Capacity is the upper bound on the total time that can be consumed to produce products. It specifies that the time used for processing (manufacturing) on a line cannot exceed the capacity of that line in time period t. ail xilt ðPCapl þ ECapl Þzilt
8i; l; t
(3)
Constraints (3) enforce the production quantity i on line l to zero, if no corresponding setup operation is performed (i.e. zilt ¼ 0). elt ECapl
8l; t
(4)
Constraints (4) guarantee that the extra capacity used for production line l and time period t cannot exceed maximum available extra capacity for that production line. X zilt Mujlt 8j; l; t (5) i2Ji
Constraints (5) ensure that product i belong to product group j can only be set, if the line is set up for the product group j. XX X X yirwt þ qipwt ¼ xilt 8p; i; t (6) r2Rp
w
w
l2Lp
Total output quantities achieved from producing product i at the production lines in plant p must be equal to the shipping quantities on the routes starting from plant p and including DC w plus the shipping quantities to the DCs which are supplied from plant p. That is, it ensures the availability of the product i at plant p in time period t. XX yirwt ai Vnrt 8r; t (7) i
w2Wr
Possibilistic Mixed Integer Linear Programming Approach for Production Allocation
515
Constraints (7) guarantee that, the total quantity of products (converted into unit loads) to be transported to the various DCs w 2 Wr included in route r determines the number of vehicles nrt required for that route in time period t. Note that variable nrt is defined as an integer number of identical vehicles each having a transportation capacity of Vunit loads. X X Iiwt1 þ yirwt þ qipwt diwt Iiwt ¼ 0 8i; w; t with Iiw0 ¼ given r2RðwÞ
p
(8) The daily demands of products must be satisfied. Constraints (8) ensure the inventory flow balance at DCs, and require each DC to have enough supply (from either inventory and/or the quantity arrived in that period) to meet the demand. That is, the inventory of product i at distribution center w at the end of time period t is determined by the ending inventory of the previous time period, the quantities received, and the external demand to be satisfied on the respective time period. xilt ; yirwt ; qipwt ; 8i; j; l; p; w; r; t
I iwt 0;
nrt 0;
and integer,
zilt ;
ujlt 2 f0; 1g
(9)
Finally, constraints (9) are integrality constraints of integer and binary variables, and non-negativity constraints of continuous variables. In real-life situation for a production and distribution planning problem, many input information related to the process are not known with certainty. Fuzzy and/or imprecise natures of the problem cannot be described adequately by the conventional approach. Fortunately, possibility distribution offers an effectual alternative for proceeding with inherent ambiguous phonemia in determining environmental coefficients and related parameters. In our model, cost coefficients are all imprecise. Therefore a possibilistic programming model is developed to determine the optimum production allocation and distribution decisions. Based on Lai and Hwang’s (1992b) approach, a possibilistic linear programming model is transformed into crisp multiobjective programming models. Finally, Zimmermann’s fuzzy programming method (1978) is applied to obtain composite single objective. In this study, production, setup, transportation, and inventory costs are represented by triangular possibility distributions. The parameters of a triangular possibility distribution are given as the optimistic, the most possible, and the pessimistic values, which were estimated by decision maker.
4 Solution Methodology 4.1
Converting Imprecise Cost Coefficients to Crisp Numbers
There are many studies to tackle with the imprecise cost coefficients in the objective function in the literature. The first method for getting a compromise solution was
516
B. Bilgen
proposed by Tanaka et al. (1984). They adapt a weighted average as a substitute for the fuzzy objective with a crisp compromise objective. An a-Pareto optimal solution proposed by Sakawa and Yano (1989) restricts the fuzzy coefficients to a-level sets. A similar concept is the b-possibility efficient solution of Luhandjula (1987). He obtained a single objective semi-infinite linear programming problem, and provided a cutting plane method to solve this semi-infinite problem. Rommelganger et al. (1989) proposed a multiple objective linear programming by using r a-level sets and establishing membership functions of the upper and lower bound for each a-level set to solve linear programming problem with triangular fuzzy costs. In contrast to the approach of Rommelganger et al. (1989) has restricted their solution method to one a-level. They used decomposition theory, and considered a convex set with extreme points defined by the lower and upper bound of the n a-level sets of the fuzzy coefficients. On the other hand, Lai and Hwang (1992b) converted the fuzzy objective with a triangular possibility distribution into three crisp objectives. Following the Lai and Hwang’s (1992b) approach, the approach developed here minimizes cm, maximizes (cm co), and minimizes (cp cm), rather than simultaneously minimizing cm, cp, co. Figure 1 represents a triangular possibility distribution of imprecise numbers. Geometrically, this imprecise objective is fully defined by three corner points (cm,1), (cp, 0) ,(co,0) in Fig. 1. Using Lai and Hwang’s approach (1992b), we substitute minimizing cm, maximizing (cm co), and minimizing (cp cm). That is the approach used in this work involves minimizing the most possible value of the imprecise costs, cm, maximizing the possibility of lower costs (cm co), and minimizing the risk of obtaining higher cost (cp cm). The three replaced objective functions can be minimized by pushing the three prominent points towards left. In this way, our problem can be transformed into a multi-objective linear programming as follows:
π~ Ci 1
Fig. 1 The triangular possibility distribution for cost coefficients
~ Ci(o)
~ (m) Ci
~ (p) Ci
Possibilistic Mixed Integer Linear Programming Approach for Production Allocation
XXX
z1 ¼
Min
XX
mðPr odÞ C~il xilt þ
i2I l2L t2T
þ
XXX
þ
t
r
z2 ¼
Max
XXX
mðSMinÞ C~il zilt þ
C~rmðLTLÞ nrt
þ
moðPr odÞ xilt þ C~il
þ
t
r
Min z3 ¼
XXX
w
XX r
t
moðCapÞ
elt
XXX
moðSMajÞ C~jl ujlt
j2J l2L t2T
w
i pmðPr odÞ C~il xilt þ
moðInvenÞ Iiwt C~iw
t
XX
EC~l
pmðCapÞ
elt
l2L t2T pmðSMinÞ C~il zilt þ
i2I l2L t2T
þ
EC~l
XXX
C~rmoðLTLÞ nrt þ
XXX
mðInvenÞ Iiwt C~iw
t
XX
moðSMinÞ C~il zilt þ
i2I l2L t2T
þ
mðSMajÞ C~jl ujlt
l2L t2T
i2I l2L t2T
XX
elt
j2J l2L t2T
i
XXX
XXX
XXX
i2I l2L t2T
þ
mðCapÞ
l2L t2T
i2I l2L t2T
XX
EC~l
517
C~rpmðLTLÞ nrt þ
XXX
pmðSMajÞ C~jl ujlt
(10)
j2J l2L t2T
XXX i
w
pmðInvenÞ Iiwt C~iw
t
To solve, many multi-objective linear programming techniques can be used, such as utility theory, goal programming, and so on. Lai and Hwang (1992b) suggested using Zimmermann’s (1978) fuzzy programming method to convert the auxiliary MOLP model into an equivalent single goal LP problem. Initially, the positive ideal solutions (PIS) and negative ideal solutions (NIS) of the three objective functions should be obtained to construct the linear membership functions of the objectives (Lai and Hwang 1992b). For each objective function, the corresponding linear membership function is computed as:
mz1 ¼
8 > < 1NIS z
if
9 z1 =
8 > <1
z2 zNIS 2 NIS zPIS 2 z2
NIS 1 if zPIS mz2 ¼ 1 > > : 1 : NIS ; 0 if z1 >z1 0 9 8 if z3 3 ;> = < 1NIS z3 z3 NIS > ; : 3 3 0 if z3 >zNIS 3
if if
9 z2 >zPIS 2 ;> =
PIS zNIS 2
if
z1
> ; (11)
Figure 2 displays the graphics of linear membership functions for the above equations.
518 mz
B. Bilgen mz
1
mz
2
1
3
1
1
PIS z1
NIS z1
NIS z2
PIS z2
z
PIS z3
NIS z3
Fig. 2 The membership functions of the objectives z1, z2, and z3
Finally we solve Zimmermann’s following equivalent single-objective linear programming model to obtain the overall satisfaction compromise solution (Zimmermann 1978). Max l s:t: l mzi ;
i ¼ 1; 2; 3;
(12)
x 2 X:
5 Numerical Investigation To demonstrate the validity and practicality of the proposed model, an industrial case inspired from a soft-drink industry is presented. This supply chain network involves three plants, six production lines, three distribution centers located in different customer zones. There are two different types of product groups, and 19 different product types. The planning horizon is 2 weeks consisting of 10 daily periods. The distance between the manufacturer and the destination and their dispatching costs of a vehicle are given in Table 2. Other relevant data are summarized as follows (Bilgen 2010). • The planning horizon consists of 2 weeks with daily periods. • The manufacturing plant is operated 16 h/day and 5 days/week. • The processing speed of the six production lines is given as 8,000 (line 1), 6,000 (line 2), 7,000 (line 3), 7,000 (line 4), 8,000 (line 5), and 6,000 (line 6) L/h independent of the specific beverage produced on the line. Corresponding linespecific processing costs per day are defined as 80, 125, 100, 100, 80, and 125 € for the individual lines. • A major setup time of 3 h is considered for setting up a specific production line for a specific product group, while a minor setup time of 15 min is required for
Possibilistic Mixed Integer Linear Programming Approach for Production Allocation Table 2 Costs per vehicle for Predefined route predefined routes between Plant 1 – DC 2 plants and DCs Plant 1 – DC 3 Plant 1 – DC 2 – DC 3 Plant 2 – DC 1 Plant 2 – DC 3 Plant 2 – DC 1 – DC 3 Plant 3 – DC 1 Plant 3 – DC 2 Plant 3 – DC 2 – DC 3
Table 3 Capacity, minor and major setup cost values (€)
519
Costs per vehicle (€) 403 624 940 403 637 927 624 637 938
Production lines
C~SMin il
C~SMaj jl
Line 1 Line 2 Line 3 Line 4 Line 5 Line 6
100 120 150 80 120 90
500 450 400 550 400 550
setting a product on a production line. The minor setup time is the same for all production lines and products. • For transportation, trucks with 26 tons loading capacity to be hired from an external logistics service provider are considered. With 750 liters per pallet, the effective loading capacity per truck was assumed as 34 pallets. The minor and major setup costs are summarized in Table 3. The MILP formulations described in the previous sections were implemented using the modeling language ILOG OPL Studio 3.7 (2003), and a variety of test problems were solved with standard mathematical programming software, namely the branch and bound algorithm of ILOG CPLEX 8.0 (2003), on a Intel Core i7 notebook with 1.6 GHz processor and 4 GB RAM. No additional parameter settings are used in CPLEX. Since a short-term planning horizon of 2 weeks is considered, seasonal demand variations are not essential. The average workload is considered as 75% of the available total capacity. Each experiment was repeated five times with different randomly generated demand data. We use a similar algorithm developed by Wang and Liang (2005). In practice the MILP solutions often were used as a starting point of the PIS and NIS, and both intervals must cover the MILP solutions. The initial PIS of the objective functions is (4,000,000, 900,000, 130,000) and the NIS is (19,000,000, 210,000, 550,000). Initial total cost is imprecise and has a triangular possibility distribution (3,634,874,
520
B. Bilgen
Table 4 Results of the initial and improved compromise solution 0.5415 0.8545 Lamda z1 z2 z3
PIS 4,000,000 900,000 130,000
Fig. 3 Possibility distribution of the optimal value of the objective function
NIS 19,000,000 210,000 550,000
PIS 4,525,000 825,000 155,000
NIS 19,000,000 250,000,000 500,000,000
mz
1
3 634 874 4 563 868 4 695 651
4,563,868, 4,695,651), and overall degree of decision maker (DM) satisfaction with multiple goal values is 0.5415. Moreover, the DM may try to modify the results interactively by adjusting the linear membership functions and related model parameters until a satisfactory solution is obtained. After five trial runs, the summary results, including the positive and the negative ideal solutions (PIS and NIS), as well as the resulting overall satisfaction level for the initial and improved compromise solutions are shown in Table 4. Figure 3 depicts the initial possibilistic distribution of the optimal value of the fuzzy objective function. Total cost is imprecise and has a triangular possibility distribution of ~z ¼ ðz1 ; z1 z2 ; z1 þ z3 Þ Table 5 displays total cost distribution under initial and improved compromised model solutions. These findings imply that the DM must specify an appropriate set of PIS and NIS of the objective functions. Total cost decrease from 4,563,868 to 4,412,963. l value was adjusted to seek a set of better compromise solutions since the DM did not accept the initial overall degree of satisfaction level. Lai and Hwang’s (1992b) possibilistic programming approach does not always produce feasible solutions; existence of a feasible solution depends on the particular shapes of the possibility distributions of imprecise data. Infeasible solutions arise because of the lack of the decision variables satisfying (1)–(9) simultaneously. Solution algorithm proposed by Wang and Liang (2005) enable the DM interactively modify the imprecise data until a satisfactory solution is found. Sakkall et al. (2010) relax Lai and Hwang’s (1992b) fuzzy ranking concept by using either-or constraints to avoid infeasibility conditions.
Possibilistic Mixed Integer Linear Programming Approach for Production Allocation Table 5 Total cost distribution for the initial and improved model solutions
Total cost Production cost Minor setup cost Major setup cost Inventory cost Transportation cost Extra capacity cost
Initial compromise solution 4,563,868 3,532,033 5,700 17,610 244,595 738,200 25,730
521
Improved compromise solution 4,412,963 3,524,166 4,460 15,740 32,200 68,340 68,057
6 Conclusion and Future Research This study propose a model integrating production and distribution plans in a multiechelon supply chain network with multiple production lines, multiple plants, multiple distribution centers. The model allows the simultaneous determination of assignments of products to production lines, and determination of the quantity of products transported, and determination of the number of vehicles used for each predefined routes. It integrates the strategic decisions concerning product production line assignments with tactical decisions concerning distribution routing. In many practical applications, the parameters in the supply chain may not be known precisely. We provide an auxiliary multiple objective linear programming problem with three objectives to solve a linear programming problem with imprecise cost coefficients. These objectives are: minimize the most possible value of the imprecise total costs, maximize the possibility of obtaining lower total costs, and minimize the risk of obtaining higher total costs. The numerical experiments indicate that the proposed model is practical and tractable. The main contribution of this study is a practical application of possibilistic programming approach to the integrated production allocation and distribution supply chain network problem in consumer goods industry. Effective supply chain integration and optimization provide a competitive advantage to firms and organizations in today’s highly intractable global business environment. Our study makes an important contribution to the academic literature and provides potential to influence managerial practice positively. But there are some limitations that provide opportunities for further research. The ambiguous parameters considered in this research are limited to objective function cost coefficients. The problem can be modeled under the consideration of the ambiguous technological constraints and right hand-side values. Continued research is necessary to study in robust fuzzy programming in which both vagueness and ambiguity are considered simultaneously. The optimal solution by max-min approach may not be efficient solution. Two-phase approach may be used to overcome the disadvantage of using max-min operator. Optimization based models developed so far usually have somewhat restrictive assumptions for the sake of analytical tractability. There is a great need for new ways of modeling inherently complex supply chains that operate under uncertainty.
522
B. Bilgen
Simulation-based techniques, AI-based techniques, hybrid techniques can be used to solve large problems for both crisp and fuzzy models. Another issue for future research can be towards the consideration of the operational level decisions under uncertainty within the supply chain management.
References Aliev RA, Fazlollahi B, Guirimov BG, Aliev RR (2007) Fuzzy-genetic approach to aggregate production-distribution planning in supply chain management. Inf Sci 177:4241–4255 Arshinder K, Kanda A, Deshmukh SG (2008) Supply chain coordination: perspectives, empirical studies, and research directions. Int J Prod Econ 115:316–335 Bellman RE, Zadeh LA (1970) Decision making in a fuzzy environment. Manage Sci 17:141–164 Bilgen B (2010) Application of fuzzy mathematical programming approach to the production allocation and distribution supply chain network problem. Expert Syst Appl 37:4488–4495 Bilgen B, Guenther H-O (2010) Integrated production and distribution planning in the fast moving consumer goods industry a block planning application. OR Spectr 32:927–955 Bilgen B, Ozkarahan I (2004) Strategic, tactical and operational production distribution models: a review. Int J Technol Manage 28:151–171 Chandra P, Fisher ML (1994) Coordination of production and distribution planning. Eur J Oper Res 72:503–517 Chen Z-L (2010) Integrated production and outbound distribution scheduling: review and extensions. Oper Res 58(1):130–148 Chen SP, Chang PC (2006) A mathematical programming approach to supply chain models with fuzzy parameters. Eng Optim 38:647–669 Chen Z-L, Vairaktarakis GL (2005) Integrated scheduling of production and distribution operations. Manage Sci 51(4):614–628 Cordeau CF, Pasin F, Solomon MM (2006) An integrated model for logistics network design. Ann Oper Res 144(1):59–82 de Matta R, Miller T (2004) Production and inter-facility transportation scheduling for a process industry. Eur J Oper Res 158:72–88 Dhaenens-Flipo C, Finke G (2001) An integrated model for an industrial production and distribution problem. IIE Trans 33:705–715 Eksioglu SD, Eksioglu B, Romeijn HE (2007) A Lagrangian heuristic for integrated production and transportation planning problems in a dynamic, multi-item, two-layer supply chain. IIE Trans 39:191–201 Elhedhli S, Gzara F (2008) Integrated design of supply chain networks with three echelons, multiple commodities, and technology selection. IIE Trans 40(1):31–44 Ereng€uc¸ SS, Simpson NC, Vakharia AJ (1999) Integrated production/distribution planning in supply chains: an invited review. Eur J Oper Res 115:219–236 Fumero F, Vercellis C (1999) Synchronized development of production, inventory, and distribution schedules. Transp Sci 33:330–340 Guenther H-O, Seiler T (2009) Operative transportation planning in consumer goods supply chains. Flex Serv Manuf 21:51–74 Guillen G, Mele E, Bagajewicz MJ, Espuna A, Puigjaner L (2005) Multiobjective supply chain design under uncertainty. Chem Eng Sci 60(6):1535–1553 Hsu HM, Wang WP (2001) Possibilistic programming in production planning of assembleto-order environments. Fuzzy Sets Syst 119:59–70 ILOG CPLEX 8.0. (2003) User’s manual. ILOG SA, Gentilly ILOG OPL Studio 3.7 (2003) Language manual. ILOG SA, Gentilly
Possibilistic Mixed Integer Linear Programming Approach for Production Allocation
523
Jolai F, Razmi J, Rostami NKM (2010) A fuzzy goal programming and meta heuristic algorithms for solving integrated production: distribution planning problem. Cent Eur J Oper Res. doi:10.1007/s10100-010-0144-9 ¨ , Ulengin € Kabak O F (2011) Possibilistic linear-programming approach for supply chain networking decisions. Eur J Oper Res 209:253–264 Klibi W, Martel A, Guitouni A (2010) The design of robust value-creating supply chain networks: a critical review. Eur J Oper Res 203:283–293 Lai YJ, Hwang CL (1992a) Fuzzy mathematical programming-methods and applications, vol 394, Lecture notes in economics and mathematical systems. Springer, Berlin Lai YJ, Hwang CL (1992b) A new approach to some possibilistic linear programming problems. Fuzzy Sets Syst 49:121–133 Lei L, Liu S, Ruszczynski A, Park S (2006) On the integrated production, inventory, and distribution routing problem. IIE Trans 38:955–970 Liang TF (2008) Integrating production–transportation planning decision with fuzzy multiple goals in supply chains. Int J Prod Res 46:1477–1494 Liang TF, Cheng H-W (2009) Application of fuzzy sets to manufacturing/distribution planning decisions with multi-product and multi-time period in supply chains. Expert Syst Appl 36:3367–3377 Luhandjula MK (1987) Multiple objective programming with possibilistic coefficients. Fuzzy Sets Syst 21:135–146 Miller WA, Leung LC, Azhar TM, Sargent S (1997) Fuzzy production planning model for fresh tomato packing. Int J Prod Econ 53:227–238 Mula J, Poler R, Garcia JP (2006) MRP with flexible constraints: a fuzzy mathematical programming approach. Fuzzy Sets Syst 157:74–97 Mula J, Poler R, Garcia JP (2007) Material requirement planning with fuzzy constraints and fuzzy coefficients. Fuzzy Sets Syst 158:783–793 Mula J, Peidro D, Poler R (2010) The effectiveness of a fuzzy mathematical programming approach for supply chain production planning with fuzzy demand. Int J Prod Econ 128: 136–143 Park YB (2005) An integrated approach for production and distribution planning in supply chain management. Int J Prod Res 43:1205–1224 Peidro D, Mula J, Poler Rl, Lario FC (2009a) Quantitative models for supply chain planning under uncertainty: a review. Int J Adv Manuf Technol 43(3–4):400–420 Peidro D, Mula J, Poler R, Verdegay J-L (2009b) Fuzzy optimization for supply chain planning under supply, demand, and process uncertainties. Fuzzy Sets Syst 160:2640–2657 Peidro D, Mula J, Diaz-Madronero M, Vicens E (2010a) Mathematical programming models for supply chain production and transport planning. Eur J Oper Res 204:377–390 Peidro D, Mula J, Jimenez M, Botella MM (2010b) A fuzzy linear programming based approach for tactical supply chain planning in an uncertain environment. Eur J Oper Res 205:65–80 Rizk N, Martel A, D’Amours S (2008) Synchronized production–distribution planning in a singleplant multi-destination network. J Oper Res Soc 59:90–104 Rommelganger H, Hanuscheck R, Wolf J (1989) Linear programming with fuzzy objectives. Fuzzy Sets Syst 29:31–48 Sakawa M, Yano H (1989) Interactive fuzzy satisfying method for multiobjective nonlinear programming problems with fuzzy parameters. Fuzzy Sets Syst 30:221–238 Sakawa M, Nishizaki I, Uemura Y (2001) Fuzzy programming and profit and cost allocation for a production and transportation problem. Eur J Oper Res 131:1–15 ¨ F, Birg€ € Baykoc¸ O Sakkalli US, oren B (2010) A possibilistic aggregate production planning model for brass casting industry. Prod Plann Control 21:319–338 Sarmiento AM, Nagi R (1999) A review of integrated analysis of production–distribution systems. IIE Trans 31:1061–1074 Stadler H (2005) Supply chain management and advanced planning basics, overview and challenges. Eur J Oper Res 163:575–588
524
B. Bilgen
Stadtler H, Kilger C (2008) Supply chain management and advanced planning, 4th edn. Springer, Berlin Tanaka H, Ichihashi H, Asai K (1984) A formulation of fuzzy linear programming problem based on comparison of fuzzy numbers. Control Cybern 13:185–194 Torabi SA, Hassani E (2008a) An interactive possibilistic programming approach for multiple objective supply chain master planning. Fuzzy Sets Syst 159:193–214 Torabi SA, Hassani E (2008b) Multi-site production planning integrating procurement and distribution plans in multi-echelon supply chains: an interactive fuzzy goal programming approach. Int J Prod Res 47:5475–5499 Tsai C-C, Chu C-H, Barta TA (1997) Modeling and analysis of a manufacturing cell formation problem with fuzzy mixed-integer programming. IIE Trans 29:533–547 Tsiakis P, Papageorgiou LG (2008) Optimal production allocation and distribution supply chain networks. Int J Prod Econ 111:468–483 Wang RC, Liang T-F (2005) Applying possibilistic linear programming to aggregate production planning. Int J Prod Econ 98:328–341 Wang JT, Shu YF (2005) Fuzzy decision modeling for supply chain management. Fuzzy Sets Syst 150:107–127 Wang J, Shu YF (2007) A possibilistic decision model for new product supply chain design. Eur J Oper Res 177:1044–1061 Zimmermann H-J (1978) Fuzzy programming and linear programming with several objective functions. Fuzzy Sets Syst 1:45–55 Zimmermann HJ (1996) Fuzzy set theory and its applications, 3rd edn. Kluwer, Boston
Coordination of Converging Material Flows Under Conditions of Uncertainty in Supply Chains Liesje De Boeck and Nico Vandaele
Abstract This chapter examines the coordination of converging material (component) flows in supply chains under conditions of uncertainty. It is well known that such flows complicate regular material flows. They entail that the components should wait for each other (synchronization time of components) and induce a modified arrival process on the part of the sets of components at the assembly operation (arrival process of kits). As such, they play a major role in supply chain performance. In order to improve this performance, one can rely on some important generic managerial insights: if component flows are independent renewal processes and warehouses have enough (infinite) capacity, the flows do not get synchronized; more variable component flows degrade system performance; more frequent component supply (keeping the level of variability fixed) does not change the synchronization time but improves productivity; more components degrade system performance and, finally, component flows need coordination. This chapter develops approximations in order to underpin these managerial insights and concludes by extending these insights to practical guidelines. Keywords Converging flows • Coordination • Supply chains • Uncertainty
Choi T-M, Edwin Cheng TC (eds) Innovative schemes for supply chain coordination and uncertainty. L. De Boeck (*) Centre for Modeling and Simulation, HUBrussel, Stormstraat 2, 1000 Brussels, Belgium and Research Centre for Operations Management, K.U.Leuven, Naamsestraat 69, 3000 Leuven, Belgium e-mail: [email protected] N. Vandaele Research Centre for Operations Management, K.U.Leuven, Naamsestraat 69, 3000 Leuven, Belgium and Faculty of Business and Economics, K.U. Leuven-Campus Kortrijk, Etienne Sabbelaan 53-bus 00000, 8500 Kortrijk, Belgium e-mail: [email protected], [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_21, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
525
526
L. De Boeck and N. Vandaele
1 Introduction Within supply chain management, enhanced competitiveness originates from a closer integration of all partners into the supply network as well as from a better coordination of information, material and funding flows (Stadtler and Kilger 2000). In this chapter we will focus on the coordination of materials and, more specifically, the coordination of converging material flows in supply chains. These converging flows are widespread in supply chains (e.g., Ramachandran and Delen 2005). They are better known by the name “assembly” in manufacturing systems. In what follows, we assume that the supply chain is considered as a single system and that all information on all aspects of this system is available to the decision maker. In this sense, “assembly operations” in manufacturing systems and supply chains can be considered as equivalent (see also Sect. 2). It is well known that assemblies in general complicate material flows because they require synchronization (e.g., Hopp and Spearman 2008). Indeed, assembly operations cannot start until all the required components (defined as a kit) are present. This means that the components have to wait for one another, creating additional waiting time which, in what follows, is defined as synchronization time. Simultaneously, a modified arrival process of kits at the assembly operation is created. As such, coordinating converging material flows plays a major role in supply chain performance. Note that at the same time the need for agility and responsiveness in the supply chain environment has never been as apparent as now. This necessitates the availability of adequate information. Adequate information requires incorporating the dynamic and complex character, the uncertainty, the variability and the capacity constraints present in the supply chain environment (e.g., Davis 1993; Vandaele and De Boeck 2003; Van Nieuwenhuyse et al. 2011). In what follows, we will model the above-mentioned synchronization time of components and the arrival process of kits, taking into account this adequate information requirement. The approximations enable us to find out how to improve performance of supply chains with converging flows (i.e., decrease the synchronization time of components and/or decrease the inter-arrival time of kits). Indeed, the approximations translate into the following managerial insights, which are widely applicable. 1. If component flows are independent renewal processes and warehouses have enough (infinite) capacity, the converging material flows do not get synchronized (Harrison 1973). 2. A more reliable supply of components (with the same frequency) improves performance (Hopp and Spearman 2008), leads to less synchronization time and to improved productivity (De Boeck and Vandaele 2008, 2011). 3. More frequent supply of components with the same level of reliability does not change the synchronization time but improves productivity (De Boeck and Vandaele 2008, 2011). 4. More components degrade system performance (Hopp and Spearman 2008).
Coordination of Converging Material Flows Under Conditions of Uncertainty
527
5. Component flows must be coordinated (Hopp and Spearman 2008; De Boeck and Vandaele 2008, 2011). The chapter is organized as follows. In Sect. 2, we introduce the concept of converging assembly flows. Then, we briefly touch upon the equivalency between converging flows in manufacturing systems and supply chains and discuss the assumptions underlying the formulas developed in Sect. 3. Section 3 is a theoretical section. It elaborates on the approximations of the synchronization time of components and the inter-arrival time of kits, which underpin the abovementioned managerial insights. Section 4 translates the theoretical analysis from Sect. 3 into managerial insights. It explains in detail how these insights follow from the formulas developed in Sect. 3. Section 5 concludes this chapter with an account of its major findings and the conversion of these insights into robust guidelines for coordinating material flows from a practical point of view.
2 Definition and Assumptions of Systems with Converging Flows We define a system with converging flows as a system where component flows are brought together in order jointly to undergo an assembly operation. We assume that the supply chain is considered as a single system and that all information on all aspects of this system is available to the decision maker. In this sense, “assembly operations” in manufacturing systems and supply chains can be considered as equivalent in terms of modeling. Indeed, the arrival process of the component flows determines the level of performance, because the presence of all components is required. It does not matter whether these components are delivered by suppliers or by other divisions of the manufacturing facility. If their arrival process is known, the level of performance can be calculated in the same way. The set of all those components which are necessary for assembly is defined as a kit. Note that any component shortage prevents the start of the assembly operation (also named assembly schedule disruption) and in this way induces a delay. This type of delay originates in the distinguishing feature of the assembly system. In what follows, we will define this time spent by the components in waiting for each other as synchronization time. Alongside synchronization time, systems with converging flows also bring about a modified arrival process at the location of the assembly operation. Besides the component arrival processes, we also have a kit arrival process at the assembly operation. It is important to note that in the sequel we will define the cycle time as the time a component spends in a part of the system (for the cycle time it is possible to specify, for instance, the average value, the variance, the density function,. . .). It may denote the time needed to supply the goods, the time needed in the manufacturing facility and so on. The lead time is a specific value provided in order to guarantee a service level given the cycle time density function (the service level is the probability that the cycle time is smaller than or equal to the lead time).
528
L. De Boeck and N. Vandaele
In order to simplify the analysis, we will assume a system with two converging component flows. The assembly operation requires one component of each flow. For later use, we draw attention to the fact that the component flows from the suppliers can take two different forms. In form (1), the components do not need processing in the manufacturing facility before being assembled and thus are used as direct input into the assembly operation in the manufacturing facility. In form (2), the components need some processing in the manufacturing facility before being assembled. This is represented in Fig. 1 by (1) and (2) respectively. The middle part of this figure (the dotted lines) represents the assembly operation. The two component flows are represented by the first two dotted squares in this middle part. The first buffer (first dotted triangle) depicts the synchronization buffer. This is the waiting place for individual components waiting to form a kit. The second buffer (the second dotted triangle) is the assembly buffer and holds the kits waiting for the assembly operation. The assembly operation itself is represented by the last dotted square. This buffer split also appears in Lipper and Sengupta (1986). In order to validate the managerial insights put forward in Sect. 1, we will develop approximations for the average value of the synchronization time of components and the inter-arrival time of kits at the assembly operation. In addition, we will make some additional assumptions in our system concerning converging
…
Component flow 1 Component flow 2
… Component flow 1
(2)
Component flow 2 (1)
…
Fig. 1 A system with converging material flows
Coordination of Converging Material Flows Under Conditions of Uncertainty
529
material flows. We assume that the component cycle time (this is to say, the time that elapses between order placement at the supplier and delivery at the manufacturing facility) is lognormally distributed. This is justified when taking into account the fact that this cycle time has a reasonable probability of taking on larger values (right tail). It should be borne in mind that the lognormal distribution is a good approximation to the processing cycle time (e.g., Vandaele et al. 2002). Along the same lines, we are confident that the lognormal distribution is a good approximation to the transport cycle time also. Since the component cycle time consists of the transport cycle time (in the event that the supplier operates in a make-to-stock environment) or the processing cycle time and the transport cycle time (in the event that the supplier operates in a make-to-order environment), the lognormal distribution is justified. Furthermore, we assume the assembly system to be open, with generally distributed processing times, and operating with discrete components which are processed following FCFS-discipline. In order to demonstrate insight (1) (see Sect. 1), the buffers have infinite capacity while component flows are independent renewal processes with generally distributed inter-arrival times. It should be stressed that this assumption is realistic when using form (2) (see Fig. 1). Indeed, assuming variable processing times for the operations (represented by the grey square and the grey “. . .”) preceding the assembly operation will result in component flows being (almost) independent when entering the assembly operation. We also assume equal average inter-arrival times for both components. That is because we want to avoid a situation where synchronization time does not converge due to unequal average component inter-arrival times. However, the variance and the entire distribution of inter-arrival times of both component flows may differ.
3 Analysis of the Synchronization Time of Components and the Inter-arrival Time of Kits In this section, we present our conclusions concerning the average value of the synchronization time of components and the inter-arrival time of kits. For a detailed analysis of these approximations, we refer to De Boeck and Vandaele (2008) for discrete uniformly distributed component inter-arrival times, and De Boeck and Vandaele (2011) for generally distributed component inter-arrival times and kits consisting of two or more components and/or different units of the component flows.
3.1
Notation
Before deriving the approximations, we introduce the following notation in Table 1. We note here that upper case letters are used for representing the random variables whereas lower case letters represent the realizations as well as the indices of components and kits.
