The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Edited by
Adam Szirmai and Paul Lapperre
The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
...
232 downloads
945 Views
1MB Size
Report
This content was uploaded by our users and we assume good faith they have the permission to share this book. If you own the copyright to this book and it is wrongfully on our website, we offer a simple DMCA procedure to remove your content from our site. Start by pressing the button below!
Report copyright / DMCA form
The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Edited by
Adam Szirmai and Paul Lapperre
The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
Also by Adam Szirmai ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL DEVELOPMENT: Trends, Problems, Policies EXPLAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH: Essays in Honour of Angus Maddison (editor with B. Van Ark and D. Pilat) INEQUALITY OBSERVED: A Study of Attitudes towards Income Inequality ONTWIKKELINGSLANDEN: Dynamiek en Stagnatie
The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Edited by
Adam Szirmai Professor of Technology and Development Studies Eindhoven Centre for Innovation Studies (ECIS) Eindhoven University of Technology The Netherlands
and
Paul Lapperre Associate Professor of Technology and Development Studies Director of Education MSc Programme Technology and Society Eindhoven University of Technology The Netherlands
Editorial matter and selection © Adam Szirmai and Paul Lapperre 2001 Chapter 1 © Donné van Engelen, Adam Szirmai and Paul Lapperre 2001 Chapter 3 © Adam Szirmai, Menno Prins and Wessel Schulte 2001 Chapter 7 © Bartelt Bongenaar and Adam Szirmai 2001 Chapter 9 © Raymond Duijsens and Paul Lapperre 2001 Chapter 12 © Paul Lapperre 2001 Chapters 2, 4–6, 8, 10, 11, 13–17 © Palgrave Publishers Ltd 2001 Chapter 5 was previously published in Public Choice 89: 3/4, pp. 375–92, 1996. Reprinted with kind permission from Kluwer Academic Publishers. All rights reserved. No reproduction, copy or transmission of this publication may be made without written permission. No paragraph of this publication may be reproduced, copied or transmitted save with written permission or in accordance with the provisions of the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988, or under the terms of any licence permitting limited copying issued by the Copyright Licensing Agency, 90 Tottenham Court Road, London W1P 0LP. Any person who does any unauthorised act in relation to this publication may be liable to criminal prosecution and civil claims for damages. The authors have asserted their rights to be identified as the authors of this work in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988. First published 2001 by PALGRAVE Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire RG21 6XS and 175 Fifth Avenue, New York, N. Y. 10010 Companies and representatives throughout the world PALGRAVE is the new global academic imprint of St. Martin’s Press LLC Scholarly and Reference Division and Palgrave Publishers Ltd (formerly Macmillan Press Ltd). ISBN 0–333–80019–2 This book is printed on paper suitable for recycling and made from fully managed and sustained forest sources. A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data The industrial experience of Tanzania / edited by Adam Szirmai and Paul Lapperre. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 0–333–80019–2 1. Industrialization—Tanzania. 2. Tanzania—Economic conditions—1964– 3. Technology—Tanzania. I. Szirmai, Adam, 1946– II. Lapperre, Paul, 1942– HC885 .I533 2001 338.09678—dc21 2001021199 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 10 09 08 07 06 05 04 03 02 01 Printed in Great Britain by Antony Rowe Ltd, Chippenham, Wiltshire
Contents Preface
vii
Conference Participants
viii
Notes on the Contributors Introduction Adam Szirmai and Paul Lapperre
1
Part I: Long-run Economic Performance
9
1
2 3
4
x
Public Policy and the Industrial Development of Tanzania, 1961–95 Donné van Engelen, Adam Szirmai, Paul Lapperre
11
Is African Manufacturing Skill Constrained? Howard Pack and Christina Paxson
50
Measuring Manufacturing Performance in Tanzania: GDP, Employment and Comparative Labour Productivity 1961–95 Adam Szirmai, Menno Prins and Wessel Schulte
73
The Role of Technological Factors in the Early Stages of Industrial Exports: A Note Charles Cooper
Part II: Innovation, Technological Capabilities and Choice of Techniques 5
6
7
8
114
133
Public Choice, Technology and Industrialization in Tanzania. Some Paradoxes Resolved Jeffrey James
135
The Form and Role of Industrial Innovativeness in Enhancing Firms’ Productivity: The Case of Selected Manufacturing Firms in Tanzania Haji H. Semboja and Josephat P. Kweka
153
Development and Diffusion of Technology: The Case of TIRDO Bartelt Bongenaar and Adam Szirmai
171
Technological Capabilities: A Core Element for National Development Opportunities? A Study of Technological v
vi Contents
9
Capabilities in the Dwelling Construction Sector for Lower-Income Households in Tanzania Emilia van Egmond-de Wilde de Ligny
194
Technical Education, Knowledge and Skills in the Metalworking Industry in Tanzania Raymond Duijsens and Paul Lapperre
218
Part III: Environmental and Energy Aspects of Industrialization
235
10 Industry and Environment: Methodologies for Environmental Assessment in Data-Poor Situations Lex Lemmens, Peter Scheren, Harro Zanting, Gregory Njau and David van Horen
237
11 Energy Conservation in the Industrial Sector in Tanzania Frank van der Vleuten, Lex Lemmens, Otto Bos, Caspar Samplonius, Dick Toussaint and Michel Yhdego
262
Part IV: Lessons from Past Experiences, Economic Reform, Prospects for the Future
281
12 Industrialization of Tanzania: Can Tanzania Learn from European History? Paul Lapperre
283
13 Macro-Economic Policy and Performance of the Manufacturing Sector in Tanzania: Has Liberalisation Helped? An Econometric Approach A.V.Y. Mbelle
300
14 The Urban Informal Manufacturing Sector in Tanzania: Neglected Opportunities for Socioeconomic Development Herman Gaillard and Amber Beernink
318
15 The Impact of Reforms in Tanzania: The Case of Privatized Manufacturing Industries Humphrey P.B. Moshi
341
16 Economic Reforms, Industrialization and Technological Capabilities in Tanzanian Industry Samuel M. Wangwe
349
17 Highlights of the Sustainable Industrial Development Policy in Tanzania, 1996–2020 A.K. Maziku
367
Bibliography
376
Index
405
Preface This volume presents the proceedings of a conference on ‘The Industrial Performance of Tanzania’ held from 25 to 27 June 1998 at Eindhoven University of Technology. The conference has been organized jointly by the Section of Technology and Development Studies (TDS) and the Centre for International Cooperation Activities (CICA) of Eindhoven University of Technology. Since 1973 CICA has been responsible for the cooperation between the Eindhoven University of Technology and organizations and universities in developing countries. The conference marked its 25th anniversary. The Technology and Development Studies section is responsible for research and teaching in the field of technology, innovation policy and development studies. The section is part of the Department of Technology and Policy, Faculty of Technology Management, at the Eindhoven University of Technology. It participates in the MSc programme Technology and Society. Its research activities are integrated into the research programme of the Eindhoven Centre for Innovation Studies (ECIS). Between 1992 and 1998 staff and MSc students of the TDS executed a wide range of research projects in firms, organizations and sectors in Tanzania, in the context of a research programme on industrialization and technological development in Tanzania. Over a hundred research assignments have been completed. These research projects have resulted in a wealth of new information about firm-level and sectoral developments in Tanzanian industry. One of the aims of the conference was to make part of this information available to the outside world. A second aim was to strengthen scientific interaction between African and European researchers and institutions. Nine researchers from Tanzania were invited to present papers at the conference. Many of their contributions have been included in this volume. We gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Faculty of Technology Management and the Department of Technology and Policy. We thank Jan van Cranenbroek of CICA for his work as co-organizer of the conference. Lutgart van Kollenburg acted as secretary of the conference and made contributions going far beyond the bounds of normal secretarial support. Thanks are due to Petra Heck, who provided invaluable support in the word processing of the manuscript. Adam Szirmai Paul Lapperre October 1999 vii
Conference Participants ‘The Industrial Performance of Tanzania’ Bartelt Bongenaar Eindhoven University of Technology IBM Deployment of New Technologies Amsterdam Charles Cooper The United Nations University/INTECH Maastricht, The Netherlands Jan van Cranenbroek Bureau for International Affairs, Eindhoven University of Technology The Netherlands Raymond Duijsens Eindhoven University of Technology Netherlands Red Cross The Netherlands Emilia van Egmond-de Wilde de Ligny Eindhoven University of Technology The Netherlands Donné van Engelen Eindhoven University of Technology The Netherlands
Herman Gaillard Eindhoven University of Technology The Netherlands Jeffrey James Tilburg University The Netherlands Josephat P. Kweka Economic and Social Research Foundation (ESRF), Dar es Salaam, Tanzania Paul Lapperre Eindhoven University of Technology The Netherlands Lex Lemmens Centre for Technology for Sustainable Development (TDO) Eindhoven University of Technology The Netherlands A.K. Maziku Ministry of Industries and Trade Tanzania A.V.Y. Mbelle University of Dar es Salaam Tanzania viii
Conference Participants ix
T.S.A. Mbwette University of Dar es Salaam Dar es Salaam, Tanzania Hubert Meena University of Dar es Salaam Dar es Salaam, Tanzania Humphrey P.B. Moshi Economic Research Bureau University of Dar es Salaam Tanzania Gregory Njau Environmental Association of Tanzania (ENATA), Dar es Salaam Tanzania
Wessel Schulte Eindhoven University of Technology The Netherlands UNIDO/UNDP Uganda Haji H. Semboja Economic and Social Research Foundation (ESRF), Dar es Salaam, Tanzania Adam Szirmai Eindhoven Centre for Innovation Studies Eindhoven University of Technology The Netherlands
Howard Pack World Bank/University of Pennsylvania USA
F. van der Vleuten Eindhoven University of Technology Free Energy Europe Eindhoven, The Netherlands
Menno Prins Eindhoven University of Technology ERICSSON, Sweden
Samuel M. Wangwe Economic and Research Foundation (ESRF), Dar es Salaam Tanzania
Notes on the Contributors Amber Beernink, Section of Technology and Development Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology, The Netherlands Bartelt Bongenaar, Section of Technology and Development Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology/IBM Deployment of New Technologies, Amsterdam, The Netherlands Otto Bos, Section of Technology and Development Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology, The Netherlands Charles Cooper, The United Nations University/INTECH Maastricht, The Netherlands Raymond Duijsens, Section of Technology and Development Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology/ Netherlands Red Cross, The Netherlands Emilia van Egmond-de Wilde de Ligny, Section of Technology and Development Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology, The Netherlands Donné van Engelen, Section of Technology and Development Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology, The Netherlands Herman Gaillard, Section of Technology and Development Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology, The Netherlands David van Horen, Centre for Technology for Sustainable Development, Eindhoven University of Technology, The Netherlands Jeffrey James, Tilburg University, The Netherlands Josephat P. Kweka, Economic and Social Research Foundation (ESRF), Dar es Salaam, Tanzania x
Notes on the Contributors xi
Paul Lapperre, Section of Technology and Development Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology, The Netherlands Lex Lemmens, Centre for Technology for Sustainable Development (TDO), Eindhoven University of Technology, The Netherlands A.K. Maziku, Ministry of Industries and Trade, Tanzania A.V.Y. Mbelle, University of Dar es Salaam, Tanzania Humphrey P.B. Moshi, Economic Research Bureau, University of Dar es Salaam, Tanzania Gregory Njau, Environmental Association of Tanzania (ENATA), Dar es Salaam, Tanzania Howard Pack, World Bank/University of Pennsylvania, USA Christina Paxson, Princeton University, USA Menno Prins, Section of Technology and Development Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology/ERICSSON, Sweden Caspar Samplonius, Section of Technology and Development Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology, The Netherlands Peter Scheren, Centre for Technology for Sustainable Development, Eindhoven University of Technology, The Netherlands Wessel Schulte, Section of Technology and Development Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology, The Netherlands, and UNIDO/UNDP, Uganda Haji H. Semboja, Economic and Social Research Foundation (ESRF), Dar es Salaam, Tanzania Adam Szirmai, Eindhoven Centre for Innovation Studies, Eindhoven University of Technology, The Netherlands
xii Notes on the Contributors
Dick Toussaint, Section of Technology and Development Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology, The Netherlands Frank van der Vleuten, Section of Technology and Development Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology/ Free Energy Europe, Eindhoven, The Netherlands Samuel M. Wangwe, Economic and Social Research Foundation (ESRF), Dar es Salaam, Tanzania Michel Yhdego, ERC Consultants, Dar es Salaam, Tanzania Harro Zanting, Centre for Technology for Sustainable Development, Eindhoven University of Technology, The Netherlands
Introduction Adam Szirmai and Paul Lapperre
This collection of articles focuses on an analysis of the industrial experience of Tanzania since independence in 1961. Tanzania is taken as a case study of industrialization in sub-Saharan Africa because it represents many of the common features of industrialization processes in other African economies. What we need to understand is why some developing economies, which started from low levels of per capita income in the post-war period, achieved some measure of success in industrialization and economic development, while others did not. In this context the experiences of some Asian countries contrast sharply with the experiences of the majority of countries in sub-Saharan Africa. As Tanzania in many ways represents one of the models of African economic development, a careful analysis of its industrial experiences, and in particular the role of policy in these experiences, contributes to a better understanding of both Tanzanian and African economic development. Common features of African development include the lack of an industrial heritage, the overwhelming importance of the agricultural sector in the post-war period, dependence on primary exports and a very small share of manufacturing in GDP and employment. In policy and development thinking industrialization was, and often still is, seen as the key to economic development. The fiery enthusiasm for industrialization was coupled with distrust of free-market forces, which were negatively associated with colonial experiences. A developmental state soon came to be seen as the main catalyst of development. Thus – irrespective of the precise shadings of ideology– state interventionism, state planning and state ownership of industrial enterprises increased all over Africa. This is not to say that Tanzania has no distinctive features of its own. It has specific characteristics which distinguish it from many other countries. Apart from the intervention in Uganda in the 1980s, Tanzania succeeded in maintaining both peaceful relations with its neighbours and internal peace. Although the process of rural resettlement during the Ujamaa period, in the late 1960s and early 1970s, resulted in some measure 1
2 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
of forced relocation and disruption of agricultural populations, it avoided the extremes of Stalinist socialism, exemplified for instance by Ethiopia. Also there were undoubted successes in fields such as education and health care. Julius Nyerere was a political leader of exceptional integrity, who played a major role in maintaining ethnic harmony and building a sense of national identity. Tanzania was also characterized by peaceful changes of leadership and a smooth transition to a multiparty democracy in 1996, though marred by rising corruption. In the late 1950s and early 1960s, after most countries gained their independence, hopes for rapid economic development were high across the African continent. Initially these hopes seemed to be well founded. Until 1973 income per capita and manufacturing GDP per capita tended to increase. From 1973 onwards, with country to country variations, a long period of stagnation set it. Apart from economic factors, political instability, corruption, military conflict and ethnic strife were major factors contributing to economic stagnation in most African countries. As time went by, the perception of the role of the state started to change. Instead of being seen as a driving force in development, the state even started to be interpreted by some observers as a predatory and corrupt institution, diverting resources and human talent and effort from productive investment in economic development. In the course of the 1980s, the international and national economic policy climate changed. Almost all countries, whether voluntarily or involuntarily, embarked on a process of structural adjustment, liberalization, deregulation, privatization and return to the market. Although there is a consensus concerning the shortcomings of state led industrialization, structural adjustment and economic reform have had mixed results in Africa. Despite some intimations of change there has, so far, seldom been a resumption of rapid sustained growth. Some sub-Saharan countries are even experiencing de-industrialization, and many are now faced with economic stagnation. In the case of Tanzania, political commitment to reforms seems to be quite strong and authentic. But, as illustrated by the articles in this volume, there is still a lively debate on the successes and failures of reform and on the future role of the state in the context of reform, liberalization and structural adjustment. This book is structured into four parts. Part I focuses on long-run economic performance. It consists of two chapters on Tanzania and two chapters which place Tanzanian industrialization in a comparative international perspective. Part II brings together five articles dealing with issues of technology and innovation. Part III presents two articles on environmental and energy aspects of industrialization. Section IV brings together six articles focusing on economic reform and its prospects. The volume combines contributions from economics, sociology and engineering. It complements articles focusing on macro trends, with
Introduction 3
articles based on a wealth of information derived from firm-level surveys in various sectors of Tanzanian manufacturing. These provide new insights into the mechanics of industrialization, technological change and the responses to reform. Part I opens with a chapter by van Engelen, Szirmai and Lapperre. The chapter provides an overview of the evolution of industrial policy in Tanzania since 1961 and the impact of policy on industrial performance. It describes the familiar process of increasing government intervention and the emergence of inward-looking import substitution, followed by painful attempts at adjustment, deregulation, opening up and reform. It argues that policy has had very significant, and after 1973 negative, effects on industrial performance. Instead of looking at policy rhetoric, the article focuses on indicators of actual policy implementation. This leads to different periodizations of policy regimes. The importance of such an approach is underscored by James’s observations in Chapter 5. He shows that at the onset reform was more rhetoric than reality. During the first reform period after 1986, the role of the state in industrial investment initially even continued to increase. Any discussion of economic policy requires adequate monitoring of economic performance by statistical institutions. The National Bureau of Statistics of Tanzania is involved in ongoing attempts to improve and revise national accounts and industrial statistics. In Chapter 3, Szirmai, Prins and Schulte try to make a contribution to these efforts by presenting newly revised estimates of manufacturing levels and trends. The authors find that the level of industrial value added has been seriously underestimated in existing statistics. The pattern of growth followed by decline, however, is even more pronounced than in earlier estimates. The article also presents new indices of real labour productivity, which show dramatic secular declines in productivity since 1973. An international comparison of labour productivity indicates that Tanzania has been falling behind in a period when labour productivity in Asia was catching up with the lead economies. In 1989 value added per person engaged in mediumand large-scale manufacturing had declined to 3.9 per cent of that of the world productivity leader, the USA. In a comparative study of the role of education in three African economies, Pack and Paxson present a critical discussion of the orthodox notion that African growth is skill constrained, and that expansion of education will in itself provide an impetus to growth of productivity. They argue convincingly that unless a complementary inflow of new technology takes place, educational investments will not lead to industrial development. In a non-competitive, inward-looking and stagnant setting, investment in human capital will have disappointing results. They are careful to point out, however, that once the economy starts becoming more dynamic, human capital and increased technological capabilities will also
4 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
become more important. In this respect it is important to remember that improved educational levels preceded economic growth in settings as diverse as Scandinavia, South Korea and Japan. In a thought-provoking article, based on an analysis of the experiences of the Asian newly industrializing economies, Cooper attacks the preoccupation with technological upgrading. He argues that it is much more important for sub-Saharan Africa to find out how and why Asian NICs transformed themselves into labour-intensive exporters, and why nonNICS got stuck in import substitution which created vicious cycles of inefficiency. Though final answers are not forthcoming, the orientation of government policy was certainly one of the relevant factors in the transformation. A second issue raised in the article is that of technological change in so-called early, labour-intensive, industries. Even in labour- intensive sectors such as textiles or leather, the pace of global technological change is accelerating. This creates special challenges for late late industrializers who now want to enter world markets. Even countries with a potential comparative advantage in labour-intensive production have to make substantial efforts to keep abreast of world technological developments. In the early stages of industrial development, technological innovation is primarily a question of taking over and adapting technologies developed in the advanced economies. However, the process of technology transfer is not effortless. It is itself a type of innovation which requires considerable effort and capabilities. The success with which developing countries take over technologies, depends to an important extent on their technological capabilities: their capacities to select, acquire, adapt and further develop internationally available technologies and to integrate them into the domestic economy. The five articles in Part II reflect different aspects of this complex of problems. In Chapter 5, James presents a political economic analysis of the role of the Tanzanian state in technology selection, and provides interesting examples of the lack of economic rationality in the investment process. The main driving force in technology selection consists of bureaucratic managers maximizing project size and budgets in negotiations with international donors. James uses this perspective to clarify two paradoxes in technology selection: different technology choices in similar industries, and a preference for capital-intensive projects in a country with a labour surplus. In Chapter 6, Semboja and Kweka discuss innovative strategies of firms. They note that, with the exception of a few firms with international partners, innovation and technological changes have been very limited in scope. They go on to discuss the factors influencing innovativeness and the obstacles to innovative behaviour. These obstacles include a shortage of technical skills in the labour force, a low volume and ineffective coordination of firm-level R&D, insufficient orientation to export markets – the
Introduction 5
literature emphasizes that exporters are forced to innovate and to meet international quality standards – , insufficient financial resources, a weak institutional framework for science and technology support, and weak links between innovation research centres and users. The issue of technological capabilities is also central to the article by van Egmond in Chapter 8. She defines technological capabilities in terms of four components: stock of technology, stock of human resources, stock of natural resources, and technology infrastructure. She argues that technological capabilities are very important for successful technology transfer. Operationalizing the four components, she goes on to map the capabilities of the dwelling-construction industry, identifying weaknesses and bottlenecks. The literature on national systems of innovation emphasizes the crucial importance of fruitful interaction and strong networks and linkages between enterprises and science and technology institutes. The importance of the science and technology infrastructure is stressed by various authors in this volume. Chapter 7, by Bongenaar and Szirmai, focuses specifically on a case study of the functioning of the Tanzanian Industrial Research and Development Organisation (TIRDO). TIRDO is an R&D organization, which explicitly aims at developing and adapting technology for domestic industry. A detailed analysis of TIRDO projects indicates a considerable degree of technical project success. In terms of transferring technologies to enterprises, however, the record is very disappointing. The organization tends to operate on the assumption that good technologies should sell themselves. Therefore, insufficient attention is paid to networking, marketing and transfer activities. The case study provides a clear illustration of the weakly developed linkages between publicly funded R&D institutes and enterprises. In Chapter 9, Duijsens and Lapperre focus on one important component of technological capabilities: technical education. In a survey study of 28 enterprises, they investigate the supply and demand for technical education in the metalworking sector. At all educational levels, major shortcomings are identified with regard to knowledge of modern metalworking techniques, awareness of safety-related aspects, awareness of preventive maintenance, striving for excellence, and mastery of English. In an analysis of the institutional sources of shortcomings, interestingly enough, the use of English as the language of instruction is identified as one of the major problems, as both teachers and pupils have insufficient mastery of the language. Part III opens with Chapter 10, by Lemmens and associates, on the assessment of environmental impacts of productive and household activities. This article develops an ingenious methodology to assess environmental impacts in data-poor situations, which is of special relevance for developing economies such as Tanzania. It uses standard pollution factors for productive outputs and human activities.
6 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
The method is initially applied to Lake Victoria where, as it turns out, industry is far less important as a source of different types of pollution than households, agriculture and wet deposition. Though industry may not yet be important at an aggregate level, point pollution turns out to be more serious, especially in major urban centres, such as Dar es Salaam, and in small-scale gold mining. A link between industrial productivity and environmental considerations is provided by energy efficiency. An increase in energy efficiency increases firm productivity and profitability, while at the same time reducing the burden on the environment associated with increasing industrial production. Though some might argue that in a poor country such as Tanzania economic development and industrialization take precedence over environmental considerations, van der Vleuten, Lemmens and associates argue persuasively in Chapter 11 that there are ample opportunities for leapfrogging to cleaner production. Their conclusions are based on meticulous studies in beer brewing and cement production. Tanzania is now trying to move towards export orientation and privatization. As various authors indicate, Tanzania is swallowing the IMF and World Bank medicine of deregulation, export orientation and privatization more wholeheartedly than many other developing countries. The chapters in Part IV focus on the reform process. On the one hand, they reflect on the lessons to be learned from past experiences; on the other they analyse the impact of reforms and make suggestions about future paths to be followed. In the opening chapter in Part IV, Lapperre puts Tanzanian industrialization in a historical comparative perspective, and asks what lessons can be derived for Tanzania from the industrial history of Western Europe. He makes systematic comparisons between the historical prerequisites for industrialization in the past, and present conditions in Tanzania. Such historical comparisons are valuable since every ‘advanced’ country was once a ‘developing’ one. However, one has to be careful, because countries do not necessarily follow identical paths of development, and the international context facing late developers may be very different from those of the first movers. This point is well illustrated in the chapter by Cooper, who points to accelerated global technological change in labour-intensive sectors such as textiles. One of the important prerequisites cited by Lapperre is that industrialization requires prior increases in agricultural productivity. Other important preconditions for successful industrialization have to do with the crucial importance of political stability and efficient, predictable and non-corrupt government. Lapperre also presents an analysis of attitudes and social institutions, such as for example extended family ties, which may be unfavourable for industrialization. With regard to education, the message is mixed. Lapperre indicates that increased formal education has not always
Introduction 7
been essential for early industrial development in Europe. Like Pack and Paxson, he doubts that simply increasing formal educational levels will provide solutions to Tanzania’s economic problems. On the other hand, many of the articles in this volume (van Egmond, Duijsens and Lapperre, Semboja and Kweka) emphasize the importance of improving education and in particular technical education. An article on the informal urban manufacturing sector by Gaillard and Beernink has a dual purpose. On the one hand, the authors criticize the neglect of the informal sector in past policy thinking and practice. On the other hand, they present a state of the art of informal-sector studies, both in Tanzania and worldwide. They are very critical of the scientific quality of informal-sector studies, concluding that this branch of research is still in a pre-scientific stage. Therefore, it is of less use for the formulation of well-specified informal-sector policies than is to be desired. Nevertheless, the authors do conclude on the basis of the available information that the relevance of this sector for economic development is very substantial in terms of employment, output, income generation and learning potential. In 1991 no less than 56 per cent of the urban active population in Tanzania was working in the informal sector, generating 32 per cent of total urban income. Gaillard and Beernink try to identify the main constraints for the future growth of this sector, which include: limited access to credit, lack of equipment and spare parts, and limited access to more permanent sites. Training is mentioned least frequently by respondents, as the informal sector is largely self-supporting with regard to training. However, the authors conclude that from a long-run perspective, training for upgrading labour in the informal sector should be part of the policy package. The articles by Mbelle, Moshi and Wangwe all focus on the process of reform and structural adjustment. It is important to note that there is consensus concerning the shortcomings of the model of state-led importsubstitution industrialization dominant in the past. None of the authors advocates a return to this model. However, their assessments of ongoing reform policies and their outcomes are mixed. In Chapter 15, Moshi provides two interesting case studies of major firms that have experienced a marked turnaround since their privatization, with increases in sales, productivity, competitiveness and profitability. In an econometric article on the impact of liberalization in chapter 13, Mbelle starts by noting that important macroeconomic indicators, such as manufacturing growth and employment, have started improving since 1994. For 1998 he even records a GDP growth in manufacturing of 8.1 per cent. GDP growth in the total economy has also picked up in recent years (Table 1.9). Like Wangwe, Semboja and Kweka, and Moshi, he also points to increased technological dynamism and ‘offensive strategies’ in some of the manufacturing firms.
8 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
On the basis of econometric analyses Mbelle concludes that manufacturing exports responded positively to liberalization after 1993. However, the share of manufacturing in investment tended to decline. Mbelle concludes that macroeconomic policies in themselves are not enough. Sector-specific policies are needed to ameliorate some negative sectoral impacts of macropolicies. Much the same conclusion is drawn by Wangwe in chapter 16. On the basis of a survey of recent literature he concludes that restructuring entails more than macroeconomic reform. He is particularly concerned with the fact that, while liberalization does expose formerly protected firms to competitive pressures, there are still no strong inducement mechanisms for technological change and improving technological capabilities. In view of Cooper’s conclusion that developing countries that want to enter world markets in labour-intensive exports are faced with more technological change than before, this is an important finding. Wangwe goes on to identify the main factors which need to be tackled by policy. They include: improving institutional capacity to provide supportive technological services to industry, improving linkages between economic activities and between establishments and R&D institutions, improving the provision of infrastructure, investing in human resource development and making labour processes more conducive to learning. He identifies three major priorities: policies aimed at technological learning and building competitiveness, priority of agro-based small and micro-enterprises, and enhancing the capability of government to complement the opening-up process of the economy with supportive policies. In the final chapter Maziku summarizes Tanzanian policy intentions contained in the recently drafted Sustainable Industrial Development Policy (SIDP) document for the period up to 2020. The new policy formulation addresses many of the issues discussed in this book. Maziku rightly emphasizes that one of the important new elements in policy making is a consultative mechanism for policy implementation, in which a revived private sector and the government are expected to cooperate and interact. Though this volume stresses that policy implementation is far more important than policy intentions, the SIDP certainly provides an indication of the extent of change in policy thinking. Adam Szirmai and Paul Lapperre Eindhoven, October 1999
Part I Long-run Economic Performance
This page intentionally left blank
1 Public Policy and the Industrial Development of Tanzania, 1961–95 Donné van Engelen, Adam Szirmai and Paul Lapperre*
1
Introduction
Throughout the past decades the economic and industrial performance of less developed countries in sub-Saharan Africa can be captured in three words: boom, crisis and adjustment (Little et al., 1993). The sequence of rapid growth, followed by crisis and an ongoing process of structural adjustment, has received a great deal of attention, both from neo-liberal and structuralist points of view. Neo-liberal doctrine emphasizes the primacy of markets and the negative effects of excessive state intervention in the process of economic development. Structuralists, on the other hand, seek explanations of economic underdevelopment in the combination of negative external influences, unfavourable initial conditions and a variety of structural and institutional constraints that developing countries have had to face (Lensink, 1996; Szirmai, 1997a) Overcoming these structural constraints requires active intervention on the part of governments. For most of the period since 1961, Tanzanian industrial policy has been overwhelmingly structuralist in nature. This article provides an analysis of 34 years of industrial development in Tanzania (1961–95), in order to gain insight into the reasons why manufacturing has so far failed to become an engine of economic growth. The central aim of this article is to analyse the combined effects of initial conditions, external influences and policy responses on the performance of the manufacturing sector in different periods. After a brief discussion of initial conditions in Section 2, Section 3 presents a discussion of industrial policies. Periods of coherent policy are identified in an empirical manner: by monitoring the actual use of instruments of industrial policy. In section 4, the emphasis is on the external influences and external shocks, that have provided challenges to industrial policy makers. Incorporation of these external influences into the analytical framework results in a revised periodization. In Section 5, we examine the impact of industrial policies and external influences on manufacturing performance. 11
12 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
2
Initial conditions
During the colonial interlude lasting from 1885 to 1961, Tanzania is subjected to German rule (until 1918) and later to British rule. During most of the colonial period, industrialization receives little attention. There is some domestic manufacturing in the nineteenth century (handicraft production of iron products, cotton cultivation, spinning and weaving), but under German rule (1890–1918) this is largely replaced by imports. Between the two world wars British colonial policy discourages investment in manufacture for the local market (Coulson, 1982b). In the twilight of colonialism after World War II, the previously almost non-existent Tanzanian industrial sector begins to take shape. Initially all industrial efforts are directed at the processing of primary agricultural commodities such as sisal, cotton, coffee and tobacco. These commodities are processed for the export market. In the 1950s production of consumer and intermediate goods for the domestic market gains in importance. But the share of these products (for example, woodwork, paint, soap, steel) in total manufacturing remains small (Silver, 1984). The demand for intermediate and capital goods (for example, iron, vehicles and machinery) is largely satisfied by imports (World Bank, 1987a). To encourage the establishment of industrial enterprises, the colonial government provides fiscal advantages (tax relief on capital expenditures, refunds of custom duties) and some measure of protection (import duties) to investors. Furthermore, the government is willing to participate in investment projects, provide specialist research and advisory services, create industrial sites and improve infrastructural facilities. Since Tanzania lacks a well-developed capitalist entrepreneurial class (Rweyemamu, 1973), the incentive package in this period aims at stimulating private foreign investment. Unfortunately for Tanzania, the other member states of the East African Community, Kenya and Uganda, are providing similar incentive packages. Moreover, Kenya possesses the largest industrial base, the best financial and physical infrastructure, the most concentrated domestic market and the largest settler community. Thus it is a more attractive country for foreign investors than Tanzania. Silver (1984) concludes that the policy incentive package of the 1950s cannot have been very effective in stimulating foreign investment in Tanzanian manufacturing. As a result of the unstimulating policy environment and the continued focus on agricultural commodity processing, Tanzania has not experienced a great deal of industrial development at the eve of independence. In 1961 the manufacturing sector contributes 3.6 per cent to GDP at factor costs (Rweyemamu, 1973). Of the total number of 891 industrial establishments, including cottage establishments (Silver, 1984), 245 are engaged in primary products processing (sisal, tea, tobacco, cotton), 248 in basic food processing and manufacturing (sugar, salt, dairy products, grain milling, bakeries,
Public Policy and Industrial Development 13
beverages), and 225 in consumer goods manufacturing (textiles, footwear, tailoring, woodworking, printing and publishing, rubber products, oil milling, soap). The remaining establishments (173) are engaged in motor vehicles manufacturing, engineering and electricity repair, and metal products manufacturing. There is no doubt that in the early 1960s, Tanzania is still overwhelmingly a producer of primary commodities (Chenery, 1979). In this period, industrial establishments vary considerably in size. In most industries there are large numbers of small-scale enterprises producing for the local (rural) market, alongside a limited number of large-scale enterprises producing either for the urban markets or for export. In 1961, an industrial census year, 62 per cent of a sample of 76 of the large-scale enterprises report to be working below full capacity. Reasons for underutilization of capacity include insufficient demand, weather conditions, inadequate transport and communication facilities, inefficient use of raw materials, breakdowns and a shortage of skilled labour (Silver, 1984). These problems are typical for the initial conditions Tanzania faces when embarking on the road to import substituting industrialization in the decades to come. More generally speaking, initial conditions are rather unfavourable for rapid industrial development in Tanzania (see Chapter 12 by Lapperre, see also Szirmai, 1997a, b; Collier and Gunning, 1999). These unfavourable conditions include a large share of agriculture in employment and GDP, low productivity in the agricultural sector, poor infrastructure, low levels of general education, and lack of technical skills and human capital in the workforce. In the political sphere there is a newly established central nation state, lacking a long history of political centralization, with low levels of fiscal and managerial capabilities in the civil service. Successful industrialization in the so-called NICs is usually associated with a longer period in which industrial experience is acquired, covering some 30–40 years. Tanzania lacks an industrial heritage and a tradition of industrial entrepreneurship. As mentioned above, an indigenous entrepreneurial class is weakly developed in the Tanzanian economy. What entrepreneurship there is, is disproportionately concentrated in the Asian community of Tanzania. Infrastructure in communications, transport and energy supply is underdeveloped, hampering the logistics of newly established industrial activities. Unfavourable initial conditions for Tanzanian industrial development also include a low population density and the small size of the domestic market for industrial goods.
3
Policy periods
Identifying the periods of coherent policy which have affected the Tanzanian manufacturing sector is the next step towards the development of an analytical framework for the examination of Tanzanian industrial development between 1961 and 1995. Such periods of coherent policy can
14 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
be established in two ways: by looking at objectives and plans, or by monitoring the use of policy instruments. The first option is to look at the changes in industrial objectives and strategies as laid down in Tanzania’s development plans. A serious shortcoming of this approach is that the objectives and strategies set down in the plans may not have actually been implemented during the planning periods. There are numerous reasons why gaps between policy plans and policy implementation exist in developing countries. For instance, development plans are at times used for obtaining local and international support, leading to the formulation of propaganda documents rather than implementable plans (Todaro, 1997). Furthermore, the unstable economic and political situation of LDCs often forces governments to implement ad hoc policies, rather than carefully spelt out plans (Killick, 1976). Finally, as Gulhati (1990) points out for the African continent, policies mentioned in plans are often subverted in the process of implementation. The pitfall of distinguishing policy periods on the basis of development plan classification can be avoided by using the second option for distinguishing periods of coherent policy: by empirically monitoring the use of policy instruments over time. As there are a large number of policy instruments at a government’s disposal (for general economic classifications see Chenery, 1958; Killick, 1981; Haggblade et al., 1990), it is necessary to cluster these policy instruments in such a manner that they allow for the identification of periods of coherent policy affecting Tanzania’s manufacturing sector. Following Weiss (1988), this is done by taking four general aspects of industrial strategies in LDCs as a point of departure. These general aspects are the industrial trade strategy, the degree of direct regulatory control, the relative roles attributed to the public and the private sector, and the nature of dependence on foreign finance. 1 Policy instruments affecting the manufacturing sector (Donges, 1976; Cody et al., 1980, 1990; Kirkpatrick et al., 1984; Killick 1990; Greenaway and Milner, 1993) can be subsumed under these four general aspects of industrial strategy, resulting in the classification presented in Table 1.1. Each aspect of industrial strategy in Table 1.1 represents a dimension of which the poles represent the use of a different combinations of policy instruments. Industrial trade strategy is scaled from import substitution to export promotion; regulatory control varies from low to high degrees of control in five policy domains; the relative importance attributed to the private and the public sectors is scaled from private to public; and nature of dependence on foreign finance varies from dependence on direct foreign investment to dependence on foreign aid. Using secondary literature and statistical indicators, the implementation of policy instruments over time is monitored, in order to identify shifts along the four dimensions discussed above. These shifts can be both gradual in nature and radical. In this
Table 1.1
Classification of policy instruments according to general aspects of industrial strategies
Aspect of Industrial strategy
Scaling
Policy instruments
I.
a. Import substitution
Tariffs, import quotas, import licences, (real) exchange rate appreciation, export taxes, export licensing, export duties
b. Export promotion
Tax concessions, export credits, foreign exchange retention, export subsidies, export processing zones, (real) exchange rate depreciation
II. Degree of direct regulatory control in the areas of: a. International trade
Low/moderate/high
Import and export licensing, import quotas and prohibitions, foreign exchange allocation, exchange rate controls
b. Monetary sector
Low/moderate/high
Interest rate control, credit allocation, money supply
c. Labour
Low/moderate/high
Minimum wage legislation, immigration and emigration quotas, legislation regarding working conditions and fringe benefits
d. Ownership
Low/moderate/high
Industrial licensing, legislation regarding foreign investment
e. Prices and internal trade
Low/moderate/high
Producer and consumer price controls, confinement
Industrial trade strategy
15
16
Table 1.1
(continued)
Aspect of industrial strategy
Scaling
Policy instruments
III. Relative roles attributed to the private and the public sector
a. Private sector
Privatisation, investment incentives (tax reductions, monopoly privileges, subsidies), openness to DFI, land allocation and tenure
b. Public sector
Public enterprise investment, nationalisation, regulation of joint ventures, preferential allocation of resources, prohibitions of investment
a. direct foreign investment (DFI)
Subsidies and tax incentives for foreign investors, monopoly privileges
b. aid
Requests for aid, restrictions for private foreign investment, requirement for domestic majority shares, constraints on profit remittances and capital repatriation, exclusion from key industries, regulation of TNCs
IV. Inflow of foreign finance: relative roles attributed to
Source: van Engelen (1996). Notes: policy instruments which have been omitted are the provision of infrastructure and vocational training. Nevertheless, these unclassifiable policy instruments are taken into account in Section 5 of the paper.