530
L. De Boeck and N. Vandaele
Table 1 Notation used in of Sect. 3 Symbol Meaning The synchronization time of the components for i kits Wi W|i The synchronization time of the components for kit i Ti The inter-arrival time for i kits MAXAT|i The maximum of the component arrival times for the components of kit i CCTc The component cycle time of component c The service level (in percentage) for component c sc LTc,s The lead time of component c guaranteeing a service level of s p The probability that all components required for a kit arrive on time mX The average value of the variable X sX The standard deviation of the variable X The variance of the variable X s2 X fX(x) The density function of the variable X ATic The arrival time of component c for kit i The inter-arrival time of component c ITc The continuous uniform distribution with lowerbound Lb and upperbound Ub Uc(Lb,Ub)
3.2
Approximations
Observe that the assembly of converging flows (see Fig. 1) necessitates purchasing components. As indicated in Sect. 2, we assume the component cycle times to be lognormally distributed. Given this distribution and given a specific service level for each component, we can calculate the corresponding lead time guaranteeing this service level. We assume the average value ðmCCTc Þ and variance s2CCTc of the cycle time of component c to be known. It is worth noting that in a make-to-order environment, these parameters can be obtained using queuing approximations (see e.g., Vandaele et al. 2002). Given these two parameters, we can easily calculate the parameters mc en sc of the lognormal distribution of each component cycle time as follows (Vandaele et al. 2002): 0
1
B mCCTc C ffiC mc ¼ lnB @rffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi A; s2CCTc þ 1 m2
(1)
CCTc
vffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi !ffi u 2 u s c sc ¼ tln CCT þ1 : m2CCTc
(2)
The lead time of component c that guarantees a service level of sc equals: LTc;s ¼ eðmc þzs sc Þ ;
(3)
Coordination of Converging Material Flows Under Conditions of Uncertainty
531
where zs is the tabulated standard normal variable yielding a cumulative percentage sc. However, when pinning down the service levels at s1, s2,. . ., sn for all n components required for assembly, the probability p that all components arrive on time is (Hopp and Spearman 2008): p ¼ s1 s2 :::sn ;
(4)
assuming that the component cycle times are independent. Note that for form (1) in Fig. 1 this analysis suffices in most instances when setting p sufficiently high. For instance, assuming p equal to 95% means that the components will arrive on time 95 times out of 100. In those 95% of cases there will be no synchronization time and the average value of the inter-arrival times of the kits will equal the average value of the component inter-arrival times. However, for form (2) we need some additional analysis. As already pointed out in Sect. 2, the assumption of stochastic processing times for the operations preceding the assembly operation will result in the component flows being (almost) independent at the moment they enter the assembly operation. This will result in an average synchronization time larger than zero and, as a consequence, the average value of the kit inter-arrival time will not be equal anymore to the average value of the component inter-arrival times. We now summarize the main steps in Fig. 2 (which is a slightly adapted version from the figure in De Boeck and Vandaele 2011) in reaching those approximations and the resulting output. It is important to see that we start with an empty system at time zero and that the average value and variance of the component inter-arrival time density functions are known. We observe from Fig. 2 that the first step in obtaining approximations for the average value of the synchronization time of components and the inter-arrival time of kits consists in approximating the arrival time distributions of both components for kit i. This approximation can be found by relying on the central limit theorem. Indeed, each component arrival time in forming kit i is the sum of i IID random variables (being the component inter-arrival times). As such, each component arrival time density function approximates to a normal distribution (De Boeck and Vandaele 2011): 1 pffiffiffiffiffiffi e fATic ðatic Þ ffi sATic 2p with mATic ¼ imITc and
ðatic mAT Þ2 ic 2s2 ATic
s2ATic
¼
1 atic þ1
(5)
is2ITc :
As a second step, we derive an approximation for the average value of the synchronization time of the components. Be aware of fact that the symbol “|i” stands for “for a specific kit i” whereas the subscript “i” refers to “for the first i kits (i.e. irrespective of a kit)”. W|i represents the synchronization time for a specific
532
L. De Boeck and N. Vandaele
Component 1
at11
at21
at31
at41
Step 1
Component 2
at12
at22
at32
at42
Step 2
Kit synchonization time Step 3
Kit inter–arrival time Kit arrival time
Fig. 2 The steps in obtaining approximations for the synchronization time of components and the inter-arrival time of kits
kit i (assuming that we start with an empty system at time zero). In Fig. 2, the horizontal bold lines indicate the synchronization time for kit 1, 2, 3 and 4 respectively. Since we are not interested in the synchronization time of each specific kit but only in the synchronization time of a random kit (that is what Wi stands for), we will ultimately translate the results of W|i into results for Wi. However, since the system is not a steady-state one (see infra) (because this synchronization time does not converge), the synchronization time of a random kit depends on the number of kits that have already been processed. As such, depending on the number of kits that are processed, the synchronization time of the system will permanently change. Observe from Fig. 2 that the synchronization time for a specific kit i is equal to the absolute value of the difference between both component arrival times. Since the density functions of those component arrival times are approximated by the normal distribution (see step 1), the synchronization time can also be approximated by a normal distribution (De Boeck and Vandaele 2011): ðwjimWji Þ2
2 pffiffiffiffiffiffi e fWji ðWjiÞ ffi sWji 2p with mWji ¼ 0 and
s2Wji
2s2 Wji
¼
is2IT1
0 wji þ1 þ
is2IT2 :
(6)
Coordination of Converging Material Flows Under Conditions of Uncertainty
533
Given this synchronization time distribution for a specific kit i, we can easily calculate the average value of the component synchronization time for a random kit (De Boeck and Vandaele 2011):
mW i
i 1X ¼ m ¼ i k¼1 Wjk
qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi ffi i pffiffiffi 2 s2IT1 þ s2IT2 X pffiffiffi k: i p k¼1
(7)
As a third step, we derive an approximation for the inter-arrival time of kits at the assembly operation. Note from Fig. 2 that the arrival time of kit i (MAXAT|i) at the assembly station equals the arrival time of the component that arrives last in the forming of kit i or, in other words, the arrival time of kit i at the assembly operation is the maximum of both component arrival times for kit i. It should be stressed that since we start with an empty system at time zero, MAXAT|i represents the time that has elapsed from 0 to MAXAT|i. During this time, i-1 other kits and kit i itself have arrived. Knowing that i kits have a arrived in a time period of length MAXAT|i, gives, on average, an inter-arrival time between two successive kits at the assembly operation (Ti) during that time period which is equal to (MAXAT|i)/i. We point out that this ratio represents the inter-arrival time of a “random” kit (i.e. for the first i kits). Given all this and assuming that the component arrival time density functions can be approximately identified by a normal distribution, we can approximately identify the kits’ inter-arrival time density function as (De Boeck and Vandaele 2011):
fTi ðti Þ ffi
ððiÞti imIT Þ2 1 2is2 IT1
i pffiffiffiffiffiffiffi e sIT1 2pi
þ
2
3
1
0
1 6 BðiÞti imIT2 C 7 4erf @ qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi A þ 15 2 2 2is IT2
ððiÞti imIT Þ2 2 2is2 IT2
i pffiffiffiffiffiffiffi e sIT2 2pi
2
1
0
3
1 6 BðiÞti imIT1 C 7 4erf @ qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi A þ 15: 2 2 2is
(8)
IT1
The average value of this density function becomes (De Boeck and Vandaele 2011):
mTi ¼ mITc
qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi s2IT1 þ s2IT2 pffiffiffiffiffiffiffi þ : 2pi
(9)
The above formulas (7) and (9) perform very well. For an extensive validation with an extensive numerical example of these approximations, we refer to De Boeck and Vandaele (2011). We will now use the above formulas to illustrate the managerial insights outlined in Sect. 1 with numerical examples.
534
L. De Boeck and N. Vandaele
4 Link Between the Approximations and Some Managerial Insights In what follows we will discuss each managerial insight pointed out in Sect. 1 separately and underpin it with the approximations of Sect. 3.
4.1
Material Flows Do Not Converge in the Event of Independent Renewal Component Processes and Enough (Infinite) Warehouse Capacity
In this section we prove that in the event that the component flows are independent renewal processes and the warehouses have enough (infinite) capacity, there is no convergence of the synchronization time of components (see also Harrison 1973). Remember from Sect. 2 that the approximations developed in Sect. 3 are derived using these underlying assumptions. From (7) we clearly observe that the synchronization time of components does not converge. Indeed, the synchronization time of components diverges to infinity when i ! 1. This can also be observed from Fig. 3. This figure is obtained using (7) and Uc(8,9) distributed inter-arrival times for both component flows.
4.2
Performance Improves if Supply Is More Reliable
Synchronization time of the components
When supply is more reliable, there is less variability in the component cycle times and the component inter-arrival times. 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0
1
11
21
31
41
51 Kits
61
71
81
91
Fig. 3 The synchronization time of components for two component flows with Uc(8,9) distributed inter-arrival times
Coordination of Converging Material Flows Under Conditions of Uncertainty
535
Assume that we require two components for assembly, each component being delivered by different suppliers who work independently from one another. For simplicity, assume that both suppliers have the same component cycle time characterized by a lognormal distribution with an average value of 10 days and a standard deviation of 15 days (scenario 1). Assume also that in a second scenario, both suppliers become more reliable: the standard deviation of both component cycle times lowers to 5 days. From (1) and (2), we can calculate the parameters mc and sc of the lognormal distribution of the component cycle times in both scenarios. Assuming a service level sc of 95% requires setting a lead time for both components which can be obtained from (3). Also the probability that both components arrive in time can be obtained from (4). We present the results in Table 2. Observe from Table 2 that the safety time (the time needed on top of the average component cycle time in order to reach the required service level) guaranteeing a service level of 95% is more than two times the average cycle time for scenario 1, whereas this is less than one time the average cycle time in scenario 2 (a) (see right hand side of Fig. 4). Figure 4 clearly illustrates that the reason for this lies in the thicker right tail (left hand side of Fig. 4) of the component cycle times for scenario 1. Note also that when assuming the same lead time as in scenario 1, one gets a service level of 99.71% for both components and a probability that both components arrive on time of 99.42% in scenario 2 (b). This demonstrates that more reliable supply does indeed improve performance (less safety time needed for Table 2 The effect of more reliable supply on component lead times (LTc,s), service level (sc), and the probability that both components arrive on time (p) Scenario 1 Scenario 2 (a) Scenario 2 (b) mCCTc ¼ 10 days mCCTc ¼ 10 days mCCTc ¼ 10 days sCCTc ¼ 5 days sCCTc ¼ 5 days sCCTc ¼ 15 days 1.71 2.19 2.19 mc sc 1.09 0.47 0.47 95% 95% 99.71% sc LTc,s 33.08 19.45 33.08 p 90.25% 90.25% 99.42%
0.12 0.1 Scenario 1
0.08 0.06
Scenario 2
0.04 0.02 0
0
6 12 18 24 30 36
1 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0
Scenario 1 Scenario 2 95% service level 99.71% service level 0
6 12 18 24 30 36
Fig. 4 The density function and distribution function of the component cycle times for two levels of supply reliability
L. De Boeck and N. Vandaele Synchronization time of the components
536 50
45 40 35 30
variance = 0.083
25 20
variance = 0.333
15
variance = 0.750
10
variance = 1.333
5
0
1
11 21 31 41 51 61 71 81 91
Kits
Fig. 5 The synchronization time of components for two component flows with Uc(8,9), Uc(7.5,9.5), Uc(7,10), and Uc(6.5,10.5) distributed inter-arrival times
Inter–arrival time of the kits
9.2 9.1 9
variance = 0.083
8 .9
variance = 0.333 variance = 0.750
8.8
variance = 1.333
8 .7
8.6 8 .5
1
11 21 31 41 51 61 71 81 91 Kits
Fig. 6 The inter-arrival time of kits for two component flows with Uc(8,9), Uc(7.5,9.5), Uc(7,10), and Uc(6.5,10.5) distributed inter-arrival times
the same service level or more service for the same lead time). An analogue rationale is valid for the safety stock (cf. Little’s law). When looking at the formula for the synchronization time of the components (7), we observe here too that the variance of the component inter-arrival time distributions plays a major role. The higher the variance, the higher the component synchronization times and the higher the synchronization stock (due to Little’s law) are. This is represented in Fig. 5 assuming component inter-arrival times to be Uc(8,9) (variance equal to 0.083), Uc(7.5,9.5) (variance equal to 0.333), Uc(7,10) (variance equal to 0.750), and Uc(6.5,10.5) (variance equal to 1.333) distributed. The same result accounts for the inter-arrival time of kits (9) as represented in Fig. 6.
Coordination of Converging Material Flows Under Conditions of Uncertainty
537
It is important to see from Fig. 6 that the higher the variance is, the higher the interarrival time of kits is. Observe that a higher inter-arrival time means lower productivity, since fewer kits arrive at the assembly operation per time unit. However, in the limit (i ! 1), the inter-arrival time of kits converges to the average value of the component inter-arrival times. It is important to see that this convergence is slower when component inter-arrival times are subject to higher variability.
4.3
Performance Improves in Terms of Productivity with More Frequent Supply
By more frequent supply, we mean lower average component inter-arrival times. When taking (3) into account, we may point out that the safety time (zssc) does not depend on the average value of the component inter-arrival times. Indeed, more frequent supply (all other things being equal) does not change the shape of the density function of the component cycle times, but only causes a shift in this distribution. This means that the probability that all components arrive in time will not alter (keeping the safety time fixed). Along the same lines, it is worth noting from (7) that the synchronization time of components only depends on the variance of the component inter-arrival times. As a result, when changing the value for the average component inter-arrival times, all other things being equal, the synchronization time of components will not change. On the other hand, when looking at (9), the formula for the average kit interarrival times, we observe that this formula depends on the value of the average component inter-arrival times. More frequent supply, or lower values for these average component inter-arrival times, will also give rise to lower inter-arrival times of kits. This means that productivity increases since, per time unit, more kits arrive at the assembly operation. This is also clearly illustrated in Fig. 7.
Inter–arrival time of the kits
10.3 10.1 9.9 9.7
9.5
average = 8.5
9.3
average = 9
9.1
average = 9.5
8.9
average = 10
8.7 8.5
1
11 21 31 41 51 61 71 81 91 Kits
Fig. 7 The inter-arrival time of kits for two component flows with Uc(8,9), Uc(8.5,9.5), Uc(9,10), and Uc(9.5,10.5) distributed inter-arrival times
538
4.4
L. De Boeck and N. Vandaele
Performance Degrades with Complex Assemblies (More Components)
1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0
2
17 7 12 Number of component flows
Individual service level required for p=90.25%
Probability (p) that all components arrive on time for assembly
To simplify the proof, we assume that all individual component flows have the same service level. From (4) and Fig. 8 (left hand side) we can clearly see that the more converging flows are present, the lower becomes the probability that all components required for the assembly of a kit arrive on time. From Sect. 4.2 we know that each component flow having a service level of 95% results in a probability of both components arriving on time of 90.25%. However, if we have 20 converging flows, this probability lowers to 30.84%. On the other hand, fixing p at a level of 90.25% requires a higher service level for the individual component flows when the number of component flows increases (Fig. 8 right hand side). In addition, the synchronization time of components and the inter-arrival time of kits will increase when the number of components rises. For the formulas in the event of more than two component flows, we refer to De Boeck and Vandaele (2011). We illustrate what happens when the number of component flows is respectively 2, 3, 4 and 5, assuming Uc(8,9) distributed component inter-arrival times for all components. Note from Fig. 9 (left hand side) that the curve for the average value of the synchronization time of components shifts upwards and gets steeper as the number 1 0.99 0.98 0.97 0.96 0.95
2
17 7 12 Number of component flows
4
2 component flows
3
3 component flows
2
4 component flows
1 0
1
6 11 16 21 Kits
5 component flows
Inter–arrival time of the kits
Synchronization time of the components
Fig. 8 The probability (p) that all components arrive on time for assembly and the individual service level for each component flow required for p ¼ 90.25% when the number of converging component flows increases
8.8
2 component flows
8.7
3 component flows
8.6 8.5
1
6 11 16 21
4 component flows 5 component flows
Kits
Fig. 9 The synchronization time of components and the inter-arrival time of kits when the number of component flows increases
Coordination of Converging Material Flows Under Conditions of Uncertainty
539
of components grows. This means that it takes longer to get the individual components synchronized. The synchronization time gets steeper as the number of kits processed in one run increases, while at the same time the number of components increases. Figure 9 (right hand side) reveals that the curve for the average inter-arrival time of kits at the assembly operation shows the same behaviour as does the synchronization time: it shifts upwards and gets steeper. As a result, productivity drops because higher kit inter-arrival times result in a lower arrival rate at the assembly operation. However, be aware of the fact that at the limit (i ! 1), the inter-arrival time of kits converges to the average value of the component inter-arrival times, independent of the number of components. This convergence is slower when there are more component flows involved for assembly.
4.5
Assembly Needs the Coordination of Component Flows
Component flows must be coordinated, since the synchronization time does not converge (when the input processes are independent renewal processes) unless buffers are finite (Harrison 1973; Sect. 4.1). As a result, we observe that in the assembly literature there is always some kind of input control to preserve stability of this system. These “controlled” assembly systems can take many different forms. First, we observe assembly systems that operate with a maximum limit on the buffer capacity. These systems can be of two different types: one removes the components from the input processes when this maximum buffer capacity is reached (e.g., Lipper and Sengupta 1986; Takahashi et al. 2000) and the other shuts down the input process when this limit on the buffer capacity is attained (e.g., Simon and Hopp 1991, 1995; Hopp and Simon 1993; Som et al. 1994). Related to these controlled assembly systems with limiting buffer capacity are the assembly systems where the number of each component allowed in the system is limited (e.g., Bhat 1986). It should be noted that these assembly systems implicitly put a limit on the buffer capacity of the system. In the same way control mechanisms such as bins (e.g., Hopp and Simon 1989), conwip (e.g., Duenyas and Hopp 1993; Khojasteh-Ghamari 2009), kanban (e.g., Duenyas and Keblis 1995; Matta et al. 2005; Khojasteh-Ghamari 2009), and polca (Vandaele et al. 2008) control the system, since bins or cards determine the work-in-process of the system and, as a result, prevent the work-in-process from exploding. De Boeck and Vandaele (2008, 2011) assume a finite number of kits in the system (after which the system is emptied). In this way the assembly system is controlled by imposing a limit on the capacity of the system. At last we have assembly systems where the component arrivals are made dependent on each other. Related to these assembly systems are systems where component arrivals depend on how far the available amount of one component exceeds the available amount of another (e.g., Latouche 1981). Assembly systems where the component arrival process is stopped when the
540
L. De Boeck and N. Vandaele
number of units of that component exceeds the number of units of all the other components with a certain value (e.g., Bonomi 1987) also belong to this category. It is important to see that the literature on controlled assembly systems clearly reveals that converging component flows need to be coordinated. In every case, a limit on input flows is mandatory. This is typically implemented through some form of input control (such as limited buffer capacity, limit on the work-in-process allowed in the system or dependent component flow processes). Such a limit preserves the system from a diverging synchronization effect while at the same time being able to count on the converging inter-arrival time effect. Both effects are adverse but influence the efficiency and productivity of the supply chain. The former points to the time lost in synchronization stock, and the latter is the goal of supply chain coordination (De Boeck and Vandaele 2008).
5 Conclusions We know that in order to increase competitiveness in the supply chains, a better coordination of materials is one of the key factors. Therefore, in this chapter, we focused on the coordination of converging material flows in supply chains, also named “assembly”. As these converging material flows induce additional waiting time (defined as the synchronization time of components) and a modified arrival process at the assembly operation (defined as the inter-arrival time of kits), they play a major role in supply chain performance. In order to improve this performance (i.e., decrease the synchronization time of components and/or the inter-arrival time of kits), a few generic managerial insights can guide our way. These insights have been scientifically grounded on good approximations to the average value of the synchronization time of components and the inter-arrival time of kits at the assembly operation. We here briefly sum up these insights. 1. If we assume the component flows are characterized as independent renewal input processes and warehouses have enough (infinite) capacity, the converging material flows do not become synchronized. Or, in other words, the synchronization time of the converging component flows continues to rise. 2. From the above-mentioned insight, it is clear that the coordination of the component flows is mandatory. Looking at the underlying assumptions for this diverging behaviour of the synchronization time, we can undertake two types of measures. We can make the component flows dependent on each other and/or we can limit the work-in-process in our system. The latter can be put into practice by imposing a limit on the storage capacity or by limiting the number of components/kits allowed in the system. Related assembly literature proves that assembly systems are indeed controlled by relying on these measures. 3. A more reliable supply of components (with the same frequency) improves performance. Lowering the variance of the component flows leads to less safety time (and less safety stock) in order to maintain the same assembly schedule.
Coordination of Converging Material Flows Under Conditions of Uncertainty
541
If the initial lead time is maintained, more reliable supply leads to a better service level for the same assembly schedule. At the same time, more reliable supply results in less synchronization time (and synchronization stock) and shorter kit inter-arrival times (or improved productivity). 4. More frequent supply of components with the same level of reliability (i.e., not changing the variance) changes neither the required safety time nor the synchronization time. However, it improves productivity since the kit inter-arrival times decrease. 5. More components degrade system performance. That is because material flows are more complicated since more components require synchronization. The insights from these managerial insights extend to realistic systems. 1. We need some kind of input control to preserve stability. This can be realized by putting a maximum limit on the buffer capacity, limiting the number of each component allowed in the system or making component arrivals depend on each other. 2. Coordinating component flows (for assembly) is mandatory for preserving a system which contains a diverging synchronization effect. This coordination favors having fewer suppliers delivering more components (and more of the total purchased amount) because it may ultimately lead to more dependent component flows. That is because negotiating power increases due to the larger purchase percentage at the suppliers. 3. When selecting suppliers, reliability plays a major role. Higher levels of reliability result in less variable component cycle times. Even when the purchase price is higher, the savings in lower safety inventory, lower synchronization stock, higher productivity and higher on-time probability (i.e. lower schedule disruption costs) may justify a switch to a more reliable supplier (see e.g., Hopp and Spearman 2008). 4. More frequent supply results in more productivity. Here, however, we should take care that the system bottleneck can keep pace with this improved release rate. If this improved productivity results in very high system utilization or overutilization, more frequent supply is not advantageous. 5. The number of components needed for assembly should always be kept to a minimum. That is because more components increase safety time, synchronization time, schedule disruption costs, and decrease productivity.
References Bhat UN (1986) Finite capacity assembly-like queues. Queueing Syst 1:85–101 Bonomi F (1987) An approximate analysis for a class of assembly-like queues. Queueing Syst 1:289–309 Davis T (1993) Effective supply chain management. Sloan Manage Rev 34:35–46 De Boeck L, Vandaele N (2008) Coordination and synchronization of material flows in supply chains: an analytical approach. Int J Prod Econ 116:199–207
542
L. De Boeck and N. Vandaele
De Boeck L, Vandaele N (2011) Analytical analysis of a generic assembly system. Int J Prod Econ 131:107–114 Duenyas I, Hopp WJ (1993) Estimating the throughput of an exponential CONWIP assembly system. Queueing Syst 14:135–157 Duenyas I, Keblis MF (1995) Release policies for assembly systems. IIE Trans 27:507–518 Harrison MJ (1973) Assembly-like queues. J Appl Probab 10:354–367 Hopp WJ, Simon JT (1989) Bounds and heuristics for assembly-like queues. Queueing Syst 4:137–156 Hopp WJ, Simon JT (1993) Estimating throughput in an unbalanced assembly-like flow system. Int J Prod Res 31:851–868 Hopp WJ, Spearman ML (2008) Factory physics. McGraw-Hill, New York Khojasteh-Ghamari Y (2009) A performance comparison between Kanban and CONWIP controlled assembly systems. J Intell Manuf 20:751–760 Latouche G (1981) Queues with paired customers. J Appl Probab 18:684–696 Lipper EH, Sengupta B (1986) Assembly-like queues with finite capacity: bounds, asymptotics and approximations. Queueing Syst 1:67–83 Matta A, Dallery Y, Di Mascolo M (2005) Analysis of assembly systems controlled with kanbans. Eur J Oper Res 166:310–336 Ramachandran S, Delen D (2005) Performance analysis of a kitting process in stochastic assembly systems. Comput Oper Res 32:449–463 Simon JT, Hopp WJ (1991) Availability and average inventory of balanced assembly-like flow systems. IIE Trans 23:161–168 Simon JT, Hopp WJ (1995) Throughput and average inventory in discrete balanced assembly systems. IIE Trans 27:368–373 Som MP, Wilhelm WE, Disney RL (1994) Kitting process in a stochastic assembly system. Queueing Syst 17:471–490 Stadtler H, Kilger C (2000) Supply chain management and advanced planning. Springer, Berlin Takahashi M, Osawa H, Fujisawa T (2000) On a synchronisation queue with two finite buffers. Queueing Syst Theory Appl 36:107–123 Vandaele N, De Boeck L (2003) Advanced resource planning. Robot Comput Integr Manuf 19:210–218 Vandaele N, De Boeck L, Callewier D (2002) An open queuing network for lead time analysis. IIE Trans 34:1–9 Vandaele N, Van Nieuwenhuyse I, Claerhout D, Cremmery R (2008) Load-based POLCA: an integrated material control system for multiproduct, multimachine job shops. Manuf Serv Oper Manage 10:181–197 Van Nieuwenhuyse I, De Boeck L, Lambrecht M, Vandaele N (2011) Advanced resource planning as a decision support module for ERP. Comput Ind 62:1–8
Part V
Empirical Analysis and Case Studies
.
Bioenergy Systems and Supply Chains in Europe: Conditions, Capacity and Coordination Kes McCormick
Abstract There are considerable biomass resources in the European Union and mature conversion technologies to exploit the potentials of bioenergy. A challenge confronting the European Union and Member States is how to accelerate the implementation of bioenergy systems and related supply chains. This chapter contributes to the identification, analysis, and discussion of constraints for bioenergy in the European Union. Adopting a combination of research methods and different informants from six case studies across Europe, this chapter identifies economic conditions, institutional capacity, and supply coordination as the key constraints obstructing the expansion of bioenergy. Furthermore, the case studies expose four points about constraints for bioenergy. First, there are no absolute constraints to realising the potentials of bioenergy in the European Union. Second, it is non-technical challenges that are hindering bioenergy rather than technical issues. Third, constraints for bioenergy are dynamic and depend on the context. Fourth, there are consistent strategies observed in the case studies to overcome constraints. Keywords Bioenergy systems • Renewable energy • Supply chains • Sustainable development
1 Introduction A significant challenge confronting the European Union (EU) and its Member States is how to expand bioenergy utilisation to meet key targets, policy goals, and international commitments on renewable energy, climate change, energy security, and sustainable development. This chapter explores the implementation of bioenergy systems in Europe with an emphasis on the required supply chains. The purpose of K. McCormick International Institute for Industrial Environmental Economics (IIIEE) Lund University, Lund, Sweden e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_22, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
545
546
K. McCormick
Fig. 1 Components and constraints for bioenergy systems
this chapter is to improve understanding of key constraints for bioenergy systems and supply chains as well as experiences of strategies to overcome constraints. Bioenergy systems comprise four main components, which are biomass resources, transport systems (to move the resources to the technologies), conversion technologies and energy services. The role of supply chains in bioenergy systems is easy to discern, particularly when considering the range of actors involved in bioenergy – from forestry companies to local governments. This chapter focuses on local bioenergy systems drawing on the experiences of six case studies from across Europe, including Sweden, Finland, the UK, Italy, Poland and Austria. To provide a broader context, this chapter also briefly discusses global supply chains for bioenergy. Based on this research, the key constraints for bioenergy can be defined as the three Cs or economic conditions, institutional capacity, and supply coordination (see Fig. 1). While this chapter focuses on the three Cs there are two further Cs that have recently emerged. These are sustainability certification and stakeholder communication. These are particularly important issues for the fast-growing bioenergy sector in the EU, both in the near-term and for long-term success. This chapter devotes some discussion to these points.
2 Background Humans exploit biomass (plant and animal matter) for many purposes. When it is utilised to produce heat, electricity or fuels for transport it is commonly called bioenergy (see Fig. 2).1 Of the range of renewable energy options available, 1
Biomass can be considered as “stored” solar energy because the process of photosynthesis “captures” energy from sun in growing plants. Utilising biomass for energy purposes is in fact tapping into the vast energy available from the sun.
Bioenergy Systems and Supply Chains in Europe
547
Fig. 2 Bioenergy pathways
bioenergy offers the greatest potentials both in the near-term and overall as it can supply a considerable proportion of renewable energy, and it offers the widest range of energy products, and provides significant direct and indirect benefits (Berndes et al. 2003; Domac and Richards 2002; International Energy Agency 2007a; Rogner 2000; Turkenburg 2000).2 These include: • Contribution to climate mitigation and adaptation strategies by replacing fossil fuels, and benefits related to a range of environmental concerns (Sims 2002). • Improvement of energy security from more indigenous energy supply, and reduction of energy imports, particularly oil (European Renewable Energy Council 2004). • Maintenance of a robust agricultural and forestry economy through the production of biomass with socio-economic benefits, such as employment opportunities (European Commission 2005a). • Potential for innovative scientific and technological developments that can provide industrial growth and security, and opportunities for exports (Boyle 2004). This research explores bioenergy systems, which shifts the emphasis to whole systems rather than a specific part. As stated, bioenergy systems comprise four main components, which are biomass resources, transport systems, conversion
2
For more details on the direct and indirect benefits of bioenergy systems see McCormick (2005).
548
K. McCormick
Local Governments Research Institutes
Forestry Companies
Biomass Resources Transport Systems ConversionTechnologies Energy Services
Waste Management Companies
Farmers
Local Energy Companies
Residents Environment Groups
Web of networks, partnerships and policies
Fig. 3 Actors in bioenergy systems
technologies and energy services. Furthermore, there are a range of actors engaged in (or affected by) bioenergy systems (see Fig. 3). These actors are connected through a complex and dynamic web of networks, partnerships and policies. The actors can include local governments, research institutes, forestry companies, farmers, waste management companies, residents, environment groups, and local energy companies. In this chapter, supply chains are considered as systems of organizations, people, technology, activities, information and resources involved in a product or service from suppliers to customers. Supply chain activities transform raw materials and technical components into a finished product or service that is delivered to customers. The role of supply chains in bioenergy systems is easy to identify, particularly when considering the range of actors involved in bioenergy systems and the diversity of suppliers for both raw materials and technical components (International Energy Agency 2007b). But what is the difference between bioenergy systems and supply chains? For this research, bioenergy systems are considered a broad concept that encompasses technical components as well as a diversity of non-technical aspects. The relationships between actors are also central to bioenergy systems, especially considering the web of networks, partnerships and policies in the bioenergy sector. Supply chains are viewed as a process within bioenergy systems, particularly in relation to biomass production for energy purposes (and to move the biomass resources to the conversion technologies).
Bioenergy Systems and Supply Chains in Europe
549
3 Methods and Approach This chapter is based on a combination of research methods and different informants from six case studies across Europe. An important objective was to utilise a number of research methods to meet the requirements of “method” triangulation (Bloor 1997; Morrow and Brown 1994). These research methods included literature reviews, case studies, site visits, stakeholder interviews, industry interactions, and research workshops. Interviews were also conducted with informants from a range of sectors and different backgrounds in order to carry out “informant” triangulation (Bloor 1997). Overall, this chapter applies a systems approach (Meadows 2002; Olsson and Sj€ostedt 2004). Systems thinking is utilised worldwide and has become established in some disciplines (International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis 1980). However, the systems approach has many interpretations and could be seen as a controversial concept (Olsson and Sj€ ostedt 2004). For this research, the systems approach involves studying problems in a holistic way utilising a range of research methods and concepts from different disciplines. Applying systems thinking to bioenergy highlights all the elements that make up bioenergy systems and the interactions between the elements (Meadows 2002). Bioenergy systems comprise a range of inputs, outputs, interactions and feedbacks. In particular, this chapter explores the web of networks, partnerships and policies relevant to the bioenergy field. A systems approach also clearly highlights that bioenergy involves both technical aspects and non-technical issues (Geels 2004).
4 Global Supply Chains The development of global supply chains for bioenergy is a “hot” topic. However, there is limited analysis of this emerging area. An exception is the work by Peck et al. (2010) who provide a range of insights into global supply chains for bioenergy. The starting point for this research is that more attention is needed on how significant amounts of biomass for energy purposes can be delivered to the market, particularly through international trade. Additionally, examples of immaturity in the bioenergy market and details of some of the challenges that exist because of this condition are provided by Peck et al. (2010). They explore a number of key areas, including: • How and where biomass supply chains are developing and the forms they take • Where institutional weaknesses are apparent and the manners in which bioenergy proponents can seek to overcome them • How can a professional system serving the bioenergy sector arise and serve global supply chains • How policy positively and negatively affects bioenergy development and where bioenergy proponents can better influence policy
550
K. McCormick
• Which potential sources and forms of biomass appear to be the most interesting or feasible for “acceleration” (Peck et al. 2010) Peck et al. (2010) present quantifications for a number of biomass resources that are viewed as potentially available in the near-term and medium-term, including: residue flows from agriculture and forestry, and “new” dedicated feedstock supply systems. Furthermore, modelling supporting this research shows that there is substantial scope for efficiency improvements in the food chain thereby reducing the amount of land required for food production. Rather than expand agricultural land globally by some 280 Mha by 2030, the scenarios developed show that it is feasible to reduce global agricultural requirements by 230 Mha from current levels – thereby providing considerable scope for expansion of dedicated energy crops (Peck et al. 2010). While this is possible, how (and if) it could be achieved is highly questionable. In addition to analysis of land availability, Peck et al. (2010) identify common themes that point towards the types of actions required to establish, develop and strengthen global supply chains for bioenergy. They suggest the following: • • • • • • •
Efforts towards increased professionalism in the bioenergy industry Markedly increased public and political acceptance and understanding Aligned and consistent forms of collective action Synergistic alliances with incumbent industries Careful application of assessment schemes Building of resilient technology strategies Sourcing of biomass via pathways that are accepted by broad stakeholder groups (Peck et al. 2010)
This work draws heavily on management theory and examples. This helps to demonstrate how themes or issues for bioenergy are common across other industries. Peck et al. (2010) therefore argue that the bioenergy industry can look to the experiences of other industries and learn from the difficulties to be anticipated for a growing sector, and the strategies employed to overcome constraints. There are many challenges ahead for the bioenergy sector in regards to global supply chains. In order to move forwards successfully, it is clear that research from the field is vital to better understand the development of both bioenergy systems and supply chains.
5 Local Bioenergy Systems As described, this research involved six case studies from across the EU located in Sweden, Finland, Austria, Poland, Italy, and the UK.3 The case studies comprise a range of inputs (such as forest resources, agriculture resources, energy crops, and municipal solid waste); outputs (such as heat, electricity, rapeseed cake, biodiesel, 3
For details about the six case studies see McCormick and Ka˚berger (2007).
Bioenergy Systems and Supply Chains in Europe
551
Table 1 Background for case studies Source
Location
Type
Input
Technology
McCormick and Ka˚berger (2005) Tomescu (2005)
Enk€oping, Sweden
Success
Forest resources, energy crops
CHP plant, biomass Heat, electricity boiler
Mureck, Austria
Success
Palonen and Nieminen (2005) Warmburg et al. (2004)
Lahti, Finland
Success
Biodiesel plant bioheat plant, CHP plant, biogas plant Biomass gasifier
Heat, electricity, biodiesel, biogas, rapeseed cake Heat, electricity, steam
Umbertide, Italy
Potential
CHP plant
Heat, electricity
Nilsson et al. (2004) Upham and Shackley (2006)
Gubin, Poland
Potential
Forest resources, agriculture resources, energy crops Municipal solid waste, forest resources Forest resources, agriculture resources, energy crops Energy crops
CHP plant
Heat, electricity
Energy crops, forest resources
Biomass gasifier
Electricity
Winkleigh, UK Potential
Output
biogas, and steam); and different conversion technologies (see Table 1). Within the case studies there are three examples of success and three examples of unrealised potential. The case studies provide insights into the key constraints hindering the development and diffusion of bioenergy systems and the related supply chains in the EU as well as strategies to overcome constraints. The selection of case studies from across Europe is based on an interest to explore experiences with bioenergy in different contexts (see Fig. 4). Only a few Member States in the EU have significant shares of bioenergy. The utilisation of biomass for energy purposes varies greatly between Member States depending on a range of factors, including policies and strategies for bioenergy and renewable energy, available natural resources, and the structure of energy systems (European Renewable Energy Council 2004). Sweden, Finland and Austria can be considered leading countries on bioenergy utilisation (Fagern€as et al. 2006). Italy and the UK in Western Europe are only starting to expand the implementation of bioenergy systems. The experiences in Eastern Europe are also relevant because of considerable biomass production potentials. Poland in particular could become exporters of solid and liquid biofuels to Europe. This chapter therefore explores countries both from Western Europe (including the pioneering Member States and those in the infant stages of developing bioenergy) and Eastern Europe.
5.1
Economic Conditions
Initiating bioenergy systems requires overcoming many obstacles related to economic conditions, which are heavily influenced by political support and policy
552
K. McCormick
Fig. 4 Location of case studies
measures (Fagern€as et al. 2006). Economic conditions have both a broad context and specific issues for investors. Broadly speaking, bioenergy systems compete with fossil fuels and nuclear power, which have the advantage of both energy subsidies and externalised costs.4 Furthermore, the positive impacts or benefits of bioenergy systems are rarely recognised in energy markets (without supportive policy measures). More specifically, the case studies from Sweden, Finland, Austria, Italy, Poland, and the UK highlight that investors face a number of significant constraints to implement (and invest in) bioenergy systems and related supply chains. Put simply, the obstacles relate to “who pays?” and “who benefits?” in relation to bioenergy systems. Investment grants, carbon and energy taxes, and green certificate schemes are all evident in the case studies as ways to recognise (and value) externalised benefits of bioenergy systems that do not flow to investors but rather to the local community or national goals (Hahn 2000). There is distorted competition in energy markets linked primarily to energy subsidies. A report by the European Environment Agency (2004) provides an assessment of energy subsides in the EU.5 While there is no agreed definition for 4 The term externalities refers to a cost or benefit from any activity that affects actors “external” to the activity. In other words, the “internal” actors do not bear all of the costs or reap all of the benefits. Externalities can be either positive, when externalised benefits are generated, or negative, when externalised costs are imposed on others (Carter 2001). 5 Visit http://www.externe.info/ for more information on energy subsidies.
Bioenergy Systems and Supply Chains in Europe
553
energy subsidies (resulting in different estimates and confusing debates) the report concludes that fossil fuels and nuclear power continue to profit from energy subsidies. It also argues that sustained support is needed for renewable energy to shift towards sustainable energy systems. In order to expand renewable energy it is also important to consider externalised costs, which are often excluded from energy markets. A report for the European Commission (2003) on externalised costs outlines the negative impacts of fossil fuels, nuclear power, and renewable energy.6 Not surprisingly, the report shows that fossil fuels and nuclear power produce significant negative impacts compared to renewable energy. For renewable energy to compete with fossil fuels and nuclear power, it is crucial that externalised costs are internalised in energy markets in some way through policy measures (Forsyth 2003). As stated, bioenergy systems often produce positive impacts that are not compensated by energy markets, including improving energy security, combating climate change, and promoting regional development (Boyle 2004; European Commission 2005b). These externalised benefits are often described and documented by investors. However, it is rare that the positive impacts of bioenergy are able to actually support investors (Sims 2002). For example, in the Winkleigh case study there are a number of benefits associated with the development of a bioenergy system. However, investors are unable to incorporate these benefits into evaluations. Investment grants were critical to establishing the bioenergy systems in both the Enk€oping case study and the Mureck case study. In the Enk€oping case study the investment grants accounted for approximately 40% of the investment costs. In the Mureck case study there are several connected bioenergy systems, which received investment grants between approximately 30 and 75% of the total investment costs. Investments grants are used as interventions in energy markets to recognise externalised benefits and therefore promote sustainable energy systems (Carter 2001). The carbon tax in Sweden has altered economic conditions making bioenergy sufficiently competitive with fossil fuels for heat production, which is evident in the Enk€oping case study.7 Recently, a green certificate scheme has provided further incentives for electricity from biomass in Sweden.8 In Finland, there is research and development, carbon and energy taxes, and investment grants, dedicated to expanding renewable energy. The Lahti case study highlights the positive effects of national policy measures in Finland. This support (in Sweden and Finland) is in explicit recognition of the positive impacts associated with bioenergy systems 6
Visit http://reports.eea.eu.int/ for more information on externalised costs. In 1991, the Swedish Government imposed a carbon tax on greenhouse gas emissions from the combustion of fossil fuels to produce heat (Swedish Energy Agency 2004). Since 2004, the Swedish Government has adjusted and reduced the carbon tax. However, it remains a powerful policy support for bioenergy. 8 The effects of the green certificate scheme in Sweden are debateable. While green certificates are intended to support bioenergy systems, they also create uncertainty for investors because it is extremely difficult to predict the evolution of prices for green certificates (Jacobsson 2006). 7
554
K. McCormick
(and negative impacts of fossil fuels), and the fact they are not recognised by energy markets. The dependence on energy imports in Italy is expanding interest in renewable energy. The implementation of a green certificate scheme has also improved the profitability of renewable energy. However, bioenergy systems in Italy, as explored in the Umbertide case study, require further support to compete with energy imports. The Gubin case study shows that there is no effective enforcement of national policy measures and no significant incentives for energy crops in Poland. If energy crops are to expand in Poland (and the EU) then it is imperative to create favourable economic conditions for farmers to invest in energy crops (Gosse 2006).
5.2
Institutional Capacity
Bioenergy systems comprise biomass resources, transport systems, conversion technologies, and energy services. When it comes to establishing bioenergy systems a combination of institutional capacity and know-how (knowledge and skills) is needed to shift from unrealised potential to success. A lack of understanding of the bioenergy industry by the finance sector may be a barrier as well as a lack of experienced maintenance staff. The required know-how may be developed in existing actors through learning processes as well as by the introduction of “new” actors. In the Gubin case study, a company from Sweden (with knowledge and skills on bioenergy) assisted with cultivating energy crops in Poland. Learning processes are evident in the Enk€ oping case study where the local energy companies developed experience with bioenergy in the decades that followed the oil crises in the 1970s. In the Lahti case study, there was confidence in the reliability of conversion technologies and availability of biomass resources, which resulted in a swift installation and transition to exploiting bioenergy. In contrast, there is modest knowledge and skills with bioenergy in the Umbertide case study. Confidence to make investments is therefore fragile. In the Gubin case study it is apparent that utilities in Poland have little experience with renewable energy and significant interests in fossil fuels. Energy crops are expected to play an important role in expanding bioenergy in the EU and across Member States (European Commission 2005a). However, farmers often have limited experience with growing, processing, storing, and transporting energy crops. Uncertainty based on a lack of experience discourages many farmers from investing in energy crops. In the Enk€oping case study, farmers thinking about establishing dedicated energy crops have articulated serious concerns over flexibility, knowledge, and risks. Even when farmers are convinced of the long-term viability of energy corps, they are often too concerned by shortterm effects on their work practices and economic flows. There are considerable possibilities for expanding energy crops in Poland (Ericsson and Nilsson 2006). However, the Gubin case study indicates that farmers are in desperate need of support and demonstrations of biomass production.
Bioenergy Systems and Supply Chains in Europe
555
In the Gubin case study the common response by farmers about their views on energy crops is “they believe what they see and not what they hear”. Since there are few examples of profitable plantations of energy crops in Poland the vast majority of farmers show little interest to invest any resources (or time) into bioenergy systems. Bioenergy is often considered a fuel of the past rather than a fuel of the present and future (Hall and Scrase 1998). An improved understanding of bioenergy systems by the public and politicians is important to generate the support necessary for expanding bioenergy in the EU. In fact, a limited awareness of bioenergy often results in resistance to viable and profitable bioenergy systems as demonstrated in the Winkleigh case study in the UK. Altering the perceptions of both the public and politicians about utilising biomass for energy purposes is closely linked to building up the legitimacy of the bioenergy industry. In the Umbertide case study, there is opposition to bioenergy because it is perceived as waste incineration. What causes some of the confusion is that biomass resources in Italy are legally categorised as waste. It is therefore commercially difficult to exploit bioenergy.9 In contrast, the reaction by the community in the Lahti case study to the utilisation of Municipal Solid Waste (MSW) in the CHP plant is predominantly positive rather than the expected negative response. What appears important is that the profits from the CHP plant flow back into the local community and the management costs for disposing of MSW have declined.
5.3
Supply Coordination
Bioenergy systems require functioning and organised supply chains that meet the needs of all relevant actors. Energy companies and biomass suppliers are significant actors in bioenergy systems. Investing in biomass resources is generally only possible if there are energy companies purchasing biomass. In addition, establishing conversion technologies is generally only possible if there are biomass suppliers supplying biomass.10 Furthermore, technologies and systems are required for harvesting, refining, and transporting biomass. Supply coordination is therefore critical to the implementation of bioenergy systems across the EU. The bioenergy system in the Mureck case study provides electricity, heat, and fuels for transport. The impressive cooperation between a regional network of actors is important to the success. The companies initiated cooperation primarily because they recognised the advantage of working together. In the Enk€oping case 9 Different definitions and legislation for waste across the Member States in the EU can present problems for investors in bioenergy systems (Fagern€as et al. 2006). When feedstocks are categorised as waste this often means more stringent legislation (and possibly different reactions from the public and politicians). On the other hand, when feedstocks receive a different classification it can be a more straightforward process for investors. 10 This can be called the “chicken and egg” problem. Essentially it highlights the challenge of investing in biomass resources at the same time as establishing conversion technologies. Neither can proceed without the other but it is difficult to draw up contracts that are acceptable to both energy companies and biomass suppliers (in many cases).
556
K. McCormick
study the formation of partnerships has helped to manage the expanding bioenergy system. In contrast, there are problems with establishing collaboration between companies and the local government in the Umbertide case study. There is a similar experience in the Gubin case study where bringing the actors together is difficult. In some instances there is competition for biomass resources. In the Enk€oping case study, the local energy companies manage a bioenergy system that utilises a range of biomass resources. This bioenergy system allows flexibility in terms of inputs when competition arises for biomass. Competition for land is also a discussion when it comes to expanding energy crops (Gosse 2006). In the Umbertide case study, the tobacco industry is hindering the introduction of energy crops. The tobacco industry is in transition. However, the already established (and heavily subsidised) tobacco plantations mean that farmers have little motivation to change to energy crops. In contrast to issues of competition, there are often synergies between local actors when establishing bioenergy systems (Fagern€as et al. 2006; Sims 2002). In the Mureck case study, farmers cultivate rapeseed, which is transformed into rapeseed cake and biodiesel. The rapeseed cake serves as a protein feed for livestock, and the biodiesel is used in local vehicles. Such examples are common in bioenergy systems. However, realising synergies often requires strong cooperation between a mix of local actors and supply coordination. Energy crops are expected to play a considerable role in future bioenergy systems (Hall and Scrase 1998). However, the present contribution of energy crops in the EU is negligible (European Commission 2005a). The Gubin case study shows the potentials for energy crops in Poland. Supply coordination appears crucial to encourage farmers to invest in energy crops. Farmers need support, demonstrations, and contracts with energy companies. The Enk€oping case study also indicates that farmers remain unconvinced by energy companies about the viability and profitability of energy crops. Greater incentives are required to compensate the risks. The Gubin case study highlights the possibilities for international trade of solid and liquid biofuels, at least within Europe. The “story” started with a number of energy companies operating a CHP plant in Berlin, who were eager to utilise biomass for energy purposes but argued that there were limited biomass resources in Germany. However, over the border in Poland there are considerable potentials for harvesting energy crops, which can be used locally or traded internationally. A challenge (or opportunity) for farmers in the Gubin case study in Poland is to establish connections (and deals) with energy companies in Germany, such as with the CHP plant in Berlin.
6 Discussion and Reflections Studies on constraints obstructing the development of bioenergy often adopt different analytical perspectives and produce lists of many types of obstacles. Based on literature reviews, case studies, site visits, stakeholder interviews, industry
Bioenergy Systems and Supply Chains in Europe
557
interactions, and research workshops, this research attempted to identify key constraints for bioenergy systems and supply chains in Europe. Furthermore, the six case studies from Sweden, Finland, Austria, Italy, Poland, and the UK illustrate how the key constraints affect “real” bioenergy systems and also the strategies applied by actors in the case studies to overcome obstacles.
6.1
Defining the Key Constraints
Bioenergy systems, as with all renewable energy, must compete with fossil fuels and nuclear power, which have received and continue to benefit from energy subsidies and externalised costs. Furthermore, bioenergy often produces positive impacts that are not compensated by energy markets. Overcoming unfavourable economic conditions through effective and efficient policy measures (that recognise externalised benefits and penalise for externalised costs) is vital to the success of bioenergy systems. When establishing bioenergy systems a combination of know-how (knowledge and skills) and institutional capacity is needed to shift from unrealised potential to success. For example, a lack of understanding of the bioenergy industry by the finance sector may be an obstacle as well as a lack of experienced maintenance staff. Furthermore, learning processes and altering perceptions of both the public and politicians about bioenergy is often required to build up legitimacy for the bioenergy industry. Bioenergy systems require supply coordination to overcome the “chicken and egg” problem. Investing in biomass resources is generally only possible if there are energy companies purchasing biomass, and establishing conversion technologies is generally only possible if biomass suppliers exist to provide biomass. In particular, agreements on biomass supply appear to be crucial for farmers to harvest energy crops. There is also emerging competition for biomass resources and potentially land use conflicts. As presented, this chapter has defined the key constraints for bioenergy in Europe as the three Cs or economic conditions, institutional capacity and supply coordination. This is based primarily on the research from the case studies. However, there are two more Cs that deserve attention. These are sustainability certification and stakeholder communication. These are emerging as particularly important for the fast-growing bioenergy sector in the EU – both in the near-term and for long-term success. There is growing concern about the environmental and social impacts of bioenergy systems, particularly for liquid biofuels. The introduction of sustainability certification appears to be firmly on the bioenergy agenda in the EU. Designing these schemes is the first step, but how to effectively implement these schemes is a problematic second step. Verified supply chains, checking carbon and sustainability criteria, is growing in importance. A key question is will this place excessive economic costs and an administrative burden on bioenergy companies and those
558
K. McCormick
engaged in supply chains or will it ensure public and political support and thereby open up the market for international trade? The current focus on carbon and sustainability criteria for bioenergy systems and related supply chains can be expected to intensify. An understanding of bioenergy systems and the related supply chains by the general public and key stakeholders appears to be essential to political support and long-term success. Furthermore, a lack of trust and awareness of bioenergy systems often results in resistance to new systems and supportive policies. This is demonstrated in the case studies from across Europe. The role of stakeholder communication can therefore not be underestimated for the growing bioenergy sector. Last, but certainly not least, increased stakeholder and public engagement (connected to sustainability certification) can help to ensure the sustainability of bioenergy systems from environmental and social perspectives. There is clearly a synergy between sustainability certification and stakeholder communication.
6.2
Overcoming the Key Constraints
While there are key constraints hindering bioenergy systems, this research identifies no absolute obstacles to realising the targets on bioenergy utilisation defined by the EU. Not surprisingly, supportive economic policies as well as partnerships between the public and private sectors, often in the form of Public-Private Partnerships (PPPs), are observed in the case studies as influential in the development of bioenergy systems and supply chains. The role of transformation processes also deserves attention. Overall, there are some consistent strategies evident in the case studies that are employed to overcome key constraints (see Table 2). These include: • Investment grants: The initial investments in bioenergy systems are often stumbling blocks even if key stakeholders consider the financial returns of the overall project viable. Investment grants for conversion technologies were clearly vital for several bioenergy systems in the case studies. • Policy measures: Agreed and established national policy measures, such as green certificate schemes and carbon and energy taxes, were critical to altering economic conditions and making bioenergy sufficiently competitive with fossil fuels in the successful case studies. • Pilot projects: Developing know-how and institutional capacity often requires pilot projects to stimulate learning processes. These initial projects helped to also build legitimacy for bioenergy in the case studies. • Local initiatives: Programs and policies on climate change, environmental protection, and regional development are identified in the case studies as the foundations for local involvement from the public and politicians in bioenergy systems. • Local champions: The successful bioenergy systems in the case studies were all characterised by leading individuals, who were able to build networks between organisations and guide the development of projects.
Bioenergy Systems and Supply Chains in Europe Table 2 Strategies for bioenergy systems Constraints Strategies Economic conditions Investment grants
Policy measures
Institutional capacity
Pilot projects
Local initiatives
Supply coordination
Local champions
Supply contracts
559
Examples In the Enk€oping case study and the Mureck case study investment grants were critical to establishing the bioenergy systems In the Enk€oping case study it is evident that the carbon tax transformed economic conditions for bioenergy In the Mureck case study and the Enk€oping case study pilot projects were important in building capacity and institutional learning In the Mureck case study the local initiatives on regional development generated interest and support for bioenergy In the Enk€oping case study and the Mureck case study the important role played by local champions is irrefutable In the Lahti case study and the Mureck case study supply contracts are the foundations of the bioenergy systems
• Supply contracts: Contracts and agreements between biomass suppliers and energy companies are observed in the case studies as significant to establishing functioning bioenergy systems. Technological systems in the early stages of development, such as bioenergy systems, often require supportive economic policies (Carter 2001). There are always debates about if subsidies should have sunset clauses and whether tax breaks are necessary. For the bioenergy industry there are two justifications for supportive economic policies. First, bioenergy systems often have lower environmental impacts and greenhouse gas emissions compared to fossil fuels. However, these externalised benefits are rarely recognised on energy markets (Boyle 2004; Sims 2002). Second, bioenergy systems may be competitive with fossil fuels in the longterm but require assistance in the short-term to establish “infant” technological systems (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development and International Energy Agency 2003; Turkenburg 2000). The second argument weakens as the bioenergy industry grows and strengthens. Supportive economic policies, such as subsidies, should therefore be temporary and involve sunset clauses (Ka˚berger 2004). However, permanent tax breaks in relation to fossil fuels are justified because of the first argument on lower environmental impacts and greenhouse gas emissions. Permanent tax breaks therefore apply a value to these externalised benefits on energy markets (Hahn 2000). As suggested, PPPs are evident in some of the case studies as ways to engage both public and private actors in the implementation of bioenergy systems. As explained, bioenergy systems often result in externalised benefits that flow to the local community or support national goals. PPPs combine the social responsibility,
560
K. McCormick
environmental awareness, and accountability of the public sector, with the finance, managerial efficiency, and entrepreneurial spirit of the private sector (Andersen 2004; von Malmborg 2003). In the case studies, PPPs between local governments and investors to develop bioenergy systems can meet the objectives of both actors. For local governments, the externalised benefits (such as creating local employment and meeting environmental targets) are obtained by collaborating with the investors. For the investors, the support from the local governments can provide the necessary ingredient to invest in bioenergy systems. However, there are “real” challenges to define the roles and activities of different actors in PPPs (Andersen 2004). This demands further research attention. While it is clear from this research that policies and economic incentives are essential for bioenergy systems, it is also apparent that success requires these policies and economic incentives to be interpreted and adapted to different local contexts and translated into transformation processes. Based on examples from Sweden, Ma˚rtensson and Westerberg (2007) show that what is fundamental for transformation processes within local energy systems is how problems and solutions are viewed, how resources and actors are mobilized, and how the process of change is organized and communicated. In this research, the case studies also point towards problem formulation, mobilization and communication as centrally important to transformation processes towards bioenergy in local energy systems. Clearly, this is another area for further research.
References Andersen O (2004) Public-private partnerships: organisational hybrids as channels for local mobilisation and participation? Scand Polit Stud 27(1):1–21 Berndes G, Hoogwijk M, van den Broek R (2003) The contribution of biomass in the future global energy supply: a review of 17 studies. Biomass Bioenergy 25:1–28 Bloor M (1997) Techniques of validation in qualitative research: a critical commentary. In: Miller G, Dingwall R (eds) Context and method in qualitative research. Sage, London Boyle G (2004) Renewable energy. Oxford University Press, Oxford Carter N (2001) The politics of the environment: ideas, activism, policy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Domac J, Richards K (2002) Socio-economic aspects of bioenergy systems. Paper presented at the European conference on biomass for energy and climate protection, Amsterdam Ericsson K, Nilsson LJ (2006) Assessment of the potential biomass supply in Europe using a resource-focused approach. Biomass Bioenergy 20:1–15 European Commission (2003) External costs: research results on socio-environmental damages due to electricity and transport. Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg European Commission (2005a) Biomass: green energy for Europe. Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg European Commission (2005b) Biomass action plan. Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg
Bioenergy Systems and Supply Chains in Europe
561
European Environment Agency (2004) Energy subsidies in the European Union: a brief overview. European Environment Agency, Copenhagen European Renewable Energy Council (2004) Renewable energy in Europe: building markets and capacity. James and James, London Fagern€as L, Johansson A, Wile´n C, Sipil€a K, M€akinen T, Helynen S (2006) Bioenergy in Europe: opportunities and barriers. VTT Processes, Espoo Forsyth T (2003) Critical political ecology: the politics of environmental science. Routledge, London Geels FW (2004) From sectoral systems of innovation to socio-technical systems: insights about dynamics and change from sociology and institutional theory. Res Policy 33:897–920 Gosse G (2006) Biomass from agricultural land? Paper presented at the European conference on biorefinery research, Helsinki Hahn R (2000) The impact of economics on environmental policy. J Environ Econ Manage 39:375–399 Hall D, Scrase J (1998) Will biomass be the environmentally friendly fuel of the future? Biomass Bioenergy 15(4–5):357–367 International Energy Agency (2007a) About bioenergy. http://www.aboutbioenergy.info/. Retrieved 15 Mar 2007 International Energy Agency (2007b) Bioenergy project development and biomass supply. http:// www.iea.org/. Retrieved 15 Mar 2007 International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (1980) Beware the pitfalls: a short guide to avoiding common errors in systems analysis. International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Laxenburg Jacobsson S (2006) Policy challenges for bio-power in Sweden. Paper presented at the world bioenergy conference, J€ onk€ oping Ka˚berger T (2004) Environmental impacts from bioenergy: a view from Sweden. Paper presented at the Scottish natural heritage conference, Pitlochry Ma˚rtensson K, Westerberg K (2007) How to transform local energy systems towards bioenergy? Three strategy models for transformation. Energy Policy 35:6095–6105 McCormick K (2005) Sustainable bioenergy systems: experiences from Sweden. Paper presented at the Asia Pacific roundtable on sustainable consumption and production, Melbourne McCormick K, Ka˚berger T (2005) Exploring a pioneering bioenergy system: the case of Enk€oping in Sweden. J Cleaner Prod 13:1003–1014 McCormick K, Ka˚berger T (2007) Key barriers for bioenergy in Europe: economic conditions, know-how and institutional capacity, and supply chain co-ordination. Energy Policy 31: 443–452 Meadows D (2002) Dancing with systems. Whole Earth 13(2):58–64 Morrow RA, Brown DD (1994) Critical theory and methodology. Sage, London Nilsson L, Pisarek M, Buriak J, Oniszk-Poplawska A, Bucko P, Ericsson K (2004) Bioenergy policy and strategies for Poland. Paper presented at the world conference on biomass for energy, industry and climate protection, Rome Olsson M, Sj€ostedt G (2004) Systems and systems theory. In: Olsson M, Sj€ostedt G (eds) Systems approaches and their application. Kluwer, Boston Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, International Energy Agency (2003) Technology innovation, development and diffusion. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development and the International Energy Agency, Paris Palonen J, Nieminen J (2005) Biomass gasifier: demonstration project at Kymijarvi power station at Lahti, Finland. http://www.fwc.com/. Retrieved 28 Oct 2005 Peck P, Berndes G, Hektor B (2010) Mobilising global bioenergy supply chains: keys to unlocking the potential of bioenergy. International Institute for Industrial Environmental Economics, Lund (Study prepared for the Swedish Energy Agency) Rogner H (2000) Energy resources. In: World Energy Assessment (ed) Energy and the challenge of sustainability. United Nations Development Programme, New York
562
K. McCormick
Sims R (2002) The brilliance of bioenergy in business and practice. James and James, London Swedish Energy Agency (2004) Renewable energy in the new millennium. http://www.stem.se/. Retrieved 10 April 2007 Tomescu M (2005) Innovative bioenergy systems in action: the case of the Mureck bioenergy cycle. International Institute for Industrial Environmental Economics, Lund (Study prepared for the Bioenergy Network of Excellence) Turkenburg WC (2000) Renewable energy technologies. In: World Energy Assessment (ed) Energy and the challenge of sustainability. United Nations Development Programme, New York Upham P, Shackley S (2006) The case of a proposed biomass gasifier in Winkleigh, Deven: implications for governance of renewable energy planning. Energy Policy 34:2161–2172 von Malmborg F (2003) Conditions for regional public–private partnerships for sustainable development: Swedish perspectives. Eur Environ 13:133–149 Warmburg B, Xie B, Hamilton I, de la Houssaye M (2004) Bioenergy implementation in Umbria. International Institute for Industrial Environmental Economics, Lund
Three Is a Crowd? On the Benefits of Involving Contract Manufacturers in Collaborative Planning for Three-Echelon Supply Networks Henk Akkermans, Kim van Oorschot, and Winfried Peeters
Abstract In today’s network economy, multi-echelon supply networks have become the dominant life form. The question of how to coordinate goods flows in such multi-echelon settings has become paramount. This study investigates the effectiveness of collaboration and information sharing in a three-echelon supply network, whereas academic research so far has focused on collaboration in twoechelon supply chains. The starting point for this study is a published and prizewinning real-world case of collaborative planning (CP) in the high-clockspeed industry of electronics. In particular, this research zooms in on the role played by the middle echelon, that of the contract manufacturers (CM), whose strategic interests typically are less aligned with the OEM than those of the key component suppliers. A system dynamics simulation model is developed and calibrated from this three-echelon supply network setting. Simulation analysis suggests that, when the CM is actively engaged in the joint CP process, the benefits are higher for all three echelons involved. On the other hand, if the CM does not collaborate, then collaboration between the two other echelons still yields significant benefits for all supply network members. In short, in goods flow information sharing in threeechelon supply network settings, “three is not a crowd”, but “two is company”.
H. Akkermans Department of Information Management, Tilburg University, Warandelaan 2, P.O. Box 90153 5000 LE Tilburg, The Netherlands e-mail: [email protected] K. van Oorschot (*) Department of Leadership and Organizational Behaviour, BI Norwegian School of Business, NO-0442 Oslo, Norway e-mail: [email protected] W. Peeters BU HPMS, NXP Semiconductors, High Tech Campus 60, 5656 AG Eindhoven, The Netherlands e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_23, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
563
564
H. Akkermans et al.
1 Introduction In today’s network economy, fragmented and fast-changing supply networks have become the dominant life form (Fine 1999; Lynn 2005). In these decentralized supply networks, effective goods flow coordination is more challenging than ever (Alfalla-Luque and Medina-Lopez 2009). It has become so challenging because many markets are more volatile than before. With the rise of the digital economy, product life cycles have shrunk as supply chains have fragmented. In the electronics industry, for example, a typical electronics product such as a mobile phone or PC may have a commercial life time of half a year up to a year, whereas the production lead time of the components that go into that product, such as ICs, may be a quarter of a year, and the design lead time even considerably more. In such settings, if one of the parts of the network experiences a glitch, the whole supply network is in danger of missing sales and holding obsolete products. Effective supply network coordination has also become more challenging because there are more parties involved that have to be coordinated. If we look again at the electronics industry, nowadays the biggest industry worldwide, we see that multi-echelon supply networks have become the dominant organizational form. Typically, such a network consists of one Original Equipment Manufacturer (OEM) who sells products that are assembled from both customized key components and off-the-shelf commodity components, sourced from a variety of suppliers, who can be both strategic partners and distributors. All these components typically are assembled by one to three so-called Contract Manufacturers (CM) and then delivered to the OEM, who ships them to various end markets. Unfortunately, academic theory about how entire networks should be coordinated is still scarce. The bulk of the publications still focuses on two-echelon coordination, and it is doubtful if the network as a whole will perform optimal if every bilateral relation in the network is optimized. Therefore, the overall research question of this paper is: how can a multi-echelon supply network be coordinated effectively? There is a tempting conjecture regarding the management of supply networks, which we will call the “jumping rope analogy”: What if one would just synchronize the beginning with the end of the supply network, and let everything in the middle follow their rhythm, just as all kids in the middle will have to jump in sync when the beginning and the end of the jumping rope are moving synchronously? Would that create effective coordination for the entire network? There are of course many problems with this goods flow control concept, for instance: where does a modern supply network begin and where does it end? Nevertheless, there are also some good reasons why such an approach might have a good chance of working. Take again the electronics industry. Here, the beginning and the end of the supply network often have a lot in common, whereas the middle part of the network usually does not. There is often a “shared destiny” between key components supplier and the OEM, as key components are usually customized for a particular customer and a particular product, so OEM sales and supplier sales go hand in hand. In contrast,
Three Is a Crowd? On the Benefits of Involving Contract Manufacturers
565
there is rarely a strong alignment between the strategic objectives of the CM and the OEM. The CM makes money if his assembly lines are fully utilized, but such assembly can be of the OEM’s products or those of her direct competitor, and changeovers from one product to another can take place within a few weeks, so lock-in is limited. Therefore, why should the CM be eager to share information and align production and procurement decisions with the OEM, leave alone with some key supplier? On the other hand, OEMs typically employ multiple CMs precisely because of this misalignment of incentives and the resulting need to hedge supply risks. So, wouldn’t it be also preferable for the OEM to leave the CMs out of the information-sharing loop as much as possible? The fact is that in the majority of electronics supply networks, fully collaborative information sharing and planning is still rare. It would appear that, indeed, “three is a crowd” in these supply network settings. Full collaborative planning in electronics supply networks is rare, but it does exist, nevertheless. One published example is the business-to-business setting of collaborative planning (CP) for optical storage drives and their components at Philips Electronics (De Kok et al. 2005) which did win the second prize in the 2004 Edelman Award contest. Here, the CMs were closely involved in the shared decision-making process between Philips Semiconductors, the key component supplier of the ICs they assembled for their OEM customer Philips Optical Storage. The two Philips companies formally belonged to the same parent company but were in daily practice very much two independent, profit-and-loss responsible product divisions. This real-world case forms the basis for our more specific research: In a three echelon supply network, is optimal performance achieved when the beginning and the end of the network collaborate, or is it preferable that all three echelons are fully involved in the collaboration? Is “three a crowd” here or not? In the current paper we combine our in-depth knowledge of this empirical setting, with a generic system dynamics supply chain model as a template to develop a simulation model whose behavior we can fit to the historical empirical reality of the case. With this model, we then investigate to what extent collaboration of the CM was essential to achieve the remarkable successes of CP in this three-echelon supply chain. Our analyses suggest that three need not be a crowd in such a setting at all. To the contrary, when the CM is engaged in the collaborative planning process, the benefits will be higher for all three parties. On the other hand, even if the CM is not involved in the CP process, and CP takes place between supplier and OEM alone, there will still be substantial benefits for all three parties, compared to the situation of no supply network collaboration at all. So, definitely, “two is company” as well.
2 Literature Review In the literature on the benefits of information sharing and collaborative decisionmaking in supply chains and networks there is much controversy. On the one hand, the relevance of customer order information sharing in supply chains has been
566
H. Akkermans et al.
established long ago, starting with Forrester’s Industrial Dynamics (Forrester 1961). In this seminal publication (c.f. Akkermans and Dellaert 2005), Forrester used a system dynamics analysis of a four-echelon supply chain to show how relatively small changes in end customer demand got amplified and delayed more and more as this information was transmitted to upstream supply chain stages. This amplification phenomenon has become better known under the label of the “bullwhip effect” (Lee et al. 1997). Almost 50 years ago, Forrester’s analysis indicated that if all supply chain parties are aware of the actual end customer demand and use this information to guide their production and ordering decisions, upstream demand amplification can be greatly reduced. Later came doubts. A series of publications from 1999 onwards looked at various aspects of information sharing from a mathematical perspective and found its benefits to be limited (e.g., Gavirneni et al. 1999; Cachon and Fisher 2000; Lee et al. 2000). When there are benefits, they appear to lie mainly, if not solely, with the supplier, not with the buyer (Lee et al. 2000; Sharafali and Co 2006). And this occurs only when the supply lead-time is relatively long (Chen 1999; Moinzadeh 2002), and when the supplier can actually do something with the additional data from the customer (Gavirneni et al. 1999; Aviv 2001, 2007). Even more extreme, Dobson and Pinker (2006) point at settings where sharing lead-time information would actually decrease a firm’s outputs. These theoretical roadblocks for effective information sharing have been met by messages from practice that supply chain collaboration is, in practice, still “an unfulfilled promise” (Sabath and Fontanella 2002). Why? Some reasons are organizational. One reason is lack of trust (Lee et al. 2000), another one the risk of “information leakage” (Li 2002) and other forms of opportunistic behavior by either party (McCarther and Northcraft 2007). Other reasons are more technical. Sahin and Robinson (2002) stress how the outdated inventory control algorithms in present-day ERP systems amplify and distort information in supply networks. Holweg et al. (2005) point out how difficult it can be for firms to integrate the advance data that they may have from one supplier or one customer with the data from the rest of their supplier or customer base. Wei and Wang (2010) stress that supply chain visibility must be seen as a dynamic capability of firms, and one that is not easy to develop. The bulk of the mathematical studies so far deals with two-echelon supply chains. Fortunately, this is beginning to change, as some three-echelon studies become available in the most recent literature (e.g. Jaber and Goyal 2008; Jaber et al. 2010; Wangphanich et al. 2009). The electronics sector could not be more different: fragmented supply networks are a fact of life in electronics. The generic two-echelon supply chain has become a three to four echelon supply network, with subassembly manufacturers supplying to OEMs who deliver to the end markets, and with key component manufacturers upstream, whose components are assembled by CMs or EMSs (Electronic Manufacturing Services) or ODM (Original Design Manufacturers). This middle group is responsible for at least 20% of all added values in the network, and this percentage has been increasing steadily over the years (Benson-Armer et al. 2004; Hameri and Paatela 2005; McCormack 2007).
Three Is a Crowd? On the Benefits of Involving Contract Manufacturers
567
Fig. 1 Business benefits of CP: fewer missed sales, less obsolete stock
Most common in mathematical studies on supply chain coordination so far is the assumption of stationary, albeit non-deterministic, demand. Again, the reality is very different in the electronics industry. Here, short product life cycles of less than a year are very common indeed. Hence, customer demand and supply rate never reach periods of stability, but are always more or less consciously following a generic product life cycle curve, with a steep ramp-up phase and a steep decline phase, and a very brief interlude of maturity in between. This combination of short product life cycles and long manufacturing lead times typically lead to a mismatch between potential market demand and actual supply as visualized in Fig. 1. During the initial market ramp-up, potential sales are missed as production is lagging behind. Once production gets going full steam, demand is already falling rapidly, resulting in obsolete stocks at the end of the product life cycle. In this industry with its short and steep product life cycles, it has long been recognized that synchronization of demand data from downstream with production plans upstream would result in timelier ramp-ups and ramp-downs of production, and hence in fewer lost sales and less obsolete stock (e.g. Van Aken 1978; Hoekstra and Romme 1992). However, such synchronization does require considerable amounts of trust and openness, leading to timely information sharing and joint decision making, called either Collaborative Planning and Forecasting (Aviv 2001, 2007) or Collaborative Planning (Akkermans et al. 2004; De Kok et al. 2005). These last two publications both refer to the empirical setting product divisions of Philips Electronics. We are investigating here, which is based on the case for various.
3 Case Setting 3.1
Company Setting: Philips Optical Storage and Its ICs
Back in 2000, Philips Semiconductors (PS) and Philips Optical Storage (POS) were both subsidiaries of Philips Electronics, a Dutch company, with a legacy of
568
H. Akkermans et al.
over 100 years, hovering around the tenth place in the list of largest electronics companies worldwide. In 2006, its Semiconductor division has been spun off to outside investors and is presently called NXP Semiconductors. Back in 2000 as well as today, this semi-conductor company has a global presence, with sales force in 60 countries, some 20 manufacturing sites in Europe, USA and Asia, and annual sales of around 5 billion €. Its customer base is mainly in consumer electronics, automotive and telecom. Back in 2000, Philips Optical Storage (POS) was an independent subsidiary of Philips Electronics, with some 9,000 employees worldwide. These 9,000 employees focused on developing and manufacturing optical storage products, such as CD-ROM and DVD-drives. Today, the POS organization has been split up in various units, some of them sold off, others integrated in NXP. In 1999, POS was one of the world leaders in CD-ROM and CD-Audio drives, with a market share of around 30%. It procured a significant part of its integrated circuits (ICs) for these drives of Philips Semiconductors. Although subsidiaries of the same parent company, both firms were run as independent companies with their own profit and loss responsibilities, so their relation was very much one of supplier and customer.