Public Policy and Industrial Development 17
article, the beginning of a new policy period is defined by the occurrence of radical shifts in policy implementation along at least two of the four main policy dimensions. Applying this approach to Tanzanian industry, one can distinguish five separate periods of coherent policy. From 1961 to 1967 the Tanzanian policy climate is characterized by import substitution through foreign private investment, along with a low level of direct regulatory control. In 1967 a jump to a moderate degree of control is made, along with an abrupt shift from reliance on the foreign private sector to reliance on the public sector as the motor for industrial development. From 1973 onwards a high degree of direct regulatory control is imposed on the manufacturing sector. At the same time, a high level of dependency on foreign aid is attained. In 1984 the first shift in trade strategy is observable, from import substitution towards export promotion. Simultaneously, a shift away from a high level of direct regulatory control can be discerned. The final policy period distinguished in this paper starts in 1990. It is then that the Tanzanian government further decontrols the sector, shifts towards a higher participation in investment of private investors, whether foreign or local, and opts for an export-oriented trade strategy. Reliance on foreign aid for industrial development is considerably reduced during this policy period. Before elaborating further on the policy periods, it is important to point out that the policy instrument approach has yielded results differing substantially from a policy periodization based on development plans. On the basis of development plans, one can only distinguish four policy periods: 1961–69 (three-year development plan, TYDP; first five-year plan, FFYP); 1969–81 (second and third five-year plan SFYP, TFYP; basic industrial strategy BIS); 1981–86 (national economic survival programme, NESP; structural adjustment plan, SAP) and 1986–94 (economic recovery programme, ERP; economic and social action programme, ESAP; rolling plan forward, RPF). Furthermore, during the first four years of the third policy period (NESP, SAP) no significant changes in implemented policies affecting the manufacturing sector occur (Stein, 1991; Bagachwa and Mbelle, 1993). It would have been misleading to use these plans as indications for changes in implemented policy. It should also be noted that the development plans do not always contain policy information specific to the manufacturing sector. For instance, for the last three development plan periods it is not possible to identify the nature of foreign financial inflows (van Engelen, 1996). In the following paragraphs, the five policy periods relevant for the Tanzanian manufacturing sector are discussed in detail. 3.1
Import substitution through foreign investment (1961–67)
The first policy period starts at independence (1961) and comes to an end when the Arusha declaration is signed (1967). During this period policy
18 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
instruments are used to encourage foreign investors to engage in first-stage import substituting industrialization. Similar policy instruments had been used in the late colonial period. However, before independence policy efforts aimed at industrialization had been constrained by the agreements and the economic status quo within the East African Community. From 1961 onwards this situation changes when the Tanzanian government starts using policy instruments which offer extremely favourable investment conditions for (foreign) entrepreneurs. The granting of tariff protection is the most striking example of the use of such policy instruments. According to Rweyemamu (1973) firms could obtain tariff protection by bargaining with the government, resulting at times in effective rates of protection amounting to 500 per cent or more. On average, the production of consumer goods received the most protection (see Table 1.5), suggesting that overall protection of the manufacturing sector is in accordance with the strategy of first-stage import substitution. Other policy instruments used to attract foreign investors are guarantees against nationalization (Foreign Investment Act of 1963), land provision for the creation of industrial estates, accelerated depreciation allowances and guarantees for the repatriation of capital (Wangwe and Bagachwa, 1990). A final policy instrument used to stimulate private investment is the granting of monopoly or near monopoly power. According to Coulson (1982b) this is ‘a condition without which the multinationals in particular would not invest’. Besides tariffs, import licences and quotas are also introduced as policy instruments during the 1961–67 period (Ndulu and Semboja, 1994), giving an extra incentive to manufacturers to produce for the local market. This form of direct regulation in the area of international trade is accompanied by legislation regarding working conditions and fringe benefits. Nevertheless, the degree of direct regulatory control is still low during this policy period. The government refrains from using monetary policy instruments or exchange rate controls, and few attempts are made to curtail the freedom of action for foreign private entrepreneurs. 3.2 Nationalization, self-reliance and increased regulatory control (1967–73) The signing of the Arusha declaration in 1967 puts an end to the low level of direct regulatory control and the reliance on foreign private investors. A new policy period commences, in which Tanzania aims to become selfreliant in industrial production. Amongst others, this results in the nationalization of large (foreign owned) industrial enterprises. The emerging public sector is developed by the National Development Corporation (NDC), which has to expand very fast in order to keep pace with the nationalization process (Skarstein and Wangwe, 1986). The state’s control
Public Policy and Industrial Development 19
of the manufacturing sector is facilitated by the introduction of an industrial licensing procedure under the National Industries (Licensing and Registration) Act of 1967 (Musonda, 1992). After the Arusha declaration foreign investors can only participate in joint ventures in which the Tanzanian government is the major partner. According to Barker et al. (1986) considerable numbers of these joint ventures come into existence. Along with the nationalization and licensing procedures, other signs of direct regulatory control can be observed from 1967 onwards. In 1967 a socalled confinement strategy is introduced in which imports and exports are channelled through the State Trading Corporation (STC). Nationalization of the internal wholesale trade by the STC follows in 1971, forcing manufacturers to sell specified goods to and purchase inputs from this parastatal organisation. At the same time a modest price control system is set up under the National Price Control Advisory Board, initially controlling the prices of a very limited number of manufactured products (Maliyamkano and Bagachwa, 1990). Finally, it should be noted that the Tanzanian government controls the exchange rate. In 1967 this has few consequences. However, when Tanzanian inflation rates start rising vis-à- vis those of trading partners in the late sixties, exchange rate rigidity leads to real exchange rate appreciation (Lipumba, 1991). A real exchange rate index is presented in Table 1.2. The real exchange rate index is set at 100 in 1966, a year for which it is assumed that the nominal exchange rate is not significantly overvalued. The index is defined in such a manner that decreases indicate real exchange rate appreciation, whilst increases indicate depreciation. As the data in the table show, the real exchange rate appreciates considerably between 1967 and 1971. It recovers slightly in 1972 and 1973, but the nominal exchange rate remains overvalued. This can also be deduced from the ratio of the parallel and nominal exchange rate. Whilst the nominal exchange rate does not change between 1967 and 1973, the parallel market rate rises steadily, roughly doubling the nominal rate between 1971 and 1973. This implies exchange rate shortages, caused by the overvaluation of the nominal exchange rate. Together with continued protection through tariff barriers, import quota and import licensing, the real appreciation of the exchange rate is an incentive for import substituting industrialization. In this respect no change in observable industrial strategy occurs. The major differences between this policy period and the previous policy period are the increased degree of direct regulatory control, the change in relative roles attributed to the private and the public sector, and the decreased reliance on private foreign investment to fuel industrial development. When discussing the following policy period it will become clear that the inflow of direct private foreign investment is substituted by inflows of foreign aid.
20 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Table 1.2 Year 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994
Exchange rates: nominal, parallel, real, 1967–94
Nominal exchange rate (TSh/US$) 7.14 7.14 7.14 7.14 7.14 7.14 6.90 7.14 8.26 8.32 7.96 7.41 8.22 7.96 8.18 9.52 12.46 18.40 16.50 51.72 83.72 125.00 192.30 196.60 233.90 335.00 479.87 523.45
Parallel market rate (TSh/US$)a
Ratio parallel/ Real exchange rate nominal (%) (1966 = 100)b
8.68 8.25 9.10 10.45 15.00 15.40 13.45 14.00 25.00 20.40 15.15 11.75 13.50 23.80 26.00 30.90 39.80 80.00 125.00 160.00 180.00 210.00 245.08 309.08 384.58 422.92 506.23 560.07
1.22 1.16 1.27 1.46 2.10 2.16 1.95 1.96 3.03 2.45 1.90 1.59 1.64 2.90 3.12 3.24 3.19 4.42 7.58 3.09 2.15 1.68 1.27 1.57 1.64 1.26 1.05 1.07
90.24 76.77 68.23 69.58 70.02 71.14 74.68 78.21 70.86 74.78 72.27 68.01 70.33 59.60 51.54 47.57 46.14 42.16 41.88 60.01 87.97 103.82 131.00 148.70 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a.
Sources: Lofchie (1988); Maliyamkono and Bagachwa (1990); Musonda (1992); Tanzania Economic Trends (1994); Bank of Tanzania (1995); Economic Research Bureau of the University of Dar es Salaam, calculations made by A.V.Y. Mbelle and J.J. Semboja (1996). Notes: a Estimates of parallel rates have been made by van Engelen (1996) using sources mentioned above. b The real exchange rate index is defined as the Tanzanian inflation rate relative to that of the USA, times 100. n.a. = not available.
3.3 Dependence on foreign aid and a high degree of direct regulatory control (1973–84) A shift towards increased dependence upon foreign aid is initiated in the early 1970s, when Tanzania is able to obtain funding at favourable terms from countries such as China, Denmark, the United States, Canada, the Federal Republic of Germany and the Netherlands. During these years approximately 4 per cent of capital expenditures in manufacturing is financed by foreign aid flows. From 1975 onwards this share increases to
Public Policy and Industrial Development 21
one third of total capital expenditures. When the volume of aid inflows starts declining in the early 1980s, manufacturing can still count on a substantial share of foreign aid. Most of the aid provided between 1973 and 1984 is in the form of donor-tied capital intensive projects (World Bank, 1987a). There is an increased reliance on foreign know-how. Apart from the shift towards a higher degree of dependency on foreign aid, this policy period is characterized by the emergence of a high degree of direct regulatory control. From 1973 onwards a new import licensing system is introduced. Along with a system for the administrative allocation of foreign exchange (Finance Act of 1973), this system allows for full control of (legally) imported goods (Musonda, 1992). The allocation of the import licences to manufacturers is considered on a firm-by-firm basis, and is driven by ‘the objective of supporting fiscal revenue earners … and keeping most existing enterprises alive, on the one hand, and by particular pressures, representations and ad-hoc decisions on the other’ (World Bank, 1987a). The resulting allocation pattern is presented in Table 1.3, which shows that from 1979 onwards the manufacturing sector can on average count on being allocated less than one fifth of the requested amounts of foreign exchange for the purchase of raw materials, machinery and spares from abroad. In 1981 no foreign exchange at all is made available for the importation of machinery and spares for manufacturing purposes. The same is true for raw material imports for manufacturing during the first six months of 1984. Another way in which the government augments the degree of direct regulatory control of the manufacturing sector is by introducing a full-scale Table 1.3 Allocation of foreign exchange, 1977–1984 (as percentage of amounts requested) Foreign exchange requested for: Industrial raw materials Raw materials (manufacturing) Petroleum Machinery Spares Machinery & spares (manufacturing) Transport % of total requests allocated
1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984a 43 60
52 51
24 22
14 41
17 14
16 11
n.a. 15
n.a. 0
100 26 44 29
100 23 43 29
93 1 14 12
71 0 17 16
67 7 20 0
89 3 1 5
n.a. n.a. n.a. 11
n.a. n.a. n.a. 16
37
35
13
10
8
2
n.a.
n.a.
50
52
38
32
31
33
n.a.
n.a.
Sources: manufacturing data from Mbelle (1988); all other data from World Bank (1984). Notes: a The 1984 data concern the January–June period. n.a. = not available.
22 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
price control system (Price Control Act of 1973). Price controls are introduced with the dual purpose of limiting the monopoly pricing power of domestic producers, and at the same time ensuring that these producers are guaranteed satisfactory financial profitability (Mongi, 1980). For the domestic producers the financial profitability is taken care of by the use of a costplus pricing method, allowing for a 30 per cent pre-tax rate of return on assets. The price of imported goods is set using a fixed percentage mark-up (Maliyamkono and Bagachwa, 1990). Trends in the numbers of price-controlled products can be derived from Table 1.4. As a result of a government directive, the number of price-controlled items is reduced from 1980 onwards (United Republic of Tanzania, 1983). Nevertheless, until 1985 almost all consumer goods, a significant number of agricultural intermediate inputs and various construction materials, such as iron sheets, rolled steel and cement, remain price controlled. Apart from import licensing and price control, the government uses confinement as yet another policy instrument to ensure a high degree of direct regulatory control over the manufacturing sector. As described in the discussion of the previous policy period, trade is confined to the State Trading Corporation STC. In order to perform more effectively the STC is decentralized and reorganized in 1973. The STC’s tasks are taken over by 6 parastatal importing companies and 18 regional trading companies (Musonda, 1992). Up to 1984 wholesale (and a part of retail) trade is confined to these trading companies. According to the World Bank (1987a) this ‘has been associated with poor service, lack of payments and high marketing costs’. The three policy instruments mentioned above not only allow for increased control of the manufacturing sector. They also allow the government to provide protection to the locally based industries. Import licensing restricts competitive imports from entering the country, whilst the price controls and the confinement system raise the prices of imported products Table 1.4 ucts)
Price controlled items, 1973–91 (product groups and separate prod-
Controls
1973
1979
1982
Total number of items locally produced imported Total number of products locally produced imported
n.a. 329 72 n.a. 154 54 n.a. 175 18 1 000 1 031 333 n.a. 456 241 n.a. 575 92
1983
1986
1987
1988
1991
56 50 6 225 216 9
21 21 0 107 107 0
22 22 0 83 83 0
12 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a.
2 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a.
Sources: 1973 data from World Bank (1984); 1979–1988 data from Kiondo (1991); 1991 data from World Bank (1991). Note: Items are groups of separate products; n.a. = not available.
Public Policy and Industrial Development 23
relative to domestic products, and limit their distribution opportunities. Along with an increasingly overvalued exchange rate (see Table 1.2), which discourages exports and lowers the price of imported inputs, this results in the continuation of the import substitution trade strategy which prevailed during the first two policy periods. By 1984, the overvalued exchange rate and the price controls have resulted in extremely high effective rates of protection (ERPs). In Table 1.5 ERP calculations are presented for 1966, 1984 and 1986. In 1984, the effective rate of protection for the total manufacturing sector is no less than 470 per cent. A comparison of selected industries in 1966 and 1984, indicates the dramatic increases in levels of protection (from 134 per cent to 526 per cent for the total sample of industries). It also shows that a shift in protection has occurred. In 1966 protection is clearly in favour of consumer good manufacturers. By 1984 producers of intermediate and capital goods can count on degrees of protection which are at least as high as the ERPs for consumer good manufacturers. From 1981 onwards the first attempts are made to counterbalance the strong incentives towards import substitution. In that year an export rebate scheme (ERS) is introduced, which is to serve as an export subsidy for the producers of manufactured and horticultural commodities. The scheme compensates exporters for losses incurred by selling at world market prices, and also compensates them for duty and sales taxes on imported inputs. Along with the ERS a presidential award is introduced for the best performing exporter. The winner of this award is given preferential treatment with regard to the acquisition of scarce resources. The most important export incentive introduced during this policy period is the general retention scheme (GRS) of 1983. This scheme allows exporters to retain between 10 and 100 per cent of the foreign exchange they earn, for the purpose of importing inputs (Board of External Trade, 1989). On average, however, the export incentives are not very effective, since they lack the desired degree of comprehensiveness to stimulate the export sector adequately (World Bank, 1987a). In short, there is no reason to conclude that a shift away from import substitution is initiated in 1981. Neither is there any indication that substantial shifts occur in the relative roles attributed to the private and the public sector. The emphasis remains on the development of the public sector, at the expense of the private sector. In the words of Henley and Assaf (1993), ‘until … 1986 the private sector is crowded out of official thinking, access to loan capital and foreign exchange allocations’. The systems of credit allocation and foreign exchange allocation are interdependent. Both serve to ensure the survival of existing large-scale publicly owned firms. Apart from credit priority, the public sector can also count on lower interest rates than the private sector. High inflation rates and a policy of interest rate rigidity mean that real interest rates for the public and the private sector are negative between
24
Table 1.5
Effective rates of protection in manufacturing, 1966, 1984 and 1986 (%)
Industry
1966
1984
Canned fruits and vegetables Soft drinks Beer Tobacco Textiles Sisal and jute bags Tanning and leather Footwear Pharmaceutical products Soap
184 –24 187 528 269 1 130 123 0 151
335 5 1 300 317 240 inf inf inf 2 952 5 258
Tyres and tubes Glass products Paper products Cement Metal products
270 31 26 12 95
59 424 6 682 101 inf
Sample average
134
526
Branch
1984
1986
Food products Beverages and tobacco
53 172
65 84
Textiles
811
55
inf
41
1 762
45
inf 309
2 28
3 780 1 347 470
28 25 n.a.
Tanneries and leather Plastics and pharmaceuticals Chemicals and fertilizers Rubber, glass, wood, paper and cement
Iron, steel and metal products Machinery and transport equipment Sectoral average
Sources: 1966 data from Rweyemamu (1973); 1984 data from World Bank (1987a); 1986 data from Ndulu et al. (1987). Notes: inf = infinite; n.a. = not available.
Public Policy and Industrial Development 25
1973 and 1984. Nominal interest rate rigidity, preferential credit allocation and interest rate discrimination once again emphasize the high degree of direct regulatory control which prevails throughout this policy period. 3.4
Decontrol and the shift away from import substitution (1984–90)
The introduction of the own funds import scheme in June 1984 marks a radical change in government policy. It marks the end of 11 years of full scale direct regulatory control of the manufacturing sector. The scheme encourages Tanzanian citizens to obtain foreign exchange on the parallel foreign exchange market, from friends, family, accounts abroad and from foreign investors, so that imports can be financed without making use of official foreign exchange (Bank of Tanzania, 1988). In Table 1.6 the various sources of foreign exchange are presented. The table shows that within two years the own funds import scheme has become the largest foreign exchange window. Administration of an own funds import licence is not subject to bureaucratic procedures, and the imports under the scheme are not subjected to any price controls or confinement rules. Due to the magnitude of the own funds window, these conditions imply that considerable trade liberalization takes place. This trade liberalization is only partial, since not all goods are allowed to be imported. Nevertheless, the decontrol of trade marks a jump in policy. Partial liberalization of imports funded with official foreign exchange follows in February 1988, when the open general licence (OGL) is introduced. The foreign exchange available through this window is provided by the World Bank and other donors, and serves to finance high priority imports. It is allocated on a non-discretionary and automatic basis, Table 1.6 Magnitudes of foreign exchange windows, 1984–92 (% of total foreign exchange available) Year
Free resourcesa
Own fundsb
Export retention
Loans/ grants
Import support
OGLc
Barter
1984 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992
35.3 26.1 32.5 18.6 29.1 22.3 13.7 *
19.4 37.2 34.6 35.0 26.3 26.1 28.7 27.3
– 0.1 0.2 0.4 1.1 n.a. 4.6 n.a.
33.4 27.6 23.6 33.5 23.0 24.3 20.8 22.2
6.7 8.2 8.2 9.2 11.1 9.1 4.8 2.6
– – – 2.7 9.1 18.0 27.0 47.4
5.2 0.8 0.9 0.6 0.3 0.2 0.4 0.5
Source: Lipumba and Mbelle (1993). Notes: a The 1992 figure is included under the open general license (OGL). b The 1984 own funds figure covers the period July–December. c The 1988 figure covers the months February–December. The 1992 figure includes free resources; n.a. = not available.
26 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
provided that an importer adheres to the conditions of utilization (legal business premises, minimum limit, red-list of forbidden imports is observed, 100 per cent cash cover up front). Major advantages of the OGL are less bureaucratic procedures and guaranteed utilization once the licence has been approved (de Valk, 1992). From Table 1.6 it can be seen that the use of the OGL rapidly increases. However, during this policy period, which ends in 1990, the own funds import scheme remains the most used (partially) decontrolled foreign exchange window. Decontrol does not remain limited to foreign exchange allocation. As Table 1.4 shows, between 1983 and 1986 the number of domestic products which are price controlled is halved, and the price control of imported products is abolished. By 1991 only two items (fertilizer and petroleum products) are still price controlled, compared to 56 items in 1983. These two items are also the only two items which remain confined after 1991. Thus, the trend towards decontrol can also be observed with regard to the system of confinement. Between 1984 and 1989 a large number of exemptions from the confinement system are granted. In 1989 the system of confinement is almost entirely abolished. The level of regulatory control is further reduced by the government’s decision to abandon the policy of nominal exchange rate rigidity. Table 1.2 shows that from 1986 onwards the nominal exchange rate is continuously devalued, resulting in real exchange rate depreciation. In 1985 the real index has reached its lowest point, 41.9, after which it steadily increases. In 1990 the real exchange rate index equals 148.7. This implies that price competitiveness of Tanzanian manufactured exports has improved, relative to the base year 1966. The continuous devaluation of the exchange rate provides increasing incentives for Tanzanian manufacturers to produce for the export market. Further incentives for export production are provided by decreases in effective rates of protection. Devaluation of the exchange rate and price decontrol are among the reasons why production for the domestic market becomes less attractive. According to the World Bank (1991) the own funds import scheme is also of importance in this respect: ‘the own funds import policy exposes the industrial sector virtually overnight to a trade regime in which levels of protection have fallen dramatically. Average levels of effective protection for industry decline from about 500% in early 1984 to about 150 per cent in 1985, and some firms become effectively disprotected’. The decline in protection through price controls, import licensing, confinement and cheap imported inputs because of overvalued exchange rates means tariffs once again become the main instrument by which manufacturing is still protected. Table 1.5 shows what the effective rates of protection would be in 1986, if tariffs were the only means of protection. As can be deduced from the table, (hypothetical) ERPs have dropped
Public Policy and Industrial Development 27
considerably since 1984, ranging from 2 to 84 per cent at the branch level in 1986. Furthermore, a shift in relative protection has taken place in favour of the manufacturers of consumer goods. These conclusions should be drawn with some caution, though. In 1986 the exchange rate is still overvalued, and price controls, import licensing and confinement are still used as policy instruments. It is more likely that the 1986 ERPs in Table 1.5 are good approximations for ERPs in 1988. By then the 1973–84 system of protection is almost fully dismantled. The remaining protection from this system is cancelled out by tariff reductions (Musonda, 1992), tariff evasions and exemptions (see also the 1990–95 policy period on this issue). A final incentive for production for export is given by the introduction of several export promotion schemes. In 1986 a new retention scheme replaces the general retention scheme described in the previous section. Under the new scheme, producers of non-traditional exports products are granted a 50 per cent retention rate. In 1985 the seed capital revolving scheme (SCRS) is introduced. Under this scheme a producer is provided with foreign exchange when starting production for the export market. Between 1985 and 1989 the number of manufacturers which benefits from the scheme rises from 18 to 51 (Ndulu and Semboja, 1996). Yet another incentive for export-oriented production is provided by commodity exchange programmes (CEPs), which allow manufacturers of export products to exchange their goods for raw materials and spare parts from abroad. Finally, the export duty drawback scheme (DDS) is established for manufacturers of exports, compensating them for the import duties they have to pay when acquiring foreign inputs (Mbatia, 1993). Apart from the decrease in direct regulatory control and the shift in the industrial trade strategy, no other significant changes occur in the other dimensions of policy during this policy period. With regard to foreign financial inflows, there is actually an increase in foreign aid flows to Tanzania and to Tanzanian industry. From 1987 to 1989 the share of official development assistance (ODA) in GDP rises from 25.5 to no less than 32.3 per cent (Szirmai, 1997a, table 12.6). UNDP data show that the share of total industry in external assistance rises from 7.8 per cent in 1986 to 24.8 per cent in 1989 (Table 1.7). From table 1.7 it becomes evident that external assistance is increasingly provided in the form of financial transfers, rather than in the form of technical assistance (transfer of skills and technology). This change in emphasis should be understood in the context of attempts to ameliorate the financial position of the often heavily indebted public enterprises (Agrawal et al., 1993). Apart from supporting public enterprises through aid inflows, the predominance of the public sector is also enhanced by continued lending (at negative real interest rates) by the government owned banking sector: ‘the financial sector has continued to lend to ailing firms, particularly
28 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Table 1.7 External assistance to Tanzania and the Tanzanian manufacturing sector 1986–94 (US$ m) Year
1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994
Total external assistance (1)
Assistance to industrya (2)
Ratio (%)
670.1 814.9 905.5 905.0 956.2 1 059.9 1 112.7 905.4 895.0
52.6 81.8 112.1 224.6 163.5 171.7 109.0 48.9 10.7
7.8 10.0 12.4 24.8 17.1 16.2 9.8 5.4 1.2
(2/1)
Technical assistance to industryb (3) 25.9 25.0 24.8 26.0 14.8 29.8 32.2 8.1 3.2
Ratio (%) (3/2) 49.3 30.6 22.0 11.6 9.0 17.4 29.5 16.5 30.0
Source: United Nations Development Programme (various issues). Notes: a For the years 1989–94 industry includes manufacturing, construction and mining; for the years 1986–1988 industry also includes the energy sector. b Technical assistance is defined as activities undertaken to promote economic and social development and well-being by enhancing human and institutional capacities through the transfer, adoption, mobilization and utilization of skills and technology.
parastatals, many of which are in serious arrears. The public manufacturing sector … draws about 70% of the total loans to the industrial sector’ (World Bank, 1991) – Furthermore, public enterprises are also favoured regarding exemptions from duty and sales taxes, emphasizing once again the importance of the development of the public sector in the minds of policy makers. Incentives for the stimulation of private entrepreneurship cannot be discerned between 1984 and 1990. In sum, in spite of marked changes in the trade regime and regulation in this period, the dependence on foreign finance increases and the state sector remains predominant. 3.5 Continued liberalization, export promotion, private (foreign) entrepreneurship and decreased inflows of foreign aid (1990–95) During the final policy period the private sector is rediscovered by policy makers. In 1990 the government passes the National Investment (Promotion and Protection) Act (NIA), an act which acknowledges the importance of the private sector. By providing tax holidays, customs duty exemptions, foreign exchange retention possibilities, constitutional safeguards against expropriation and guarantees against nationalization without compensation, the government attempts to encourage foreign and local private investment in industry. Additionally an institutional investment framework is established: the Investment Promotion Centre (Tanzania Economic Trends, 1990). Priority areas for investment are mostly
Public Policy and Industrial Development 29
consumer goods industries, steel and metal engineering, cement and ceramics, bottles and glassware, paints and automotive engineering industries. Iron and steel production, machine tool manufacturing and chemical and pesticides production are designated to remain controlled by public enterprises (United Republic of Tanzania, 1990b). In 1992 and 1994 the NIA is amended to allow for slight expansions of the incentive package (United Republic of Tanzania, 1992a, b, 1994). Along with the stimulation of the private sector, the government sets out to reform the parastatal sector. The legal basis is provided by the Public Corporations Act of 1992, which is amended in the same year to allow for the establishment of the Presidential Parastatal Sector Reform Commission. This commission is empowered to decide which public enterprises should be retained, privatized or wound up. Up to 1 January 1995, 40 of the 170 manufacturing parastatals are divested, of which six are closed down (United Republic of Tanzania, 1995a). Furthermore, as a consequence of the liberalisation of the financial sector in 1991 (Bank of Tanzania, 1992), the parastatal sector can no longer count on preferential treatment regarding credit allocation. Since the banking system is forced to operate on commercial principles, negative real interest rates also belong to the past, again implying that from 1990 onwards the public manufacturing sector faces a changing policy environment. Apart from the liberalisation of the monetary sector and liberalisation of private investment, there is also further liberalisation of the trade regime. As Table 1.4 shows, price control is no longer operative as a means of direct regulatory control from 1991 onwards. Table 1.2 indicates that the nominal exchange rate is depreciated to such an extent that by 1994 nominal and parallel market rates no longer differ significantly. This is caused by the liberalisation of the foreign exchange market under the Foreign Exchange Act of 1992. This act enables the setting up of ‘bureaux de change’, which are allowed to sell and buy foreign exchange at freely determined market rates. As a result of the liberalisation of trade, Tanzanian manufacturers are to rely on the tax system for protection against foreign competition. However, as a document prepared by the Textile Manufacturing Association of Tanzania (TEXTMAT, 1994a) shows, the tax system performs poorly in this respect. Import duty collection rates are far below official tariff rates, implying large scale exemptions and evasions of taxes on imported goods (TEXTMAT, 1994a). The report concludes that importers manage to evade both import and sales taxes on a large scale. A confidential 1995 study by the World Bank and the Tanzanian government would, if published, shed more light on the magnitude of exemptions and evasions. The fact alone that such a study has been carried out shows that the threat to Tanzanian firms manufacturing for the domestic market from untaxed imports is being taken seriously.
30 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
From 1990 to 1995 further decreases in protection due to tax exemptions and evasions do not stimulate production for the local market. However, production for the export market is stimulated, resulting in a situation in which export promotion has become the dominant industrial trade strategy. Production for the export market is stimulated during this policy period by further devaluation of the nominal exchange rate and by several export promotion schemes (see National Investment Act and previous policy period). Additionally the Bank of Tanzania introduces the export credit guarantee scheme (ECGS) in 1990. This scheme is designed to encourage pre- and post-shipment credit provision to exporters of non-traditional exports. The final criterion distinguishing this policy period from the previous one is the decreasing flow of foreign aid to the manufacturing sector. Total aid flows to Tanzania start declining, after peaking in 1992. The share of industry in total external assistance decreases rapidly from 1990 onwards (see Table 1.7). In 1990 this share amounts to 17.1 per cent. It drops to 9.8 per cent in 1992, and declines further to 1.2 per cent or US$10.7 m in 1994. These data show that foreign aid no longer plays a significant role in industrial policy. In terms of reliance on foreign financial inflows, the emphasis is once again on private foreign investment. 3.6
Overview of the policy periods (1961–95)
The characteristics of the five policy periods which have been distinguished are summarised in Table 1.8.
4
Synthesis of external influences and policy periods
An overview of the external influences affecting the performance of the Tanzanian manufacturing sector is the final step towards the completion of the analytical framework used in this paper. Two types of external influences are distinguished: changes in the macroeconomic environment in Tanzania and influences external to the Tanzanian economy. Changes in the external environment can take the form of shocks or of more gradual changes. Both kinds of changes in the external environment provide challenges to which industrial policy may or may not respond. If there are changes in external influences which are not accompanied by policy responses, the periodization presented in Table 1.8 needs to be refined. This is the case for the period 1980–84, when the policy regime shows no change, while the macroeconomic situation deteriorates dramatically. When changes in the external environment of manufacturing are followed at short notice by changes in policy implementation, no changes in the periodization are required. An example of the latter situation is the Arusha declaration of 1967, which was followed by nationalization of large
Table 1.8
Overview of policy periods
Aspect of industrial strategy Import substitution (IS)/export promotion (EP) Degree of direct control (low/moderate/high) Private ownership (priv.)/public ownership (publ.) Relative inflows of foreign investment (DFI) and aid
1961–67
1967–73
1973–84
1984–90
1990–95
IS low priv. DFI
IS moderate priv. → publ. DFI → aid
IS high publ. aid
IS → EP moderate publ. aid
EP low publ. → priv. aid → DFI
31
32 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
scale enterprises and other measures signalling a turn towards a centrally planned economy. Table 1.9 presents macro-indicators for the total Tanzanian economy. This table indicates that up to 1973 the macroeconomic situation in Tanzania is relatively stable. According to Ndulu (1993) this is facilitated by the ‘relatively benign’ external environment the country faces. The negotiations regarding industrial investment between Tanzania and the other partner states of the East African Community are an example of this relatively benign environment. Thus, in 1964 it is agreed that Tanzania has the sole right to the manufacturing of radios, motor tyres and tubes, and aluminium foil, circles and plain sheets for the East African market (Gulhati and Sekhar, 1982). Furthermore, during this period the world economy and world trade are growing at historically unprecedented rates. The first worldwide oil crisis takes place in 1973. This causes the Tanzanian current account deficit as a percentage of GDP to rise from 6.5 per cent in 1973 to 14.3 per cent in 1974. Simultaneously, inflation rates rise from 7.6 per cent in 1972 to 27.0 per cent in 1975. Thanks to policy measures and the coffee boom of 1977, Tanzania initially manages to stabilize the external and internal imbalances (Green et al., 1980). Inflation decreases to 6.9 per cent in 1976, and the current account deficit shrinks to 9.5 per cent of GDP in 1975 and 1.3 per cent of GDP in 1976. However, in 1978 the current account deficit increases substantially again to 12.7 per cent of GDP. This time the external imbalances are less manageable. Reasons for the second balance of payments crisis include the dissolution of the East African Community in 1977, the second oil crisis of 1979, the war with Uganda in 1979, severe droughts and deteriorating terms of trade. Inflation rates are on the rise again from 1979 onwards. In 1980 a 30.3 per cent inflation rate is recorded, setting the standard for inflation over the next fifteen years. Most important, it should be noted that macroeconomic growth comes to a halt in 1981. In this year a negative real growth rate of –0.5 per cent is experienced, followed by close to zero growth in 1982 and another year of negative real growth (–2.4 per cent) in 1983. Negative real growth rates, high inflation rates and current account deficits clearly show that the Tanzanian economy is in crisis from 1980 onwards. The crisis years are highlighted in Table 1.9. The crisis persists up to 1984, the year in which the own funds import scheme is introduced (see Section 3.4). From then onwards positive real growth rates of GDP are recorded. Nevertheless, inflation rates remain high and current account deficits start rising again in 1986. Between 1986 and 1993, deficits of 10 to 12 per cent of GDP are not uncommon. Obviously, external and internal imbalances persist after the crisis. Within this context it is important to point out the worsening of Tanzania’s debt position. Total debt rises from 74 per cent of GDP in 1985 to 241 per cent of GDP in 1993. The relatively low levels of indebtedness during the crisis years
Indicators of changes in the external environment of the Tanzanian manufacturing sector, 1970–94
Year
GDP growth rate (%)a
Inflation (%)b
Curr. acc./GDP (%)c
Terms of Trade (1987 = 100)c
Debt/GDP (%)c
GDP growth 9 African Economiesd
1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997
4.0 3.5 6.3 2.8 1.3 5.1 6.1 0.4 2.1 2.4 3.0 –0.5 0.6 –2.4 3.4 4.6 6.6 5.9 4.8 2.2 7.1 2.8 1.6 –0.6 1.2 3.2 4.6 3.2
3.1 5.0 7.6 10.6 18.4 27.0 6.9 11.4 6.6 12.9 30.3 25.7 28.9 27.1 36.1 33.3 32.4 30.0 31.2 30.4 35.9 28.8 21.9 25.2 34.1
–3.1 –8.0 –4.6 –6.5 –14.3 –9.5 –1.3 –2.3 –12.7 –8.8 –11.4 –7.7 –8.7 –5.5 –7.4 –6.6 –8.1 –16.1 –11.6 –10.5 –12.5 –11.9 –12.2 –12.8 n.a.
n.a. n.a. n.a. 145.7 173.6 142.0 151.7 182.0 151.9 138.7 142.0 129.0 127.1 128.0 131.0 126.1 140.5 100.0 107.2 103.2 92.6 93.8 84.7 n.a. n.a.
n.a. n.a. n.a. 34.2 43.1 48.3 56.2 60.5 62.2 64.3 65.0 58.3 55.4 64.1 77.2 74.0 123.6 211.4 188.0 171.1 202.1 188.5 210.9 240.9 n.a.
9.1 5.3 2.5 5.0 6.5 1.4 5.8 4.3 1.4 4.6 5.1 2.0 2.1 –1.3 3.7 4.1 3.9 1.9 5.3 3.2 2.2 1.4 –0.6 n.a n.a
Notes: a Source: Bureau of Statistics (1995a, 1995b, 1995e, 1999). b Source: Bank of Tanzania (various issues). c Source: World Bank (various issues). d Source: Maddison (1995). n.a. = not available.
33
Table 1.9
34 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
(1980–84) reflect the drying up of external financial flows due to disagreements with the IMF concerning economic reforms. On the basis of the preceding analysis of the changes in the external environment of the manufacturing sector one may conclude that industrial entrepreneurs operate in a relatively stable macroeconomic climate prior to the early 1970s. During the mid- and late 1970s the first signs of external and internal imbalance can be distinguished, and from 1980 to 1984 Tanzania suffers a severe economic crisis. This crisis is characterized by negative real growth rates of GDP and external and internal imbalances. Growth rates pick up from the mid-1980s onwards, but external and internal imbalances persist well into the 1990s. Calling to mind the periods distinguished in Table 1.8, it becomes apparent that an additional period of analysis is to be introduced if external influences on the sector are to be taken into account. This is the crisis period 1980–84. Although no changes in policy implementation occur during these years, the macroeconomic situation changes to such an extent that it is useful to make this distinction. Thus, the analytical framework drawn up to explain Tanzanian manufacturing development is characterized by six periods with differing combinations of implemented policies and external circumstances. These are summarized in Table 1.10.
5
Tanzanian industrial development: trends and explanations
In this section the framework drawn up in the previous sections is used to analyse trends in manufacturing development. It will be shown that turning points and breaks in trends in manufacturing growth, productivity or structure coincide to a considerable extent with the six periods of analysis presented in Table 1.10. As may be expected, there is not always a oneto-one relationship between the beginning of a new period and a trend change. There may be lags caused by the time it takes for implemented policies to take effect or external influences to exert their impact. Nevertheless, close relationships can be observed between the periods defined and the changes in manufacturing trends. On the basis of the analysis of the periods, it can be argued that public policy has been one of the important factors determining the development and performance of the Tanzanian manufacturing sector. The following four figures provide a picture of long-run trends in manufacturing performance in Tanzania. Figure 1.1 presents the changing share of total manufacturing in national income. Figure 1.2 reproduces a newly revised index of manufacturing value added in constant prices for the period 1961–95 (see Chapter 3). The index refers to the formal sector and excludes establishments with less than ten persons engaged. In the long run, one can distinguish a period of rapid growth from a very low level
Table 1.10
Periods of analysis
Characteristics Industrial strategy IS/EP Control Priv./public DFI/aid Macroeconomic situation
1961–67
1967–73
1973–80
1980–84
1984–90
1990–95
IS low priv DFI
IS moderate priv. → publ. DFI → aid
IS high publ. aid
IS high publ. aid
IS → EP moderate publ. aid
EP low publ. → priv. aid → DFI
relatively stable
relatively stable
first signs of imbalance
crisis
internal and external imbalance
internal and external imbalance
35
36 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Figure 1.1
The share of manufacturing value added in GDP (%)
14 12
MVA/GDP (%)
10 8 6 4 2
0 1964 1966 1968 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 Year Sources: Bureau of Statistics (1995a, 1995b, 1995e).
Figure 1.2 Index of manufacturing gross value added, 1961–95 (establishments with 10 or more persons engaged, 1976 = 100) 120
Index
100
80
60
40
20
0 1961 1963 1965 1967 1969 1971 1973 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995
Year Source: Chapter 3.
Public Policy and Industrial Development 37 Figure 1.3 Index of manufacturing labour productivity, 1965–90 (establishments with 10 or more persons engaged, 1976 = 100) 120 100
Index
80 60
40
20
0 1965
1967 1969 1971 1973 1975 1977 1979 1982 1983 1985 1987
1989
Year Source: Chapter 3.
from 1961 to 1978, a period of collapse from 1978 to 1985 and a period of uncertain stabilization from 1985 to 1995. Figure 1.3 presents an index of labour productivity in constant Tanzanian shillings using the output series of Figure 1.2 and newly revised employment series (see Chapter 3). This figure illustrates the secular decline in productivity after 1973. Figure 1.4 puts Tanzanian manufacturing productivity in comparative perspective. This figure derives from a level comparison between Tanzania and the world productivity leader, the USA, for 1989 (see Chapter 3). The binary comparison is based on the calculation of industry of origin unit value ratios, which are used to convert Tanzanian gross value added for purposes of international comparison. In this paper, the benchmark comparison is extrapolated using national time series of GDP per person. For Tanzania, we used the series described in the source notes to Figure 1.2; for the USA we used national accounts series (see Timmer and Szirmai, 1999). One of the interesting results documented in Figure 1.4 is that relative labour productivity in Tanzania shows secular decline from a rather high initial level. Having started at around 9 per cent of US levels in 1965, comparative labour productivity increases until 1973, starts to decline after that year and falls to 3.7 per cent in 1987. In the following paragraphs, each period of analysis is discussed in terms of the interrelatedness of policy, external influences and manufacturing
38 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Figure 1.4 Comparative labour productivity in Tanzanian manufacturing, 1965–90 (USA = 100) 12
Tanzania/USA (%)
10 8 6 4 2 0 1965 1967 1969 1971 1973 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 Year Sources: 1989 benchmark from Szirmai et al. (Chapter 3); index of GDP per person in Tanzania from Figure 1.2; GDP per person in USA from national accounts sources (see Chapter 3).
performance. Within this context the effects of infrastructural constraints and low levels of industrial skills are also mentioned. 5.1
1961–67
Between 1961 and 1967 the growth performance of the manufacturing sector is impressive. Double-digit growth rates of real value added are recorded for the whole sector, causing the share of manufacturing value added in GDP to rise to 10.2 per cent in 1967 (Figure 1.1). During this period the index of real value added for enterprises with ten or more persons engaged rises 68 per cent (from 22 to 37; see Figure 1.2), and there are also increases in labour productivity (see Figure 1.3). Between 1965 and 1967 one can also discern some catch-up in labour productivity levels vis-àvis the world productivity leader, the USA (Figure 1.4). The investment thrust necessary to raise output and labour productivity levels is mainly provided by foreign owned firms. As Perkins (1983) emphazises, many of the new firms established after 1961 are owned by transnational corporations (TNCs), or their Kenyan subsidiaries. In 1965 no more than 32 per cent of all industrial firms are exclusively owned by Tanzanians. The predominance of private foreign owned firms can be explained by the negotiations within the East African Community
Public Policy and Industrial Development 39
(see Section 4), and even more by the policy climate prevailing at the time. As described in Section 3.1, between 1961 and 1967 policy instruments are used to encourage private foreign investment. The most notable incentives are the granting of monopoly or near monopoly power and tariff protection. As pointed out in Section 3.1, tariff protection results in high effective rates of protection, especially for the manufacturers of consumer and intermediate goods. Changes in degrees of import substitution and changes in industrial structure can be explained in this context. Table 1.11 presents data on trends in the total supply of manufactured goods in Tanzania. The total manufactured supply (TMS) is defined as the sum of locally produced goods (for the domestic market, DM and exports, EXP) and imported goods, IMP. A declining IMP/TMS ratio, combined with a rising DM/TMS ratio, implies that imports are being substituted for locally manufactured goods.2 Table 1.11 confirms that import substitution is taking place between 1961 and 1965. From the last three columns of the table it can be seen that import substitution is primarily taking place in the consumer goods sector, and to a lesser extent in the intermediate goods sector. This coincides with the structural changes taking place in the share of branches in gross value added (10+). As Table 1.12 shows, the shares of consumer goods (ISIC 31 and 32) and intermediate goods (ISIC 33, 34, 35 and 36) in manufacturing value added rise between 1965 and 1967, whilst the share of capital goods declines. These changes can be traced back to the pattern of effective protection (Table 1.5), which stimulates (foreign) entrepreneurs to invest in consumer and intermediate good import-substitution activities. 5.2
1967–73
Between 1967 and 1973 the role private foreign investors play in the development of the manufacturing sector is considerably reduced. From 1967 onwards the public sector provides the main development thrust, as can be deduced from the rising shares of the public sector in total manufacturing value added and total manufacturing employment. In 1966 the public sector accounts for only 5 per cent of total value added. This percentage has increased to 32 per cent by 1973. The share of public sector employment in total manufacturing employment rises from 15.5 per cent in 1967 to 46.7 per cent in 1973 (Skarstein and Wangwe, 1986). These major changes are realized through the nationalization of private enterprises and by public investment in additional capacity. Public investment in manufacturing peaks in 1970, when the share of the public sector in total manufacturing investment reaches 63.7 per cent. 3 Thereafter, the rate of public investment in manufacturing slows down, since, as the World Bank (1988) puts it, ‘little is left to nationalize [and] fewer joint ventures are established’.