3.2
Three-Echelon Supply Network Setting
This is a three-echelon supply network, serving a global group of OEM customers. Going from upstream to downstream in the network, we start with the IC supplier. In IC manufacturing, so-called wafers are set up in “fabs”, a lengthy and highly complex production process. These wafers are tested and then sawn into dies, which makes die stock a key inventory point in this network. From there on, assembly and test take relatively less long and are less complex. Chips are moved from the industrial warehouse to regional stores, often also to customer specific stock locations. Here the CMs take over. They assemble chips into crucial components of the optical storage drive, the so-called Flex and the OPU. Combined with the loader the drive manufacturer integrates these into a drive engine, which can then be shipped to various OEMs in the consumer and PC industry. Figure 2 visualizes demand
Diffusion
Assy/Test
IC Supplier
demand
bullwhip effects
FLEX
OPU
Contract manufacturers
Fig. 2 The supply network setting for ICs for DVD drives
LOADER
Engine
Drive manufacturers
OEM Customer
Customers
Three Is a Crowd? On the Benefits of Involving Contract Manufacturers
569
these processes where for reasons of simplicity the three echelon supply network is condensed into a three-echelon supply chain. Under normal business conditions, every part of the network is planned and controlled by an independently run MRP engine, inevitably leading to considerable Forrester or bullwhip effects as one moves upstream (Forrester 1961; Lee et al. 1997).
3.3
The Semiconductor Industry and Philips Semiconductors in 2000–2004
In 2000, the semiconductor industry as a whole experienced a 30% increase in worldwide demand. In 2001, worldwide demand dropped again by 30% (source: wsts.org). The results for the industry were profound in both years. In the boom year of 2000, IC manufacturers found it impossible to meet the needs from their customer base. Service levels dropped to unprecedented levels and lost sales were numerous. In 2001, inventory levels reached equally unprecedented levels. In response to the increase in demand and the shortages in supply, customers had over-ordered massively in 2000, and cancelled their increased orders equally massively when the bubble burst at the beginning of 2001. According to Gartner, a market analyst firm specializing in the IT industry, inventory to sales ratios remained in the range of 1.7–1.5 until the first quarter of 2002, where a ratio of 1.2. already counts as “severe excess inventory” (source: http://www.gartner.com). Much of this inventory was actually obsolete stock, for when demand picked up again, customers ordered the newer generation ICs, so that the older generations became unsellable. Philips Semiconductors did not escape from these industry developments. Figure 3 shows its normalized inventory and sales during these times, which are 250% Inventory (value) Sales
%
200%
150%
100%
50%
1999
2000
Time
2001
2002
Fig. 3 Inventory versus sales rate at Philips Semiconductors, 1999–2002, indexed
570
H. Akkermans et al.
similar to inventory/sales ratios as observed for the industry as a whole (Bezemer 2003; Bezemer and Akkermans 2003). Large portions of the inventory in 2001–2002 were indeed obsolete products, as our third author, who was working in this area within Philips at that time, can also confirm from direct experience. Nevertheless, with regard to obsolete stocks, the period of 2001 was not unique at all for this industry. Indeed, the collaborative planning pilot we will be discussing next was set up in response to the loss of an entire product generation turning into obsolete stock as a result of bad supply network coordination.
3.4
Collaborative Planning at Philips Electronics
In 1999, the optical storage supply network within Philips experienced substantial bullwhip effects that led to serious glitches in delivery performance in this booming market. An entire product generation could not be supplied timely to the market, which resulted into major obsolete stocks. It was felt that the poor planning coordination between Philips Semiconductors and Philips Optical Storage was largely to blame for this catastrophe. In response, in the Spring of 2000 both companies started the development of a collaborative planning process and tool to improve supply network performance. The third author was one of the main initiators and sponsors of this process on the POS side, the first author was involved as an external consultant in this project from the beginning. The project that created the collaborative planning process itself is described in more detail elsewhere (Akkermans et al. 2004). Its business context, the specifics of the decision support environment that was developed and its business benefits are described in De Kok et al. (2005). In short, this was a very successful business process innovation indeed, with multi-million direct savings and considerable impact on company competitiveness in a ruthless market. In the crucial period of late 2000, the CP project enabled this product group to ramp down some 4–6 months earlier than most other product groups did, which led to hardly any obsolete inventories, contrary to the high stock levels experienced by most of the other groups, much of which was obsolete stock. When the market picked up again, the CP process enabled faster response times from the supplier and thereby fewer lost sales (c.f. de Kok et al. 2005).
3.5
Hypotheses
This brings us to a translation of our research question to four hypotheses, which we will test with the simulation model we developed on the basis of this case setting: . H1: With collaboration between the OEM and supplier (SUP), supply chain performance in a three-echelon supply chain will improve, with regard to (a) lost sales, (b) inventory levels, including obsolete stocks, (c) production volatility.
Three Is a Crowd? On the Benefits of Involving Contract Manufacturers
571
. H2: This improvement will benefit all three parties, i.e. OEM, SUP and CM. . H3: When the CM also joins the collaboration between OEM and SUP, supply chain performance in a three-echelon supply chain will further improve, with regard to (a) lost sales, (b) inventory levels, including obsolete stocks, (c) production volatility. . H4: This improvement will benefit all three parties, i.e. OEM, SUP and CM.
4 Model Description 4.1
Data Collection and Model Calibration
In this section we present a system dynamics simulation model. System dynamics is a suitable method for analyzing situations involving multiple and interacting processes, time delays, and other nonlinear effects such as feedback loops and thresholds (Davis et al. 2007) and has been used extensively by other scholars (e.g., Oliva and Sterman 2001; Repenning and Sterman 2002; Garcia et al. 2003; Croson and Donohue 2006). In the area of supply chain coordination, the dynamics in these networks has been noted as an underresearched area and the development of system dynamics simulation models of these contexts have been recommended as a promising way to make progress in this area (Chan and Chan 2010). The simulation model we present here employs data sources from various origins. The starting point is a generic textbook supply chain model (Sterman 2000), that traces its origins back to the original Forrester model (1961). In 2000, we modified this model to fit the supply network setting at hand on the basis of a number of process modeling workshops (Akkermans et al. 2004). In preparing the current version of the model, we relied on the expertise of the first and third author, the first author having worked in this industry as a researcher for 13 years and the third author a practicing supply chain manager for more than two decades in this industry and Philips Electronics. The person operationally in charge for 4 years of the decision support tool in the CP process was interviewed, and historical demand and supply time series data were collected to check model validation. Industry averages for price levels throughout the supply chain were also derived from the third author’s extensive expertise in this area. For model calibration, we were able to use the actual supply data from the Philips collaborative planning case (Fig. 6).
4.2
Supply Chain Structure
The real Philips CP setting was a three-echelon supply network, with multiple independent entities at every echelon and a multitude of good flow paths. In this section, we simplify this network to a three-echelon supply chain, consisting of
572
H. Akkermans et al.
system boundary SUP
OEM
CM
MI material delivery rate
Customer
WIP material usage rate
production start rate
FI production rate
shipment rate
Fig. 4 Stocks and flows of the production process within a supply chain echelon
three companies: a supplier (SUP), a contract manufacturer (CM) and an original equipment manufacturer (OEM), shown in Fig. 4. Each of the companies acts both as supplier and as customer, because each company buys materials from its supplier and sells finished goods to its customer. Though the production processes within each of the three companies in the supply chain are different, they can be modeled in a similar way. All companies have three stock points: material inventory (MI), work in process (WIP), and final inventory (FI). Figure 4 shows these three stock points and the flows between them. All companies have a make-to-stock policy, which implies that customer orders may be fulfilled immediately if the final inventory levels are sufficient, and that production is driven by a forecast of customer orders.
4.3
Model Structure
The model is based on the interaction of customer demand, which pulls products out of the final inventory, and demand forecast, which pushes products from material inventory, through the work in process inventory into the final inventory. Products that are shipped from the final inventory of the SUP to the CM are stored in the material inventory of the CM. Products that are shipped from the final inventory of the CM are stored in the material inventory of the OEM. When products are shipped from the final inventory of the OEM to the end-customer they move outside the system boundary. For a detailed description of the equations that are used to define these decision rules, we refer the readers to Sterman (2000, Chap. 18, pp. 709–740) and the Appendix. Here, we will only describe the salient differences between our model and the Sterman textbook model. All changes to the textbook model were made to better reflect the actual decision-making processes in the studied supply chain setting. The detailed model is available from the authors upon request. The variables that are used in the equations below are listed in Table 5 of the Appendix in alphabetical order.
Three Is a Crowd? On the Benefits of Involving Contract Manufacturers
4.3.1
573
Endogenous Product Life Cycle Customer Demand
The end-customer demand in the model is defined by both an exogenous and endogenous part. The exogenous part refers to the shape and the maximum height of the demand curve in time (maximum Customer Order Rate, CORmax). It is assumed that customer demand takes the shape of a product life cycle, including product introduction, growth, saturation and decline. This results in a so-called Bass diffusion curve (Bass 1969). CORmax is the highest possible demand (or maximum demand) that can be realized when the actual delivery delay is equal to the target delivery delay and when no customers are lost. CORmax is an exogenous function, the value of which is determined by the marketing department of the OEM, based on an estimation of total market size and desired market share of the company. It is used by decision makers for production planning and it is also discussed (shared) in collaborative planning sessions with supply chain partners. In the Appendix more information on CORmax can be found. The endogenous part is concerned with the actual height of the demand, which is influenced by the behavior of the OEM in the model in terms of delivery performance (effect of delivery delay, efDD). For example, when delivery performance is poor, customers have to wait a long time before their products are delivered (delivery delay perceived by market, DDPM). The longer the DDPM is compared to what is expected in this market (target delivery delay, TDD), the higher the negative effect of this delivery delay on future customer orders. This negative effect is shown graphically in Fig. 5. In Fig. 5 three product life cycles are shown. The shape of the curves is the same (the exogenous part of the customer order rate). The height of the curves is different and influenced by the delivery performance of the OEM (via efDD). Variable efDD is modeled as a non-linear decreasing function (f0) of the ratio of DDPM and the target delivery delay (TDD). The Customer Order Rate (COR) can now be defined as: 4,000 Customer order rates The lower the delivery performance of OEM, the lower the customer order rate. The shape of the curve remains the same.
3,000
2,000
1,000
0
1
38
76 Time (Week)
Fig. 5 Customer order rate depends on delivery performance
113
150
574
H. Akkermans et al.
COR ¼ CORmax efDD
(1)
efDD ¼ f0 ðDDPM =TDDÞ
(2)
where f0 0; f0 0 <0; f0 00 <0; f0 ð0Þ ¼ 1; f0 ð2Þ ¼ 0:6; f0 ð5Þ ¼ 0:5
(3)
So, according to function f0, when the DDPM is twice as long as the TDD, the efDD will be 2, which means that the actual COR is only 60% of the CORmax. The values of this function f0 were determined based on interviews with stakeholders. The market does not perceive long delivery delays instantly. It takes a certain time before first the OEM notices it (time for company to perceive delivery delay, TCPDD) and then again a certain time before customers start noticing it (time for market to perceive delivery delay, TMPDD). Thus, DDPM lags behind the quotes given by the company (delivery delay perceived by the company, DDPC), which in turn lag the true availability of the product, defined by the delivery delay of the OEM (DD1, e.g., Sterman 2000, p. 620).
4.3.2
d DD1 DDPC DDPC ¼ TCPDD dt
(4)
d DDPC DDPM DDPM ¼ TMPDD dt
(5)
Production in Compliance with Forecasts
Production is driven by a forecast of future customer orders. Forecasts are not only based on order rates that are expected in the future, but forecasts are also determined by past behavior. When forecasts are always too optimistic (order forecast is higher than actual order rate), it is expected that, after a certain delay, the actual production rates will not be in perfect compliance with these forecasts. In this situation, actual production rates will be adjusted downwards in alignment with the optimistic forecast to prevent high inventory levels. So, in order to calculate the net production start rate forecasts (PSRFnet), it is necessary to determine to what extent the actual order rates (OR) are compliant with the gross production start rate forecasts (PSRFgross). This compliance is defined by the average ratio of actual order rate and the forecasted order rate (ARafo) during a certain period (p). d ARafo ¼ dt
OR PSRFgross
ARafo
p
PSRFnet ¼ ARafo PSRFgross
(6) (7)
Three Is a Crowd? On the Benefits of Involving Contract Manufacturers
575
The way in which the PSRFgross is determined depends on the scenario that is modeled and will be discussed in the next section.
4.4
Scenario Design
The purpose of our simulations is to analyze whether “three is a crowd”: in a supply chain consisting of three echelons, what is the best policy with respect to information sharing and collaboration between these three echelons? To examine this question, we specify three scenarios. Two scenarios have already been described in the literature (De Kok et al. 2005). First, there is the traditional scenario without any collaborative planning (No CP scenario). Information delays are long, and each echelon in the chain has its own way of interpreting the information received. Trust in the chain is low, leading to shortage gaming (the customer will over-order when the delivery delay of the supplier increases, c.f. Sterman 2000, pp. 735–737). Second, there is the full collaborative planning scenario (Full CP). In this scenario, all three echelons share information without delays and distortions. Trust is high, so there is no shortage gaming. The production forecasts of the SUP are based on the forecast of the customer order rate of the OEM plus the inventory corrections of both the OEM and the CM. Likewise, the production forecasts of the CM are based on the forecast of the customer order rate of the OEM plus the inventory corrections of the OEM. Next to these two scenarios, we have specified a third scenario to examine whether or not the CM really needs to be involved in the collaborative planning effort. In this scenario (CP with hostile CM), the SUP and OEM will share information with each other, but not with the CM. The CM will not share any information with its supply chain partners. Furthermore, the CM does not trust its partners, leading to shortage gaming. Shortage gaming is a way to get the desired materials from the SUP. This means that when the delivery delay of the SUP increases, the CM will over-order. This policy is described on pp. 735–740 of Sterman (2000). In the No CP scenario both the CM and the OEM use shortage gaming. The characteristics of the three scenarios are summarized in Table 1. The equations of the PSRFgross for the SUP and the CM depend on the level of collaboration between supply chain partners, and thus depend on the scenario.
4.4.1
PSRF Without Collaborative Planning
When there is no collaborative planning, no information is shared throughout the chain and the PSRFgross for the SUP and CM must be based on the actual order rate that is received. Based on interviews with stakeholders in the company, it was derived that in the No CP-scenario, forecasts are made by extrapolating the average trend in order rates during the recent past. So, to determine the PSRFgross, first the average actual order rate is calculated (AOR) during a certain forecast period (fp), then the average trend in the order rate is calculated (ATOR) over this same period.
576
H. Akkermans et al.
Table 1 Summary of scenarios Info sharing of Production CP between CM with planning SUP and OEM Shortage gaming partners of CM
Scenario No CP ctr1
ctr1
ctr1
SUP
CM
OEM
No (8)
CM $ SUP and OEM $ CM No
Determined by CM (8)
CM $ SUP
No (15)
Determined by CM (8)
Yes (15)
Determined by partners (15)
CP with hostile CM contro1 ctr1 SUP
CM
OEM
Yes (15) Full CP control SUP
CM
OEM
Yes (15)
No
The horizon of the forecast is determined by the stacked lead time (L*), which is the sum of cycle time (CT) and safety stock coverage (IC*). Now, for the No CP-scenario, the PSRFgross is defined by (where subscripts 1, 2, 3 denote the OEM, CM, SUP respectively, when the equation is equal for all parties, no subscripts are given): for PSRFNoCP gross;i ¼ ORi 1 þ Li ATOR;i
i ¼ 2; 3
(8)
L ¼ CT þ IC
(9)
d TOR ATOR ATOR ¼ fp dt
(10)
The trend in the order rates (TOR) is based on actual order rates and the average order rate during the forecast period: TOR ¼
OR AOR fp AOR
(11)
Three Is a Crowd? On the Benefits of Involving Contract Manufacturers
d OR AOR AOR ¼ fp dt
577
(12)
For the OEM the PSRFgross is determined in a different way than for the SUP and CM. The actual customer order rate of the OEM is a direct determinant of the PSRFgross. Because of the relatively short manufacturing cycle time of the OEM compared to the target delivery delay, and because of the high safety stocks, there is hardly any need to make long-term production forecasts of future demand. This holds for each of the three scenarios. So, for the OEM, the PSRFgross is: PSRFgross;1 ¼ COR1
(13)
This means for the OEM that ARafo ¼ 1, and the PSRFgross is equal to PSRFnet (7).
4.4.2
PSRF with Collaborative Planning
In the scenario with collaborative planning, the OEM shares its actual COR with the SUP and CM. This information, together with the stacked lead time and the CORmax, is used to calculate the expected COR (CORexp,i): the customer order rate that echelon i (so either the SUP or the CM), after the collaborative planning effort, expects that the OEM will receive in the future. For a detailed description of how CORexp and CORmax are determined, we refer to the Appendix. Besides sharing information on customer order rates, in the collaborative planning scenario the supply chain partners also share information on inventory corrections (adjustments for inventory, AfI). For the SUP (or for the CM), the inventory corrections of downstream echelons are the inventory corrections of the OEM and the CM (or only the OEM). Inventory correction is calculated as the difference between desired (I*) and actual inventory (I) divided by the time to adjust inventory (TAI): AfI ¼
I I TAI
(14)
So, the PSRFgross in this scenario can be determined by: PSRFFullCP gross;3 ¼ CORexp;3 þ AfI1 þ AfI2 PSRFFullCP gross;2 ¼ CORexp;2 þ AfI1
(15)
Note, that in the scenario “CP with Hostile CM” the CM is not willing to share information on inventory corrections with the SUP, so in this scenario, the term AfI2 is left out of the PSRFgross,3 equation of the SUP.
578
H. Akkermans et al.
Table 2 Cost and sales price per unit per echelon
4.5
Sales price per unit Material cost per unit Other material cost per unit Organization cost per unit -
SUP 8.0 4.6 0.0 0.6 -
EBIT per unit
2.8
CM 35.0 8.0 23.6 1.7 -
OEM 100.0 35.0 40.0 15.0 -
1.8
10.0
Performance Measures (EVA)
Some scenarios perform better in terms of extra revenue, others in terms of reduced inventory costs. To compare the results of the different scenarios in an integrated measure, we use the Economic Value Added (EVA) indicator. The use of EVA for financial decision-making was first suggested by Steward (1991). To calculate EVA, the opportunity cost of capital is subtracted from the profits generated by the firm. Therefore, EVA focuses on the profitable use of capital. EVA is defined by the earnings before interest and taxes (EBIT), taxes (TX), the weighted average cost of capital (WACC) and the working capital (WC): EVA ¼ EBIT TX WACC WC
(16)
To calculate the EBIT, we need material costs, organization costs, costs of obsolete inventory and the sales price per echelon in the supply chain. For confidentiality reasons we use normalized costs and prices. We set the sales price to the end customer to 100 and calculate backwards to derive the material costs of the three echelons. In Table 2 these indexed costs and prices are given.
5 Model Analysis We start with the Full Collaborative Planning scenario because this is the scenario that actually was implemented in the Philips electronics case. In this way, by using real data from this real-life scenario, we are able to validate our system dynamics model for this setting. Then, with the model, we can simulate what could have happened and what could have been the performance of the supply chain without collaborative planning or with collaborative planning only between the SUP and the OEM (and a hostile CM). In this way, we can test our research hypotheses.
5.1
Model Estimation
We defined in (7) that the PSRFnet is equal to the factor of PSRFgross and ARafo. The period (pi) that is used to calculate the ARafo was first set to 26 weeks for both SUP
Three Is a Crowd? On the Benefits of Involving Contract Manufacturers
579
and CM. The length of this period was not directly observable anymore, nor did the interviewees recall precisely the length of this period. It was known that in general the CM had a shorter period than the SUP. Therefore, we estimated this parameter p, defining the length of the period in which the supply chain partners look back at past behavior to determine future production rates. To estimate this parameter, we used the non-linear least squares method (which is also known as the automated calibration module of the simulation software, e.g., Oliva and Sterman 2001; Oliva 2003). Recently, this method was criticized by Dogan (2007), who pointed out that one assumption that these methods use, which is that the data are normally distributed, not autocorrelated and not heteroskedastic, is often violated in dynamic models, which may lead to wrong estimates for the parameter values. Dogan (2007) describes a state-of-the-art bootstrapping method for confidence interval estimation that is suitable for dynamic models. However, as he himself writes in his conclusions, “the biggest disadvantages of bootstrapping are its computational burden and implementation difficulties” (p. 434). Unfortunately, Dogan’s approach has not yet been automated in software such as Vensim. Fortunately though, we have in our third author a manager with in-depth expertise of this industry and this setting, and he confirmed that the values of the estimated parameters we obtained by non-linear least squares were in line with his inside knowledge of the real-world setting. For these reasons, we have used the “conventional” least squares method. The estimation process minimizes the sum of squared errors between simulated (SR) and actual shipment rates (ASR) of the OEM to the end customer given the structure of the full model and driven by the data for actual customer order rates (which are used to determine CORmax): Min p2 ;p3
150 X
ðSR1 ðtÞ ASRðtÞÞ2
t¼1
(17)
Over : 1 p2 26 and 26 p3 76 We used data on actual shipment rates that were presented in De Kok et al. (2005). To model an entire product life cycle, we have combined the ramp-up time series of one product with the ramp-down curve for another product, which results in a typical time series for product life cycle demand. The resulting actual supply rate (ASR) is shown in Fig. 6. In Table 3 the estimated values for the parameters are shown, with 95% confidence intervals. All estimates have the correct signs and tight confidence bounds. As was suggested in the interviews, the period for the CM is much shorter than that for the SUP. This difference in period-length is large, but the difference is similar to the difference in cycle times (the cycle time of the SUP is eight times longer than that of the CM). Because of the short cycle time, the CM is much more flexible than the SUP and therefore, there is less need for the CM to look back at previous order rates to forecast the future ones. We decided to keep these estimated values of the period in our model. The fit between simulated series and real, historical data is presented in Fig. 6.
580
H. Akkermans et al. Actual Supply Rate (ASR) Simulated Supply Rate (SR)
4,000
units/week units/week
Summary Statistics for Historical Fit – Supply Rate n =130 R2
0,9660
Mean Absolute Percent Error Root Mean Square Error
2,000
0,1979 196,0768
Theil’s Inequality Statistics Bias
0,0077
Unequal Variation
0,0086
Unequal Covariation
0,9837
0 1
38
76 Time (Week)
150
113
Fig. 6 Actual versus simulated supply rate Table 3 Estimated values of period (pi)
p2 p3
Estimate
95% Confidence interval
6.76 51.34
5.95 48.79
7.52 61.86
There is a high fit between real and simulated supply (R2 ¼ 0.966). The Theil inequality statistics provide a decomposition of the error by dividing the mean square error into three components: unequal means (bias), unequal variances, and imperfect correlation (Sterman 2000; Oliva and Sterman 2001). Low bias and variance fractions indicate that the error is unsystematic (Sterman 1984). A similar technique was used to estimate parameters describing the product life cycle curve of CORmax [used in (15)] based on real demand data. The values of all other exogenous model parameters could be obtained through interviews. A list of these exogenous model parameters is found in the Appendix. Unfortunately, no other real-life data series (such as real inventory levels) are available for further testing the historical fit of the model.
5.2 5.2.1
Simulation Results No Collaborative Planning Versus Full Collaborative Planning
The simulation results of all three scenarios that were defined in the previous section are given in Table 4. The specific benefits of full collaborative planning differ per echelon. Starting with the benefits for the OEM, we will describe these benefits per echelon below. Next, we will first discuss the results of two “extreme” scenarios: no collaborative planning and full collaborative planning. Then, the “middle” scenario (CP with Hostile CM) is discussed. Effects of Full Collaborative Planning for the OEM. The EVA results in Table 4 show that moving from the No CP scenario to the Full CP scenario will increase the
Contract manufacturer (CM)
OEM
No CP Hostile CM Full CP No CP Hostile CM Full CP No CP Hostile CM Full CP Sales 819,160 822,624 913,632 3,127,320 3,501,365 3,995,705 8,935,200 10,003,900 11,415,800 Cost of goods sold 468,969 470,952 523,054 2,822,630 3,160,232 3,606,409 6,701,400 7,502,925 8,561,850 Organization costs 63,485 63,753 70,806 148,324 166,065 189,511 1,340,280 1,500,585 1,712,370 62,174 12,123 13 0 0 0 0 0 0 Obsolescence costs EBIT 224,532 275,796 319,758 156,366 175,068 199,785 893,520 1,000,390 1,141,580 22,453 27,580 31,976 15,637 17,507 19,979 89,352 100,039 114,158 Taxes (10%) Net operating profit after taxes 202,078 248,216 287,782 140,729 157,561 179,807 804,168 900,351 1,027,422 Working capital 80,452 48,118 45,009 240,738 118,262 88,054 279,363 301,496 397,575 Capital cost (12%) 9,654 5,774 5,401 28,889 14,191 10,567 33,524 36,180 47,709 EVA 192,424 242,442 282,381 111,841 143,370 169,240 770,644 864,171 979,713 a Inventory costs for MI, WIP and FI are based on average inventory levels during the simulation period. The costs of the MI are equal to the material costs times average MI level. The costs of WIP and FI are equal to the material + organization costs times the average WIP and FI level. Inventory costs of products that remain at the end of the product life (obsolete stock) are based on final inventory levels at the end of the simulation and the material + organization costs (shown also in Table)
Table 4 Simulation results (EVA) of each scenarioa Supplier (SUP)
Three Is a Crowd? On the Benefits of Involving Contract Manufacturers 581
582
H. Akkermans et al. 200,000
Full CP CP with Hostile CM No CP
150,000
100,000
50,000
0
1
38
76 Time (Week)
113
150
Fig. 7 Cumulative sales of OEM in units in all three scenarios
economic value added for the OEM with over 27%. This result is primarily caused by an increase of sales. The cumulative sales of the OEM during the entire product life cycle are shown in Fig. 7 for all three scenarios. These extra sales occur during both the ramp-up and the ramp-down. This is because in the No CP scenario, the delivery delays that were caused by a slower ramp-up resulted in lost sales (potential customers moving to the competitor). Moreover, throughout the product life cycle, the OEMs sales rate is much smoother in the Full CP scenario than in the No CP scenario, which is caused by a smooth production rate of the OEM, which in turn is caused by a smooth delivery of materials by the CM. In the No CP scenario, information delays are very long, leading to amplifications and oscillations in the supply chain. Effects of Full Collaborative Planning for the SUP. The EVA results for the Supplier in Table 4 show high costs of obsolete stock in the No CP scenario (over 62 k€). This obsolete stock is the result of the long information and production delays. Figure 8 shows the behavior over time of the final inventory level of the SUP. At the end of the product life cycle some 12,000 units remain in stock in the No CP scenario, compared to 3 units in the Full CP scenario. Though the level of obsolete stock seems very high in the No CP scenario, please note that 12,000 units is 11.7% of the total number of units that the SUP sold in the No CP scenario (i.e. 102,395 units). This value is a common level of obsolete stocks for this industry, as has been argued before. Why this high level of obsolete inventory? In the Full CP scenario, the final inventory level decreases after week 80, when slowly the ramp-down begins. However, in the No CP scenario, the SUP does not receive demand information of the OEM. The SUP plans its production based on a forecast of the order rate of the CM. Based on these forecasts, the SUP increases his production start rate in week 91. Eight weeks later, these items are ready to be sold. However, in the meantime, the order rate of the CM has rapidly collapsed to zero, because the CM has suddenly realized that the end-of-life of the product is near. As a result, we see the
Three Is a Crowd? On the Benefits of Involving Contract Manufacturers 40,000
583
Full CP CP with Hostile CM No CP
30,000 20,000 10,000
0
1
38
76 Time (Week)
113
150
113
150
Fig. 8 Final inventory of the SUP in units for all three scenarios 8,000
Full CP CP with Hostile CM No CP
6,000 4,000 2,000 0
1
38
76 Time (Week)
Fig. 9 Production rate of the CM in units per week in all three scenarios
inventory level of the SUP increase fast during the second half of the product life cycle, leading to a large number of obsolete items. Full CP reduces the costs of obsolete stock, and on top of this, the SUP also increases its sales because the OEM requires more materials in this scenario. These two effects (reduction of costs and increase of sales) lead to the large increase of the EVA for the SUP (an increase of almost 47%). Effects of Full Collaborative Planning for the CM. Looking at the EVA results for the CM we see an increase of 51% from the No CP scenario to the Full CP scenario. This result is mainly caused by an increase of sales with almost 28%. Because of the short production times of the CM, and because of the more downstream position of the CM in the supply chain compared to the SUP, the CM does not suffer from high levels of obsolete items at the end of the product life cycle, as the SUP does. However, besides the increase of sales, collaborative planning results in another major benefit for the CM: smooth production rates, as can be seen in Fig. 9.
584
H. Akkermans et al.
Why? The production rates of the CM are based on the production forecasts. As was described in the previous section, in the Full CP scenario these forecasts are based on the actual end customer demand of the OEM. In the No CP scenario, these forecasts are based on the order rate of the OEM. Without collaborative planning, the ramp-up in the supply chain is too slow. So, when the OEM orders products from the CM, it takes a long time before these products are delivered. As a result, the OEM starts with shortage gaming: the order rate is inflated. After a while, the supply chain is up to speed and the CM delivers all of the ordered products, including the “inflated” products. As a result, the material inventory of the OEM is much too high, and the order rate of the OEM suddenly drops to zero. Later on, the order rate increases again, but by that time, the production rates in the supply chain have also dropped to zero. Again delivery delays are the result, leading to more shortage gaming, etc. As a result, production rates in the chain oscillate strongly. In summary, Full CP in a three-echelon supply chain offers strong benefits for all three echelons. For all parties, these benefits consist of smooth order –, production – and sales rates as well as an increase in sales. Furthermore, for the SUP there is an added benefit of a decreased level of (obsolete) final inventory. In the next section we will examine whether or not these benefits can be realized without involving the CM.
5.2.2
Collaborative Planning Without Involvement of Contract Manufacturer
We now turn our attention to the middle scenarios in Table 4: CP with Hostile CM, or in other words, collaborative planning without involving the CM. In this scenario there is still collaborative planning between the SUP and the OEM. The CM is considered “hostile”, because it does not share any information with its supply chain partners and it uses shortage gaming as a policy to get the required materials from the SUP. The EVA results show that, even without involving the CM, all three parties in the chain benefit from the cooperation between the SUP and the OEM. In the CP with Hostile CM-scenario compared to the No CP-scenario, the EVA figures increases by 26%, 28% and 12% for the SUP, CM and OEM, respectively. The improvement in EVA is doubled when the CM joins the collaboration. Apparently, there are two big “jumps” in improvement, as we move from a non-cooperative into a fully cooperative chain. The first “jump” is between No CP at all and CP between the beginning and end of the chain (SUP and OEM). The second “jump” in improvement can be made when all partners in the chain are collaborating (SUP and CM and OEM). What are the causes of the first improvement jump, when only the SUP and OEM are collaborating without involving the CM? Because of the alignment between the SUP and OEM, both the production ramp-up and ramp-down of the SUP happen on time. This increases the shipments for all parties in the chain (because of a reduction of delivery delays and consequently, a reduction in lost sales). The timely ramp-down causes a sharp reduction in the obsolete inventory level for the SUP. As
Three Is a Crowd? On the Benefits of Involving Contract Manufacturers
585
a result of not involving the CM in the collaboration, the CM will still be a little too late in ramping-up and -down its production rates. This results in some nervousness in the behavior of the CM (Fig. 9). However, because the SUP and OEM are aligned, any nervous behavior of the CM is dampened by the other two. For example, when the CM starts to over-order (shortage gaming), the SUP can simply not comply with all of these inflated orders, because the production rates of the SUP are based on the customer demand of the OEM. For example, when the CM orders 100 units in 1 week and 0 in the next, the SUP delivers a stable 50 units in each week. In the Full CP scenario, all parties are aligned, all production ramp-ups start at the right time, and the nervous behavior of the CM is prevented.
5.3
Summary of Findings
Now, going back to our hypotheses we can conclude that all four of our hypotheses are confirmed. The results of the CP with Hostile CM-scenario outperform the results of the No CP scenario. This means that with collaboration between the OEM and SUP only (and excluding the CM), supply chain performance increases with regards to (a) lost sales (Fig. 7), (b) inventory levels, including obsolete stocks (Fig. 8), and (c) production volatility (Fig. 9). The graphs shown in these figures confirm Hypothesis 1. The EVA results in Table 4 show that this improvement will benefit all three parties in the chain (confirming Hypothesis 2). When only the SUP and the OEM collaborate, compared to the situation without collaboration, the EVA increases with 26, 28, and 12% for respectively the SUP, CM, and OEM. When the CM also joins the collaboration between OEM and SUP, supply chain performance in a three-echelon supply chain will further improve, with regard to (a) lost sales, (b) inventory levels, including obsolete stocks, (c) production volatility. The results in Figs. 7–9 confirm this (Hypothesis 3). This further improvement benefits all three parties. As is shown in Table 4, in the Full CP scenario, compared to the scenario where the CM is not involved (CP with Hostile CM), the EVA increases further by 16%, 18% and 13% for the SUP, CM and OEM, respectively, thereby confirming Hypothesis 4.
6 Discussion and Conclusions 6.1
Main Findings: Two Is Company and Three Is Not a Crowd
The first version of the simulation model that is presented in this paper goes back to December 2000, to the very beginning of the collaborative planning project that was conducted at Philips Electronics. Then, a simulation model was developed by the first author at the request of the third author, who was then the manager leading
586
H. Akkermans et al.
the CP effort from Philips Optical Storage, the OEM in this three-echelon supply network. Back in 2000, the simulation analysis was helpful in identifying the relevant role that the CMs could play and what might be in it for them: less obsolete stock and more stability in demand and supply, so crucial for their own capacity utilization. Back then, our ex ante analysis suggested what our ex post analysis has confirmed: there are benefits to CP when the CMs do not collaborate, but there are even more benefits when they do. Where does this benefit come from? Here, we have to differentiate between the three parties. With collaborative planning, all parties sell more, but the OEM clearly has the greatest gain from a higher sales volume, if we compare the collaborative scenarios with the non-collaborative one. For the supplier, the biggest benefit lies in the vastly reduced obsolete stock at the end of the PLC, which so plagues this short PLC-industry whenever steep market downturns occur. And for the CM, perhaps the most obvious difference between collaborative and non-collaborative settings, both in theory and in practice, is the greatly reduced volatility in required production rates. That may lead to lower inventory levels, but for companies working on such razor-thin profit margins as the CMs, the improved capacity utilization and lower switchover costs may be at least as important.
6.2 6.2.1
Limitations and Implications Research Limitations
The simulation model we have developed and used is both more and less than a model of the Philips Optical Storage supply network that so successfully used collaborative planning to synchronize its goods flow. We believe it is more, because it is really a generic model of a three-echelon supply network, where the supplier has long lead-times and produces to forecast, the other two echelons have short lead-times and the demand for the end product has a short and steep product-life cycle. Such a typology will fit many supply networks within the electronics industry and in other high-clockspeed industries. The insights that our analysis of this model yields should provide useful starting points for managers in other supply networks that want to engage in some form of collaborative planning. On the other hand, we readily admit that the simulation model is also less than a model of the Philips CP supply network. Yes, the model is parameterized in such a way that it fits the actual historical values for orders, goods flow, demand curves and prices throughout the Philips optical storage network. However, the range of empirical time series and parameter values available from this case is certainly too limited to claim a full mapping of this hugely complex supply network. Also, we have modeled a three-echelon supply chain, consisting of only three actors that supply each other in a linear manner, whereas the real-world setting was a convergent three-echelon supply network, with over a dozen of production locations and a far greater number of independent decision-making units. Nevertheless, one
Three Is a Crowd? On the Benefits of Involving Contract Manufacturers
587
advantage of having our generic model calibrated to the historical performance of this particular real-world setting, is that we can afford to worry less about the degree in which our proposed policies are implementable. After all, they have already been implemented in the real world, and with real success. However, other supply network settings will have other parameter values, which may lead to other quantitative outcomes, and this remains an inherent limitation of our research approach. Another research limitation is that we have looked at the product life cycle as a whole, and not specifically at different stages of the product life cycle, whereas it is obvious that the incentives for the different supply network partners differ per stage. During the ramp-up, it is the OEM who stands to gain most, as it is here that most of the sales opportunities are lost in the non-cooperative settings. For the supplier, it is during the ramp-down that the business benefits are obvious, as they also were in the Philips case, as it is then that with CP the end-of-life stock can be managed down to a minimum.
6.2.2
Business Implications
This difference in incentives during different stages in the product life cycle may be one explanation of why there are not so many successful CP projects as the analysis in this paper would suggest that there should be. Basically, there is never a stage in the PLC when all supply network partners really need CP badly. During the ramp-up, it is the OEM that stands to gain most but the supplier may well be hesitant to put in the extra effort, for the same capacity of this new technology could also be used for other products for other customers. During the ramp-down, the supplier’s incentive to manage obsolete stock is obvious, but the OEM may well be less interested in sharing its demand forecasts, as she needn’t worry about supply shortages in times of excess capacity. And in this industry setting, there is never an obvious leading role for the middle echelon, the CM.
6.2.3
Research Implications
The research implications from this study are already apparent from the literature review. Firstly, most of the research into supply chain information sharing so far has assumed stable auto-correlated demand patterns, but the biggest potential for CP lies in supply chain settings where the demand follows an S-shaped diffusion pattern (Bass 1969). Clearly, the existing conclusions in the literature have to be reconsidered in light of this particular demand pattern. Secondly, almost all the current research assumes exogenous demand, whereas the real world tells us that demand is highly endogenous: if you can deliver better, demand will increase and vice versa. Therefore, future studies should include endogenous demand (e.g., Gonc¸alves et al. 2005). Thirdly, the dominant goods flow structure in highclockspeed industries is that of the three- or four-echelon supply network, while almost all the literature is concerned with only two echelon supply chains. Again,
588
H. Akkermans et al.
there exists a clear opportunity to endeavor analysis of multi-echelon supply network collaboration.
6.2.4
Business Limitations
The potential for collaborative supply network collaboration remains high in theory, and can be huge in practice as well, as this study has illustrated. Nevertheless, the uptake of collaborative planning arrangements in industry has been lagging behind this potential severely. One key explanation for this is timing: although all parties benefit over the course of the entire life cycle, there is in every stage one party that greatly benefits from CP and another party that does not have an immediate incentive, so it is difficult to get all parties behind this at the same time. The other key word in practice is supply network trust. Engaging in a collaborative supply network coordination process required considerable initial levels of trust, and such trust is often hard to find in supply networks, and often for good reasons as well. As another study already pointed out, one may boost initial trust levels through the CP process itself, through working together on the design and the operation of the CP workflow that has to be followed (Akkermans et al. 2004). The more people from different companies will work together, the more they will come to understand each other, the better they will be able to communicate, the better they will collaborate, the more successful and trustworthy they will be, the more they will start to trust each other, the better they will work together, and so on. Getting this virtuous cycle to operate is often highly challenging in practice, because of resistance to change and of a biased focus on short-term benefits.
7 Conclusion So, in the end, it will require a combination of solid analysis, strategic vision and hard work, to overcome organizational inertia and move into the virtuous cycles of ever-better communication, collaboration, performance and mutual trust. Supply networks with managers and entrepreneurs that can muster all these will be among the winners in this new world of the network economy. For in this new world, two is almost always company and three is rarely a crowd. . . Acknowledgements Many people made this study possible. In particular, we wish to salute Erik van Wachem, as a long-term and perseverant advocate of CP within Philips. Also, we acknowledge Fred Janssen for his help in providing the real-world data and his helpful suggestions on appropriate performance measures. We also thank Paulo Gonc¸alves for his expert advice on model calibration.
Three Is a Crowd? On the Benefits of Involving Contract Manufacturers
589
Appendix: Model Documentation The system dynamics model that we developed is based on the model of Sterman (2000). In Chap. 18 of his book “The Manufacturing Supply Chain” (pp. 709–740), Sterman describes all the equations and causal loops of one echelon in a supply chain with three inventory positions: material inventory, work in process, final inventory. Furthermore, processes that are required to order materials, to transform these in time into final products and to ship these products to customers are fully described (see for order fulfillment: pp. 711–713, for production scheduling: pp. 713–716, for demand forecasting: pp. 716–718, for order backlog: pp. 723–725, and for material ordering: pp. 725–740). The model is based upon four general assumptions that influence the behavior of the model. These assumptions will be described shortly below. First, to keep the model as simple and straightforward as possible, it is assumed that production capacity is always available in the right amount and at the right time. In other words, it is assumed that capacity does not influence the demand and production processes and therefore it is not included in the model. Second, we assume that the end-customer demand in the model is defined by both an exogenous and endogenous part, see Sect. 4.3.1 for further details. Third, for the Supplier, the CM, and the OEM, three stock points can be distinguished (see Fig. 10): material inventory (MI), work in process (WIP) and final inventory (FI). Inventory levels are controlled by comparing actual levels with desired levels. When deviations are measured, the inflow (production) is increased or decreased in order to reach the desired level within a certain adjustment time. Finally, we assume that the production rates of all three echelons in the supply chain are based on the actual work in process and final inventory level (when these levels are below the desired levels, the production rate increases) and on the forecasted production start rate. In this Appendix we elaborate on two differences with the Sterman-model. These differences are (1) three-echelon supply chain, (2) product life cycle demand.
Order Fulfillment B Stockout material delivery rate
Material Inventory
production start rate
material usage rate
B Material Control Material ordering
Fig. 10 Policy structure
B Material stockout
Work in Process
production rate
Final Inventory
B
B
WIP control
Inventory Control
B shipment rate R
Compl with forecasts Production Scheduling
Demand Forecasting
Delivery Delay Customer Order Rate
590
H. Akkermans et al.
The last section consists of a list of all variables used in this text and all exogenous variables used in the model.
Three-Echelon Supply Chain Where the Sterman-model consists of only one echelon, we model a three-echelon supply chain, by simply copying and pasting the one-echelon-model two times and by connecting the echelons through the shipment rates (SR) of one echelon and the material delivery rate (MDR) of the subsequent echelon, and through the material order rates (MOR) of one echelon and the order rates (OR) of the previous echelon. The materials that the supplier orders from his supplier are outside our system boundaries. It is assumed that these materials are always delivered at the agreed time in the agreed amount. Note that the subscripts 1, 2, and 3 are used to denote respectively the OEM, CM, and SUP. SRi ¼ MDRi1
for
i ¼ 2; 3
(18)
ORi ¼ MORi1
for
i ¼ 2; 3
(19)
OR1 ¼ COR
ð¼ end customer order rateÞ MDR3 ¼ MOR3
(20) (21)
By connecting the three echelons via the shipment and order rates, we now have a supply chain consisting of three organizations, with nine inventory levels: three material inventories, three work in process inventories and three final inventories. The model is based on the interaction of customer demand, which pulls products out of the final inventory, and demand forecast, which pushes products from material inventory, through the work in process inventory into the final inventory. At an aggregate level, the policy structure for each echelon in shown in Fig. 10. The rounded rectangles in Fig. 10 denote organizational policies, or decision rules. For a detailed description of the equations that are used to define these decision rules, we refer to Sterman (2000, Chap. 18, pp. 709–740). Here, we will only describe the general behavior of the model and the differences between our model and the Sterman-model. The arrows pointing clockwise, named B or R, show the feedback structure of the model. The B stands for balancing feedback loop. Balancing loops are self-correcting, they counteract change. The R stands for reinforcing feedback loop. Reinforcing loops are self-reinforcing, they strengthen change. These loops are described below. Inventory control loops. The three balancing inventory loops that are shown in Fig. 10: Material Control, WIP Control and Inventory Control, describe the inventory adjustment policies. Actual inventory levels are compared to desired levels, and when necessary deviations are adjusted over a certain time period. For example,
Three Is a Crowd? On the Benefits of Involving Contract Manufacturers
591
an increase of the work in process inventory, which makes this level higher than the desired work in process level, is corrected by a decrease of the production start rate, in order to balance the work in process level. Stock out control loops. The inventory control loops balance inventory levels by controlling the inflows (for example increasing or decreasing production rates). The two stock out control loops: Material Stock out and Stock out, balance inventory levels by controlling the outflows. Outflows are defined by the maximum of the desired outflow (determined by, for example, customer orders) and the inventory level. Thus, when the final inventory level is low, and customer orders are high, outflow is constrained by the inventory level and delivery of customer orders will be delayed until the inventory level is raised. Delivery delay loop. Production processes in the model are initiated when customer orders are received with a certain customer order rate. These orders are accumulated in a stock of unfulfilled orders, or backlog. Products are shipped to customers with a certain delivery delay, which is determined by the ratio of orders in the backlog and the shipment rate (or fulfilled orders). Thus, the higher the shipment rate, the lower the delivery delay. On the other hand, when the final inventory level is low and products cannot be shipped, delivery delays increase until the final inventory level is sufficiently high. The order rate of the end-customer (COR) is endogenous. In our model this means that the COR is influenced by the delivery delay of the OEM. The delivery delay loop is a balancing loop, because an increase of orders results in a higher backlog, which in turn increases delivery delays. The longer these delays, the more customers will become disappointed and consequently, future customer order rates will drop, leading to a decrease of the backlog, etcetera (see also the next subsection). Compliance with forecasts loop. This loop differs from the Sterman-model. It is included in the model because it reflects the real-life decision rules in the supply chain we analyzed. In Sect. 4.3.2 this compliance-loop is further described.
Product Life Cycle Demand The customer demand of the OEM in the model is defined by both an exogenous and endogenous part. For a description of the endogenous part of the demand, we refer to Sect. 4.3.1. Here, we focus on a description of the exogenous part. The exogenous part is the “shape” and maximum height of the demand curve in time (CORmax). CORmax is the highest possible demand that can be realized when the actual delivery delay is equal to the target delivery delay and when no customers are lost. The maximum demand is defined by the stocks and flows structure of Fig. 11. The equations are given below: TM ¼ ipc þ ic ¼ PC þ C
(22)
ncr ¼ wom ¼ cnc f
(23)
592
H. Akkermans et al. Contacts of noncustomers with customers cnc
potential customer concentration pcc
initial potential Customers ipc
Potential Customers PC
word of mouth demand wom
new customer rate ncr
sociability s fruitfulness f initial customers ic contacts with customers cc
Customers C
Total Market TM
Fig. 11 Stocks and flows of a product life cycle demand
cnc ¼ pcc cc
(24)
cc ¼ C s
(25)
PC TM
(26)
pcc ¼
ncr ¼ CORmax
(27)
The behavior-over-time of the variable “new customer rate” shows a product life cycle curve. This rate determines CORmax. This is the exogenous part of the possible demand of the OEM. Regardless of the scenario modeled, this shape will always be the same. In the Full Collaborative Planning scenario, the OEM shares his demand information with the SUP. But, due to the long production lead times in the supply chain, and in particular of the SUP, the product life cycle must begin earlier for the SUP than for the OEM. We assume that the SUP knows that the demand pattern of the new product will have the shape of the product life cycle (the exogenous shape, as defined above), but for the SUP the curve is shifted a number of weeks to the left (depending on the stacked lead times, L*). CORmax;1 ðtÞ ¼ CORmax t þ L1 CORmax;2 ðtÞ ¼ CORmax t þ L2 þ L1 CORmax;3 ðtÞ ¼ CORmax t þ L3 þ L2 þ L1
(28)
The further upstream in the chain, the longer the stacked lead time and the more the exogenous demand curve is shifted to the left, see Fig. 12. So, the CORmax defines the shape of the demand curve. But the height of the curve is determined by the actual delivery performance of the OEM. When delivery
Three Is a Crowd? On the Benefits of Involving Contract Manufacturers 6,000
CORmax,1 CORmax,2 CORmax,3
4,500
593
units/week units/week units/week
3,000
1,500
0
1
38
76 Time (Week)
113
150
Fig. 12 Possible demand shifted in time for SUP, CM and OEM
performance is poor, the actual customer order rate will be lower than the possible demand of the OEM. In the full collaborative planning scenario this information must be shared immediately with the CM and SUP, to prevent high inventory levels. Based on the actual customer order rate of the OEM, the SUP and CM estimate the height of the future demand curve, to estimate the expected customer order rate (CORexp). For example, suppose that the actual customer order rate in week 70 is 2,500. As we can see in Fig. 12, the possible demand of the OEM was 3,000 in week 70. This means that due to the delivery performance of the OEM, the product life cycle curve is 2,500/3,000 part (83.3%) of what it could have been. This is an immediate sign for the SUP that he has to lower his expectations of future demand with 16.7%. CORexp;i ¼ CORmax;i
COR CORmax;1
(29)
Now, the expected customer order rate will be used in determining the production start rate forecasts. This will be described in the next subsection.
Exogenous Variables Besides all equations that are used to make the model work, we have used a number of exogenous variables that are specific for the three-echelon supply chain. These variables are summarized in Table 5.
594
H. Akkermans et al.
Table 5 List of variables Symbol AfI AOR ARafo ASR ATOR C cc cnc COR CORexp
Description Adjustments for final inventory Average order rate during a certain period Average ratio of actual and forecasted orders Actual shipment rate (from real-life case) Average trend in the order rate during a certain period Customers Contacts with customers Contacts of noncustomers with customers Actual customer order rate Expected customer order rate, which is the customer order rate that all parties in the chain expect based on their collaborative planning effort (sharing of information on end-customer demand and inventory levels) CORmax Maximum customer order rate that can be realized when delivery delays are on target Cycle time: the average delay between the start and CTi completion of production Desired delivery delay: the firm’s internal target for DD*i delivery time Actual delivery delay of the company, defined by ratio DDi of the actual backlog of orders and the shipment rate DDPC Delivery delay that is perceived by the company DDPM Delivery delay that is perceived by the market EBIT Earnings before interest and taxes Effect of the delivery delay on the future customer efDD order rate EVA Economic value added f Fruitfulness defines the measure in which contacts between customers and potential customers leads to new customers f0 Non-linear decreasing function used to calculate the effect of the delivery delay perceived by the market on the future customer order rate Final time Final time of the simulation The forecast period that is used to calculate the fpi average order rate and the average trend in the order rate i Indication of echelon in the supply chain I Actual final inventory level I* Desired final inventory level iC Initial number of customers that have already bought the product from the OEM Final inventory safety stock coverage in number of IC*i weeks Initial time Initial time of the simulation
Valuea/units Units/week Units/week Dimensionless Units/week 1/week Customers Contacts/week Contacts/week Units/week Units/week
Explained in Main text Main text Main text Main text Main text Appendix Appendix Appendix Appendix Appendix
Units/week
Appendix
3, 1, 8 weeks
Sterman
1, 2, 2 weeks
Sterman
Weeks
Sterman
Weeks Weeks Euro Dimensionless
Main text Main text Main text Main text
Euro 0.0062 customers/ contact Dimensionless
Main text Appendix
Main text
150 weeks Sterman 26, 26, 52 weeks Main text
OEM, CM, SUP Units Units 18 customers
Main text Sterman Sterman Appendix
2, 1, 1 weeks
Sterman
1 week
Sterman (continued)
Three Is a Crowd? On the Benefits of Involving Contract Manufacturers
595
Table 5 (continued) Symbol iPC L* MDR MITmin MOR MSS*i
MUU
ncr OPTmin OR PC pcc
pi PSRFgross PSRFnet
s
Description Initial number of potential customers that may be interested in the product sold by the OEM Stacked leadtime, which is the sum of cycle time and safety stock coverage Material delivery rate Minimum material inventory time is the time required to prepare and utilize materials Material order rate Material safety stock coverage is the number of weeks of the desired material usage rate the firm would like to maintain in materials inventory over and above the minimum material coverage Materials used per unit is the number of raw materials the supplier uses per unit of supplier output (raw material unit/material unit produced) Rate in which potential customers become customers Minimum order processing time is the time required to process and ship an order Actual order rate Potential customers Potential customer concentration, which is the number of potential customers as a percentage of the total market Period that is used to calculate the average ratio of actual and forecasted orders Gross production start rate forecast (uncorrected for any optimistic or pessimistic forecasting behavior) Net production start rate forecast, which is the gross forecast corrected for either optimism or pessimism Sociability defines the number of contacts each customer has with a potential customer per week
Valuea/units 210,882 customers Weeks
Explained in Appendix Main text
Units/week 1 weeks
Sterman Sterman
Units/week 1, 1, 1 weeks
Sterman Sterman
1 unit/unit
Sterman
Customers/week Appendix 1 weeks Sterman Units/week Customers Dimensionless
Sterman Appendix Appendix
26, 6.8, 51.3 weeks Units/week
Main text Main text
Units/week
Main text
18.15 contacts/ customer/ week SAVEPER Frequency with which output is stored 0.25 weeks SR Shipment rate (from simulation model) Units/week Time to adjust final inventory level is the time period 8 weeks TAI over which the plant seeks to bring inventory in balance with the desired level 2 weeks Time to adjust material inventory is the time over TAMI which the firm seeks to correct imbalances in its materials inventories TAOR Time to adjust expected order rate is the time required 8 weeks to adjust the expected order rate to actual customer orders TASL Supply line adjustment time is the time constant for 2 weeks adjusting the supply line to the desired level TAW WIP adjustment time is the time required to adjust the 2 weeks WIP to the desired level
Appendix
Sterman Sterman Sterman
Sterman
Sterman
Sterman Sterman (continued)
596
H. Akkermans et al.
Table 5 (continued) Symbol TCPDD TDDi TIME STEP TM
Description Time for company to perceive delivery delay Target delivery delay: the firm’s target for delivery delay Time step for the simulation
Valuea/units 12 weeks 2, 3, 3 weeks
Explained in Main text Main text
0.0625 weeks
Total market size, which is the sum of potential and Customers Appendix current customers Time for market to perceive delivery delay 25 weeks Main text TMPDD TPMDD Sterman Time to perceive material delivery delay is the delay 4 weeks in perceiving and responding to changes in supplier lead times TX Taxes Euro Main text WACC Weighted average cost of capital Euro Main text WC Working capital Euro Main text Customers/week Appendix wom Word of mouth demand, which is the rate in which customers influence potential customers to buy the product a When there is no constant value given, this means that the variable is an endongenous variable which is defined by an equation that is given in the main text, Appendix, or in Sterman (2000)
References Akkermans HA, Dellaert NP (2005) The rediscovery of industrial dynamics: the contribution of system dynamics to supply chain management in a dynamic and fragmented world. Syst Dyn Rev 21(3):173–186 Akkermans HA, Bogerd P, van Doremalen J (2004) Travail, transparency and trust: a case study of computer-supported collaborative supply chain planning in high-tech electronics. Eur J Oper Res 153:445–456 Alfalla-Luque R, Medina-Lopez C (2009) Supply chain management: unheard of in the 1970s, core to today’s company. Bus Hist 51(2):202–221 Aviv Y (2001) The effect of collaborative planning on supply chain performance. Manage Sci 47 (10):1326–1343 Aviv Y (2007) On the benefits of collaborative forecasting partnerships between retailers and manufacturers. Manage Sci 53(5):777–794 Bass F (1969) A new product growth model for consumer durables. Manage Sci 15:217–227 Benson-Armer RJ, Dean DL, Kelleher JC (2004) Getting contract manufacturers back on track. McKinsey Q. http://www.mckinsey.com. Accessed July 2004 Bezemer JJ (2003) Modeling the dynamics of business fulfillment: improved understanding of stacked lead time. Master thesis, Eindhoven University of Technology, Eindhoven Bezemer JJ, Akkermans HA (2003) Not with a bang, but with a whimper: Understanding delays in semiconductor supply chain dynamics. Presentation made at the International System Dynamics Conference, New York Cachon GP, Fisher M (2000) Supply chain inventory management and the value of shared information. Manage Sci 46(8):1032–1048 Chan HK, Chan FTS (2010) A review of coordination studies in the context of supply chain dynamics. Int J Prod Res 48(10):2793–2819
Three Is a Crowd? On the Benefits of Involving Contract Manufacturers
597
Chen F (1999) Decentralized supply chains subject to information delays. Manage Sci 45(8): 1076–1090 Croson R, Donohue K (2006) Behavioral causes of the bull-whip effect and the observed value of inventory information. Manage Sci 52(3):323–336 Davis JP, Eisenhardt KM, Bingman CB (2007) Developing theory through simulation methods. Acad Manage Rev 32(2):480–499 De Kok TG, Janssen F, Van Doremalen J, Van Wachem E, Clerkx M, Peeters W (2005) Philips Electronics synchronizes its supply chain to end the bullwhip effect. Interfaces 35(1):37–48 Dobson G, Pinker EJ (2006) The value of sharing lead time information. IIE Trans 38:171–183 Dogan G (2007) Bootstrapping for confidence interval estimation and hypothesis testing for parameters of system dynamics models. Syst Dyn Rev 23(4):415–436 Fine CH (1999) Clockspeed – winning industry control in the age of temporary advantage. Perseus Books, Reading, MA Forrester JA (1961) Industrial dynamics. MIT, Cambridge, MA Garcia R, Calantone R, Levine R (2003) The role of knowledge in resource allocation to exploration versus exploitation in technologically oriented organisations. Decis Sci 34(2):323–349 Gavirneni S, Kapuscinski R, Tayur S (1999) Value of information in capacitated supply chains. Manage Sci 45(1):16–24 Gonc¸alves P, Hines J, Sterman JD (2005) The impact of endogenous demand on push–pull production systems. Syst Dyn Rev 21:187–216 Hameri A, Paatela A (2005) Supply network dynamics as a source of new business. Int J Prod Econ 98:41–55 Hoekstra S, Romme S (1992) Integral logistics structures: developing customer-oriented goods flow. McGraw-Hill, London Holweg M, Disney S, Holmstr€ om J, Sma˚ros J (2005) Supply chain collaboration: making sense of the strategy continuum. Eur Manage J 23(2):170–181 Jaber MY, Goyal SK (2008) Coordinating a three-level supply chain with multiple suppliers, a vendor and multiple buyers. Int J Prod Econ 116:95–103 Jaber MY, Bonney M, Guiffrida AL (2010) Coordinating a three-level supply chain with learningbased continuous improvements. Int J Prod Econ 127:27–38 Lee HL, Padmanabhan V, Whang S (1997) Information distortion in a supply chain: the bullwhip effect. Manage Sci 43(4):546–558 Lee HL, So KC, Tang CS (2000) The value of information sharing in a two-level supply chain. Manage Sci 46(5):626–643 Li L (2002) Information sharing in a supply chain with horizontal competition. Manage Sci 48(9):1196–1212 Lynn BC (2005) End of the line: the rise and coming fall of the global corporation. Double Day, New York McCarther MW, Northcraft GB (2007) Happy together? Insights and implications of viewing managed supply chains as a social dilemma. J Oper Manage 25:498–511 McCormack K (2007) Flextronics adds a key part. Business Week, 4 June Moinzadeh K (2002) A multi-echelon inventory system with information exchange. Manage Sci 48(3):414–426 Oliva R (2003) Model calibration as a testing strategy for system dynamics models. Eur J Oper Res 151(3):552–568 Oliva R, Sterman JD (2001) Cutting corners and working overtime: quality erosion in the service industry. Manage Sci 47(7):894–914 Repenning NP, Sterman JD (2002) Capability traps and self-confirming attribution errors in the dynamics of process improvements. Adm Sci Q 47:265–295 Sabath RE, Fontanella J (2002) The unfulfilled promise of supply chain collaboration. Supply Chain Manage Rev 6(4):24–29 Sahin F, Robinson EP (2002) Flow coordination and information sharing in supply chains: review, implications, and directions for future research. Decis Sci 33(4):505–536
598
H. Akkermans et al.
Sharafali M, Co HC (2006) Some models for understanding the cooperation between the supplier and the buyer. Int J Prod Res 38(15):3425–3449 Sterman JD (1984) Appropriate summary statistics for evaluating the historical fit of system dynamics models. Dynamica 10(1):51–66 Sterman JD (2000) Business dynamics. systems thinking and modeling for a complex world. Irwin McGraw-Hill, Boston Steward G (1991) The quest for value: a guide for senior managers. Harper Business, New York Van Aken JE (1978) On the control of complex industrial organizations. Martinus Nijhoff Social Sciences Division, Leiden Wangphanich P, Karaa S, Kayisa B (2009) Analysis of the bullwhip effect in multi-product, multistage supply chain systems-a simulation approach. Int J Prod Res 48(15):4501–4517 Wei H-L, Wang ETC (2010) The strategic value of supply chain visibility: increasing the ability to reconfigure. Eur J Inf Syst 19:238–249
Managing IT Suppliers: A Capability-Based Approach Carlos Brito and Mafalda Nogueira
Abstract This chapter addresses the opportunities for capabilities exchange within the process of interaction between a firm and an IT (Information Technology) supplier. Research on the features of this type of relationship has focused on IT implementation, relationship between IT resources, organisation performance and competitive advantage, IT outsourcing relationships and definition of IT capabilities. However, the current understanding of the context where IT capabilities are exchanged within consultancy projects and how this exchange emerges is rather limited. The chapter aims to bridge this gap by adopting the IMP (Industrial Marketing and Purchasing) group’s interaction approach as a tool to conduct an in-depth investigation of a case study to analyse the context, the parties and the interactions through which IT capabilities are exchanged. Evidence was found that interpersonal relationships between users and consultants within consultancy projects are crucial to reduce uncertainty by establishing long-lasting and stable relationships. As a result, during consultancy projects IT-related resources, in the form of IT physical infrastructures, human IT resources and IT intangible resources, are exchanged and combined to create or enhance IT capabilities. Furthermore, the success of such an exchange depends very much on the degree of social and interpersonal exchange. Keywords Capabilities • Consultancy project • Information technology • Interaction • Relationships
C. Brito Faculty of Economics, University of Porto, Rua Roberto Frias, 4200-464 Porto, Portugal e-mail: [email protected] M. Nogueira Management School, Lancaster University, Lancaster LA1-4YX, UK e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_24, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
599
600
C. Brito and M. Nogueira
1 Introduction IT is changing the way companies perform. The importance of understanding the results of IT implementation is revealed by the amount of research dedicated to the subject. Lai and Mahapatra (1997) identified 71 papers related to IT implementation issues. Others adopting a Resource Based View (RBV) of the firm, focused on the relationship between IT resources, organisation performance and competitive advantage (Bharadwaj 2000; Mata et al. 1995; Ross et al. 1996; Powell and DentMicallef 1997; Tippins and Sohi 2003) and on the definition of IT capabilities (Yongbeom et al. 2006; Duhan 2007; Bharadwaj et al. 1999). IT outsourcing relationships are also being strongly discussed among researchers (Kern and Willcocks 2002; Hurley 2001; Gonzalez et al. 2006; Kishore et al. 2003; Goo et al. 2007; Lacity et al. 1996) where the reasons for success in IT adoption are shifted from the IT products implementation to the management of relationships with service providers. The importance given to relationships in the context of IT implementation is also evident in research on client–consultant relationships (Mike 2003; Shah 1990; Chornoboy and Gardner 1990; Larwood and Gattiker 1986; Dawes et al. 2007). Despite these examples of IT research, existing literature relies very much on what Bharadwaj et al. (1999, p. 379) refer to “anecdotal evidence, discussions with a few visionary IS executives or case studies of highly successful firms”. This is particularly accurate when the subject on how to enhance IT capabilities is raised. Taxonomies of IT capabilities were identified (Bharadwaj 2000; Duhan 2007; Mulligan 2002; Feeny and Willcocks 1998), the importance of relationships with suppliers, consultants and service providers as keystones to successful implementations was also addressed (Kern and Willcocks 2002; Goo et al. 2007; Mike 2003; Webster 1995; Lui and Chan 2008), but the links between IT capabilities development and relationships with IT suppliers was not fully explored. Researchers of the IMP (Industrial Marketing and Purchasing) group argue that capabilities are developed through interactions in the relationships with other parties (Ha˚kansson and Snehota 1989) and “if properly used supplier relationships can dramatically enhance the resources and capabilities that a company can use” (Ford et al. 2003, p. 97). In the same way, the capabilities perspective based on the RBV suggests that relationships work as mechanisms to coordinate resources and capabilities that a company does not possess (Foss 1999; Loasby 1994, 1998). This chapter seeks an understanding of the context, the parties and the interactions through which IT capabilities are exchanged within a client–IT supplier. To achieve this understanding, we combine the contributions from the fields of industrial marketing and purchasing research and capabilities approach, specifically on IT capabilities, to argue that a company may boost its IT capabilities and reduce uncertainty, not only by purchasing and implementing IT resources, but also through the process of interaction with the IT supplier during the implementation, which in turn will depend on the specific features of such a relationship.
Managing IT Suppliers: A Capability-Based Approach
601
The chapter is organized as follows. First, a review of the relevant literature is presented based on three main theoretical keystones: the IMP Interaction Model, the literature on consultancy relationships research and the IT capabilities approach. The section which follows presents the analytical framework. Thirdly, we address the case analysis and discussion of the findings. The last section reveals the conclusions and a number of both theoretical and managerial implications.
2 Theoretical Background 2.1
The IMP Interaction Approach
A great amount of research on industrial markets has been conducted by academics within the IMP group to provide a wider understanding of business markets in terms of dyadic buyer–supplier relationships and industrial networks in which those relationships are developed and managed (Axelsson and Easton 1992; Ford 1980, 2002; Ford et al. 1998; Ha˚kansson 1982, 1987; Ha˚kansson and Snehota 1995). The IMP group has provided a key conceptual model, often quoted in industrial markets studies, focused on the nature of buyer–supplier relationships – The Interaction Model (Ha˚kansson 1982). Originally developed in the 1980s in the context of manufacturing companies, the model was later extended to explore relationships in services sectors. The model is adopted here to capture the key features of the client – IT supplier relationship since it provides a way of drawing the richness of relationships in a four element analytical approach: the interacting parties, the interaction process, the interaction atmosphere and the interaction environment (Ha˚kansson 1982). This approach takes relationships as a process of continuous exchanges (products and services, information, social and financial exchanges) developed in short-term episodes. Such exchange episodes may become institutionalized over time leading to expectations of further exchanges and to long-term relationships. In addition, the parties may make adaptations in the elements exchanged or in the process of exchange, which includes adaptations of the product specification, product design, manufacturing processes, planning, delivery procedures, stockholding, administrative procedures or financial procedures (Ha˚kansson 1982). The interaction process also depends on the idiosyncrasies of the participants, organizations or individuals. Organizations are characterized in terms of technology, size, structure, strategy and experience, whereas individuals are characterized by their functional area, hierarchical level, personality, experience and motivation. The environment within which interaction takes place is characterized in terms of market structure, dynamism, internationalization, position in the manufacturing channel and social system. Finally, the atmosphere affecting and being affected by the interaction is described in terms of power-dependence relationships, conflict or cooperation, closeness and distance, and mutual expectations.
602
C. Brito and M. Nogueira
As shown by some researchers from the IMP group, the interaction approach is particularly suitable to investigate dyadic relationships in an IT context (Leek et al. 2003; Naude´ et al. 2000). Information Systems researchers also adopted this model to explore outsourcing relationships (Kern and Willcocks 2002, p. 12) claiming that it helps researchers to “catch some fundamental aspects of interorganisational relationships in IT outsourcing”. Thus, the adoption of the Interaction Model to investigate a client–IT supplier relationship seems worthwhile in the context of our research objectives.
2.2
Client - IT Supplier Relationships
There is a vast range of studies on client–IT supplier relationships: client–consultant relationships (Mike 2003; Shah 1990; Chornoboy and Gardner 1990; Larwood and Gattiker 1986; Dawes et al. 2007), IT outsourcing relationships (Kern and Willcocks 2002; Hurley 2001; Gonzalez et al. 2006; Kishore et al. 2003; Goo et al. 2007; Lacity et al. 1996), and client–IT supplier/IT service provider relationships (Kishore et al., 2003). These studies emphasize the importance of relationship management and partnerships with suppliers to achieve benefits from IT adoption. Karantinou and Hogg (2001), for example, described the features of client–consultant relationships combining IMP contributions and a relationship marketing approach. Complexity, information asymmetry, conflicts of interests and differences in perceptions and expectations between clients and consultants are some of the identified features. In consultancy projects, as Willcocks et al. (2004) claim, clients are seeking both human capital (in the form of new skills and knowledge), and structural capital (in the form of knowledge bases and best practices, due to the expertise consultancy firms can offer). Therefore, skills and knowledge achieved in consultancy projects may be resources that work together to create IT capabilities. Surprisingly, none of those studies considered IT capabilities exchange as a potential feature of a client–IT supplier relationship which endorsed the motivation to conduct this investigation. Another feature of this type of relationship is the organizational form through which exchanges are developed – the consultancy projects (Richter and Niewiem 2004). The literature on project marketing provides some valuable insights that cannot be neglected. The discontinuity trend, as a consequence of the time breaks generally observed between projects must be considered if one seeks an understanding of client–consultant relationships. The capacity to manage such a relationship is limited by the fact that “the purchasing of a project by a given client may not be repeated until a few years have elapsed since the previous purchase” (Cova and Salle 2000, p. 670). The adoption of the interaction model (Ha˚kansson 1982) to understand social exchanges in IT outsourcing was described elsewhere (Kern and Willcocks 2002), but the role they play in struggling with discontinuity between projects was not addressed.
Managing IT Suppliers: A Capability-Based Approach
603
Studies on client–consultant dyads (Richter and Niewiem 2004; Graubner and Richter 2003) suggest that such relationships are observing fundamental changes in the last decade since “consulting market is turning from a sellers’ into a buyers’ market” (Richter and Niewiem 2004, p. 9). Evidence shows that consultancies can no longer obtain large margins as in the past. Competition is growing fast and clients are becoming more and more knowledgeable and demanding (Graubner and Richter 2003), especially after the scandals involving well-known consultancy firms namely Enron, Arthur-Anderson or KPMG. Interaction between firms is therefore crucial to reinforce the strength of the relationship and personal interaction is cited as the “most important sources of actionable and hence relevant knowledge” in client–consultant relationships (Richter and Niewiem 2004, p. 12) where both parties can learn and benefit from each other. A parallel may be established with findings from a study on the determinants of ERP implementation knowledge transfer (Xu and Ma, 2008) according to which the benefits of ERP depend on knowledge and skills transfer within a bidirectional flow, from consultants to users and vice versa. In line with this argument, we see knowledge/ skills in an IT implementation context as potential drivers to enhance IT capabilities in both parties of the relationship. Knowledge and skills exchange are therefore highlighted in the literature as a feature of such relationships (Richter and Niewiem 2004), which lead us to question how this exchange emerges in consultancy projects. Understanding how this transference or exchange occurs is therefore crucial to take the best out of IT-based relationships.