40
Table 1.11
Import substitution of manufactured goods, 1961–90
Year
1961 1965 1973 1980 1984 1990
Total manufactured supply
Domestic market/total manufactured supply
Domestic market (%)
Exports (%)
Imports (%)
Consumer (%)
Intermediate (%)
Capital (%)
29.6 36.0 42.5 50.9 58.6 46.6
8.2 7.8 6.4 6.6 5.7 8.5
62.2 56.2 51.1 42.5 36.3 44.9
50.0 59.5 72.2 81.2 87.4 89.4
25.7 32.1 39.8 55.2 58.6 47.1
16.4 16.6 21.4 24.3 23.7 27.7
Sources: 1961–73 data from World Bank (1987a); 1980–90 data calculated from United Republic of Tanzania (1995c).
Public Policy and Industrial Development 41 Table 1.12 Structure of medium- and large-scale manufacturing gross value added, 1965–95 (%) Year
31a
32b
33/34c
35d
36e
37/38/39 f
1965 1967 1973 1980 1984 1990 1995
32.4 26.4 26.8 21.4 31.9 44.2 51.4
23.0 33.2 36.1 33.9 25.4 14.8 12.2
10.4 9.9 7.2 9.9 9.5 9.9 12.8
6.2 11.5 10.6 15.4 14.4 13.1 11.9
1.5 4.6 3.3 3.3 2.1 3.1 3.7
26.5 14.3 16.0 16.1 16.7 14.7 7.8
Source: Prins and Szirmai (1998). Notes: a Food, beverages and tobacco. b Textiles and leather. c Wood products, furnishing and fixtures, paper products, printing and publishing. d Chemicals, petroleum, rubber and plastic products. e Non-metallic mineral products. f Metals, machinery and equipment and others.
The shift in the relative importance attached to the public and the private sector finds its origin in the Arusha declaration. The subsequent change in the use of policy instruments (industrial licensing, nationalization, regulation of joint ventures) explains the growth of the public sector. As documented in Figures 1.1 and 1.2, the increasing importance of the public sector has been accompanied by accelerating growth of value added and increased shares of manufacturing in GDP. The period 1967–73 records the most rapid growth of 10+ manufacturing value added in the history of Tanzania. This growth in value added is accompanied by absolute and relative labour productivity growth (Figures 1.3 and 1.4). In 1973 labour productivity is 44 per cent higher than in 1967. The process of import substitution continues throughout this period. By 1973, 42.5 per cent of the total manufactured supply is produced for the domestic market, whilst 51.1 per cent is imported (Table 1.11). In 1965 these percentages were respectively 36.0 per cent and 56.2 per cent. Again, most import substitution is taking place in the consumer and intermediate goods sector, as is to be expected, given the pattern of tariff protection. Along with other policy instruments (overvaluation of the exchange rate, import licensing and import quota), the tariff barriers explain the continued import substitution taking place. 5.3
1973–80
In terms of industrial performance, 1973 marks an important trend break. From 1973 onwards, labour productivity in 10+ manufacturing enterprises starts declining steadily (see Figure 1.3). The labour productivity index drops from 110 in 1973 to 75 in 1980, a decline of 5.3 per cent per year.
42 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
Comparative labour productivity declines from its peak value of 11 per cent to 7.2 per cent of the US level. There have been declines in value added between 1973–75 and 1978–80, but the index of manufacturing value added in 1980 is higher than that in 1973, indicating a net expansion of output over the whole period (see Figure 1.2). Given the fact that between 1973 and 1980 investments are largely taking place in capital intensive projects (Perkins, 1983), the combination of declines in labour productivity and expansion of output suggests that throughout this period manufacturing enterprises are producing less and less efficiently. The decline in efficiency, which also manifests itself in the drop in capacity utilization (World Bank, 1987a; Maliyamkono and Bagachwa 1990), is closely related to all four characteristics of the policy period prevailing at the time. First, it should be noted that the increased reliance on foreign aid results in investments in inefficient, large-scale and capital-intensive publicly owned enterprises. On this matter Perkins (1983) writes that ‘in many cases it appears that the government approves the establishment of new parastatals … merely because a foreign equipment supplier or TNC is willing to implement the project, and to provide equity capital, commercial credit or a soft loan through the aid programme of its home country’. These newly established publicly owned enterprises are not in accordance with resources available within the country, since they prove to be extremely import intensive, and require highly developed managerial skills and highly trained workers (see Chapter 5). On the latter issue, Gulhati and Sekhar (1982) point out that in subSaharan Africa inefficient production in public manufacturing results to a considerable extent from an ‘acute scarcity of skilled managers, administrators and technicians’. By expanding the Tanzanian public sector through aid programmes, the strain on the scarce availability of managerial skills and skilled labour is increased. On top of this, by allowing for the establishment of import-intensive enterprises, the already deteriorating balance of payments (see Section 4) is put under even more strain. Because of the balance of payments crisis and the continued establishment of new importintensive firms, available foreign exchange has to be spread out more thinly over claimants. This results in shortages of machinery, spare parts and raw materials (see Table 1.3). It is not surprising that the paradox of capital intensive industrial expansion in a situation of scarcity of material, financial and human resources results in declines in labour productivity. Another cause of the decline in efficiency should be sought in the combination of the emphasis on the public sector and the high degree of direct regulatory control prevailing from 1973 onwards. This combination, which is not uncommon in developing countries (White, 1984; Szirmai, 1997a), is known to result in inefficiency, since the imposition of direct regulatory controls (for example, foreign exchange allocation, price control, confine-
Public Policy and Industrial Development 43
ment, industrial licensing) in a government-led sector leads to corruption and increased lobbying activities. Parastatal managers ‘spend their time escorting their papers through government offices’, rather than attempting to find solutions to the constraints hampering production (Krueger, 1992). In Tanzania this phenomenon is indeed observed (World Bank, 1988): ‘[The use of direct regulatory controls] has encouraged [parastatal] managers to focus their efforts on seeking additional import allocations and permissions to charge higher prices rather than on efforts to control costs, search for new markets and improved technologies.’ The imposition of direct regulatory controls also makes for extremely high degrees of protection. From 1973 onwards, trade and price controls, together with an overvalued exchange rate, protect both the private and the public sector from foreign competition. Such sustained importsubstituting policies have generally been associated with a loss of efficiency in the longer run (Page, 1990; Krueger, 1992). Protection allows manufacturers to produce above world market prices, ‘entailing production that is increasingly high cost and less economic’ (Meier, 1990). This mechanism exposes yet another manner in which policy instruments used between 1973 and 1980 are related to declines in efficiency. Table 1.11 shows that import substitution is indeed taking place throughout the period 1973–80. The domestic market–total manufactured supply ratio rises from 42.5 to 50.9 per cent, whilst the share of imports in the total manufactured supply declines from 51.1 to 42.5 per cent. Most import substitution takes place in the intermediate goods sector, a phenomenon which can be explained by the shift in relative protection in favour of the manufacturers of intermediate and capital goods (see Table 1.5: the 1984 effective rates of protection presented can be taken as indicative for levels of protection during the 1973–80 period). The shift in relative protection also contributes to the structural change taking place in this period. Table 1.12 shows that in 10+ manufacturing the share of intermediate goods in total manufacturing value added rises at the expense of the consumer goods sector. 5.4
1980–84
A second turning point in Tanzanian manufacturing performance occurs in 1979. In this year the trend of manufacturing (10+) growth is reversed. As Figure 1.2 reveals, the index of medium- and large-scale manufacturing GDP declines rapidly after 1979. In 1984 it is already beneath its 1973 level. The four years of negative growth cause the share of manufacturing value added in GDP to shrink from 12.4 per cent in 1979 to 9.1 per cent in 1984 (Figure 1.1). Between 1979 and 1983 the decline in labour productivity accelerates. Comparative labour productivity declines dramatically from 8.1 per cent in 1979 to 4.8 per cent in 1983. The divergence is the result of the combination
44 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
of labour productivity growth in the USA, and steeply declining levels of labour productivity in the Tanzanian manufacturing sector (see Figure 1.3). To a certain extent these steep declines in Tanzanian labour productivity levels can be explained by the policy environment prevailing in this period. The line of reasoning is similar to that used to explain the decline in labour productivity between 1973 and 1980. High levels of protection do not stimulate competitive behaviour, and contribute to inefficient production. Furthermore, the combination of high degrees of direct regulatory control and an emphasis on public ownership stimulates corruption and lobbying activities, rather than stimulating improvements in productive efficiency. Finally, by relying on foreign aid as a source of investment finance, capacity has been installed which cannot be used to its full potential, since the human and material resources to attain such a goal are in short supply. It should be noted, however, that the same mix of policy instruments used between 1973 and 1978 does not cause such a steep decline in labour productivity. Neither does the policy environment result in persisting negative growth rates of real output throughout that period. It is clear that factors other than policy alone are needed to understand the performance trends between 1979 and 1984. As stressed in section 4, the analytical difference between the period 1973–80 and the period 1980–84 can be found in the change in the external circumstances. From 1980 onwards the total Tanzanian economy faces an economic crisis, and it is precisely the combination of this crisis with the prevailing policy environment that brings about the radical deterioration in manufacturing performance. The aspect of the general crisis which has the largest impact on the performance of the manufacturing sector is the shortage of foreign exchange (de Valk, 1992). As Table 1.3 shows, during the early 1980s on average only 30 per cent of all requests for foreign exchange within the Tanzanian economy are awarded. The percentage of manufacturing requests awarded is even lower (on average 10 to 15 per cent). In fact, in some years no foreign exchange at all is made available for imports of raw materials, machinery and spare parts. Furthermore, as a World Bank (1987a) study shows, the bulk of the foreign exchange available is allocated to the least efficient enterprises. This is caused by the high degree of direct regulatory control the government has assumed over the manufacturing sector (see Section 3). Between 1982 and 1985 inefficient (mostly public) enterprises receive 74 per cent of the available foreign exchange. Given that the manufacturing sector is import intensive (see analysis of previous period), it is very likely that the shortage and inefficient allocation of foreign exchange have had negative effects on output and productivity levels. The 1980–84 crisis is also characterized by frequent interruptions in water and electricity supply. Along with the foreign exchange shortage, these infrastructural problems are reckoned amongst the principal production
Public Policy and Industrial Development 45
constraints prevailing at the time. Other production constraints are caused by firms supplying inputs, by a lack of supervisory and technical manpower, and by a lack of labour discipline (de Valk, 1992). In the publicly owned enterprises the latter production constraint is the result of the socialist approach to management adopted after the drawing up of the Arusha declaration (Weaver and Kronemer, 1981). Infrastructural problems (including inadequate transport and communication facilities) and the lack of supervisory and technical manpower are closely linked to the unfavourable initial conditions discussed in Section 2. The investments in large scale manufacturing enterprises have not been accompanied by sufficient investments in infrastructure and training of the industrial workforce by the Tanzanian government. In conclusion, the weaknesses of the oversized and already inefficiently operating manufacturing sector are revealed by the 1980–84 macroeconomic crisis. The roots of the crisis in the manufacturing sector are to be found in government policy, which has stimulated the establishment of an import-intensive, publicly owned manufacturing sector, which is not compatible with material and human resources available at the time. Hence, aspects of the overall crisis, such as a lack of foreign exchange and insufficient infrastructural provisions, result in scarcity of inputs and frequent work stoppages. Labour productivity levels drop further, and declines in real output levels are recorded. The continued import substitution taking place between 1980 and 1984 (Table 1.11), is more a result of a shortage of foreign exchange for the financing of imports, rather than the result of deliberate import substitution policy (Wangwe and Bagachwa, 1990). The shares of intermediate and capital goods in gross value added do not change throughout the period (Table 1.12). This lack of structural change in an environment of high levels of protection for the manufacturers of intermediate and capital goods also illustrates the seriousness of the 1980–84 crisis in the manufacturing sector. 5.5
1984–90
In 1984 the decline in output and labour productivity levels comes to an end. As Figures 1.2 and 1.3 show, output and labour productivity levels stabilize between 1984 and 1989. So does the trend in the share of manufacturing value added in GDP: 1985 and 1989 shares both equal 8.4 per cent. The declining trend in comparative labour productivity levels, however, is not reversed. In 1984 the ratio of Tanzanian and US manufacturing labour productivity levels equals 5.8 per cent. This ratio has dropped to 3.9 per cent in 1990. Comparative productivity in medium- and large-scale manufacturing is well below that of developing economies in Asia, such as China, India and Indonesia (between 5.7 and 10 per cent of the US level in 1987; see Timmer and Szirmai, 1999). The further decline in comparative
46 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
manufacturing labour productivity levels is the result of the combination of labour productivity increases in the lead country and the already noted stabilization of labour productivity levels in Tanzania. From an international perspective, this is indicative of a process of falling behind. The introduction of foreign exchange windows (e.g. own funds, open general licence) other than loans and grants and the free resources allocated by the Bank of Tanzania, forms the main reason why output and productivity levels do not decline further from 1984 onwards. Through the newly introduced foreign exchange windows, import-starved manufacturers can obtain raw materials, machinery and spare parts necessary to improve capacity utilization. As a consequence of these new import possibilities, the trend in import substitution is reversed. Table 1.11 shows that the share of imports in the total manufactured supply rises from 36.3 per cent in 1984 to 44.9 per cent in 1990, whilst the DM/TMS ratio drops from 58.6 per cent to 46.6 per cent over the same period. Between 1984 and 1990 there is also a significant rise in the share of exports in the total manufactured supply for the first time since independence. This coincides with the trade policy shift taking place throughout this period. As explained in Section 3.4, because of trade liberalization, nominal exchange rate devaluations and tax evading importers, production for the home market has become less attractive than it was in previous policy periods. Consumer goods manufacturing, and manufacturing of food products in particular, once again becomes the most attractive sector in terms of protection (Table 1.5), a change which is reflected by the structural changes occurring during the period (Table 1.12). Another disincentive for production for the home market is provided by export promotion schemes introduced from 1984 onwards. It is often argued that trade liberalisation and incentives for export oriented production ‘result in the contraction of inefficient sectors and the expansion of new, efficient ones’, because trade liberalisation and export promotion force domestic producers to comply to international price and quality standards (Michalopoulus, 1987). However, Kirkpatrick and Maharaja (1992) point out that in the case of less developed countries there is little empirical evidence supporting this view. Trends in Tanzanian manufacturing performance between 1984 and 1990 do not provide any support for this view either (Figures 1.2 and 1.3). Moreover, a World Bank (1991) study states that the extremely inefficient firms which survived during the heyday of protectionism still manage to survive from 1984 onwards, despite the liberalisation of internal and external trade. This remarkable observation is closely linked to the preferential treatment of the public sector, which is still cherished by the government between 1984 and 1990. In 1989, 56 per cent of the publicly owned manufacturing enterprises are operating at a loss (World Bank, 1991). But despite this troublesome figure, the public manufacturing sector is exempted from
Public Policy and Industrial Development 47
duties and sales taxes, is allocated foreign exchange on favourable terms (through aid inflows), and can count on the bulk of available (subsidized) credit. As pointed out in Section 3.4, public enterprises receive about 70 per cent of total loans made available to manufacturing firms. Preferential treatment of public enterprises regarding the allocation of loans is enabled by the control the government still has over the monetary sector. 5.6
1990–95
With the 1990–95 decontrol and shift away from the predominance of the public sector in the industrial strategy, it would seem that the many policy barriers to efficient production are removed. But this is not (or not yet) reflected in the indicators of manufacturing performance. The share of manufacturing value added hardly changes between 1990 (7.8 per cent) and 1994 (7.6 per cent) (Figure 1.1). Output levels in medium- and largescale manufacturing do not rise substantially either: the 1995 output level is only just above the 1989 output level (Figure 1.2). Furthermore, a sample of 20 manufacturing activities shows only modest improvements in the use of capacity throughout the period. In 1990, 32 per cent of the installed capacity in the sample industries is used. In 1994 capacity utilization in these industries has increased to 37 per cent (United Republic of Tanzania, 1995b). The absence of significant improvements in manufacturing performance can be traced back to the macroeconomic situation, the unfavourable initial conditions Tanzania has had to face and the policy changes in the period studied. Regarding parastatal reform, for instance, it cannot be expected that privatization of 34 of the 170 manufacturing parastatals immediately results in productivity gains. In the words of Adam (1994), public sector reform is accompanied by ‘changes … in terms of managerial attitudes, and a greater perception of operating autonomy, which will gradually be translated into efficiency gains and increased profitability’. It is unlikely that these desirable effects take place at short notice though, a point which can also be made regarding the inflow of direct foreign investment after the opening up of the sector to private entrepreneurs. Another reason why policy changes do not result in improvements in manufacturing performance can be found in the combination of the liberalisation of the banking system and the high inflation rates prevailing between 1990 and 1994 (Table 1.9). The high inflation rates force the banks to charge extremely high nominal interest rates in order to maintain positive real interest rates (see Section 3.5). These high nominal interest rates are a threat to the liquidity of manufacturing enterprises. Furthermore, the high inflation rates erode the purchasing power of the bank overdrafts. Since banks are reluctant to raise bank overdrafts, manufacturers have less and less access to short-term credit to finance procurement of raw materials and intermediate inputs. On top of that, non-creditworthy enterprises are
48 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
no longer allocated medium- and long-term credit, since this would contradict the commercial principles banks operate on from 1991 onwards. As such, credit has replaced foreign exchange as the major production constraint the manufacturing sector faces. Other production constraints are related to the conditions Tanzania has had to face since independence. As discussed in Section 2 and in this section (1980–84 period), the manufacturing sector has been operating in an environment characterized by poor infrastructure and a shortage of supervisory and technical manpower. In a more general sense, Helleiner (1994) points out that ‘industrial development hinges, in any case, upon local capabilities and appropriate supporting institutions no less than on incentives, and, in sub-Saharan Africa these have been typically lacking’. In Tanzania, this lack of local capabilities and supporting institutions has continued to hamper manufacturing development between 1990 and 1995 (United Republic of Tanzania, 1996b). Along with the unfair competition by tax-evading importers (see Section 3.5), the production constraints mentioned above result in an environment which is not very conducive to rapid industrial growth. Neither is the environment conducive to structural change. As Table 1.12 shows, in 1995 more than 50 per cent of manufacturing value added (10+) is produced in the food, beverages and tobacco branch. In 1995 the total consumer goods sector accounts for 64 per cent of manufacturing value added, higher than the share recorded 30 years earlier. Thus, in terms of structural change little has changed throughout these 30 years, a conclusion which can also be drawn regarding the importance of the manufacturing sector for the economy as a whole (see Figure 1.1).