2.3
IT Capabilities Approach
IT is being claimed as a source of competitive advantage and recognised as an organisational capability (Mata et al. 1995; Ross et al. 1996; Feeny and Willcocks 1998; Clemons and Row 1991). IT capability literature is rooted in the RBV which highlights the link between competitive advantage and resources of the firm, seen as firm-specific, rare and difficult to imitate by competitors (Barney 1991; Foss and Roberston 2000). This chapter endorses much of the spirit of the RBV but does not seek to engage in this particular debate. Rather the aim is to step forward and suggest a framework within which IT capabilities are leveraged in client–IT supplier relationships. In this sense our focus is directed to what is being defined as IT capabilities. In the context of IT resources it is generally argued that various IT-related resources may be combined to form an IT capability that is valuable, rare, non-imitable and non-substitutable (Mata et al., 1995). It can be seen as the “organization’s ability to understand and utilize IT tools and processes that are needed to manage market and customer information” (Tippins and Sohi 2003, p. 748) which comprises IT objects, IT knowledge and IT operations. In line with Bharadwaj’s (2000, p. 171) definition of IT capability we understand this ability “as the ability to mobilize and deploy IT-based resources in combination or co-presence with other resources and capabilities”. Over the past two decades, researchers have
604
C. Brito and M. Nogueira
been studying what type of IT resources may be considered as sources of competitive advantage and combined to create IT capabilities: (1) IT physical infrastructures, namely, shared platforms and databases (Ross et al. 1996), computer-based hardware and software (Bharadwaj 2000; Tippins and Sohi 2003); (2) technical and managerial skills of human resources (Bharadwaj 2000; Ross et al. 1996; Tippins and Sohi 2003), (3) relationship assets in the sense of coordination and interaction with user community (Mata et al. 1995; Ross et al. 1996), (4) capabilities to acquire technologies (Flowers 2007) and (5) IT-enabled intangibles such as synergies, customer orientation and knowledge assets (Bharadwaj 2000) are some of the relevant resources that work together to create IT capabilities referred in the literature. Bharadwaj’s (2000) taxonomy was adopted to conduct the empirical investigation as it presents a comprehensive analysis of IT capabilities. He suggests a scheme to classify IT resources capable of creating organisational capabilities: (1) IT physical infrastructure, (2) IT human resources comprising managerial and technical skills and (3) IT intangible resources where knowledge assets, customer orientation and synergies are included. IT physical infrastructure comprises computer and communication technologies and shared technical platforms and databases, which in turn are essential to systems integration and to develop cost-effective IT applications. Human IT resources cover the technical IT skills (e.g. programming, systems analysis and design, competencies in emerging technologies) and managerial skills, often tacit and dependent on interpersonal relationships, such as leadership, project management skills, coordination and interaction with users. Lastly, IT-enabled intangibles embrace the intangible benefits derived from IT utilization. The way users employ technology is regarded as a knowledge that is tacit, idiosyncratic and deeply embedded on the organisation. Firstly, IT is an indispensable ingredient for achieving high levels of customer orientation, which enables firms to track and predict shifts in customer choices, to forecast product demand and to improve customer service. Secondly, “a key aspect of a firm’s intangible resources is its intellectual capital or knowledge assets” (Bharadwaj 2000, p. 175). IT systems embedded with employees’ knowledge enables the development of new knowledge and crystallization of existing knowledge, which leverages the firm’s ability to respond to environmental changes. Lastly, IT also promotes synergies through knowledge and information sharing across all business units, which enables firms to be more flexible and to respond faster to market needs. Competitive advantages associated with synergies are, therefore, difficult to imitate because they are “often achieved under a unique set of circumstances and on the basis of firm-specific resources” (Bharadwaj 2000, p. 176).
3 Analytical Framework The aim of this chapter is to explore the opportunities for IT capabilities exchange within the relationship between a client and an IT supplier. From the literature review on the topic, an avenue for research was identified since existing studies focus on the adoption of IT resources to enhance organisation performance and
Managing IT Suppliers: A Capability-Based Approach
605
competitive advantage, the identification of IT capabilities, IT outsourcing and client–consultant relationship’s management. However, the understanding about the context where IT capabilities are exchanged within consultancy projects and how this exchange emerges is rather scarce. In this context, two research questions emerge. Firstly, we aim to expand our understanding of the characteristics of client–IT supplier relationships. Some of their specificities were revealed in the theoretical background section; however, we concluded from the revision of the relevant literature that understanding such characteristics in a dynamic context of interaction was scarcely approached. Therefore, the first research question is: “What are the features of the interaction process within a client–IT supplier relationship?”
Secondly, the literature on the topic is mainly focused on IT implementation issues, relationship between IT resources, organisation performance and competitive advantage, IT outsourcing relationships and definition of IT capabilities. What is missing is an understanding on how IT capabilities are leveraged in client–IT supplier relationships, beyond the mere implementation of IT products. Therefore the second research question was formulated as follows: “How can a company enhance their capabilities through interactions with IT suppliers within consultancy projects?”
We seek to address these research questions by adopting the Interaction Model (Ha˚kansson 1982) as a tool to analyse the context, the parties and the interactions through which IT capabilities are exchanged. In this sense, an analytical framework (Fig. 1) was constructed on the basis of (1) the IMP work on the understanding of business-to-business relationships and interactions (e.g., Ford 1980, 2002; Ford et al. 1986; Ha˚kansson 1982; Ha˚kansson and Ford 2002; Ha˚kansson and Prenkert 2004) and (2) the approach of IT as capabilities of the firm (e.g., Bharadwaj 2000; Mata et al. 1995; Ross et al. 1996, Rockart et al. 1996). The framework embodies the dyadic relationship between a client and an IT supplier by exploring the dimensions of the original interaction process (Ha˚kansson, 1982) and by adding a new type of exchange – IT capabilities – proposed here as a critical dimension to characterize this specific kind of relationship. Firstly, inspired by the original model the interaction process is reflected as embedded by its atmosphere and explored in two perspectives of analysis. The short-term episodes may reflect transactions, negotiations, consultancy projects, etc. whereas the long-term perspective intends to represent the evolution of the relationship. Each episode involves different types of exchanges, namely, products and services, social and financial exchange and information. In addition, these exchange types are a result of the contacts and negotiations developed between the parties, as well as necessary investments and adaptations trough which the relationship is institutionalized. In a client–IT supplier relationship context the latter may include, for example, adaptations in software, working processes, planning, delivery procedures, stockholding, administrative procedures, etc. Finally, the atmosphere affecting and being affected by the interaction is described in terms of cooperation or conflict
606
C. Brito and M. Nogueira
RELATIONSHIP ATMOSPHERE
Interaction Process
CLIENT
Perspective of Analysis
Exchanges Products/Services Financial Social Information
Short-term: Episodes
TYPES
IT Capabilities
Long-term: Relationships
Contacts Negotiations Adaptations / Investments Cooperation / Conflict
IT SUPPLIER
Power / Dependence
Distance / Closeness
FORMS
Mutual Expectations
Fig. 1 Analytical framework
positions during IT projects, contract negotiations, power-dependence positions in the dyad, distance and closeness between parties and mutual expectations about the past, present and future of the relationship (Ha˚kansson 1982). Secondly, the IT capabilities access is introduced as a specific type of exchange that emerges throughout interaction episodes. Adopting a Capabilities Approach, this investigation endorses a wide range of researchers who look into inter-firm relationships as a key mechanism to coordinate capabilities (Loasby 1994; Foss and Roberston 2000, Foss and Loasby 1998; Mota and De Castro 2005). Therefore, considering IT as capabilities of the firm (Bharadwaj 2000; Mata et al. 1995) the framework suggests that access to new IT capabilities may emerge from consultancy projects during succeeding interaction episodes. The framework was designed with two major concerns: on the one hand, to fairly represent the overall interaction process between the parties, comprising the opportunities to access IT capabilities as a type of exchange; secondly, to be used as a tool to conduct the empirical investigation in the sense that each dimension of the framework was operated as bedrock to collect, organize and analyse the empirical data (Table 1).
Managing IT Suppliers: A Capability-Based Approach
607
Table 1 Data analysis dimensions Dimensions Sub-dimensions A Interaction process A1 Key Actors Companies’ history and focal activities Market positions A2 Relationship background Relationship “age” and history Motivations for supplier selection A3 Perspectives of analysis Short term: episodes Long term: relationship evolution A4 Exchanges (IMP view) Types: product/service, information, social, financial Forms: contacts, negotiations, adaptations/investments A5 Relationship atmosphere Cooperation and conflict Power and dependence Distance and closeness Mutual expectations B IT capabilities exchange B1 Tangible Physical infra-structures B2 Human IT resources Technical and managerial skills B3 Intangible Customer orientation Synergies Knowledge assets or intellectual capital
4 Research Strategy It is argued that case research may provide a significant contribution to the development of theory in purchasing and supply management fields (Dubois and Arau´jo, 2007). Time delimitation, definition of boundaries, dynamic nature of relationships embedded in networks are said to be problematic issues which can be properly tackled with case studies as case methods are concerned with dynamics and changes over time and are able to provide longitudinal data (Dubois and Arau´jo 2004, 2007; Dubois and Gadde 2002; Easton 1998). This research deals with business interactions between actors within which a specific type of capabilities may be exchanged. Therefore, given the nature of the research problem and the type of research questions, the adoption of case research seems appropriate to conduct this investigation. A reflection on what type of case would be more suitable in the context of our research aims led us to search for a dyadic relationship between a client and an IT supplier who was simultaneously an IT physical infrastructure supplier, a service provider (in terms of technical and managerial skills) and a business consultant. Having these three features together would provide a rich context within which different IT capabilities
608
C. Brito and M. Nogueira
could be exchanged. Furthermore, it would also have to involve a long-term relationship involving numerous and complex IT projects in order to grant a plentiful collection of inspirational interaction episodes. The relevance of the selected case is thus associated with the extensive supplier offer in terms of IT related products and services as well as the length of the relationship comprising different and numerous projects. Adopting the Interaction Model as a keystone to design the analytical framework, a single case design with embedded cases was carried out. The dyadic relationship was at the heart of the study whereas the interaction episodes were the embedded cases providing the means to delimit time borders and define research boundaries. An in-depth analysis of a relationship between a client and an IT supplier was undertaken and 18 interaction episodes based on IT implementation projects (Enterprise Resource Planning – ERP, Customer Relationship Management – CRM, Domino software for electronic e-mail and workflow processes), contract negotiations, search for new solutions, etc., which occurred between 1980 and 2006, were comprehensively investigated (see Appendix). The companies involved in the selected focal relationship were a paint manufacturer and its main IT supplier. The supplier company was selected based on a privileged access rationale. The selection of the client was attached to two main reasons: firstly, it is the Iberia market leader of paint industry and one of the most technology-oriented companies in Portugal; secondly, because it holds a key position in the supplier’s customer portfolio which implies the involvement of both parties in numerous consultancy projects. Although, this research does not seek to generalize findings, but to provide new insights on the understanding of business relationships as drivers to exchange capabilities, a considerable amount of data was sought and obtained in order to investigate the research problem. As claimed by Easton (1998), a set of multiple data sources on both sides of the dyad is needed to fully understand the relationship complexity. As a result, multiple data sources were investigated and crossed to corroborate findings. Firstly, the research was based on semi-structured interviews conducted in both companies, where the framework’s dimensions and sub-dimensions (see Table 1) were investigated. Fourteen interviews were carried out with people who were highly involved in the IT implementation episodes throughout the period 1980–2006. From the supplier side, project managers, key account manager, product manager and business and technical consultants were interviewed. From the client side, the IT department director, project managers and six final users were questioned. All the interviews were recorded and fully transcribed. Secondly, a wide range of documents was analyzed from both sides of the dyad. In one hand, rich information was collected from the institutional websites where the researchers had access to companies’ annual reports, market positions, histories, mission statements and focal activities. Newspaper articles and newsletters from both companies were also used to build the case study. On the other hand, a large amount of internal documentation was provided by both firms which played an important role to corroborate the insights given by the interviewees (minutes from IT projects meetings related to different episodes, reports related to evaluation
Managing IT Suppliers: A Capability-Based Approach
609
of IT needs, analysis of software adaptations, project management, commercial proposals, contracts, PowerPoint presentations used by the supplier to present new solutions. . .). Finally, observation was also a rich source of data. Observationparticipation was possible since one of the researchers was involved in one of the IT projects which provided the opportunity to get close access to final users and observe their expectations and feelings about the relationship with the IT supplier. Regarding the process of data analysis, in a first stage, the multiple sources of empirical evidence were organised and displayed in a set of tables. Each table was related to each dimension of the analytical framework (following Table 1).Within a table, each column represented a sub-dimension of the model and the n lines represented all the references retrieved from different sources related to that dimension. This way, the findings from each dimension were triangulated and corroborated by different sources of evidence which provided a rich basis to build the case. In a second stage, the analysis of the tables gave place to a unique report describing the case.
5 Case Analysis As previously described, the analytical framework was designed not only to reflect the potential IT capabilities exchange and the overall interaction process between the parties, but also to provide a useful tool to conduct the empirical investigation. In this sense, the case analysis is developed according to the elements of the framework and sub-divided along two major dimensions: the interaction process and the IT capabilities exchange.
5.1
Dimension A - Interaction Process
A1. Key Actors The companies involved in the focal relationship were the client PaintCo and the supplier ITSup.1 PaintCo is the largest Portuguese paint group and the only one in their market quoted on the stock exchange. With products divided into decorative, industrial, car repainting, anticorrosive and accessories segments, the group has around 800 employees and comprises several companies, with nearly 70 whollyowned stores and factories in Portugal, Spain, Angola, Mozambique and Cape Verde. Ranked 16th in Europe and 46th worldwide, PaintCo is the Iberian leader
1 For confidentiality reasons, companies’ names are fictional. The organizational profiles presented in this chapter illustrate the companies’ features by the time this research was undertaken.
610
C. Brito and M. Nogueira
in the paint market. ITSup, in turn, is a leading provider of business systems, with a presence on the Stockholm Stock Exchange. Its offer includes business applications and professional services extended to several areas (e.g. sales and marketing support, customer relationship management, supply chain management, manufacturing and distribution, financial control, business intelligence). Portugal is the headquarters for the Iberian competences centre and a founder of the Southern Area of ITSup Group, along with Spain, Italy, France, Brazil and Colombia.
A2. Relationship Background The relationship between PaintCo and ITSup started in the 1980s, not as a standard client–supplier relationship, but as a partnership to develop software. At the time, the client was totally autonomous in developing in-house IT. Through personal relationships between top managers, PaintCo and ITSup decided to jointly develop a financial solution, suitable for the requirements of the painting industry. After small IT projects (see Appendix) involving both companies the relationship was gradually strengthened. In the early 2000s, observing a fast growth, PaintCo decided to adopt a corporate philosophy. The main goal was to standardise working procedures and define a new business model used universally by the group. The new strategy brought with it the need to search for an ERP (Enterprise Resource Planning) system. ITSup was first short listed as a potential supplier and then selected, largely due to the trusting relationship that had already existed for nearly 20 years. The ERP covered the financial, commercial and distribution areas. Other departments, such as R&D and human resources had specific software adapted to their requirements, which led to a massive need to create interfaces between different systems. Currently, PaintCo maintains frequent contact with ITSup.
A3. Perspectives of Analysis In a short-term perspective, episodes comprised mainly negotiations and consultancy projects and became intense from the moment PaintCo decided to invest in ITSup’s ERP solution. The ERP project turned out to be the most conspicuous of the relationship and considered the point of departure for subsequent projects. The following projects consisted of programming language acquisitions, adaptations to existing software, physical infrastructure renewal, Customer Relationship Management (CRM) system among others. From a long-term perspective, the several episodes following the initial partnership established in the late 1980s, gave place to a strong and solid relationship, seriously energised through personal and social relationships amongst personnel from both companies. In fact, personal and social relationships were identified as a central characteristic of client–IT supplier relationships.
Managing IT Suppliers: A Capability-Based Approach
611
A4. Exchanges Exchange Types. Throughout the several episodes that were considered in the analysis, the following exchange types were identified: products and services (hardware, software, and consultancy professional services), financial exchange (disbursements), information exchange (about work procedures and routines, activity sectors), and social exchange. Social exchange had on one hand and during the projects, a daily, intense and informal nature, contributing to the development of personal bonding between the people from both parties. On the other hand, in discontinuity periods between projects, social exchange played the role of a communication bridge, which explains how the relationship could carry on, healthy and stable, for 20 years even witnessing several and extensive hiatus between projects. Exchange Forms. The exchanges took several forms. Specific negotiations occurred for each project and were formalised via contracts. There were also intense and frequent formal and informal contacts via diverse channels, namely project meetings, support documentation, daily encounters, e-mail, phone and fax. Finally, and what was more obvious, was that both organisations made huge adaptations and investments. Both carried out high time and human resources investments so that the project’s success would not be jeopardised. In terms of adaptations, we highlight the client adaptations to new working processes and the uncountable supplier adaptations to standard software in order to be able to reply to client’s demands.
A5. Relationship Atmosphere Power/Dependence. The client seems to hold a greater control over the relationship, apparently because is a strategic reference in the client portfolio of the supplier as well as a considerable source of income. The supplier expects the client, as Iberian leader in sales volume and innovation, to play a key role as opinion maker in the diffusion of the positive experience of the relationship. The power position held by the client became clear as all their solicitations and requirements for adaptations to software were always approved by ITSup. This evidence was corroborated by documents describing the amount of adaptations to the standard software that were accepted and developed by the supplier. Despite this control position, the client seems to maintain a certain level of dependence toward the supplier, as a consequence of frequently having the need to expand IT exploitation, eliminate program errors and demand for changes in standard programs. Conflict/Cooperation. The relationship atmosphere was not dominated by conflict, although there were some conflict situations, mainly due to the high number of software adaptations and following delays in the accomplishment of pre-defined implementation deadlines. Still, both parties agreed there was strong cooperation between them in order to solve the conflicts and reduce uncertainty. This cooperation included the implementation of measures by the project management team, mostly at the level of a reinforcement of the involvement of PaintCo’s users in the prompt
612
C. Brito and M. Nogueira
identification of non-conformities and consequent need to change standard programs and at the level of postponement of implementation deadlines. In fact, the majority of the interviewees emphasised the importance of cooperation between project leaders from both sides as a key dimension for a good relationship. Closeness/Distance. Although the projects were formalised by contracts, the decisive role of personal and social bonds for increasing proximity between parties and reducing uncertainty was highlighted. On the relationship’s distance in its several dimensions (cultural, social, technological, temporal and geographic) only the temporal distance might have some relevant meaning, given the length of the projects, especially the ERP project. Mutual Expectations. Both companies showed common expectations on relationship continuity, as well as in the costs and benefits associated with the relationship.
5.2
Dimension B - IT Capabilities Exchange
B1. Tangible Capabilities The relationship allowed the client to access IT tangible capabilities, which previously did not possess. The ERP project demanded a new physical infrastructure (information systems, interfaces between systems, hardware) common to all companies of the group. In this sense, these physical resources provided the client with a universal platform of information sharing and distribution. From this project onwards, it was possible to implement standardized working processes, allowing the client to take advantage of synergies generation between several units. The acquisition of software for application development (Lotus Notes software), another IT physical resource, also granted PaintCo with a greater autonomy to develop new applications in-house and to proceed to changes of existing software. B2. Human IT Resources PaintCo users increased their technical skills on programming techniques and systems administration, through observation in daily, intense and informal contacts with ITSup consultants. Interestingly is that the supplier acquired greater capabilities in the use of its own software by providing training, simultaneously, to placement consultants and PaintCo users throughout the ERP project. Nowadays, some of those apprentices are key consultants of ITSup. As stated by one interviewee from the client side “ITSup won a lot more with our projects than we did, in terms of acquired knowledge.” From the several projects, ITSup was also able to increase their own capabilities in the best practices for the paint sector. Furthermore, both companies acquired new knowledge on project management practice
Managing IT Suppliers: A Capability-Based Approach
613
which was considered by the supplier as a major element of added value retrieved mainly from the ERP project. In fact, the frequent (but expected) conflicting situations that emerged from the high number of software adaptations and implementation delays along with PaintCo’s power position, can explain this statement. Both events pressured the supplier to develop and deepen new skills in project management in order to fulfil PaintCo’s expectations.
B3. Intangible Capabilities The several episodes of the relationship contributed to PaintCo’s access to intangible IT capabilities in the form of Bharadwaj’s concept of intellectual capital. Once again the informal relationships between PaintCo’s users and ITSup’s consultants brought out the conditions to build new knowledge in several areas: about PaintCo’s processes, about the chaining activities between departments and also about the IT that supported the development of those processes and activities as a whole, and not as atomistic processes and activities supported by independent IT systems. Taking advantage of synergies was also possible, after the infrastructure implementation. A group knowledge that exceeds the knowledge held by individuals and companies was generated, especially from the ERP episode, where a central database/server stored and unified all the information about customers, products and processes retrieved from all companies to be afterwards shared by the whole group. There were also some synergies resulting from that knowledge they promoted, and consequently a greater customer orientation in the sense of providing a better service. In sum, the analysis of the case provides valuable findings to address the purpose of our research. The next section elaborates on the key dimensions of a client–IT supplier relationship and on the opportunities to exchange IT capabilities.
6 Major Findings This case provides relevant insights about the features of a business relationship based on the transaction of IT-related products and services. One of the distinctive features of such a relationship is the critical role played by social exchanges as illustrated by the case of ITSup and PaintCo. In fact, our proposition that IT capabilities may be exchanged within interactions in a dyad should be rephrased in the sense that social exchanges are important keystones, if not the most important, to allow IT capabilities exchange to occur. The potential value of the suggested analytical framework and findings will be discussed in detail in the following sections.
614
6.1
C. Brito and M. Nogueira
About the Features of the Interaction Between Client and IT Supplier
The Interaction Approach proved to be highly stimulating as a tool to capture the fundamental dimensions of a client–IT supplier as demonstrated previously by other researchers as Kern and Willcocks (2002) or Leek et al. (2003). Firstly, about the actors, our findings revealed the importance of having in-depth knowledge about the parties in interaction to fully understand the evolution of the relationship as suggested by Ha˚kansson (1982) in the original model. Both parties in this study are large companies in terms of size and market positions but more importantly they are technology-oriented which provided the means to develop a technological partnership in the 1980s. A balance between IT skills and knowledge possession may have triggered the beginning of a 20 years relationship during which each company enhanced their IT resources to create new or improve existing IT capabilities. Secondly, about the short-term and long-term perspectives, our findings reinforce the view that a relationship between a client and a consultant is generally organised within time-framed consultancy projects, as suggested by Richter and Niewiem (2004). Following the IMP view we see consultancy projects as processes of continuous exchanges which can become institutionalized over time leading to expectations to further exchanges and to long-term relationships. Relationships that deal with complex IT implementation (such as an ERP or CRM system) are normally organised under a project umbrella where each project emerges and is managed based on previous experience with the supplier. This suggestion goes in line with Ha˚kansson’s et al. (1999) view according to whom in industrial contexts companies tend to get involved in new projects with suppliers who provided positive experiences in the past. Thirdly, about the types of exchanges, we also highlight as demonstrated elsewhere (Kern and Willcocks 2002) the importance of social exchanges to sustain the relationship. Citing Kern’s work in the past, Kern and Willcocks (2002, p. 14) claimed that “social exchanges are possible the most underrated and ignored dimension by researchers who have looked at the outsourcing relationships”. In their 2002 paper, the authors attempted to fill this gap by suggesting that social exchanges are a guarantee of the relationship ongoingness, especially in situations of disputes and conflicts. Our findings revealed similar conclusions but moreover highlighted a new role. As emphasized in the theoretical background section, relationships organised in consultancy projects tend to “suffer” from a discontinuity trend between projects (Cova and Salle 2000). Our analysis provided peremptory answers from interviewees about the importance of social exchanges to fill the temporal gap between projects and even to discuss new projects in between. Fourthly, about the forms of exchanges, it was clear the magnitude of adaptations and investments undertaken in PaintCo-ITSup case which led to further projects and further involvements between them. In complex IT-base projects these
Managing IT Suppliers: A Capability-Based Approach
615
adaptations were said to be highly influential in manipulate power-dependence positions held by the parties. Lastly, about the interaction atmosphere within a client–IT supplier relationship, we agree with previous research (Kern and Willcocks 2002; Karantinou and Hogg 2001) on the consideration of conflict, commitment, power and dependency as behavioural dimensions of the relationship. However our findings on the power and control positions support a reversed view of the traditional perspectives on IT outsourcing relationships. Kern and Willcocks (2002, p. 16) argued that “traditionally, clients expect that the supplier takes over and delivers the service while the client stands back and monitors”. They claimed this is a misperception, because 70% of clients’ time is spent in managing the relationship. We concur with this view but we further argue that instead of standing back, monitoring or managing the relationship, the client has the power to control the relationship, if holds a key position in the supplier’s customer portfolio.
6.2
About the Opportunities to Exchange IT Capabilities Within Interactions
We followed Bharadwaj (2000) taxonomy of IT capabilities to conduct our investigation. This scheme has proven to be advantageous in some respect. Although it was meant to analyse the relationship between IT capabilities and firms’ performance we found the division into IT tangible, human resources and intangible resources particularly useful to assist our research. Our findings suggested that the acquisition of IT tangible resources in the form of physical infrastructure and software for application development expanded the client’s IT capabilities. About the opportunities to exchange IT physical assets in order to create IT capabilities we obviously consider physical infrastructure and programming software as part of products exchanges within Ha˚kansson’s (1982) interaction model. However those tangible resources were combined with human resources skills to create a universal platform of information sharing and distribution, a valuable IT asset from the viewpoint of IT capabilities researchers (Bharadwaj 2000; Ross et al. 1996; Bharadwaj et al. 1999). The combination of IT physical infrastructure with technical skills from users and consultants enhanced the client’s opportunity to take advantage of synergies generation between several units. Mata et al. (1995) argued that IT physical assets are easily purchased and duplicated by competitors being unlikely to add value as a source of competitive advantage. We hold a different view and agree with Bharadwaj’s (2000, p. 172) belief that “such a reductionist view of technology, however, seeks to value the infrastructure solely in terms of its individual components, assumes the separability of the IT assets, and ignores the synergistic benefits of integrated systems”. We back up this view and argue that the combination of IT assets with IT technical skills, which in turn are accessed within interactions between users and consultants,
616
C. Brito and M. Nogueira
as illustrated by PaintCo-ITSup case especially in the Lotus Notes and ERP episodes, enable the client with opportunities to exploit synergies across business units. We have already mentioned that in ERP projects knowledge and skills are transferred in a bidirectional flow, from consultants to users and vice versa (Xu and Ma, 2008). Our case corroborated this view, but besides a mere transference of knowledge and skills we argue that is possible to observe a bidirectional flow of IT capabilities. Social exchanges, in the form of informal and intensive relationships between consultants and users, exert a powerful role of leveraging IT capabilities beyond the ones expected to achieve. This is a major finding of this research and led us to a second reflection about the opportunities to exchange IT technical and managerial skills. IT services concerning the physical assets implementation (infrastructure and software) were part of the contracts in different episodes. Consultants and users ought to possess a certain level of technical and managerial skills to implement ITs. In our case, we realized that what was exchanged within the consultancy projects exceeded the contracted product and service package. In one hand and remarkably during ERP episodes, the supplier managed to enhance greatly their human IT resources by training PaintCo’s users and ITSup apprentices simultaneously. Service and social exchanges within ERP episodes built a bridge for the supplier to grant technical and managerial skills to their apprentice consultants without additional costs. Furthermore, extended project management capabilities were also highlighted as a major achievement from the supplier. A curious aspect we derived from our analysis is related to the literature on client–consultant relationships where clients are said to seek for structural capital in their relationships with consultants (Willcocks et al., 2004), i.e., the expertise consultancy firms can offer in terms of best practices in the industry. Interestingly, our findings gave us the opposite direction. The supplier claimed vehemently that one of the major outcomes from the episodes with this specific client was the increase of their own capabilities in the best practices for the paint sector which gave them the proper skills to engage self-confidently in new projects in the paint sector. In addition, interviewees from the supplier side revealed high appreciation for consultants’ availability and patience. This type of social exchanges seems to be the key point to elucidate the process by which PaintCo absorbed technical skills on programming techniques which follows Graubner and Richter’s (2003) viewpoint that personal interaction is the major source of relevant knowledge exchange. From the last two discussion points we already highlighted the role social interactions may play in enhancing IT intangible capabilities. Hence, about the opportunities to exchange IT-enabled intangibles we conclude that IT assets combined with human IT resources encourages the creation of intellectual capital and synergies exploitation which led to a higher customer orientation by providing the tools and information needed to analyse their data, anticipate their needs and provide an active relationship management. This conclusion aligns with Bharadwaj’s (2000) contributions. Still, it is worthy to emphasize that informal relationships turned out to be a major feature of this case and brought out the conditions to exchange IT-enabled intangibles.
Managing IT Suppliers: A Capability-Based Approach
617
In sum, we support the viewpoint of the IT capabilities literature (e.g. Bharadwaj 2000; Mata et al. 1995; Rockart et al. 1996) that IT capabilities are created or enhanced by the combination of IT resources during day-to-day practice. However, we argue that this creation or enhancement may have the consultancy project as a promising starting point. Consultancy projects observe intense interaction between users and consultants and from this interaction IT capabilities are likely to emerge, to be afterwards refined and improved during daily usage. The perspective held by different fields of research such as the IMP approach (Mota and De Castro 2005; Ha˚kansson et al. 1999) and the capabilities approach (Foss 1999; Loasby 1994; 1998) that relationships work as mechanisms to coordinate resources and capabilities that a company does not possess, was illustrated by our case. We extend this vision by arguing that the interaction process is at the heart of such coordination, enhancing IT capabilities exchange and reducing uncertainty, by combining different types of expected exchanges (information, products, services and especially, social exchanges).
7 Conclusion This chapter has examined some of the key features of the interaction process within a client–IT supplier relationship whereby IT capabilities may be exchanged and enhanced. The achieved findings and conclusions will be useful, not only for the supply side, i.e., IT companies who wish to play an active role as IT capabilities promoters in their customers’ IT projects, but also for the demand side, especially for IT users and managers responsible for decision-making in IT procurement. Firstly, this chapter builds on earlier IMP research that examines the four exchanges types (products and/or services, information, financial and social exchanges) within interaction and has sought to complement this approach with a fifth one of paramount importance: the exchange of IT capabilities in a bidirectional flow mainly achievable within social exchanges. Our study provides strong evidences that throughout client–IT supplier relationships, IT resources from both parties are exchanged and combined enhancing their IT capabilities. This exchange goes beyond the expected (or contracted) exchange of IT physical infrastructure or consultancy services. Rather it also flourishes through the closeness and informality of social relationships between users and consultants. This bilateral access can be explained through the idiosyncrasy of client–consultant relationship featured by daily contacts, informal communication processes and intense knowledge and experience sharing. Secondly, in line with the previous argument we conclude that social exchanges, outlined from informal and close relationships between consultants and end-users, are important keystones, if not the most important, to allow IT capabilities exchange to occur. Using the Interaction Model as a valuable approach to investigate the dimensions of a client–IT supplier relationship, we claim that social
618
C. Brito and M. Nogueira
exchanges perform a crucial role in sustaining and strengthening the relationship inasmuch as they are a key driver to reduce uncertainty. Given that during consultancy projects, IT implementation is featured by frequent, but typical conflicts, close relationships based on mutual trust between consultants and users encourage cooperation and conflict resolution and tend to reduce uncertainty during IT projects. The PaintCo – ITSup case also exemplified how companies may expand or enhance their capabilities portfolio through social interaction with an IT supplier/consultant, whether they are involved or not in consultancy projects. It was highlighted that given the peculiarity of intermittent transactions, social exchange is imperative to fill in the discontinuity between IT projects. Therefore, we acknowledge that in high-technology products/services markets, and not only in the IT context, the frequency of buyer–supplier transactions is low since companies engage in this type of investments in a rather irregular basis. In this sense, during these discontinuity periods, social bonds between actors may be lost and the opportunity to enhance IT capabilities may fade away. It is vital to keep social contact and engage in activities (seminars, fairs, new product presentations) to reduce the formality of the relationship as was demonstrated by our case study. Fourthly, the chapter draws attention to the fact that managing a capabilities gap, between existent and necessary capabilities, is a problem faced by all companies whether they are searching for IT capabilities or other types of capabilities. In this sense, companies have to evaluate their options and take “make or buy” decisions to overcome this gap. They can manage the gap exogenously through access to third parties relying on IT suppliers or consultants or endogenously through internal development of the nonexistent capabilities. The exogenous route requires necessarily the construction and management of relationships with third parties. As demonstrated by our case the process to expand a firm’s IT capabilities within client–IT relationships is long, complex and painful, especially when a huge number of changes and adaptations arise. This is due to gaps between the buyer’s capability to choose the product/service they need and the supplier’s capability to meet their customers’ needs. This is particularly relevant in the IT market where customers not always know what to buy. In this case, companies may be keen to look for more players (for example external consultants or advisors) to minimize their capabilities gap. In our case, for example, attention was focused on a dyadic relationship but it was known that PaintCo normally takes advice from an external consultant to evaluate their decisions on IT procurement. The endogenous route, in turn, requires an internal organisation of in-house capabilities. Consultancy projects are long but not endless. IT managers and users, like someone who is learning how to drive, must be willing to practice, fail, retry and improve. Thus “learning by doing” processes are also a vehicle to boost the firm’s IT capabilities. Moreover, companies, who were engaged in consultancy projects in the past, may be willing to engage in new IT projects and expand their IT capabilities without external help. They may combine the technical and managerial skills obtained by learning from
Managing IT Suppliers: A Capability-Based Approach
619
previous projects with the new physical IT infrastructure and achieve new capabilities that were previously absent. In sum, we conclude that managers, IT users, consultants and IT suppliers may increase their understanding of how interactions may facilitate IT capabilities exchange across their buyer–supplier relationships and how social interactions, whether developed within, between or after consultancy projects, may arise as a promising starting point to create or enhance IT capabilities. In fact, we claim that social exchanges, in the form of informal and intensive relationships between people from both companies, exert a powerful role of leveraging IT capabilities beyond the ones expected to achieve which tends to reduce the perception of the relational uncertainty. In this sense, given the current state of the consultancy market where capabilities, commitment and even reputation are being cautiously tested by existing and potential clients, our findings may possibly help software houses and consultancy firms reflecting on the role they wish to play as IT suppliers – an active role as a skilful partner capable of enhancing their clients’ IT capabilities or a passive role as a mere IT implementer. IT buyers, in turn, may get the most of their relationships with IT suppliers by engaging their staff in proactive “learning by doing” practices towards the enhancement of IT capabilities, within or beyond consultancy projects.
Appendix. Relationship Episodes # 1
Period 1980–1990
2
1999
3
2000
4
5
Episode Engagement in a partnership to develop a solution suitable to the painting industry PaintCo purchases the Electronic E-mail solution from ITSup PaintCo purchases IT and services within a consultancy project to implement Workflow solutions
Main features Staff from customer’s IT department and staff from the IT supplier jointly developed and tested a software solution to be used in accounting and finance area The customer decides to substitute their Exchange e-Mail platform by ITSup’s Lotus Notes solution (Domino platform) From the previous episode where PaintCo starts to work with Domino platform, it was possible to develop several internal workflow solutions (price maintenance, colour maintenance, products in stock maintenance based on that technology) PaintCo demands the The supplier prepares a demonstration of the supplier for a CRM software after having several meetings demonstration of a CRM to better understand the context of painting solution suitable to their sector. The client ends up buying a solution sector from an ITSup competitor PaintCo demands the PaintCo decides to search for an ERP solution supplier for a capable of unifying the information systems demonstration of an of all the companies of the group. ITSUP is ERP solution suitable shortlisted as a potential supplier to their sector (continued)
620
# 6
C. Brito and M. Nogueira
Period 2001
7
8
9
2002
10
11
12 2003
13
Episode Main features ITSup is selected as ERP To pre-prepare the implementation of the ERP supplier which involved solution in Portugal and Spain, an intensive a first phase of needs period of meetings and discussion groups with evaluation among the ITSup, PaintCo and IBM as external adviser client’s departments were arranged to identify what issues should be addressed by the software Start-up: Implementation of Start-up of the project with an action plan divided ERP project starts in in 3 stages (1) implementation in financial PaintCo’s headquarters (FIN) area, simultaneously in Portugal and ERP Phase 1 Spain; (2) implementation of supply chain management (SCM) area in Portugal; (3) implementation of supply chain management (SCM) area in Spain In the process of implementing and training final ERP Phase 1: During the users, a number of non-conformities were first stage of FIN’s identified. PaintCo’s users demanded for implementation a adaptations in FIN software in order to fill number of adaptations to their needs. This involved the arrangement of software were identified numerous and frequent meetings to re-design and developed in order a new FIN prototype and a long period of to suit the painting software development to correct nonsector conformities ERP Phase 1: Real Start-up The FIN area “goes live” in January 2002, of finance area in simultaneously in Portugal and Spain. Period Portugal and Spain of high tension but without severe problems Key users from procurement, production, ERP Phase 2: logistics, distribution, procurement, sales and Implementation of ERP marketing are involved with consultants project continues with to design a SCM prototype the SCM area in PaintCo’s headquarters Again SCM area detected a huge amount of nonERP Phase 2: During the conformities to software in order to suit the implementation and painting sectors which led to a new phase only training of SCM final dedicated to discuss those adaptations and reusers, an outstanding design the prototype number of adaptations to software were identified Given the massive number of adaptations ERP Phase 2: Analysis of requested by SCM final users, a long period of requested adaptations, meetings and discussion groups with ITSup decision-making on and PaintCo were arranged to structure a costwhich adaptations analysis plan and identify what nonshould be developed conformities should be address and what adaptations should be developed Once again PaintCo expresses an interest in A new presentation of the supplier’s CRM ITSup’s CRM solution since the one implemented in 2000 was abandoned by software is demanded by PaintCo PAINTCO’s users. Since the relationship evolved in a close partnership in last 3 years, ITSup is selected as supplier of CRM solution and implementation (continued)
Managing IT Suppliers: A Capability-Based Approach
621
# Period 14 2004
15
16
17 18
Episode Main features CRM Phase I: As PaintCo is implementing ITSup’s ERP Implementation of CRM solution, the interfaces between ERP and project in PaintCo’s PaintCo’s solutions are totally compatible, headquarters and easily implemented ERP Phase 2: Real Start-up The SCM area “goes live” in Portugal in of SCM area in Portugal December 2004 after 2 years of needs evaluation, non-conformities corrections, and adaptations to software 2005 CRM Phase II: “CRM PaintCo realized that for a second time users were Dynamization Project” not using CRM tools. They decided to find out the reasons behind the non-adherence and motivate the use of CRM ITs. A new project was developed with the presence of an ITSup consultant working with end-users in a dailybasis during 2 months 2006 ERP Phase 2: Real Start-up The SCM area “goes live” in Spain during 2006 of SCM area in Spain 2006 Draft CRM Phase III: “CRM A new project is planned after the 2005 schedule mobility project” Dynamization project. PaintCo wants to grant their commercial staff with CRM tools in PDAs (personal digital assistant) CRM Phase I: The CRM area is planned to “go live” in Spain Implementation of CRM during 2006 project in Spain
References Axelsson B, Easton G (eds) (1992) Industrial networks: a new view of reality. Routledge, London Barney J (1991) Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. J Manage 17(1):99–120 Bharadwaj AS (2000) A resource-based perspective on information technology capability and firm performance: an empirical investigation. MIS Q 24(1):169–196 Bharadwaj AS, Sambamurthy V, Zmud RW (1999) IT capabilities: theoretical perspectives and empirical operationalization. In: Proceedings of the 20th International Conference on Information Systems. Association for Information Systems, Charlotte, NC, USA Chornoboy K, Gardner HW (1990) Client/consultant relations. ARMA Rec Manag Q 24(2):28 Clemons EK, Row MC (1991) Sustaining IT advantage: the role of structural differences. MIS Q 15(3):275–292 Cova B, Salle R (2000) Rituals in managing extra business relationships in international project marketing: a conceptual framework. Int Bus Rev 9(6):669–685 Dawes PL, Lee DY, Midgley D (2007) Organizational learning in high-technology purchase situations: the antecedents and consequences of the participation of external IT consultants. Ind Market Manage 36(3):285–299 Dubois A, Arau´jo L (2004) Research methods in industrial marketing studies. In: Ha˚kansson H, Harrison D, Waluszewski A (eds) Rethinking marketing. Developing a new understanding of markets. Wiley, Chichester, pp 207–228 Dubois A, Arau´jo L (2007) Case research in purchasing and supply management: opportunities and challenges. J Purch Supply Manage 13(3):170
622
C. Brito and M. Nogueira
Dubois A, Gadde LE (2002) Systematic combining: an abductive approach to case research. J Bus Res 55(7):553–560 Duhan S (2007) A capability based toolkit for strategic information systems planning in SMEs. Int J Inf Manage 27(5):352–367 Easton G (1998) Case research as a methodology for industrial networks: a realist apologia. In: Naude´ P, Turnbull P (eds) Network dynamics in International marketing. Pergamon, Oxford, pp 73–87 Feeny DF, Willcocks LP (1998) Core IS capabilities for exploiting information technology. Sloan Manage Rev 39(3):9–21 Flowers S (2007) Organizational capabilities and technology acquisition: why firms know less than they buy. Ind Corp Change 16(3):317–346 Ford D (1980) The development of buyer–seller relationships in industrial markets. Eur J Mark 14 (5/6):339–354 Ford D (ed) (2002) Understanding business marketing and purchasing, 3rd edn. Thomson Learning, London Ford D, Gadde LE, Ha˚kansson H, Lundgren A, Snehota I, Turnbull P, Wilson D (1998) Managing business relationships. Wiley, Chichester Ford D, Gadde LE, Ha˚kansson H, Snehota I (2003) Managing business relationships, 2nd edn. Wiley, Chichester Ford D, Johanson J, Ha˚kansson H (1986) How do companies interact? Ind Market Purch 1(1):25–41 Foss NJ (1999) Networks, capabilities and competitive advantage. Scand J Manage 15(1):1–15 Foss NJ, Loasby BJ (eds) (1998) Economic organization, capabilities and co-ordination. Essays in Honour of G. B. Richardson, Vol. 8. Routledge Studies in Business Organization and Networks. Routledge, London Foss NJ, Roberston PL (eds) (2000) Resources, technology and strategy. Explorations in the resource-based perspective. Routledge advances in management and business studies. Routledge, London Gonzalez R, Gasco J, Llopis J (2006) Information systems outsourcing: a literature analysis. Inf Manage 43(7):821–834 Goo J, Kishore R, Nam K, Rao HR, Song Y (2007) An investigation of factors that influence the duration of IT outsourcing relationships. Decis Support Syst 42(4):2107–2125 Graubner M, Richter A (2003) Managing tomorrow’s consulting firm. Consult Manage C2M 14 (3):43–50 Ha˚kansson H (ed) (1982) International marketing and purchasing of industrial goods: an interaction approach. Wiley, Chichester Ha˚kansson H (ed) (1987) Industrial technological development: a network approach. CroomHelm, London Ha˚kansson H, Ford D (2002) How should companies interact in business networks? J Bus Res 55(2):133–139 Ha˚kansson H, Havila V, Pedersen AC (1999) Learning in networks. Ind Market Manage 28 (5):443–452 Ha˚kansson H, Prenkert F (2004) Exploring the exchange concept in marketing. In: Ha˚kansson H, Harrison D, Waluszewski A (eds) Rethinking marketing, Developing a new understanding of markets. Wiley, Chichester, pp 75–94 Ha˚kansson H, Snehota I (1989) No business is an Island: the network concept of business strategy. Scand J Manage 4(3):187–200 Ha˚kansson H, Snehota I (eds) (1995) Developing relationships in business networks. Routledge, London Hurley M (2001) IT outsourcing: managing the key asset. Inf Manage Comput Secur 9(5):243–249 Karantinou KM, Hogg MK (2001) Exploring relationship management in professional services: a study of management consultancy. J Market Manage 17(3/4):263–286 Kern T, Willcocks L (2002) Exploring relationships in information technology outsourcing: the interaction approach. Eur J Inf Syst 11(1):3–19
Managing IT Suppliers: A Capability-Based Approach
623
Kishore R, Rao HR, Nam K, Rajagopalan S, Chaudhury A (2003) A relationship perspective on IT outsourcing. Commun ACM 46(12):86–92 Lacity MC, Willcocks LP, Feeny DF (1996) The value of selective IT sourcing. Sloan Manage Rev 37(3):13–25 Lai VS, Mahapatra RK (1997) Exploring there search in information technology implementation. Inf Manage 32(4):187–201 Larwood L, Gattiker UE (1986) Client and consultant management problem- solving values. Group Organ Stud 11(4):374–386 Leek S, Turnbull PW, Naude´ P (2003) How is information technology affecting business relationships? Results from a UK survey. Ind Mark Manage 32(2):119–126 Loasby BJ (1994) Organisational capabilities and interfirm relations. Metroeconomica 45(3):248–265 Loasby BJ (1998) The organisation of capabilities. J Econ Behav Organ 35(2):139–160 Lui KM, Chan KC (2008) Rescuing troubled software projects by team transformation: a case study with an ERP Project. IEEE Trans Eng Manage 55(1):171–184 Mata FJ, Fuerst WL, Barney JB (1995) Information technology and sustained competitive advantage: a resource-based analysis. MIS Q 19(4):487–505 Mike T (2003) What clients want in consultants. Des Manage J 14(3):10 Mota J, De Castro LM (2005) Relationship portfolios and capability development: cases from the moulds industry. J Purch Supply Manage 11(1):42–54 Mulligan P (2002) Specification of a capability-based IT classification framework. Inf Manage 39(8):647–658 Naude´ P, Turnbull PW, Leek S (2000) Is the interaction approach of any relevance in an IT/ e-commerce. In: Proceedings of the 16th Industrial Marketing and Purchasing Conference. Bath, UK Powell TC, Dent-Micallef A (1997) Information technology as competitive advantage: the role of human, business, and technology resources. Strateg Manage J 18(5):375–405 Richter A, Niewiem S (2004) The changing balance of power in the consulting market. Bus Strategy Rev 15(1):8–13 Rockart JF, Earl MJ, Ross JW (1996) Eight imperatives for the new IT organization. Sloan Manage Rev 38(1):43–55 Ross JW, Beath CM, Goodhue DL (1996) Develop long-term competitiveness through IT assets. Sloan Manage Rev 38(1):31–42 Shah Y (1990) Understanding client–consultant interaction. Cost Eng 32(6):15–22 Tippins MJ, Sohi RS (2003) IT competency and firm performance: is organizational learning a missing link? Strateg Manage J 24(8):745–761 Webster J (1995) Networks of collaboration or conflict? Electronic data interchange and power in the supply chain. J Strateg Inf Syst 4(1):31–42 Willcocks L, Hindle J, Feeny D, Lacity M (2004) IT and business process outsourcing: the knowledge potential. Inf Syst Manage 21(3):7–15 Xu Q, Ma Q (2008) Determinants of ERP implementation knowledge transfer. Inf Manage 45(8):528–539 Yongbeom K, Jeffrey H, Mel S (2006) An update on the IS/IT skills gap. J Inf Syst Educ 17(4):395–403
.
Methodology for Assessing Collaboration Strategies and Incentives in the Pulp and Paper Industry Nadia Lehoux, Sophie D’Amours, and Andre´ Langevin
Under current economic conditions, several companies have decided to implement collaborations with their suppliers, distributors, and retailers, in order to share products and information efficiently as well as reduce their operational costs. Even traditional industries such as the forest industry are now seeking for new business relationships to outperform the competition. In this article, we propose a case study of collaboration between a pulp and paper producer and a wholesaler. In particular, we describe a methodology used to compare different collaborative approaches. We show that this methodology is useful to take multiple operational parameters and constraints into account, as well as to update planning decisions over time. We also discuss the different results obtained for the case study. We demonstrate that collaborative approaches such as CPFR and VMI may reduce network costs, but the savings obtained with these strategies must be distributed fairly. Furthermore, we analyze the use of several incentives to increase the value and strength of the collaboration. Keywords Incentives • Inter-firm collaborations • Long-term relationships • Pulp and paper industry • Supply chain management
N. Lehoux • S. D’Amours FORAC, Department of mechanical engineering, Pavillon Adrien-Pouliot, Universite´ Laval, Que´bec, Canada, G1V 0A6, e-mail: [email protected]; [email protected] A. Langevin CIRRELT, Department of mathematics and industrial engineering, E´cole Polytechnique de Montre´al, C.P. 6079, succ. Centre-ville, Montre´al, Canada, H3C 3A, e-mail: [email protected] T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9_25, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
625
626
N. Lehoux et al.
1 Introduction In recent years, an increasing number of companies have decided to work together to better coordinate activities and respond promptly to customer demand. Through information and resources sharing and the use of logistics strategies, companies aim to decrease their production and distribution costs significantly as well as better deal with environmental, social, and economic issues. Even traditional industries are searching for new business models and relationships to outperform the competition and maximize the customer service level. The forest products industry is a good example. Some forest companies have started implementing collaborative approaches in order to gain access to appropriate wood fibre, better use transportation capacity, and reduce stock levels. In Canada, the forest products industry constitutes a major manufacturing sector, supporting more than 860,000 jobs, i.e. 5.3% of Canada’s total employment (Natural Resources Canada 2008–2009). Nevertheless, because of increased competition among countries, rising energy costs, and declining demand for paper, several mills have closed temporarily or permanently. Therefore, many companies have decided to change their way of doing business by trying to optimize forest resource utilization and their operations. In this paper, we will explore a case study of collaboration between a Canadian pulp and paper producer and its wholesaler. The pulp and paper supply chain involves many activities conducted by different companies in order to offer a large number of products such as newsprint, copy papers, several types of tissues, bottle labels, and so on. While some companies control all the activities from the forest to the final consumer (i.e., integrated pulp and paper operations), others work with subcontractors for specific operations. The pulp and paper production process also involves managing capacity and inventory efficiently, since starting the production of a new paper roll with specific characteristics is both time-consuming and costly. Demand is furthermore not generally known very far in advance of delivery time so a wide variety of paper sheet sizes and rolls must be stocked. The price for products may also change over time. So the objective of the study was to identify which collaboration strategies would ensure an efficient exchange of products and information between the pulp and paper producer and its partner as well as maximum benefits. However, because of business conditions, considering different collaborative approaches without considering many operational parameters and constraints was not possible. For this reason, we have developed a specific methodology to model this kind of relationship. More precisely, by selecting different collaboration strategies and incentives, developing planning models, and testing them using a rolling horizon of 2 weeks for a total planning period of 1 year, we have succeeded in identifying the best way for partners to collaborate. The results showed that letting the producer be responsible for managing the inventories of the wholesaler or sharing demand forecast and jointly developing a production and distribution plan can significantly decrease the costs of the network. On the other hand, the use
Methodology for Assessing Collaboration Strategies and Incentives
627
of an incentive was necessary to share fairly the benefits obtained from a coordination of network activities. The paper is structured as follows: we first describe the concepts of inter-firm collaborations through a literature review. Next, we introduce the case study as well as the methodology developed for assessing different collaboration strategies and incentives. The results obtained from the experiments are also explained in detail. Finally, a discussion and some concluding remarks are provided.
2 Literature Review Given that raw materials are typically bought from different suppliers, products are sold to multiple wholesalers, retailers and customers, and goods are moved from mills and warehouses to markets via transportation companies, the establishment and management of business relationships becomes a key success factor. Rather than sell or buy without any collaboration scheme, companies have to work together to better coordinate activities and respond promptly to customer demand (Arshinder and Deshmukh 2008).
2.1
Establishment and Management of Collaborations
Long-term relationships involve strong and trustful interactions between partners, which is why it is important to select the right partner. This partner needs to have a similar organization size, culture and philosophy, and it must pursue common goals and objectives, be ready to share benefits and risk, and use similar technologies and planning techniques (Liu et al., 2006). Each partner also has to contribute positively to the value of the collaboration (Ryu et al., 2009). Naesens et al. (2007) have developed an evaluation method for measuring the strategic compatibility between two potential partners, based on 58 key performance indicators found through in-depth interviews and a literature study. An inter-firm relationship also necessitates the establishment of a legal framework, specifying who has authority over what, which resources should be involved, etc. It is possible that a company leads the relationship, deciding for example how benefits should be divided between partners (Kilger et al., 2008). This greatly depends on the size of the companies involved in the collaboration as well as their contribution and organization philosophy. The leadership may also change over time or be exercised in different ways according to the evolution of the relationship (Stadtler 2009). Collaborations must then be managed carefully, be based on common rules, with inter-organization meetings and mechanisms to settle conflicts. In particular, partners need to be able to measure the performance of the relationship (Verdecho et al., 2009)
628
N. Lehoux et al.
so that they can continuously review the collaboration and eventually end the relationship if it becomes unprofitable. Gonzales (2001), Dyer et al. (2001), Pietras and Stormer (2001), Mejı´asSacaluga and Prado-Prado (2003), Barratt (2004), Lehoux and D’Amours (2004), and Liu et al. (2006) are some examples of works describing the stages for creating a viable relationship in greater detail.
2.2
Coordination of Activities
From the procurement of raw material to the delivery of the final product, many operations have to be performed and consequently, many planning decisions have to be made. Therefore, if partners do not share information and prefer to manage their activities separately, the quantity produced and the real needs of the network may not necessarily be the same. This may lead to higher stock levels or shortages, higher operational costs, poor quality of service, longer lead times, etc. (Lee et al., 1997). This is why it is crucial to deploy coordination mechanisms to ensure the synchronization of network activities and better satisfy customer demand (Arshinder and Deshmukh 2008). If partners are located close to each other, the coordination of the activities may be easier (Holweg et al., 2005). A stable demand can also facilitate the synchronization of operations. Thomas and Griffin (1996), Sarmah et al. (2006), Li and Wang (2007), Arshinder and Deshmukh (2008), Chan and Chan (2010), and Frayret (2009) have all proposed a literature review which explores the use of coordination mechanisms as a means to improve the performance of supply chains. In the following part of this section, we focus on the coordination mechanisms analyzed in the case study, namely collaboration strategies and incentives.
2.3
Collaboration Strategies
In recent years, many strategies have been developed to facilitate information sharing and synchronization of network activities. A first well-known strategy concerns the Make-to-Order (MTO) approach. This traditional technique does not need a high level of interaction between partners and is frequently used, particularly in the pulp and paper industry. In this operational environment, a manufacturing process is established to satisfy the demand only after an order has been placed. In this way, it is possible to reduce stock levels and offer customized products. Dell is a good example of a company that has succeeded by using this technique in order to let the customer select each component of its personal computer (Durand 2007). By dyeing its sweaters according to customer demand, Benetton has also obtained benefits such as reduction of its stock level (Ballou 2004). However, even though Make-to-Order involves a low implementation
Methodology for Assessing Collaboration Strategies and Incentives
629
cost without strategic information sharing, it is not appropriate for every type of product. Before choosing this logistics strategy, one should determine if the customer is ready to wait for its products or not, and take into consideration the production lead time, the inventory cost, the set-up cost, the impact of the method on the system design, etc. (Andel 2002). In addition, this method does not increase visibility nor create true collaborative relationships. ECR (Efficient Consumer Response) is another strategy implemented by the food industry in which each partner collaborates to deliver the right product to the right place with the best price to customers. The method is based specifically on four main concepts (Martel 2000): introduce products on the market efficiently following the principles of simultaneous engineering; optimize the merchandizing via a good assortment of products and a strategic use of shelf space; review and simplify the promotion process; and improve the replenishment process. Kurnia and Johnston (2001) have studied ECR through a case study. They have demonstrated that even if each actor can obtain the benefits of implementing ECR, some of them will have to bear more costs. This is why they recommend adopting a method to better share ECR benefits. The authors have also published an article on the same subject in collaboration with other authors. More specifically, Kurnia et al. (2006) have analyzed the Australian food industry and observed that many enterprises have difficulty implementing ECR with their partners since this approach involves inter-organizational relationships. They have suggested thirdparty logistics providers as stakeholders that could help enterprises implement ECR relationships. Some strategies have also been created that shift several responsibilities from one entity to another in order to improve the global effectiveness of the relationship. This is the case of VMI (Vendor Managed Inventory), an approach developed in the 80’s whereby the supplier is responsible for managing the inventories of its products for the customer (Barratt and Oliveira 2001). The supplier is responsible for taking care of the entire replenishment process, and is vested with the necessary authority. This method aims to efficiently use production and distribution capacities, increase visibility, improve the replenishment process, and decrease value chain costs (such as stock-out costs, distribution costs, etc.). Danese (2006) has reported the benefits gained by the pharmaceutical giant GlaxoSmithKline. By implementing VMI with eighteen distributors and suppliers, the company has optimized its capacity utilization, increased the service level, and reduced the stock of the network. De Toni and Zamolo (2005) have also demonstrated how the application of VMI to the household electrical appliances sector has resulted in more benefits than traditional replenishment systems. Dong et al. (2006) have analyzed the case of a clothing producer in China who established a VMI relationship with two of its retailers, while working with others based on a traditional method. The authors optimized the VMI replenishment policy and showed that if some deliveries are postponed or anticipated, the production capacity might be better equilibrated without really affecting the service level. Razmi et al. (2010) have compared VMI with a traditional system for a two-level supply chain. Using mathematical modelling, sensitivity analysis, and numerical examples, they
630
N. Lehoux et al.
showed that VMI generated greater benefits and lower costs than the traditional system. Nevertheless, with this kind of relationship, partners are sometimes afraid of losing control over their operations (Disney and Towill, 2003). When the information and communication system of each partner is very different, information sharing can also be complex (Danese, 2006). In addition, Yao et al. (2007) and Yu et al. (2009) have observed that putting VMI into practice may contribute to moving the stock from the buyer to the supplier. Therefore, the supplier inventory cost may increase, then requiring the use of an incentive to better share VMI benefits. Another strategy, called CR (Continuous Replenishment), is based on carrier or production capacity. Specifically, the replenishment is structured around a prescheduled reservation of capacity. For example, the collaboration may set a one truck per day delivery and the customer is then responsible for setting the mix of products to be on the truck every day (Audy et al. 2009). This approach satisfies the needs of the customer over time and reduces the pressure on the producer. The same approach applies with production capacity reservation (see for example Shen and Pang 2004 or Durango-Cohen and Yano 2006). CPFR (Collaborative Planning, Forecasting and Replenishment) is a collaboration strategy developed in recent years to improve the overall performance of supply chains (Voluntary Interindustry Commerce Solutions (VICS), 2004). With this technique, trading partners jointly plan key supply chain activities, from the production and delivery of raw materials to the production and delivery of final products to end customers. Collaboration encompasses business planning, sales forecasting, and all operations required to replenish raw materials and finished goods. The objective is to share information such as sales history, point-of-sale data, product availability, lead times, etc., to better synchronize activities and eliminate excess inventory. This technique is also useful to rapidly identify any changes in the forecasts or inventory, in order to correct problems before they negatively impact sales or profits. Steermann (2003) has described the case of Sears who put CPFR into practice with one of its main suppliers, Michelin. CPFR was implemented for eighty products, resulting in a decrease of the stock level and a more efficient introduction of new products on the market. Chung and Leung (2005) have also described a CPFR relationship between a producer and its main supplier that contributed to reducing stock-outs and the response time of the two companies. Cederlund et al. (2007) reported a reduction of 50% of transportation costs and 30% of inventory holding costs at Motorola. Du et al. (2009) have shown how the CPFR approach could be adapted for agricultural products, by developing a model that took the biological nature of raw material and the characteristics of perishable products into account. Some other CPFR implementation cases have been enumerated by Min and Yu (2008). This technique seems very beneficial for network members, but its implementation can be very expensive and timeconsuming (Cederlund et al. 2007). CPFR also involves building trustful relationships since strategic information has to be shared (Fliedner 2003). To facilitate communication, this information must be based on a standard (Bocheng et al. 2006).
Methodology for Assessing Collaboration Strategies and Incentives
2.3.1
631
Incentives
Long-term collaborations have to be based on mutual benefits. Unfortunately, partners do not always act in ways that maximize network profit (Narayanan and Raman 2004). Furthermore, in some situations, the level of benefits achieved by each entity may differ, which is why it is useful to implement incentives that will encourage partners to collaborate and ensure benefits sharing. In a review proposed by Cachon (2003), five types of incentive have been explored: wholesale price, buyback contract, revenue sharing, quantity flexibility contract, and quantity discount. One frequently used incentive considers the price charged by the supplier to the customer. This is referred to as wholesale price. For example, a lower price can be offered before a high demand period (e.g., the sale season), and a higher price offered during the high demand period to properly use production capacity and share inventory costs (Cachon 2004). If adequately defined, this incentive can play an important role in the coordination of the network depending on conditions (demand pattern, product life cycle, price volatility, etc.) (Weng 1997). The second incentive is associated to the use of a buyback policy. The retailer (or merchant, or customer, etc.) can return some or all unsold items for compensation. The supplier recovers the salvage value of the returned items at a given rate per unit. In this way, the retailer is encouraged to order the optimal quantity for the network. This incentive is generally useful to better coordinate partners’ decisions (Paul and Bose 2004). Burer et al. (2008) have explored the case of a seed supplier who offered its products to different retailers. They demonstrated that the use of this strategy, combined with the use of bonus and penalties, can coordinate the system, even under demand uncertainty. A third incentive is based on revenue sharing. The retailer shares the revenue generated from sales with the supplier in return for a lower supplier price. In this way, the decisions of each partner can be coordinated and benefits distributed fairly. This incentive is helpful particularly when the demand for products is not price sensitive (Wang et al. 2004, Cachon and Lariviere 2005). Such incentives have become more prevalent in the DVD/Blu-ray rental industry than the more conventional wholesale price contracts (Cachon 2004). A fourth incentive is named the quantity flexibility contract. Under such contracts, the retailer has to commit to a minimum order, but this can be adjusted as more accurate information on the demand becomes available. This incentive may contribute to better synchronizing network activities only for certain contexts, such as under a forced compliance regime (Tsay 1999). The fifth incentive refers to quantity discounts. With this incentive, reductions in unit prices are offered to encourage buyers to order the best quantity for the network. Weng (2004) has demonstrated that the benefits of using this incentive increase with higher transportation costs, ordering costs, and setup costs. Other incentives have also been studied, such as the sharing of economies (Corbett and Decroix 2001, Corbett et al. 2005) or the guarantee of a certain profit
632
N. Lehoux et al.
margin (Urban 2007). They all have the same objective, which is to: coordinate stakeholder decisions, maximize network profit, and provide win-win options to the collaborating companies.
2.3.2
Collaboration in the Forest Products Industry
It is only recently that the potential of collaborations for the forest products industry has been evaluated and fibre allocation has been one of the first aspects to be studied. In Canada, many companies obtain their fibre from forests owned by the state. Therefore, they often need to agree on a common plan describing how trees will be harvested. Beaudoin (2008) has addressed this problem, proposing collaborative approaches to aid the negotiation process. The benefits of collaboration have also been explored for the transportation of logs to mills. Since companies frequently operate in different parts of the country, the idea is to optimize the transportation activities to ensure that a truck that has carried one load between two points carries another load on its return trip. This is called backhauling. This opportunity has been examined in different parts of the world. Frisk et al. (2006) (Sweden), Palander and Vaatainen (2005) (Finland), and Audy et al. (2007) (Canada) have worked on different aspects of this problem. Finally, supply chain management models are being used more and more often to better coordinate network activities and increase value added for the final customer. Haartveit et al. (2004) have proposed two supply chain mapping methods: one focusing on the supply chain structure and relationships among stakeholders, and the other on lead times. They then have used these methods to map the supply chains of three Western Canada companies from the solid wood sector. Chambost et al. (2009) have explored the creation of partnerships for implementing the forest biorefinery successfully.
2.3.3
Motivations for Collaborations in the Pulp and Paper Industry
The pulp and paper industry involves many business units: various entrepreneurs who convert trees into logs, multiple sawmills that produce wood chips and boards, several wholesalers that sell paper products to customers, and so on (D’Amours et al. 2008). Therefore, many planning decisions related to procurement, production, distribution, and sales activities are distributed among many independent business units. Nevertheless, supply chain members typically work together using a push system. Therefore, little information on customer demand or on inventory levels is shared; many products are kept in stock; and for some products, the transportation capacity is not used efficiently. Moreover, while some stakeholders want to optimize material yield and operational costs, others aim to reduce logistical costs and to improve service levels. Therefore, inter-firm collaborations can be an effective way to improve the coordination of planning decisions and tend towards a common goal.
Methodology for Assessing Collaboration Strategies and Incentives
633
In the following section, we describe a case study of collaboration between a pulp and paper producer and its wholesaler. Among the different collaboration strategies discussed in the literature review, we only consider MTO, CR, VMI and CPFR as potential approaches to implement between the two actors. These four strategies were chosen in order to analyze different interaction levels that could be put into practice by the pulp and paper industry. Furthermore, we have also selected three different incentives that could be easily adapted for a multi-period context and that might contribute to a better use of production and distribution capacities: two types of revenue sharing and quantity discounts.
3 The Case Study We now describe a case study of inter-firm collaboration conducted with a Canadian pulp and paper company from 2006 to 2008.
3.1
The Context
With around 1 million hectares of wood harvested every year (Natural Resources Canada, 2008–2009), the forest products industry is one of Canada’s leading manufacturing sectors. Moreover, Canada is the world’s largest exporter of forest products and the world’s leading producer and exporter of newsprint. Its products are exported to more than 100 different countries. Nevertheless, the forest industry is changing and new business models are being put into practice to better use the wood fibre and create value for customers. Our case study is a good example. The pulp and paper producer, after analyzing its processes and its value chain, decided to establish a partnership with its key wholesaler to reduce costs and improve service level.
3.2
The Partners
The pulp and paper producer is one of the main paper suppliers in Canada, with ten pulp and paper mills in operation, eight in the United States, and two in Canada. It manufactures and sells pulp, paper, and lumbers, and controls the major part of the activities from wood harvesting to delivery of the final products. The wholesaler has two warehouses in the province of Quebec and offers more than 2,000 different products to its Canadian and American customers. The wholesaler orders products from the producer or from another supply source, keeps them in stock, and then sells them to the final customer without converting the products. The producer fixes
634
N. Lehoux et al.
Other supply source
Wholesaler
Final customer
The forest
Producer
Other customers
Fig. 1 The case study
the price to offer to the wholesaler and to other customers, and the wholesaler defines the quantity to order from the pulp and paper producer (Fig. 1).
3.3
The Problem
At the time of the study, the production process was characterized by a limited capacity, so the producer had to plan operations carefully to satisfy the demand of the partner and the demand of all the other customers. However, even though the partners wanted to create a real partnership with mutual benefits, they made planning decisions based on their own costs and constraints rather than on the global costs and constraints of the network. The producer planned operations in order to minimize production, distribution and inventory costs, while the wholesaler ordered products so as to minimize its buying, ordering and inventory costs. Thus the objective of the study was to identify the best collaboration strategy to implement to improve the decision-making process and to increase the profits of both the producer and the wholesaler.
3.3.1
Business Conditions
Consumers ask for a wide variety of paper rolls and sheet sizes, and all these products need to be manufactured on the same paper machine. Demand is typically not known far in advance of delivery time and inventory costs are significant. In addition, because the environment is dynamic, the price for products may change and planning decisions must be reviewed over time. Consequently, in order to take all these operational parameters and constraints into account, we developed a specific methodology that allowed us to compare several collaboration strategies, consider demand uncertainty, and update planning decisions based on more recent information.
Methodology for Assessing Collaboration Strategies and Incentives
635
4 The Methodology Each stage of the methodology will be described in this section. This methodology involves: the selection of collaborative strategies; the development of mathematical models; data collection and experimental design; and experiments and feedback. The concepts are summarized in the figure below (Fig. 2). Selection of Collaborative Approaches. We first identified different collaboration strategies that could be implemented by the pulp and paper industry. The first selected was Make-to-Order since it is frequently used by pulp and paper companies, and does not necessitate a high interaction level. With this method, the producer manufactures the paper products after receiving the order from the wholesaler and then delivers these products. As a result, the producer does not know the demand of the final consumer and plans the production based on different wholesaler orders. The second approach chosen was based on CR, a technique generally useful to reduce stock levels. With this approach, deliveries are made regularly based on an order plan defined and updated by the wholesaler. This order plan, covering several days, is sent to the producer in advance, so the information can be integrated into the production planning. The third strategy selected was VMI. The pulp and paper producer becomes responsible for maintaining the partner’s inventory levels and has to make sure that the inventory is sufficient so that the wholesaler is always able to satisfy its own demand. We assume that demand of the final consumer is again unknown, thus the production planning is based on historical data and the stock consumption made by the partner. The last approach selected was CPFR, a strategy requiring real cooperation between partners. With this method, partners have to jointly estimate the demand and then use the forecast in their planning as well as make planning decisions based on each of the partner’s constraints and aim to maximize network profit. Therefore, by choosing four collaboration strategies with different information sharing needs and interaction levels, we were able to explore several possibilities and measure their effect on the profit of the partners.