6
Concluding remarks
Although a promising start is made in the period 1961–67, both in terms of policy and performance, changes in the policy climate from 1967 onwards affect manufacturing development adversely. This is due to the fact that the policy regimes prevailing between 1967 and 1980 stimulate the establishment of an oversized and increasingly inefficient sector, which is not well adapted to Tanzania’s resources in terms of factor proportions, skills, human capital, infrastructure, availability of foreign exchange and other relevant factors. The macroeconomic crisis of the 1980s reveals this weakness, and the manufacturing sector plunges into a crisis from which, to this day, it is still attempting to recover. The policy responses to the crisis in the period 1984–90 seem conducive to industrial stabilization, but further changes in policy between 1990 and 1995 have so far not been followed by industrial recovery. A recent review of African economic performance by Collier and Gunning (1999) indicates that the industrial experience of Tanzania is representative of that of many economies in Sub-Saharan
Public Policy and Industrial Development 49
Africa. The detailed analysis of the Tanzanian experience provided in this volume should be seen as a case study in African industrialization. Looking at Tanzanian industrialization from a long-term perspective, one may conclude that post-war industrial policy has been informed by a mainly structuralist interpretation of the process of economic development. This interpretation called for heavy government involvement in order to force the pace of industrialization. The problems discussed in this paper suggest that this approach is flawed and that many of the problems of the manufacturing sector are policy related. However, the fact that the return to neo-liberally inspired policies since 1984 has so far not led to a resumption of manufacturing growth suggests that a return to the market alone will not automatically solve all problems either.
Notes *
1
2
3
Section of Technology and Development Studies and Eindhoven Centre for Innovation Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology Some classifications focus on the level of dependence on foreign finance, but in the case of Tanzania this dimension does not help distinguish policy periods. The dependence on foreign finance continues to be high throughout the whole period studied. For total manufacturing, one can also take production for the domestic market (DM) as a proportion of production for the domestic market plus imported goods (IM). However, these ratios are not available for subcategories of manufacturing. Calculated from United Republic of Tanzania, Analysis of Parastatal Accounts, and Bureau of Statistics, National Accounts (various issues).
2 Is African Manufacturing Skill Constrained? Howard Pack and Christina Paxson*
1
Introduction
In most of the sub-Saharan African economies neither the levels of total factor productivity (TFP) nor the growth rates of TFP in manufacturing have been high. All studies of cross-country performance find that the subSaharan African economies are the largest bloc of nations that have not converged on the US. Most of the inter-country explanations have focused on easily measured aggregate variables such as the ratio of investment to GDP, education levels, and, in some models, proxies for political stability (Barro and Lee, 1993; Easterly, 1993). These models have as their underlying theoretical framework a view that the national economy can be modelled with a set of multiplicative inputs – an increase in the right hand side variables such as the investment rate or education level will produce an increase in growth rates. However, as is increasingly recognised, by, among others, the authors of the many papers on convergence, the particular specification of the implied production function is open to question, and the right-hand-side variables may themselves be endogenous. Moreover, in the case of the African nations, close observers question whether a simple increase in investment rates will generate the impact implied by the crosscountry regressions – many countries have experienced growing marginal capital–output ratios over the last two decades (Husain, 1993). There are two divergent though complementary views of the lack of productivity growth in sub-Saharan Africa.1 The first holds that pervasive government intervention imposes large costs on individual firms and reduces incentives to become efficient (Collier and Gunning, 1999). It is not only protection from foreign competition that has such effects but also problems stemming from bad macroeconomic policies, such as highly variable real exchange rates, which make long-term planning difficult for firms. A second interpretation focuses on the paucity of technological competence as measured by the small supply of trained managers and engineers.2 This paper examines the determinants of manufacturing productivity and the 50
Is African Manufacturing Skill Constrained? 51
role of education and technology variables at the level of individual firms. A major implication of our results is that, ceteris paribus, it is unlikely that an increase in education levels will have much impact on manufacturing TFP levels. We suggest a more complex view of the role of education, emphasizing that, in the absence of technology inflows, higher skills may have very low productivity. Using the results of surveys of industrial firms in Ghana, Kenya and Zimbabwe, we consider the connection between technological abilities and productivity in the three nations. Section 2 sets out the determinants of productivity. Section 3 provides some aggregate measures of factors that may affect productivity in the three economies in question. Section 4 presents empirical results on the analysis of the determinants of productivity in a large group of firms in the three countries. Section 5 offers an interpretation of the results, and Section 6 contains conclusions.
2
The determinants of productivity levels
While economy-wide and sectoral shortages of human capital are widely assumed to limit efficient industrial development, there is little empirical evidence on whether this is indeed the case in individual African firms. The presence of trained and experienced managers and workers does not guarantee high firm productivity for several reasons. First, individuals with formal credentials may not possess the cognitive skills necessary to improve TFP. Second, if there is limited rivalry, firms may view investment in costreducing efforts as not being necessary to remain competitive. Third, an industry’s organization, such as vertical integration between manufacturers and retailers, may result in low productivity if, for example, each firm produces a large range of products, the profitability of firms being guaranteed by protection from imported goods. Hence, the frequently drawn policy conclusion of the need for higher levels of education and training based on the assumed shortages of skilled manpower may be unwarranted. In theory technological abilities are important for cost reduction in industrial firms, facilitating learning by doing. The simplest interpretation of pure learning by doing envisions a manual worker tightening a bolt in 40 per cent less time the hundredth time she does it as compared to the first time. But a complete specification of ‘pure’ learning by doing would recognise that there is usually an ongoing reorganization of the flow of work, the design or distribution of improved machinery, and additional training. Thus, even in the simplest case of learning by doing, one would expect that the presence of more educated or trained supervisors and production workers will facilitate realization of greater TFP growth. However, there is little empirical support, even in industrialised countries, for a close relation between technological abilities and cost reduction for industrial firms.3
52 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
By itself, the purchase of modern equipment does not guarantee that high TFP will be realised with such machinery – many complementary firm-level actions are required. Production engineering must be mastered, the flow of intermediate inputs to the plant and spare parts must be arranged, workers must be trained, and marketing must be enhanced so that it is not necessary to produce short production runs to order, and incur excessive set-up costs. Education, vocational training, foreign training, firm-level research and development, expenditures on technology licences, and the nationality of owners may all affect the ability of firms to master the software of technology, and are thus important determinants of firm-level productivity. The economic environment established by macro- and micro-economic policies will also impinge on the firm and discourage or partly offset positive efforts at the firm level. Difficulty in obtaining raw and intermediate inputs of a given quality due to exchange controls, erratic supply of public services such as electricity, the incentive provided by import restrictions to expand the range of products, and the general absence of incentives to improve productivity all affect firm-level performance. For any given set of firms the impact of the economic environment and firm-level factors jointly determine productivity. Assuming that all firms within a given industry face the same economic environment, it is possible to test whether firm technological abilities affect TFP or its mirror image, unit costs. There are two alternate views of the role of education and technology in the production function. The first views them as multiplicative inputs in a standard production function. Thus, if a production function is estimated, elasticities of output with respect to technology inputs can be calculated. A second view that we believe is more useful (Nelson and Phelps, 1966) argues that education will have its greatest impact when there is rapid technological change. If the basic technology (a loom used in weaving) is largely unchanged over time, the production process becomes routine and the ability to deal with change is not germane – high education results in only limited productivity gains. In contrast, where technology is rapidly evolving, learning about the existence of new processes, learning to use them when they are deployed, and staying abreast of new developments require the adaptability provided by formal education. The preceding can be formalised following a model of Nelson and Phelps (1966). Firms in LDCs operate with a technology level equal to A(t) in period t. Their peers in industrial countries operate technology T(t). The rate at which the DC technology is introduced into the LDC depends on the level of human capital, h, and is T (t ) − A(t ) A(t ) / A(t ) = ( h) A(t )
(2.1)
Is African Manufacturing Skill Constrained? 53
The extent to which local LDC technology improves is a positive function, ’(h) > 0, of the level of human capital and proportional to the magnitude of the differential between current and ‘best practice’ technology. As the technology T(t) does not have to be invented, the potential productivity gain from the transfer of this technology is the benefit of relative backwardness (Gerschenkron, 1962). Assume that the DC technology improves each year by per cent, so that T(t) = T0et
(2.2)
Given (2.1) and (2.2), the underlying differential equation implies that the potential equilibrium path of technology of an LDC firm is A(t) = [(h)/((h) + )]T0et
(2.3)
The potential level of technology realised by an LDC firm at a moment in time will thus be higher: (1) the greater its ability to deal with new technologies as a result of the presence of qualified individuals on its staff; (2) the larger the inflow of technology to the firm in the form of new equipment, new material inputs, new knowledge obtained from consultants, licensers and foreign owners. The potential level of technology characterizing a firm will evolve along Equation 2.3 and depends solely on its own level of h and the rate of technical progress in the DCs that becomes available to the LDC firm. If foreign exchange shortages or arbitrary rules prohibiting some forms of technology imports reduce the inflow of new knowledge, the benefit conferred by h is reduced. This might stem, for example, from regulations that limit expenditures on technology licensing payments so that a firm cannot purchase a potentially useful technology, implying that F < where F represents the lower rate of technology inflow. Thus Equation 2.3 can be rewritten as A(t) = [(h)/((h) + F)]T0eF t
(2.4)
Equation 2.4 underlines the fact that, at a given point in time, the level of productivity A(t) for a given firm may be weakly associated with h unless firms’ ability to obtain new technology varies systematically with h. Unlike formulations which treat education or purchases of knowledge as conventional inputs in the production function, Equation 2.4 implies that human capital will have no effect on the level of output obtained with conventional inputs unless F > 0, which can only occur if new productive inputs are introduced. Schultz (1975) argued that in addition to the ability to absorb new technology, education would be important if there were a changing sectoral structure or internal product mix of firms, more highly educated workers
54 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
being better at reallocating factors, exploring new profitable opportunities and securing markets. Changing sectoral structure and internal product mix in turn reflect growth in per capita income in the internal market combined with different Engel elasticities and changes in the net trade balance in individual commodities. If sectors are not changing, it is likely that product mix within a sector is also stable, putting little premium on the ability to cope with change.
3.
Aggregate evidence on technology
The payoff to education depends in the above view on two measurable magnitudes: (1) the inflow of imported machinery and industrial intermediate inputs that may embody new technology and (2) the sectoral structure of production. To measure the first Table 2.1 shows the rate of growth of all imports of goods and services, in constant prices, for the three African countries as well as Korea and Malaysia, two Asian countries that are widely viewed as having benefited from the inflow of technology. The second is measured by the change in the split between light and heavy industry and the standard deviation of the percentage change in sectoral shares of value added (Table 2.2). In the period 1980–93 the three African economies exhibited a negative or very slow growth of all imports, reflecting their inability to earn foreign exchange through exporting, and the limited inflow of concessional aid. Kenya, for example, experienced a decline in constant price imports of 0.8 per cent per year over the period. As the share of machinery and transport equipment and other manufactured inputs in total imports was roughly constant over the 1985–93 period, the absolute level of imports that could embody new technology declined.4 In Ghana and Zimbabwe there were significant declines in the share of imported equipment with only slight growth of exports; thus a significant decline in the level of imported capital goods occurred. The figures also suggest that, at most, a modest increase occurred in manufactured intermediate inputs. In contrast, in Korea and Malaysia, two NICs in which the level of education is widely perceived to have been an important contributor to industrial growth, the level of imports was rising very rapidly, reflecting the growth in export earnings, and the share of the two technology-embodying inputs was constant or increasing, implying potential for significant returns from the ability to effectively utilise the new technology component of these imports. The African nations also show a striking lack of change in sectoral structure, compared to dramatic structural changes in the Asian NICs. Table 2.2 shows the distribution of manufacturing value added among light and heavy manufacturing for the five countries in question, and an index of structural change given by the standard deviation of the percentage change
Table 2.1 Country
Kenya Ghana Zimbabwe Korea Malaysia
Imports of goods embodying new technology Growth rate of imports, 1980–93
–0.8 2.7 0.2 11.4 9.7
Share of machinery and transport equipment in total imports
Share of other manufactured imports in total imports
1985
1993
1985
1993
23 40 65 34 46
25 26 36 34 54
28 28 26 23 28
29 31 31 29 30
Source: World Development Report (various issues).
55
56 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Table 2.2
Sectoral distribution of value added in manufacturing Ghana Kenya Zimbabwe Korea Malaysia 1980 1990 1980 1990 1980 1990 1980 1990 1980 1990
Light industry 57.8 59.9 52.7 55.2 49.3 53.3 41.5 29.6 47.8 30.8 Heavy industry 42.2 40.1 47.2 45.1 50.7 46.7 58.5 70.4 52.2 69.2 SD of the % change in sectoral value shares in 28 ISIC sectors 1.58 1.25 2.05 2.18 2.98 Source: UNIDO (1993).
between 1980 and 1990 in value added, calculated over 28 three-digit industrial sectors. As can be seen, both the sectoral distribution between heavy and light and the summary standard deviation measure show that the three African economies have experienced relatively little change in the structure of sectoral production, a phenomenon also replicated at the firm level.5 The firms in our sample manufacture relatively simple products, and it is unlikely that the internal product mix of firms has changed much. Indeed, many of the items produced by the larger firms are not that different from those fabricated in the informal sector. These results suggest that unless some firms were able to deviate from the overall pattern of stagnation of new inputs, it would be surprising if firms with higher technical skills realised greater levels of productivity.
4. 4.1
Empirical results at the firm level The data
We analyse the relationship between skills and production costs using firmlevel data from three African countries, Kenya, Zimbabwe, and Ghana. The survey data were collected in 1993 (for Kenya and Zimbabwe) and 1992 (for Ghana) by the Regional Program on Enterprise Development of the World Bank. Although the data are by now panel data, with up to three years of information for each firm, only the first year of data was available for this study. The surveys for each country used similar questionnaires and sampling procedures. All collected information on the value of output, production costs, the skill level of the owners and managers in each firm, and each firm’s involvement in foreign markets, such as raw material imports, exports and foreign ownership.
Is African Manufacturing Skill Constrained? 57
The Kenyan data are drawn from a survey of 223 manufacturing firms. The original sample consisted of 162 formal sector firms drawn from the Central Bureau of Statistics register of firms, and 61 informal (that is nonregistered) firms. Four sectors are represented: food processing, textiles and garments, woodworking, and metalworking. The sample is stratified by sector and (for formal firms) by firm size. Detailed information on the survey design and the procedures used to compute weights for the strata are in World Bank (1993b). Although the descriptive statistics presented below make use of data on all 223 firms, we had to exclude 51 firms when estimating cost functions, because of missing or incomplete data on costs, output, capital values and other variables used in the analysis. In Zimbabwe 201 firms were surveyed in the summer of 1993. The firms were selected from two sources. Large firms, with 50 or more employees, were drawn from a firm registration list provided by the Central Statistical Office. Smaller firms were drawn from a list compiled by the Gemini Survey of small-scale firms, conducted in 1991 (see World Bank, 1994b, for further details on the sample design and the sample weighting procedure). We use data on 200 firms (one firm had no sector information and was excluded), and lose an additional 30 firms for the estimates of cost functions because of missing data. The sample from Ghana consists of 186 firms surveyed in the summer of 1992. The sample design is described in World Bank (1993c). The design of the survey appears to have been complicated by the fact that two censuses, an industrial census and a population census, yield inconsistent information on the numbers of small-scale enterprises (World Bank, 1993c, p. 28.) Because of this ambiguity, we do not use population weights, the number of firms in the population in each stratum, in calculating the summary statistics that follow, but the means of all firms in the sample. It is thus possible that our sample statistics may not accurately reflect the characteristics of the population of firms in Ghana. The firms in the Ghanaian sample tend to be smaller than the firms in Zimbabwe and Kenya. Furthermore, there is no simple definition of “formal” versus “informal” firms, as there is for the other two countries. In what follows we sometimes split the Ghanaian sample between ‘large’ firms, defined as those with 10 or more employees (as opposed to more than 50 employees for Zimbabwean formal-sector firms), and small firms. The Ghanaian data also have a larger fraction of missing values than the other two surveys. Of the original 186 firms, only 132 can be used to estimate cost functions. Valuation of the capital stock of firms appears to have been a particular problem in Ghana, and so we do not include capital stock in the cost functions: doing so would have resulted in losing 19 more firms. The results for Ghana should be treated with extra caution, because of the small sample and the selection problems that may result from missing dependent variables.
58 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
4.2
Descriptive information on the firms
The surveys indicate that the majority of firms are engaged in producing fairly simple products. In all three countries the modal product of firms in the food sector is bread-making. Garments and wooden household furniture are the modal products for the textile and woodworking sectors. The metal sectors in each of the three countries are somewhat more diverse, although the majority of sampled firms report metal doors, windows, gates and burglar bars as their primary products. The picture does not change much in Kenya and Zimbabwe when sample weights are used to calculate the percentage of firms in the population (and labour shares) in each activity.6 Most of the firms in each of the countries are sole-proprietorships, partnerships or limited liability enterprises, and for almost all of these firms a person identified as ‘the owner’ took part in a survey about his education, experience and personal background. Owners in each country were asked about the highest educational level obtained, and were also asked if they had additional vocational, technical, or (for Kenya and Ghana) professional training. In each country the majority of surveyed owners had at least some secondary education, and a third to a half of these had extra training as well (see Table 2.3). Without reliable data on the distribution of skills in the populations of each of these countries it is impossible to tell if owners of manufacturing firms have better than average skills. Data from the Table 2.3a
Kenya: education of firm’s owners (193 firms)
Education level None Primary Secondary University
Total 6 54 87 46
5.4% 51.0% 40.0% 3.7%
Vocational 0 5 7 0
0.0% 7.6% 2.0% 0.0%
Technical 0 3 13 3
0.0% 1.7% 4.2% 0.0%
Professional 0 0 10 8
0.0% 0.0% 4.4% 0.5%
Note: Numbers indicate numbers of sampled firms. Percentages indicate estimated percentages of firms in the population, and are calculated using population weights provided by the survey study.
Table 2.3b
Zimbabwe: education of firm’s owners (134 firms)
Education level None Primary Secondary University
Total 3 32 64 35
Vocational or technical training 2.4% 45.3% 46.5% 5.8%
0 14 30 6
0.0% 8.8% 20.2% 1.0%
Note: Numbers indicate numbers of sampled firms. Percentages indicate estimated percentages of firms (with owners) in the population, and are calculated using population weights provided by the survey study.
Is African Manufacturing Skill Constrained? 59 Table 2.3c
Ghana: education of firm’s owners (153 firms)
Education level None Primary Secondary University
Total 17 12 107 17
Vocational
11.1% 7.8% 69.9% 11.1%
0 1 13 0
0.0% 0.7% 8.5% 0.0%
Technical 0 3 18 0
0.0% 2.0% 11.8% 0.0%
Professional 0 0 4 3
0.0% 0.0% 2.6% 2.0%
Note: Numbers indicate numbers of sampled firms, and percentages indicate percentages of sampled firms. Population weights are not used.
Ghanaian Living Standards Measurement Study, conducted in 1988 and 1989, indicate that average years of schooling among people aged 15 to 55 was six years (Jolliffe, 1995), with a lower average for people in older age groups, so it is likely that owners of manufacturing firms have better than average skills than the working population. Owners may hire managers with skills that exceed their own, in which case the appropriate measure of skill for the firm may be that of the manager rather than the owner. Tables 2.4a, 2.4b and 2.4c tabulate the education levels of ‘general managers’ and ‘production managers’ for firms that indicate that they have a manager of either type. The distribution of education among managers is not too dissimilar from the distribution among owners, although a higher fraction of managers have attended a university. However, this does not imply that owners hire managers who are more educated than themselves, and may reflect the fact that it is larger firms with more educated owners that hire managers. Among firms that have both owners and managers present, there is a high correlation between the skill levels of the two.7 The survey also asked about the average education levels of ‘managerial employees’. Tabulations of these for Kenya and Ghana are shown in Table 2.5 (the results for Zimbabwe were miscoded Table 2.4a Kenya: distribution of managers’ education General manager (N = 110) None Primary Secondary University – nontechnical University – technical Postgraduate (Kenya) Postgraduate (abroad)
2 8 47 25 21 3 4
0.1% 33.4% 40.2% 3.4% 17.8% 0.3% 4.9%
Production manager (N = 58) 1 3 25 5 21 1 2
15.2% 1.2% 57.7% 1.4% 23.8% 0.3% 0.5%
Note: Numbers indicate numbers of sampled firms. Percentages indicate estimated percentages of firms in the population, and are calculated using population weights provided by the survey study.