Selection of collaborative approaches
Development of mathematical models
Data collection and experimental design
Evolution of the business environment
Fig. 2 Methodology summary
Experiments and feedback
636
N. Lehoux et al.
Development of Mathematical Models. After selecting four potential collaborative approaches, we developed decision models from the point of view of each partner in order to illustrate all their planning decisions. More precisely, we first identified the costs, revenues and constraints involved in using each collaborative approach, since the establishment of a specific relationship will directly affect the way goods and information are exchanged between partners. For example, MTO involves: • • • • • •
An ordering cost (wholesaler) Two buying prices (one from the producer and one from the other supply source) A production cost (including setup cost) Inventory holding costs (producer and wholesaler) Lead times A delivery cost (producer)
With CR, the wholesaler does not have to take the producer lead times into account, since the producer knows the order ahead of time and has to deliver it at the right moment. With the VMI approach, the wholesaler does not have to support ordering and inventory holding costs for the producer’s products. On the other hand, the producer has to take into consideration inventory holding costs for its products at the wholesaler site and to keep inventory between a minimum and a maximum level. With CPFR, we assumed that the wholesaler never uses the other supply source, so a specific buying price becomes unnecessary because it represents revenue for one and a cost for the other. Using mixed-integer linear programming, we then integrated these costs and constraints into mathematical models (all the mathematical models are explained in detail in Lehoux et al. 2009a). The objective of the models was to maximize profit, subject to a certain number of constraints. The quantity of products to manufacture, deliver and stock (producer), as well as the quantity of products to order (wholesaler), are examples of the decision variables evaluated. Seven mathematical models have been developed, two for each approach (one for the producer, one for the wholesaler), except for CPFR which has been modelled using a unique planning model. For example, if we look at the VMI models, the following mathematical notation was used: Set Description T IP Suci FP FPF FPS M
The length of the planning period The set of intermediate products The set of finished products that can be obtained from the intermediate products The set of finiXshed products (FPF [ FPS) The set of finished products proposed by the producer The set of finished products proposed by the other supply source The set of machines that manufacture intermediate products
Methodology for Assessing Collaboration Strategies and Incentives
637
Parameter Description t i cf amit ld lds ri tsetmi dit dccit stccit c mt capt cmit hit hcit ctru cord pSSit pit pcit g s S
A planning period A intermediate or finished product Conversion factor indicating number of units of intermediate products to produce Production capacity consumption rate of intermediate products at machine m at period t Transportation lead time of the producer Transportation lead time of the other supply source Transportation resource absorption rate for finished products Setup time to manufacture intermediate products on the machine m at the beginning of period t Demand for finished products ordered by the other clients at period t Demand for finished products ordered by the final consumer at period t Consumption forecast for the producer’s finished products used by the wholesaler at period t Production capacity of machine m at period t Transportation capacity of a truck at period t Production cost of the intermediate product on the machine m at period t Inventory holding cost of the finished products at the mill at period t Inventory holding cost of the finished products at the wholesaler site at period t Transportation cost of finished products delivered to the wholesaler at period t Ordering cost of the wholesaler Price for finished products proposed by the other supply source at period t Price for finished products proposed by the producer at period t Price for finished products proposed by the wholesaler to the final consumer at period t A large number Minimum inventory level at the wholesaler site Maximum inventory level at the wholesaler site
Variable Description pmit rmit Qit Qmit Dcit Rit
Binary variable equal to 1 if the product is manufactured on the machine m at period t, 0 otherwise Binary variable equal to 1 if a setup for the product is made on the machine m at period t, 0 otherwise Quantity of finished products manufactured at period t Quantity of intermediate products manufactured on the machine m at period t Quantity of finished products bought from the producer at period t Quantity of finished products shipped by the producer at period t
638
N. Lehoux et al.
RCit QSSit RSSit Iit IFcit ISScit Ntrut dSSt
Quantity of producer’s finished products received by the wholesaler at period t Quantity of finished products bought from the other supply source at period t Quantity of finished products received by the wholesaler from the other supply source at period t End of period inventory level of finished products at the mill at period t End of period inventory level of producer’s finished products at the wholesaler site at period t End of period inventory level of finished products bought from the other supply source at period t Number of trucks needed at period t Binary variable equal to 1 if the wholesaler orders other supply source’s products at period t, 0 otherwise
For the wholesaler, the planning model based on the VMI approach is formulated as follows: XX X XX XX ditcc pcit RCit pit corddSSt QSSit pSSit Max t2T i2FP
XX
t2T i2FPF
t2T
t2T i2FPS
hcit ISScit
t2T i2FPS
subject to
(1) RSSit þ ISScit1 ISScit ¼ ditcc
8i 2 FP 2 = FPF;
RCit þ RSSit þ IFcit1 þ ISScit1 IFcit ISScit ¼ ditcc 8t 2 T IFcit RCit þ IFcit1 ISScit RSSit þ ISScit1 QSSit ¼ RSSiðtþldsÞ QSSit gdSSt QSSit gdSSt
8i 2 FPF; 8i 2 FPS;
8i 2 FPF \ FPS; 8t 2 T
(2) (3) (4)
8t 2 T
(5)
8i 2 FPS;
8t 2 T
(6)
8i 2 FP 2 = FPF;
8t 2 T
(7)
8i 2 FPF \ FPS;
8t 2 T
QSSit 0; RCit 0; RSSit 0; IFcit 0; ISScit 0; 8i 2 FPS;
8t 2 T
8t 2 T dSSt 2 f0; 1g
8t 2 T
(8) 8i 2 FPF;
(9) (10)
Methodology for Assessing Collaboration Strategies and Incentives
639
The objective function (1) tries to maximize the total profit of the wholesaler. Constraints (2) and (3) ensure that the quantity ordered and kept in stock is sufficient to satisfy the demand of the final consumer. Constraints (4) and (5) distinguish stock origin, specifically products delivered by the producer and products delivered by the other supply source. If the wholesaler purchases from the other supply source, a transportation lead time is necessary (6). Finally, constraints (7) and (8) ensure an ordering cost if the wholesaler orders products from the other supply source. For the producer, the formulation of the planning model based on VMI is: Max
XX
stccit pit
t2T i2FPF
XX
þ
XX
dit pit
" " X X X
t2T i2FPF
hcit IFcit ctru
t2T i2FPF
X
t2T
m2M
#
X
þ
m cm it Qit
i2IP
# hit Iit
i2FPF
Ntrut
t2T
(11) subject to X X Qm Qjt =cf ¼ 0 it m
8i 2 IP;
8t 2 T
(12)
Suci
X
pm it 1
8m 2 M;
8t 2 T
8m 2 M;
8i 2 IP;
8t 2 Tnf1g
(14)
8m 2 M;
8i 2 IP;
8t 2 Tnf1g
(15)
8t 2 T [ f0g
(16)
(13)
IP m m pm it pit1 þ rit m pm it1 þ rit 1
Qit þ Iiðt1Þ Iit Rit ¼ dit m m m m m am it Qit þ rit tseti ct pit
X
8i 2 FPF; 8m 2 M;
8i 2 IP;
ri Rit capt Ntrut
8t 2 T
8t 2 T
(17) (18)
i2FPF
RiðtldÞ þ IFcit1 IFcit ¼ stccit s IFcit S Qm it 0
8i 2 FPF;
8i 2 FPF;
8m 2 M;
m pm it ; rit 2 f0; 1g
8m 2 M;
8t 2 T
8i 2 IP;
Qit 0; Iit 0; Ntrut 0; Rit 0
8t 2 T [ f0g
(20)
8t 2 T
8i 2 FPF; 8i 2 IP;
(19)
(21) 8t 2 T
8t 2 T
(22) (23)
640
N. Lehoux et al.
The objective function (11) maximizes the total profit of the producer (sales revenue minus the total cost of the producer) and includes inventory holding cost for the products stocked at the wholesaler site. Constraints (12) are used to evaluate the number of intermediate products needed to manufacture finished products. Constraints (13) ensure that only one intermediate product is manufactured per period. Note that those constraints are imposed by the pulp and paper industry context. Constraints (14) and (15) make sure that a setup is made for each product change. Constraints (16) ensure that the quantity produced and kept in stock is sufficient to satisfy the demand of the partner and the demand of other clients. Constraints (17) and (18) indicate the production and transportation capacity to respect. Finally, constraints (19) ensure the flow conservation at the wholesaler site and constraints (20) are used to keep wholesaler inventory levels between a minimum (s) and a maximum (S) value. Data Collection and Experimental Design To compare each collaboration strategy and measure its profitability, many data were necessary. Therefore, we spent several months collecting this information from the pulp and paper producer, asking the people involved questions to better understand the relationship. The demand for 20 finished products was collected, as well as the different set-up times (for each type of paper), production costs, inventory costs, and so on. The only information that the producer was not ready to share was its price list, so we had to estimate prices based on our knowledge and previous studies. To develop the experimental design, we first inserted data into an Excel database. We grouped products into four families, each family corresponding to one intermediate paper roll (i.e. jumbo roll) with specific characteristics. We also used a rolling horizon of 2 weeks to update decisions for each t ¼ 1, 2, 3. . . n days over the planning horizon. With this rolling horizon, the demand was known for the first week and estimated for the second week (2% error on the forecast) (Fig. 3). The exponential smoothing method was used to forecast the demand in order to use the same technique as the pulp and paper producer. We then used Cplex to solve the models. Depending on which collaborative approach was analyzed, the wholesaler model or the producer model was tested first. Specifically, with MTO and CR approaches, the wholesaler model was first solved to determine the optimal quantity to order, based on the demand to satisfy, ... Planning decisions
Planning decisions updated
t=1
D1, D2, ... D7 known D8, D9, ... D14 estimated
t=2
D2, D3, ... D8 known D9, D10, ... D15 estimated
Fig. 3 Rolling horizon for experiments
Planning decisions updated
...
t=n
Planning horizon
Dn, Dn+1, ... Dn+6 known Dn+7, Dn+9, ... Dn+14 estimated
Methodology for Assessing Collaboration Strategies and Incentives
641
the inventory level and the deliveries planned. Next, the producer model was solved, based on the wholesaler order, the demand of other customers, and the stock level (Fig. 4). With VMI, the producer model was first solved to determine the optimal quantity to produce as well as the quantity to deliver to the wholesaler site, taking into account the demand to satisfy, the stock consumption of the wholesaler, and the inventory level. Next, based on the quantity delivered by the producer, the wholesaler model was solved (Fig. 5). Producer model solved Wholesaler order Inventory level Demand of other customers Wholesaler model solved Demand of final customers Inventory level Deliveries planned t=1
Producer model solved Wholesaler order Inventory level updated Demand of other customers updated Wholesaler model solved Demand of final customers updated Inventory level updated Deliveries planned updated t=t+1
Planning horizon
Fig. 4 Method to solve MTO and CR models
Wholesaler model solved Quantity delivered Demand of final consumers Inventory level Deliveries planned
Producer model solved Demand of other customers Wholesaler stock consumption Inventory level
t=1
Fig. 5 Method to solve VMI models
Wholesaler Wholesaler model model solved solved Quantity delivered Demand of final customers updated Inventory level updated Deliveries planned updated
Producer model solved Demand of other customers updated Wholesaler stock consumption updated Inventory level updated
t=t+1
Planning horizon
642
N. Lehoux et al.
Producer + Wholesaler model solved Demand of final customers Demand of other customers Inventory levels Deliveries planned
t=1
Producer + Wholesaler model solved Demand of final customers updated Demand of other customers updated Inventory levels updated Deliveries planned updated
t=t+1
Planning horizon
Fig. 6 Method to solve the CPFR model
CPFR combines the producer and the wholesaler models so all the decisions were made simultaneously (Fig. 6). Experiments and Feedback Using the experimental design described above, each model was solved for a total planning period of 1 year. We assumed that the producer and the other supply source offered the same products. We also assumed a production and transportation lead times of one period. The producer could manufacture paper products on two paper machines (with different capacities), the bottleneck stage of the production process. After each experiment, the results were analyzed to find a collaborative approach profitable for everyone. The profit of each partner and the profit of the network (profit of the producer + profit of the wholesaler) were used to compare each model (the results are discussed in detail in Lehoux et al. 2009a).
5 Results and Analysis For our case study, we compared each collaborative approach using first the network profit, and then the individual profit of each partner.
5.1
Network Profit
The results showed that CPFR generated the greatest total system profit through optimization of both transportation and inventory costs. CPFR inventory costs were reduced by as much as 44% compared to other approaches, while CPFR transportation costs were reduced by as much as 18%. VMI was second best, with reductions in transportation costs. CR and the traditional system yielded the lowest total system profit. So these first experiments demonstrated that if partners were
Methodology for Assessing Collaboration Strategies and Incentives
643
ready to change their way of doing business, the performance of the network could be improved. Such results were found for a specific set of parameters. However, the business environment may probably change over time, in terms of demand, prices, costs, etc. And this evolution will certainly have an effect on the profit of each partner as well as on the choice of the collaboration model to implement. This is why we analyzed the effect of changing different parameters on the system. We observed that a higher demand might contribute to reducing the transportation cost for MTO and CR, because the transportation capacity was better used. However, this change had no effects on CPFR or VMI results. We also observed that a longer lead time contributed to decreasing the network profit, especially for CPFR and VMI. Specifically, with the VMI or the CPFR method, the producer could choose to stock more products in order to better use transportation capacity and decrease the delivery cost. However, with a longer lead time, the producer had less flexibility to correctly plan the production and optimize costs. Therefore, benefits were less significant. So for our case study, even though a specific collaboration strategy is the most profitable at a certain moment, this may change over time. Therefore, partners need to pay attention to the evolution of their environment and make adjustments in order to keep the relationship profitable. The use of a rolling horizon is a good way to test the effect of those changes.
5.2
Individual Profit
After comparing each approach using the network profit, the investigation pursued evaluating the profit of each partner. The objective was to verify if the same approach could generate the greatest profit for both the producer and the wholesaler. The analysis revealed that CPFR generated the greatest profit for the producer, while CR was the most profitable for the wholesaler. In fact, with the CPFR method, the wholesaler had to keep more stock to better use production and transportation capacities. Consequently, the wholesaler inventory cost increased considerably. However, with a CR system, the wholesaler could order products depending on its needs to minimize its own inventory cost. On the other hand, if the collaboration was based on CR, the producer did not know the demand of the final consumer or the inventory level of the wholesaler, so it could not synchronize operations adequately. Therefore, none of the approaches was the most profitable for both partners. For this reason, we analyzed if the use of CPFR, combined with an incentive, could create a win-win relationship. The incentive selected was based on the sharing of the CPFR transportation savings. Specifically, since CPFR contributed to reduce the number of trucks required for delivering the products and,
644
N. Lehoux et al.
consequently, the transportation cost, we decided to verify if sharing this saving among the two partners at the end of the year could ensure a fair distribution of benefits. We observed that with a sharing of 10% of the transportation savings, the profit of the wholesaler was higher than the one obtained with CR, and the producer obtained a higher profit than the one generated by the other approaches (MTO, VMI, and CR). Thus the use of the CPFR approach, combined with the share of a part of the transportation savings, contributed to better synchronizing network activities and to distributing collaboration benefits fairly. Furthermore, in case of high demand uncertainty, CPFR could be a good way for improving forecast accuracy and sharing risk. However, since these results were again found for a specific set of parameters, a dynamic environment may necessitate a modification of the incentive. For example, in our case study, a higher demand involved a better use of the transportation capacity and, consequently, a higher CR profit. Therefore, in these conditions, the value of the savings shared should be higher than 10%, otherwise, there would be no advantage for the wholesaler to remain in a CPFR relationship.
5.3
CPFR or Not CPFR?
Even though some companies decide to adopt CPFR with their partners, others do not want to implement this form of collaboration. In fact, this approach can be very costly in terms of implementation cost, management cost, information systems, and so on. This technique is also based on a high level of information sharing, while companies are typically not ready to share their knowledge (Fawcett et al., 2007). This is why we have explored the use of incentives as a means to encourage partners to make planning decisions that are good for the entire network. In particular, we tested three different incentives: a bonus if orders are optimized with regard to shipments; the sharing of transportation savings if the transportation capacity is well used; and a quantity discount if the wholesaler orders more than usual. We then applied these incentives to the models based on MTO (the model with the lowest level of interaction) to verify whether their use could improve the profit of the network or not. With the first incentive, the wholesaler was encouraged to order less frequently, but with larger orders, to better use transportation capacity and in return, the producer gave a bonus for small orders that were avoided. With the second incentive, the wholesaler had to order enough products to efficiently use the transportation capacity (% truckload) and in return, the producer shared a part of the savings (% of the transportation savings). With the third incentive, the producer gave a discount on additional units if the quantity ordered was higher than a certain value. Mathematical models were modified so as to take these new parameters and constraints into account.
Methodology for Assessing Collaboration Strategies and Incentives
645
The results showed that these incentives could considerably improve the profit of both the producer and the wholesaler without requiring a high level of information sharing if they were defined correctly (the results are discussed in detail in Lehoux et al., 2009b). So for our case study, if partners do not want to completely change their way of doing business, the use of some incentives, combined with a MTO mode, may be a good strategy to obtain higher profits without large investments. However, a major change in the business environment may certainly have an effect on the value of the incentive implemented. For example, we observed that an increase of buying prices necessitated a higher value of savings shared between the two partners. Otherwise, the incentive was not profitable for the wholesaler.
5.4
Summary of the Methodology
In order to compare different collaborative approaches between a pulp and paper producer and its wholesaler and measure their profitability, a methodology has been developed: selection of collaborative strategies; development of mathematical models; data collection and experimental design; and experiments with feedback. With this methodology, it was possible to analyze a complex system, to take multiple operational parameters and constraints into account, and to integrate some uncertainty conditions into the analysis. The use of a rolling horizon was also a good way to integrate past decisions into the actual decision-making process. Since the business environment is typically dynamic with multiple changes over time, it will have an effect on the planning decisions made by each partner. Therefore, this kind of methodology becomes useful to test these environments and their effect on the collaboration benefits. It can also be used to determine which collaboration models should be implemented for which business conditions.
5.5
Discussion
At the beginning of the study, the pulp and paper producer and its wholesaler had already initiated the establishment of the relationship: the objectives were defined; the partner selected; and different resources were involved. So our role was rather to analyze how the partners worked together and how they could change their way of doing business to improve the collaboration performance. However, by working with the two partners, we observed that implementing an inter-firm collaboration can be very complicated. First, trust seemed the key to establish a long-term relationship. This is why the two partners held many interorganization meetings to get to know each other better and understand their respective ways of doing business. Communication between partners as well as through the organization was also very useful to explain to everyone the collaboration development, the policies implemented, the results obtained, and so on. When
646
N. Lehoux et al.
we started to study VMI as a potential collaboration strategy to implement, the wholesaler became very anxious. In particular, the wholesaler was afraid of losing control over its operations and was not necessarily ready to shift certain responsibilities to the producer, thinking that its place could be taken by the producer. Other difficulties not always discussed in the literature were observed. For example, partners were not able to evaluate the fixed costs associated with the implementation of a specific collaborative approach. This cost seemed complex to define and to anticipate, even though it represented risk for partners. Partners also had difficulty evaluating the potential “life span” of the relationship. In past experiences with other wholesalers, the producer observed that collaborations fail for many reasons: lack of trust; management complexity; lack of financial incentives; and so on. So the producer was not able to anticipate whether the collaborative relationship would be a success or not, as well as the key elements to establish to ensure a long-term partnership. Another problem concerned the shift of responsibilities within the organization. Depending on the collaborative strategy implemented, some changes will have to be made within the organization, involving the shift of responsibilities from one department to another. And these changes may not be easy to put into practice. For example, in our case study, the sales department was feared losing its role as vendor if VMI was implemented with key partners. So the company decided to offer a bonus to the sales department each time a collaborative relationship was created. In this way, the sales department was encouraged to establish long-term relationships with customers rather than selling products day-to-day. Finally, another difficulty concerned the technology to implement. The producer realized that the wholesaler used basic information systems and furthermore, the wholesaler did not want to invest in the acquisition and implementation of a complex system. Nevertheless, the producer was ready to support this cost by itself. At present, partners work together using the CR strategy, but in the future, they aim to implement a form of CPFR. Therefore, as our results have shown, the producer will certainly need to share benefits with the wholesaler to maintain a win-win collaborative relationship. Otherwise, it is possible that the wholesaler may prefer to work with another organization.
6 Conclusion In this paper, we have described a case study of collaboration between a pulp and paper producer and a wholesaler. We have first proposed a literature review to explain different concepts related to collaborations. Next, we have defined a methodology to follow to compare different collaborative approaches: selection of collaborative strategies; development of mathematical models; data collection and experimental design; and experiments and feedback. We have shown different results obtained from experiments and demonstrated the utility of the methodology. Some observations on the implementation of inter-firm collaborations have finally been explained.
Methodology for Assessing Collaboration Strategies and Incentives
647
The methodology developed was useful for taking into consideration several operational parameters and constraints such as lead times, set-up times, inventory costs, ordering cost, etc. With the use of a rolling horizon, we succeeded in integrating past decisions into the actual decision-making process and studying the effect of changes over time. By comparing different collaborative approaches for our case study, namely MTO, CR, VMI, and CPFR, we observed that CPFR was the most profitable approach for the system because of a reduction in transportation and inventory costs. However, this strategy was not the most beneficial for the two actors. We therefore explored the use of CPFR, combined with the sharing of savings, as a means of ensuring a win-win relationship. Since implementing CPFR may be costly and time-consuming, we also analyzed whether the use of incentives, combined with a MTO mode, could increase the profit of each partner. Three different incentives were defined: the use of a bonus for orders optimized; the sharing of transportation savings; and a quantity discount. We observed that these incentives improved the profit of both the producer and the wholesaler, without requiring a high level of information sharing. However, these results were found for specific parameters and conditions and consequently, if a change in the environment occurs, it may probably be necessary to adjust the collaborative relationship as well as the incentive used. Otherwise, the collaboration may become unprofitable. For the forest products industry, collaboration between network members is a real challenge. Companies that are willing to share resources and information as well as risks and benefits, undoubtedly stand to gain from working together. This is why much research will have to be conducted in the future to explore this issue more intensively.
References Andel T (2002) From common to custom: the case for make-to-order. Material Handling Management, November 2002, 1–4 Arshinder KA, Deshmukh SG (2008) Supply chain coordination: perspectives, empirical studies and research directions. Int J Prod Econ 115:316–335 Audy J-F, D’Amours S, Rousseau L-M (2007) Collaborative planning in a log truck pickup and delivery problem. Sixth Triennial Symposium on Transportation Analysis, June 10–15, Phuket Island, Thailand Audy J-F, D’amours S, Lehoux N, R€ onnqvist M (2009) A review on collaborative logistics. IESM’2009, May 13–15, Montre´al, QC, Canada Ballou RH (2004) Business logistics/supply chain management. Prentice-Hall, Upper Saddle River, NJ, USA Barratt M (2004) Understanding the meaning of collaboration in the supply chain. Supply Chain Manage Int J 9(1):30–42 Barratt M, Oliveira A (2001) Exploring the experiences of collaborative planning initiatives. Int J Phys Distrib Logist Manag 31(4):266–289 Beaudoin D (2008) Distributed wood procurement planning within a multi-firm environment. Ph.D. Thesis, Universite´ Laval, Que´bec, QC, Canada
648
N. Lehoux et al.
Bocheng C, Ip WH, Li Y (2006) The study and application of CPFR model and its analysis in China, International Conference on Service Systems and Service Management (ICSSSM’06), Vol 1, 745–749 Burer S, Jones PC, Lowe TJ (2008) Coordinating the supply chain in the agricultural seed industry. Eur J Oper Res 185:354–377 Cachon GP (2003) Supply chain coordination with contracts. In: de Kok AG, Graves SC (eds) Handbooks in operations research and management science. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 229–339 Cachon GP (2004) The allocation of inventory risk in a supply chain: push, pull, and advancedpurchased discount contracts. Manage Sci 50(2):222–238 Cachon GP, Lariviere MA (2005) Supply chain coordination with revenue-sharing contracts: strengths and limitations. Manage Sci 51(1):30–44 Cederlund JP, Kohli R, Sherer SA, Yao Y (2007) How Motorola put CPFR into action. Supply Chain Management Review, October 2007, 28–35 Chambost V, McNutt J, Stuart PR (2009) Partnerships for successful enterprise transformation of forest industry companies implementing the forest biorefinery. Pulp & Paper Canada May/June 2009, 19–24 Chan HK, Chan FTS (2010) A review of coordination studies in the context of supply chain dynamics. Int J Prod Res 48(10):2793–2819 Chung WWC, Leung SWF (2005) Collaborative planning, forecasting and replenishment: a case study in copper clad laminate industry. Prod Plann Control 16(6):563–574 Corbett CJ, Decroix GA, Ha AY (2005) Optimal shared-savings contracts in supply chains: linear contracts and double moral hazard. Eur J Oper Res 163(3):653–667 Corbett CJ, Decroix GA (2001) Shared-savings contracts for indirect materials in supply chains: channel profits and environmental impacts. Manage Sci 47(7):881–893 D’Amours S, R€onnqvist M, Weintraub A (2008) Using operational research for supply chain planning in the forest product industry. INFOR 46(4):47–64 Danese P (2006) The extended VMI for coordinating the whole supply network. J Manuf Technol Manag 17(7):888–907 Durand B (2007) La dimension strate´gique des chaıˆnes logistiques multi-acteurs du commerce e´lectronique B to C. In: Pache´ G, Spalanzani A (eds) La Gestion des chaıˆnes logistiques multiacteurs: perspectives strate´giques. Presses universitaires de Grenoble, France De Toni AF, Zamolo E (2005) From a traditional replenishment system to vendor-managed inventory: a case study from the household electrical appliances sector. Int J Prod Econ 96:63–79 Disney SM, Towill DR (2003) Vendor-managed inventory and bullwhip reduction in a two-level supply chain. Int J Oper Prod Manag 23(6):625–651 Dong AH, Wong WK, Chan SF, Yeung PKW (2006) Improve production balance for apparel supply chain adopting VMI replenishment strategy. International Conference on Management of Innovation and Technology, Singapore Du XF, Leung SCF, Zhang JL, Lai KK (2009) Procurement of agricultural products using the CPFR approach. Supply Chain Manage Int J 14(4):253–258 Durango-Cohen E, Yano CA (2006) Supplier commitment and production decisions under a forecast-commitment contract. Manage Sci 52(1):54–67 Dyer JH, Kale P, Singh H (2001) How to make strategic alliances work. MIT Sloan Management Review. Summer, 37–43 Fawcett SE, Osterhaus P, Magnan GM, Brau JC, McCarter M (2007) Information sharing and supply chain performance: the role of connectivity and willingness. Supply Chain Manage Int J 12(5):358–368 Fliedner G (2003) CPFR: an emerging supply chain tool. Ind Manage Data Syst 103(1):14–21 Frayret J-M (2009) A multidisciplinary review of collaborative supply chain planning. Conference Proceedings – IEEE International Conference on Systems, Man and Cybernetics, 4414–4421
Methodology for Assessing Collaboration Strategies and Incentives
649
Frisk M, J€ornsten K, G€ othe-Lundgren M, R€ onnqvist M (2006) Cost allocation in forestry operations. In: Proceedings of the 12th IFAC Symposium on Information Control Problems in Manufacturing, May 17–19. Saint-Etienne, France Gonzalez M (2001) Strategic alliances, the right way to compete in the 21st century. Ivey Business J, September/October, 47–51 Haartveit E, Kozak RA, Maness TC (2004) Supply chain management mapping for the forest products industry: three cases from western Canada. J For Prod Business Res 1(5):31 Holweg M, Disney S, Holmstr€ om J, Sma˚ros J (2005) Supply chain collaboration: making sense of the strategy continuum. Eur Manage J 23(2):170–181 Kilger C, Reuter B, Stadtler H (2008) Collaborative planning. In: Stadtler H, Kilger C (eds) Supply chain management and advanced planning: concepts, models, software, and case studies. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg, pp 263–284 Kurnia S, Johnston RB (2001) Adoption of efficient consumer response: the issue of mutuality. Suppy Chain Manage Int J 6(5):230–241 Kurnia S, Johnston RB, Dare A (2006) The mediating roles of third party organizations in ECR adoption. In: 39th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences. Kauai, January 4–7 Lee HL, Padmanabhan V, Whang S (1997) Information distortion in supply chain: the bullwhip effect. Manage Sci 43(4):546–558 Lehoux N, D’Amours S (2004) La collaboration interentreprises dans le secteur alimentaire: l’E´tude d’une relation entre manufacturier et distributeur. Revue Franc¸aise de Gestion Industrielle, 23(2) Lehoux N, D’Amours S, Langevin A (2009a) Collaboration and decision models for a two-echelon supply chain: a case study in the pulp and paper industry. J Operat Logistics 2(4):1–17 Lehoux N, D’Amours S, Frein Y, Langevin A, Penz B (2009b) Collaboration for a two-echelon supply chain in the pulp and paper industry: the use of incentives to increase profit. To appear in Journal of Operational Research Society Li X, Wang Q (2007) Coordination mechanisms of supply chain systems. Eur J Oper Res 179:1–16 Liu D, Roberto Boe¨r C, Sacco M, Fornasiero R (2006) A networked engineering portal to support distributed supply chain partnership. Int J Computer Integr Manuf 19(2):91–103 Martel A (2000) Conception et gestion de chaıˆnes logistiques. Department of Operations and Decision Systems, Universite´ Laval, Que´bec, Canada Mejı´as-Sacaluga A, Prado-Prado JC (2003) Implementing buyer-supplier partnerships in retailing channels through continuous improvement. Int J Serv Technol Manage 4(2):181–193 Min H, Yu WB (2008) Collaborative planning, forecasting and replenishment: demand planning in supply chain management. Int J Inf Technol Manage 7(1):4–20 Naesens K, Gelders L, Pintelon L (2007) A swift response tool for measuring the strategic fit for resource pooling: a case study. Manage Decis 45(3):434–449 Narayanan VG, Raman A (2004) Aligning incentives in Supply Chains. Harvard Business Review, November 2004, 94–103 Natural Resources Canada. Annual economic review and outlook for the Canadian forest sector [Accessed August 21rd, 2010] Palander T, Vaatainen J (2005) Impacts of interenterprise collaboration and backhauling on wood procurement in Finland. Scand J For Res 20(2):177–183 Paul A, Bose I (2004) Demand variability and incentives in inventory-based contracts. Oper Res Lett 32:409–414 Pietras T, Stormer C (2001) Making strategic alliances work. Business & Economic Review, July–September, 9–12 Razmi J, Hosseini Rad R, Sadegh Sangari M (2010) Developing a two-echelon mathematical model for a vendor-managed inventory (VMI) system. Int J Adv Manuf Technol 48:773–783 Ryu I, So S, Koo C (2009) The role of partnership in supply chain performance. Ind Manage Data Syst 109(4):496–514 Sarmah SP, Acharya D, Goyal SK (2006) Buyer vendor coordination models in supply chain management. Eur J Oper Res 175:1–15
650
N. Lehoux et al.
Shen H, Pang Z (2004) Supply chain coordination via capacity options with uncertain demand and supply. In: Proceedings of the International Conference on Systems, Man and Cybernetics, vol 7. IEEE, The Hague, New York, pp 5597–6002 Stadtler H (2009) A framework for collaborative planning and state-of-the-art. OR Spectr 31:5–30 Steermann H (2003) A practical look at CPFR: the Sears-Michelin experience. Suppl Chain Manage Rev, July, 46–53 Thomas DJ, Griffin PM (1996) Coordinated supply chain management. Eur J Oper Res 94:1–15 Tsay AA (1999) The quantity flexibility contract and supplier-customer incentives. Manage Sci 45 (10):1339–1358 Urban TL (2007) The effect of margin guarantees on pricing and production. Int J Manuf Technol Manage 12(4):314–326 Verdecho MJ, Alfaro JJ, Rodriguez-Rodriguez R (2009) Foundations for collaborative performance measurement. Prod Plann Control 20(3):193–205 Volontary Interindustry Commerce Solutions (VICS), (2004) CPFR Guidelines, http://www.vics. org/home [Accessed August 21, 2010] Wang Y, Jiang L, Shen Z-J (2004) Channel performance under consignment contract with revenue sharing. Manage Sci 50(1):34–47 Weng ZK (1997) Pricing and ordering strategies in manufacturing and distribution alliances. IIE Trans 29:681–692 Weng ZK (2004) Coordinating order quantities between the manufacturer and the buyer: a generalized newsvendor model. Eur J Oper Res 156:148–161 Yao Y, Evers PT, Dresner ME (2007) Supply chain integration in vendor-managed inventory. Decis Support Syst 43:663–674 Yu H, Zeng AZ, Zhao L (2009) Analyzing the evolutionary stability of the vendor-managed inventory supply chains. Comput Ind Eng 56:274–282
Index
A Acquisition management, 125 Additional ordering cost contract, 235–253 Advance capacity procurement, 222, 230 Assembly, 526–531, 533, 535, 537–541 Asymmetric information, 165–186
B Bioenergy systems, 545–560 Buy-back, 13, 18, 19, 26–28, 35 Buyer-supplier, 408, 410, 418
C Capabilities, 600–609, 612–619 Capacity, 4, 6, 10 Capacity management, 189–215 Channel conflict, 166, 170, 173, 181 Closed-loop supply chain, 117, 119–121, 126 Collaborative planning, 457–479, 563–596 Competition, 281–313 Component cycle time, 529, 530, 535 Consignment contract with revenue sharing, 427–452 Consultancy project, 617, 619 Contracting, 132–134, 145, 150, 154 Converging flows, 527–529 Cooperative game, 430, 434, 435, 439, 440, 445–447, 452 Coordination, 3–30, 33–36, 110, 121, 126, 282–284, 299–301, 303–305, 307–311, 403–424, 525–541 Coordination mechanisms, 39–76 Credit option, 403–424 Credit period, 405, 407, 408, 412–419, 422
D Demand uncertainty, 189–215, 403–424 Detailed scheduling, 457–479 Distribution distortion, 273 Dominance and bargaining, 350, 353–362
E Evolutionary algorithm, 459, 469–475
F Franchise fee (FF), 256, 259, 262, 263, 268
G Game theory, 172, 173, 182, 284
I Incentives, 625–647 Incremental quantity discounts, 221, 226, 231 Information asymmetry, 256, 257, 260, 264, 267, 269 Information sharing, 380, 382, 390, 565–567, 577, 587 Information technology (IT), 600–619 Interaction, 600–605, 607–612, 614–618 Inter-arrival time of kits, 526–527, 529–533, 536–540 Inter-firm collaborations, 627, 632, 646 Inventory, 483–502
L Long-term relationships, 627, 646
T.-M. Choi and T.C. Edwin Cheng (eds.), Supply Chain Coordination under Uncertainty, International Handbooks on Information Systems, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-19257-9, # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2011
651
652 M Mixed channel, 165–186 Monopoly revenue management, 192, 199, 211 Multi-echelon, 564, 588 Multi-echelon inventory control policy, 84, 88–89, 102 Multi-period setting, 235–253
N Nash bargaining, 5, 19, 21, 24, 26, 27, 34, 35 Newsvendor model, 141, 145–147, 319 Nonlinear optimization, 348
O Online channel, 180, 183 Option contracts, 189–215
P Pareto optimality, 4, 7–10, 13, 27, 29 Partial backlogging, 342 Performance, 526, 527, 534–541 Possibility programming, 505–522 Price discrimination, 189–215 Pricing, 283, 284, 292, 303 Production and transport planning, 506, 511 Pulp and paper industry, 625–647
R Record inaccuracy, 483–502 Relationships, 600–605, 607, 608, 610, 613–619 Remanufacturing, 109–126 Renewable energy, 545, 547, 551, 553, 554, 557 Reorder point, 404, 405, 408, 409, 412, 414, 421, 423 Reservation profit, 256–258, 260, 262, 267, 270–273, 276, 277 Retail price maintenance (RPM), 256, 259 Returns, 6 Revelation principle, 261, 263, 269, 273 Revenue sharing, 13, 18, 26–28
Index Review, 84, 86–89, 93–95, 97 Revised revenue-sharing contract, 317, 318, 338 RFID. See Radio frequency identification devices (RFID) Risk averse agents, 3–30, 33–36 Risk aversion, 4, 6, 17, 21, 22, 35, 36 Risk-sharing, 131–162 Radio frequency identification devices (RFID), 483–502
S SAP APO, 459, 467–468, 475 Selling agents, 256, 258, 269 Stability, 283, 291–297, 299 Strategic interactions, 220 Supply chain, 403–424 Supply chain contract design, 382 Supply chain coordination, 4, 10–11, 34, 36, 39–76, 154, 221, 226, 235–253, 315–342, 349, 427–452, 483–502 Supply chain coordination index (SCCI), 70–74 Supply chain management (SCM), 4, 5, 10, 84, 99, 121, 282, 505, 507, 522, 632 Supply chains, 545–560 Supply contracts, 236–239, 248, 255–279, 347–377 Supply networks, 563–596 Sustainable development, 545 Synchronization time, 526–534, 536–541 System dynamics, 565, 566, 571, 578, 589
T Two ordering opportunities, 315–342
U Uncertainty, 430, 435, 443, 445, 448, 450–452, 506–509, 521, 522
W Warranty, 281–313