60 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Table 2.4b
Zimbabwe: distribution of managers’ education General manager (N = 190)
None Primary Secondary University – nontechnical University – technical Postgraduate (local) Postgraduate (abroad)
3 27 86 31 31 2 10
Production manager (N = 108)
2.4% 42.4% 47.1% 3.7% 2.7% 0.1% 1.7%
1 16 49 10 27 3 2
0.9% 14.8% 45.4% 9.3% 25.0% 2.8% 1.9%
Note: Numbers indicate numbers of sampled firms. Percentages indicate estimated percentages of firms in the population, and are calculated using population weights provided by the survey study.
Table 2.4c
Ghana: distribution of managers’ education General manager (N = 47)
None Primary Secondary University – nontechnical University – technical Postgraduate (local) Postgraduate (abroad)
4 4 10 7 18 1 3
8.5% 8.5% 21.2% 14.9% 38.3% 2.1% 6.4%
Production manager (N = 51) 0 3 11 2 28 1 6
0.0% 5.9% 21.6% 3.9% 54.9% 2.0% 11.8%
Note: Percentages are calculated from firms in the sample.
and cannot be used), and these indicate that the majority of managerial employees have attended secondary school, and roughly a quarter of the sampled firms with managerial employees list the average education level of their managers at the university level. In the cost functions presented below we use a variety of skill measures that reflect the education levels of both owners and managers. We have no direct measures of the rate at which different firms acquire new technology (that is, the term F in Equation 2.4). However, it is likely that the acquisition of new technology from abroad is positively correlated with activities in foreign markets, and Table 2.6 presents information on these activities. The predominant picture is of firms that have little involvement in international markets. The vast majority of all firms import none of their raw materials, export none of their output, and do not have any foreign ownership. The firms were also asked about the use of foreign technology licences and foreign technical assistance. In Kenya only 9 out of 220 firms that answered these questions had foreign licences, and 17 out of 220 received
Is African Manufacturing Skill Constrained? 61 Table 2.5
Average education of managerial employees
Education level Kenya (126 firms) None Primary Secondary University Ghana (64 firms) None Primary Secondary University
Total
Vocational
Technical
Professional
1 8 82 35
0.2% 14.2% 74.2% 11.4%
0 0 7 1
0.0% 0.0% 6.4% 0.0%
0 2 8 0
0.0% 8.0% 14.3% 0.0%
0 0 11 9
0.0% 0.0% 1.5% 1.6%
2 1 45 16
3.1% 1.6% 70.3% 25.0%
0 0 4 0
0.0% 0.0% 6.2% 0.0%
0 0 8 0
0.0% 0.0% 12.5% 0.0%
0 0 14 2
0.0% 0.0% 21.9% 3.1%
Note: Numbers indicate numbers of sampled firms. For Kenya, the percentages are calculated using population weights provided by the survey. The data from Ghana are unweighted.
foreign technical assistance. In Zimbabwe licences and technical assistance were somewhat more common: 28 out of 200 firms had foreign licences, and 26 out of 200 received technical assistance. The questions asked of Ghanaian firms were phrased differently, but also indicate little use of licences or assistance. Of the 186 firms in the sample, only 6 firms indicated that they had held at least one foreign licence during the past 10 years, 6 said they had received foreign technical assistance in the last year, and 2 said they had used foreign consultants in the past two years. 4.3
Estimates of cost functions
The data described above have been used to estimate cost functions for firms in each of the three countries. Our primary interest is to see whether firms with more skills (as measured by the education levels of owners and/or managers) and more involvement in foreign markets have lower productions costs, given output. We start with the short-run cost function for firm i: ci = C(pi, ki, qi/Ai)
(2.5)
where c is costs defined as the cost of labour, raw materials and indirect costs such as utilities and rent; p is a vector of input prices, q is the value of output, k is the replacement value of the firm’s capital equipment, and A is a measure of the technology level of the firm. This form of the cost function follows from the assumption that the short-run production function has the form qi = AiQ(Mi, ki), where Mi is a vector of variable inputs and Ai depends on the level of ‘technological’ inputs such as education. The Nelson-Phelps view discussed in Section 2 implies that Ai is a function of both the skill level of the firm (measured by hi) and also by factors that
62
Table 2.6
Involvement in foreign markets
Kenya Percentage of raw materials imported Percentage of output exported Percentage of foreign ownership of the firm Zimbabwe Percentage of raw materials imported Percentage of output exported Percentage of foreign ownership of the firm Ghana Percentage of raw materials imported Percentage of output exported Percentage of foreign ownership of the firm
None
0–25%
25–50%
50–75%
75–100%
121 (76.1%)
32 (11.4%)
15 (3.3%)
25 (3.3%)
25 (5.9%)
170 (78.0%) 184 (96.5%)
29 4
(6.6%) (0.2%)
7 (0.1%) 6 (1.7%)
4 (0.2%) 10 (0.3%)
8 (0.3%) 14 (1.3%)
92 (93.0%)
57
(4.4%)
20 (0.9%)
13 (0.4%)
12 (1.3%)
104 (92.2%) 155 (96.7%)
58 12
(4.4%) (0.5%)
23 (1.1%) 7 (0.6%)
9 (1.1%) 8 (0.9%)
6 (1.3%) 15 (1.3%)
127 (72.6%)
12
(6.9%)
6 (3.4%)
11 (6.3%)
19 (10.9%)
163 (90.1%) 154 (82.8%)
11 2
(6.1%) (1.1%)
2 (1.1%) 12 (6.5%)
1 (0.6%) 13 (7.0%)
4 (2.2%) 5 (2.7%)
Note: The numbers in parentheses indicate percentage of firms. The percentages for Kenya and Zimbabwe are calculated using population weights. The percentages for Ghana are unweighted.
Is African Manufacturing Skill Constrained? 63
affect the firm-specific rate of flow of new technologies from abroad (measured by F), the two entering the cost function interactively. We start by estimating basic cost functions that do not include any variables that may affect Ai. Because we have small samples of cross-sectional data, and no data on input prices p, we employ simple specifications for the short-run cost functions. We work with the following: ln(ci) = s + q ln(qi) + qq[ln(qi)]2 + k ln(ki) + kk[ln(ki)]2 + qk ln(qi)ln(ki) + i
(2.6)
where s is a sector-specific intercept meant to capture the effects of differences in input prices across sectors. As discussed above, the data from Ghana contain many missing values for the value of capital, and so for it the terms in Equation 2.6 that involve the logarithm of capital are excluded. Estimates of these basic cost functions are shown in Table 2.7. The top panel shows estimates for formal firms (or, in the case of Ghana, firms with ten or more employees), and the bottom panel shows results for the full set of firms. The estimates for the three countries are quite similar, and are also similar for the formal and full samples. In all specifications the sectoral dummy variables are jointly insignificant.8 The results for the simplest specification, in which the logarithm of costs is regressed on the logarithm of output and a set of sector dummies, indicate that the underlying production technology displays constant or slightly increasing returns to scale. Variation in output explains a high fraction of variation in costs, with R squares that exceed .92 for all countries. Including the logarithm of output squared, the measures of capital, and the interaction of capital and output does not greatly improve the fit of the cost functions. The cost function shown in Equation 2.6 was modified to include variables that are likely to affect A. As discussed above, A is meant to capture the effects of skills and determinants of technology inflows on costs. We begin by including measures of the skill level of the firm’s owner or, if no owner was present, the skill level of the firm’s manager. For Kenya and Ghana the education levels of owners and the average education of managerial employees were coded in the same way, and we construct dummies that indicate whether the owner (or managerial employees) had no schooling, primary schooling, secondary schooling or university training. We also experimented with using more finely detailed educational categories that made use of the information on whether owners/employees had received occupational or vocational training. These results are not reported, but were essentially no different from the results that are discussed below. For Zimbabwe the variable pertaining to the average education of managerial employees was miscoded, and so for firms without owners we substitute the education level of the general manager or, if there was no general manager, the production manager. There are only three firms in Zimbabwe
64 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Table 2.7 Basic cost functions for formal sector firms or (for Ghana) large firms (absolute values of t-statistics in parentheses) Kenya Wood Textiles Metal ln(q)
–0.11 (0.92) –0.03 (0.23) 0.06 (0.48) 0.915 (44.94)
ln(q)2 ln(k) ln(k)2 ln(q)ln(k) Obs 125 R2 .95 Full sample of firms Formal 0.35 (3.56) Wood –0.18 (1.59) Textiles –0.10 (0.85) Metal –0.08 (0.70) ln(q) 0.90 (47.93) ln(q)2 ln(k) ln(k)2 ln(q)ln(k) Obs R2
172 .96
Zimbabwe –0.09 (0.70) –0.02 (0.20) 0.04 (0.32) 0.75 (5.68) 0.02 (1.57) 0.24 (1.65) –0.01 (0.70) –0.01 (.43) 125 .95
–0.23 (1.55) 0.01 (0.08) –0.02 (0.12) 0.88 (43.20)
0.28 (2.15) –0.17 (1.50) –0.09 (0.79) –0.09 (0.79) 0.78 (9.94) 0.022 (2.03) 0.10 (1.54) 0.003 (0.33) –0.02 (1.11) 172 .96
0.32 (2.40) –0.11 (0.83) 0.04 (0.42) 0.07 (0.56) 0.89 (46.29)
142 .93
170 .96
Ghana –0.22 (1.60) –0.04 (0.38) –0.01 (0.09) 0.42 (3.87) 0.05 (1.90) 0.37 (3.65) –0.01 (.73) –0.02 (0.36) 142 .94
–0.32 (1.58) –0.18 (0.96) –0.18 (0.95) 1.00 (27.10)
0.31 (2.26) –0.06 (0.51) 0.03 (0.27) 0.04 (0.30) 0.69 (9.46) 0.06 (3.06) 0.13 (2.69) 0.016 (1.42) –0.06 (2.09) 170 .96
0.12 (0.72) –0.14 (0.73) –0.14 (0.77) 0.02 (0.09) 1.109 (25.78)
80 .93
132 .92
–0.32 (1.56) –0.15 (0.79) –0.19 (0.98) 1.33 (6.45) –0.022 (1.64)
80 .93 0.10 (0.65) –0.11 (.55) –0.11 (0.63) 0.02 (0.12) 1.19 (8.21) –0.01 (1.17)
132 .92
Is African Manufacturing Skill Constrained? 65
with owner/managers with no education, and so we combine the ‘no schooling’ and ‘primary education’ categories. For all countries we experimented with altering the definition of ‘skills’ in a variety of ways, for example by using the education level of managerial employees and only using the owner’s education if no managerial employees were present. Doing so had no effect on the results. The first columns of Tables 2.8a, 2.8b and 2.8c show estimates of cost functions when the ‘skill’ measures are included. As the coefficients on the variables shown in Table 2.7 are largely unchanged, only coefficients for the skill variables are reported. The results are easily summarised. In no country are higher managerial skills associated with lower costs, given output. There is one anomalous result for formal sector firms in Ghana (Table 2.8c): firms with educated owners appear to have higher costs than those with no education. However, the three educational dummy variables are not jointly significant. In the second column of the three tables we include variables that measure involvement in foreign markets: the percentage of raw materials imported, the percentage of output exported and the percentage of foreign ownership. If firms with more involvement in foreign markets have more access to lower-cost technology, then these variables should be negatively correlated with costs. However, interpreting the parameter estimates requires caution: it could be that firms whose costs are initially lower export their output. This could also produce a negative correlation between exports and costs, and it would be incorrect to interpret the results as reflecting the effects of the rate of technology transfer on costs (Clerides et al., 1999).9 However, the results indicate that there is no correlation between involvement in foreign markets and costs in any of the countries, and the hypothesis that the variables are individually and jointly insignificant cannot be rejected. The lack of a statistically significant relationship between these variables and costs may not be surprising given that very few of the firms have any involvement in foreign markets. If only high-skill firms are able to take advantage of new technologies from abroad, the Nelson-Phelps view, there should be a negative correlation between costs and an interaction term between skills and the variables reflecting access to foreign markets. The third column of Tables 2.8a, 2.8b and 2.8c show estimates of cost functions when these interactions are included. Overall, the results provide very little support for the hypothesis that high skills combined with access to foreign markets result in reductions of unit costs. With only one exception, the coefficients on these interactions are insignificant. The exception is for Kenya, for which firms with university-trained owner/managers that export higher fractions of their output have lower costs, all else being equal. One should not, however, make too much of this finding. First, there are only 17 formal
Cost functions with skill measures included, Kenya
66
Table 2.8a
Sample means
Kenya: formal firms (obs = 125) Owner/manager’s education: Primary school Secondary school University
–0.038 (0.32) –0.062 (0.47) –0.056 (0.47)
% raw materials imported % output exported % foreign ownership
–0.017 (0.15) –0.065 (0.49) –0.041 (0.33)
–0.053 (0.45) –0.009 (0.07) 0.032 (0.23)
0.0006 (0.46) –0.0034 (1.78) –0.0019 (1.16)
0.0000 (0.04) 0.0014 (0.59) 0.0001 (0.04)
26.8 8.9 10.2
0.0010 (0.43) –0.0115 (3.20) –0.0023 (0.72)
16.5 4.3 6.5
Owner/manager education is university, times: % raw material imported % output exported % foreign ownership R2
.95
.95
0.32 0.18 0.31
.96
Kenya: all firms (obs = 172) Owner/manager’s education: Primary school Secondary school University
–0.054 (0.56) –0.005 (0.05) 0.016 (0.15)
% raw materials imported % output exported % foreign ownership Owner/manager education is university, times: % raw material imported % output exported % foreign ownership 2 R
.96
–0.034 (0.35) 0.004 (0.03) 0.039 (0.34)
–0.042 (0.42) 0.033 (0.26) 0.076 (0.60)
0.0000 (0.02) –0.0026 (1.26) –0.0020 (1.27)
–0.0008 (0.47) 0.0027 (1.09) –0.0021 (0.84)
22.3 6.5 8.2
0.0017 (0.74) –0.0123 (3.33) 0.0011 (0.32) .97
12.4 3.1 5.3
.96
0.31 0.15 0.24
Notes: Absolute values of t-statistics in parentheses. Also included in cost functions were the logarithms of output and capital, each of these terms squared, and an interaction term between output and capital (as in Table 2.7).
Table 2.8b
Cost functions with skill measures included, Zimbabwe Sample means
Zimbabwe: formal firms (obs = 142) Owner/manager’s education: Secondary school University
0.0216 (0.15) –0.0373 (0.25)
% raw materials imported % output exported % foreign ownership
.0107 (0.08) –0.0321 (0.21)
–0.041 (0.29) 0.102 (0.63)
0.0004 (0.24) 0.0030 (1.46) 0.0011 (0.80)
0.0024 (1.19) 0.0033 (1.33) 0.0032 (1.62)
19.2 13.0 14.0
–0.0044 (1.50) –0.0025 (0.61) –0.0041 (1.58)
8.7 5.7 8.0
Owner/manager education is university, times: % raw material imported % output exported % foreign ownership .95
.95
.95
0.0500 (0.44) –0.0256 (0.20)
0.0376 (0.33) –0.0204 (0.16)
0.0008 (0.01) 0.1104 (0.77)
0.0005 (0.33) 0.0031 (1.48) 0.0012 (0.86)
0.0025 (1.21) 0.0034 (1.37) 0.0030 (1.50)
16.0 11.5 11.8
–0.0043 (1.45) –0.0023 (0.56) –0.0037 (1.36)
7.2 4.8 6.7
Zimbabwe: all firms (obs = 170) Owner/manager’s education: Secondary school University % raw materials imported % output exported % foreign ownership Owner/manager education is university, times: % raw material imported % output exported % foreign ownership R2
.96
.96
.97
0.46 0.37
Is African Manufacturing Skill Constrained? 67
R2
0.48 0.42
Cost functions with skill measures included, Ghana
68
Table 2.8c
Sample means
Ghana: large firms (10 or more employees) (obs = 80) Owner/manager’s education: Primary school Secondary school University
0.043 (0.22) –0.087 (0.42) 0.427 (1.71)
% raw materials imported % output exported % foreign ownership
0.038 (0.19) –0.091 (0.44) 0.426 (1.70)
0.044 (0.22) –0.135 (0.61) 0.340 (1.22)
–0.0006 (0.29) –0.0023 (0.78) 0.0044 (1.36)
–0.0041 (1.29) –0.0034 (0.77) 0.0099 (1.71)
20.0 6.7 10.6
0.0059 (1.40) 0.0022 (0.38) –0.0070 (1.14)
11.5 3.7 6.6
Owner/manager education is university, times: % raw material imported % output exported % foreign ownership R2
.93
0.39 0.33 0.16
.93
.94
0.386 (2.24) 0.215 (1.15) 0.519 (2.07)
0.389 (2.23) 0.190 (0.96) 0.465 (1.72)
–0.0002 (0.09) –0.0027 (0.75) 0.0027 (0.80)
–0.0019 (0.57) –0.0038 (0.72) 0.0045 (0.92)
12.8 4.0 7.2
0.0035 (0.75) 0.0024 (0.35) –0.0037 (0.54)
7.1 2.3 4.0
Ghana: all firms (obs = 132) Owner/manager’s education: Primary school Secondary school University
0.389 (2.29) 0.216 (1.16) 0.526 (2.12)
% raw materials imported % output exported % foreign ownership Owner/manager education is university, times: % raw material imported % output exported % foreign ownership R2
.92
.92
0.45 0.27 0.11
.92
Notes: Absolute values of t-statistics in parentheses. Also included in cost functions were the logarithm of output and the logarithm of output squared (as in Table 2.7).
Is African Manufacturing Skill Constrained? 69
sector and one informal sector firms with university-trained owner/managers who export any of their output. Second, as discussed above, without better information on exogenous determinants of access to export markets, it is not possible to know whether low-cost firms with educated owners are better equipped to sell their output abroad, or whether involvement in foreign markets makes it easier for more educated owners to produce using lower-cost methods.
5.
Interpretation of the results
There are a number of potential explanations for the absence of significance of the components of technological ability (A) in countries in which it is generally believed that a constraining factor is human capital and technological infrastructure. Consider the specification that assumes the components of A are multiplicative elements in the cost function. First, the relatively non-competitive environment may lead to limited efforts to utilise those skills that are present. Second, even where skilled managers are present or R&D takes place, these may simply be devoted to efforts to redress the productivity-depressing effects imposed by the protectionist regimes. For example, engineers may spend their time adjusting equipment to cope with low-quality intermediate inputs that are locally available. While this may lead to higher productivity than in their absence, they are mainly redressing the productivity-depressing effects of policy, and the net effect of their effort is likely to be small. Surveys of firms in Africa repeatedly find that firms frequently encounter difficulties with arbitrary foreign exchange allocations, zoning, building and licensing codes, and uncertain quality of telecommunications and electricity. For example, the surveys discussed in this paper indicate that the availability of foreign exchange is a special problem among formal sector firms. In Kenya, 35.4 per cent of firms indicate they have ‘very severe problems’ regarding delays in obtaining foreign exchange, and 41.6 per cent report very severe problems in foreign exchange availability. Of formal firms in Zimbabwe, 27 per cent firms report very severe problems with delays in obtaining foreign exchange, and 52.1 per cent report very severe problems with foreign exchange availability. Reports of problems with infrastructure are also common. With such a large set of governmentimposed handicaps affecting them, it would be surprising if their technological abilities, however measured, would reveal themselves in a systematic fashion across firms. Some companies may use technologists to address regulations, some to correct infrastructure deficiencies, as in Nigeria (Lee et al., 1990), and others to improve productivity. Only after liberalization are the benefits from improved technological capacity likely to be measurable and lead to a significant reduction in costs.
70 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
The firms in our sample have not been challenged by newer technologies where the payoffs to domestic skills are likely to be largest. Simultaneously the failure of agricultural productivity to grow has limited the economywide growth in per capita income. Thus the change in sectoral structure engendered by different income elasticities among industrial goods has not had an effect. The absence of a need to alter production methods or sectoral mix has reduced the payoff to education. Even if there were an inflow of technology, and high education made its absorption potentially productive, the absence of a competitive environment limits these gains. Much of the empirical testing of the role of education in adjusting to technical change has been in the agricultural sector, which is usually much more competitive than the industrial sector, particularly in developing countries (see the references in footnote 3). In contrast, in Ghana, Kenya and Zimbabwe the survival environment is lax. Tariffs and quotas protect industrial firms from external competition, while internal rivalry is reduced by the relatively small number of firms producing a specified product. The shift in short-run supply curves induced by abnormal profits in competitive markets is not forthcoming, as there are a limited number of firms capable of entering most industries. Firms possessing technical abilities may choose not to utilise them to increase productivity or reduce costs. The abilities of skilled personnel may be devoted to insuring the existence and exploitation of profit possibilities made possible by tariffs, quotas and cheap credit. Firm-level efforts to improve productivity are the result of an income and a substitution effect. High levels of protection, ceteris paribus, increase the firm’s profits per unit of effort. If the foregone ‘leisure’ or easy life is a normal good, protection will tend to reduce cost saving efforts. However, higher levels of effective protection increase the opportunity cost of forgoing additional output from productivity-augmenting activities. Thus, the impact of firm-level abilities on productivity in the presence of protection is ambiguous. An absence of an association between firm skills, however measured, and productivity levels among firms is not an indication that such skills do not provide the potential to raise productivity. Rather, such a capacity may not be deployed in pursuit of greater cost reduction but in the search for greater rents or an easier life.
6.
Conclusions
The absence of a significant private payoff to technological capability may be surprising given the frequently heard statement that the binding constraint on African industrial development is an insufficient supply of technologically capable manpower. This is also the implication of the many cross-country studies that find that an important source of low growth in per capita income in Africa is the low level of human capital, however
Is African Manufacturing Skill Constrained? 71
measured. Our results are not necessarily in conflict with this view. They should be interpreted as indicating that in the non-competitive industrial sector with very little inflow of new technology the contribution of technological abilities, however measured, is limited. If there were a liberalisation of the economy that generated greater competition or if there were an acceleration of export growth, permitting the import of new technology embodying inputs, the contribution of local skills would become more significant in raising output. The experience of other countries also suggests that as the economy becomes open to flows of international knowledge, whether through informal transfers from purchasers of exports or through technology licences, the technological capacity of local industry becomes important.10 The policy implications of the empirical analysis are clear. Absent greater prospective competition, continued efforts to develop high level industrial skills may be wasteful. The conundrum is that the absence of these skills may limit the benefits to the industrial sector from future liberalisation, and lead to a weak supply response to improved incentives.
Notes *
1 2
3
4
5
University of Pennsylvania and Princeton University. We are grateful to Tyler Biggs of the Africa Technical Department of the World Bank for making available the data upon which this paper is based. We received helpful comments from participants at a symposium at the Eindhoven Technical University. A. Szirmai provided many helpful suggestions. Part of the research was financed by the World Bank’s Regional Program on Enterprise Development. Pack gratefully acknowledges partial support from the University of Pennsylvania Research Foundation and the World Bank Development Research Group. Meier and Steel (1989) contains a good selection of representative views. For a general discussion of the technological requirements for industrial development see Lall (1990). Pack (1993) provides an overview of industrial development in Africa and extensive references to the literature. For studies demonstrating the interaction of education and technological change in agriculture see Welch (1970), Foster et al. (1995a, 1995b), Rosenzweig (1995). The measures described in the text and shown in Table 2.1 could be improved. For example, standard international trade data contained in the UN Yearbook of International Trade Statistics allow a disaggregated breakdown of imports that would allow more precision with respect to both the equipment and intermediate imports. However, the latest date for which these are available for the African economies is 1990, two years before the firm-level surveys were carried out. Thus we have cited the aggregate data generated by the World Bank. In almost all cases the sectoral shares of the 28 sectors, not reproduced in Table 2.2, show little change, with the exception of the Zimbabwean food and beverage sectors. The greater summary measure in Zimbabwe compared to Ghana and Kenya is largely due to the expansion in the share of the beverage sector, a sector in which the technology employed has not changed.
72 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania 6 It should be noted that the use of sample weights together with small sample sizes can yield a misleading picture of the activities of these firms. For example, the Kenyan numbers indicate that 58.7 per cent of wood-sector workers are in the ‘miscellaneous’ category that includes ‘carvings, camping equipment, and automobile trim.’ This is due to one 70-person firm that makes camping equipment, and which was given a sample weight four times the sector average. Likewise, the result that 41 per cent of food and beverage workers make animal feed and hay is due to one poultry-feed firm with 420 workers and a sample weight three times the sector average. 7 The survey does not ask whether the owner and manager are the same person, and this might account for the similarity between the education of owners and managers. 8 We also experimented with including dummy variables for the city in which firms are located, and these were also insignificant. The results are consistent with there being neither regional nor sectoral variation in input prices. 9 One of the benefits of panel data would be the ability to address the question of whether efficient firms are more successful exporters or whether exporting generates learning. 10 See the East Asian Economic Miracle (World Bank, 1993d), chapter 6.
3 Measuring Manufacturing Performance in Tanzania: GDP, Employment and Comparative Labour Productivity, 1961–95 Adam Szirmai, Menno Prins and Wessel Schulte*
1
Introduction
Tanzania is a late late-comer to the process of industrialization: the first steps towards industrialization were taken after World War II. These took the form of processing for export markets. The expansion of manufacturing activities for the local market started in the mid-1950s. This late start is illustrated by the modest numbers of manufacturing establishments in Table 3.1. Of the establishments with ten or more persons engaged in operation in 1961, only 101 predated 1945. Including small scale establishments, the number of establishments in 1933 was 321 (Silver, 1984, p. 42). According to official figures, the manufacturing sector contributed 3.5 per cent to GDP at factor cost in 1961 (Central Statistical Bureau, 1964b). 1 Since independence, the number of establishments increased sharply to 569 by 1965, peaking at 1282 in 1978 and subsequently declining to 886 establishments in 1989. In 1961, the large- and medium-scale manufacturing sector (10+) employed 22,000 persons. Manufacturing employment increased to 110,000 in 1978, in which year the sector registered a peak share of 12 per cent of GDP. In 1989 employment in medium- and largescale manufacturing had increased to 124,000 persons, while its share in GDP dropped to 8 per cent. One may conclude that Tanzanian industrialization started almost from scratch in the mid-1950s. The aim of this article is to chart the course of industrialisation since independence, by contributing to the statistical measurement of manufacturing performance. To this end, we will scrutinize the available statistics on medium- and large-scale establishments (with ten or more persons engaged), for which the most reliable data are available. This article summarizes and integrates the results of two bodies of research on 73
74 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Table 3.1
Indicators of Tanzanian manufacturing performance, 1946–89a
Year
Number of establishments In production (number)
1946 1957 Independence (1961) 1965 1978 1989
101 b 293 b 380 b 569 1 282 886
Increase c (annual average) 17 22 38 51 –33
Persons engaged (thousands)
22 28 110 124
Value added (% of GDP)
3.5 9.2 12.3 8.4
Source: Number of establishments 1946–65 from Survey of Industries 1965 (Central Statistical Bureau, 1966), table 5; persons engaged and value added 1961 from Skarstein and Wangwe (1986), p. 79; persons engaged 1978 and 1989 from Census of Industrial Production 1978 (Bureau of Statistics, 1995b) and Census of Industrial Production 1979 (Bureau of Statistics, 1994a); value added 1978 and 1989 from Bureau of Statistics (1995c), table 7.2. Notes: a All data refer to establishments with 10 or more persons engaged, except for value added data which refer to the entire manufacturing sector. Data until 1965 include activities in sisal decortication and motor vehicle repair, which are excluded in 1978 and 1989. b Number of establishments which were still in production in 1965. c Average annual increase in the number of establishments.
Tanzanian manufacturing performance: a reconstruction of nominal and real output and employment in Tanzanian manufacturing (Prins and Szirmai, 1998) and a benchmark comparison of levels of real output and labour productivity in manufacturing between Tanzania and the world productivity leader, the USA, for 1989 (Szirmai and Schulte, 1998).2 The article has the following objectives: • to present consistent newly revised time series of 10+ manufacturing value added at current prices for the medium- and large-scale manufacturing sector as a whole and for major branches of manufacturing (Sections 2 and 3) • to present consistent indexes of industrial output and labour productivity for major branches of manufacturing and total manufacturing, for the period 1961–95 (Section 4) • to present a benchmark comparison of real output and labour productivity in Tanzania vis-à-vis the USA in 1989, using the methodology developed in the International Comparisons of Output and Productivity project (ICOP) (Section 5)
Measuring Manufacturing Performance 75
• to combine US and Tanzanian time series and the 1989 benchmark, in order to measure comparative trends of Tanzanian labour productivity (Section 6) • to discuss the implications of the newly constructed series for our understanding of growth, structural change and productivity in Tanzanian manufacturing (Section 6)
2
Data sources for time series on 10+ manufacturing
The main data sources for the manufacturing sector in Tanzania are the annual survey of industrial production (Bureau of Statistics, ASIP, various issues), the 1978 and 1989 censuses of industrial production (Bureau of Statistics, 1985b, 1993a, 1994a) and the quarterly surveys of industrial production covering establishments with 50 or more persons engaged (Bureau of Statistics, QSIP, various issues). Additional sources are input-output tables (Bureau of Statistics, 1986), informal sector surveys (Planning commission, 1991, 1995), and price indices and economic surveys (Bureau of Statistics, 1972, 1977, 1982, 1985a). Our main source for nominal value added in 10+ manufacturing are the surveys and censuses. Figure 3.1 summarizes these sources and compares their coverage.
Figure 3.1
Comparison of coverage of statistical sources
Coverage Census
a
I/O table
b
Census
IS-
IS-
surveyd
surveyd
1+
Census
5+ ASIP
10+ 1961
1965–74
Ec. surveyc 1976 1978
ASIP 1979–88
ASIP 1989 1990 1991 1994/95
Year
Notes: ASIP = Annual Survey of Industrial Production. IS-survey = Informal Sector Survey. I/O table = Input–Output table. Ec. Surv. = Economic Survey. a 1961 Census results are not comparable to later industrial surveys/censuses. z The coverage of the I/O table is not based on a canvassing procedure of 1+ establishments, but on estimates based on data such as the ‘final demand’ for certain manufacturing products. Estimates thus attempt to reflect 1+ coverage. c Although no ASIP was published in 1975–77, data were collected through the ASIP questionnaires and the aggregates were published in the Economic Survey. For 1978, 10+ estimates have been published in the Economic Survey, since census results did not became available till 1985. d The Informal Sector Surveys covered establishments with 5 or fewer paid employees not using high technology. This does not correspond to our categorization of 1–4 persons engaged.
76 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
3
Reconstruction of nominal 10+ GDP, 1961–95
Careful analysis of the primary sources identifies three main sources of error (Prins and Szirmai, 1998): (a) undercoverage of 10+ establishments in the directory of establishments (b) treatment of non-response (c) conceptual errors. Adjustments for these sources of error are made for two periods: 1978–90 and 1965–78. Additional sources of error, which will not be discussed in this article, are errors in the raw data of the 1989 census, the changing categorization of activities in economic sectors and inadequate treatment of the small-scale and informal sector in the national accounts, using rules of thumb (see Prins and Szirmai, 1998, sections 2.2.2, 2.4 and 2.5). The issue of changes in categorization has been dealt with by aggregating manufacturing sectors into six major branches. The informal sector merits treatment in a separate article (see also Chapter 14). This paper limits itself to medium- and largescale enterprises with ten or more persons employed. 3.1
Coverage
The framework for data collection is the directory of establishments maintained at the industrial section of the Bureau of Statistics. The coverage of medium- and large-scale establishments in the directory varies over time and does not adequately reflect changes in the real volume of activities. There are particularly large differences in coverage between survey years and census years (see Prins and Szirmai, 1998, table 2.2). For instance, the directory for the 1974 survey lists 499 enterprises. This jumps to 1282 in the census year 1978. In the survey year 1988 the directory includes 711 establishments; this jumps to 866 in the census year 1989. In some cases establishments, such as furniture making and tailoring, have deliberately been omitted from the annual surveys (omitted establishments). In most cases, the differences are unintentional (undercoverage). 3.1.1
Adjustments for undercoverage
For the period 1978–90 coverage adjustments have been based on analysis of a sample of 102 50+ establishments drawn from the 1989 census. For these establishments files were available with the original survey and census returns for all years. These files also indicated which years an establishment was in operation, but was not covered. Coverage rates are calculated as percentages of the establishments in operation in a given year. These coverage rates were used to make upward adjustments of value added.
Measuring Manufacturing Performance 77
For the period 1965-78 we made a rough adjustment. We compared gross output from the 1978 economic survey, which is consistent in coverage with the surveys prior to 1978 with gross output from the 1978 census. We used this ratio to make an upward adjustment for value added in the pre-1978 years. 3.1.2
Adjustment for omitted establishments
Value added in omitted establishments (1965-78) was calculated as follows (see Prins and Szirmai, 1998, appendix D). For 1966, we calculated omitted value added as a residual, by subtracting the following from total 5+ value added in the national accounts: unadjusted 10+ value added, estimated value added for non-response (see below) and estimates for 5–9 value added. The 1966 proportion of omitted to total value added was used to adjust value added for the whole period. 3.2
Treatment of non-response in official statistics
Between 1961–71 the numbers in the ASIP reflect responding establishments only. No adjustments have been made for non-response. Between 1972 and 1974 the ASIP data have been adjusted for non-response. In 1976, the data in the input-output table have been adjusted for non-response. For the period 1978–90 no published information is available on treatment of non-response. Interviews within the bureau of statistics revealed that the methodology for dealing with non-response was that of simple repetition. If an establishment does not respond in a given year, one takes the previous year’s figures. If an establishment does not respond for several years, one takes the figures from the last year in which it responded. 3.2.1
Adjustments for non-response, 1978–90
For the calculation of the effects of non-response on value added, we have examined records of a sample of 102 50+ establishments from the 1989 census. The aim of this exercise is to make an estimate of the understatement of value added of non-responding establishments, resulting from the method of simple repetition of value added. Our basic approach is to inflate the repeated value added figures with the consumer price index, to account for rapid price changes.3 For the sample it is known for each year between 1978 and 1990 whether an establishment is a non-respondent in that year, and, if so, for how many successive years it has been a non-respondent. 4 The establishments in the sample are subdivided into three size classes (50–99, 100–499, 500+). Within each of the three size classes distinguished we can express the degree of underestimation of value added in year t (UEt in percentages) as a sum of underestimations (ue in percentages) caused by subsets (or cohorts) of establishments of which nominal value added data are repeated for a given number of successive years, because of non-response. For one
78 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
cohort the degree of underestimation equals the proportion of all establishments which are not responding for a given number of years (for example, two successive years), weighted by the price indexes over the period of successive non-response.5 In formula, the degree underestimation of value added in a size class is calculated as follows: UEt =
St
∑ ue
t ,i
and uet ,= i
i= 1
tnrt nrt (t − i ) CPI t − 1 Nt tnrt CPI t − i
(3.1)
UEt is the underestimation of value added due to non-response, expressed as a percentage of unadjusted value added Nt is the number of establishments in the sample which are in production in year t tnrt is the total number of non-respondents in the sample in year t St is the maximum number of successive years value added is repeated for a given establishment in year t, nrt (t–i) is the number of non-respondents of which value added has been repeated since year t–i CPIt is the consumer price index in year t The estimate for the overall underestimation of value added was calculated as a weighted average of the degrees of underestimation per size class, weighted with value added weights per size class from the census.6 3.2.2
Adjustments for non-response, 1965–74
The records of the annual surveys enabled us to make estimates for value added of non-responding establishments for the years 1965–71. For the years 1965–71 we have calculated non-response rates and calculated non-response value added at branch level (see Prins and Szirmai, 1998, tables E-2 and E-3). 3.3
Conceptual errors
A change in the questionnaire design for the ASIP, gradually introduced from 1980 onwards, gave rise to errors in the calculations of manufacturing value added. These flaws were discovered during the in-depth analysis of the results of the 1989 census, which was based on the same flawed questionnaire design. Owing to an ambiguous definition of an intermediate input category labelled all other costs, responding establishments were inclined to allocate huge amounts of interest payments to intermediate inputs. Since interest costs are a component of value added rather than intermediate inputs, value added is wrongly defined and, as a consequence, substantially underestimated. Examination of the cost structure of 10+ establishments in the census revealed that some establishments have
Measuring Manufacturing Performance 79
enormous amounts of costs allocated to the residual all other costs category. In particular they have allocated large amounts of interest payments to this category, where they do not belong.7 This conclusion is based on the following reasoning. The questionnaire distinguishes 16 categories for production costs. One of these categories is bank charges and insurance paid, which explicitly excludes interest costs. However, the instructions for the category all other costs do not indicate that interest costs should be excluded. They explicitly exclude labour costs, sales taxes, corporate taxes, excise duties and depreciation, but there is no mention of interest at all. In Figure 3.2 we can see how important all other costs are compared to most other intermediate input cost categories. From an analysis of firm level-data for 175 large firms accounting for 96 per cent of ‘all other costs’, we conclude that the all other costs category indeed includes interest payments which should have been allocated to value added. Some other components of value added have also been erroneously included in all other costs, because they were not identified elsewhere in the questionnaire. These cost categories are bad debts, directors’ fees and donations. A less important conceptual error is that profits from sale of fixed assets should not have been included in the calculation of gross output. As gross output is too high, gross value added at factor cost is overstated by 0.3 billion TSh. Figure 3.2
Cost structure, 1989 census
50 40 30 20 10
All other costs
Miscellaneous
Professional & office exp.
Bank charges & insurance
Cost of resales
Transport
Industrial services
Fuel, Lubr., Electr. & Water
Chem. & Pack. materials
0 Raw materials
Intermediate inputs (billion TSh)
60
80 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
3.3.1
Adjustments to value added, 1978–90
The most important conceptual adjustment to the census data has been achieved by reclassifying a portion of the cost category all other costs from intermediate inputs to value added. Our estimate of the total amount of non-intermediate inputs incorrectly allocated to all other costs was 11 billion out of a total of 17 billion TSh. in this category (Prins and Szirmai, 1998, tables A-1 and A-4). Reallocation of these cost categories to value added resulted in a downward adjustment of intermediate inputs from 98 billion TSh to 87 billion TSh. Correspondingly, gross value added was adjusted upwards by 11 billion TSh. Thus, huge adjustments have been made in 1989 value added for all branches (except branch 39). Total value added has been adjusted upward by 51 per cent. The most notable adjustment is the 241 per cent increase in value added for ISIC category 32 (textiles and leather), which increases its share in total value added from 7.9 per cent to no less than 17.8 per cent! The questionnaire used for the 1989 census had gradually come into use since 1980. We have made an estimate of the rate of adoption of the new questionnaire and have backcast and forecast the 1989 adjustments to value added and intermediate inputs at branch level. The questionnaire adoption rate was estimated from the sample of 50+ establishments taken from the 1989 database (see Prins and Szirmai, 1998, appendix B). For each establishment we were able to identify the year the ‘new’ questionnaire design was first used. The adjustments made in the 1989 census have been extrapolated to 1980–88 and to 1990, multiplying 1989 adjustments to gross output and intermediate inputs with the adoption rate of the new questionnaire for each year.
3.3.2
Estimates of nominal value added 1961–65 and 1991–95
Although no annual surveys were held between 1961 and 1964, we do have data for nominal value added in 1+ manufacturing from 1960 to 1966 (OECD, 1971, table 2-4). Assuming that the growth rate of nominal value added for 10+ manufacturing equals that of 1+ manufacturing , we have applied the growth rates of the 1+ series to backcast 1965 10+ value added to 1961. No annual survey has been published since the 1990 survey. Therefore, we use a real output index and a price index to extrapolate 1990 value in order to arrive at value added estimates in current values for the years 1991–95. The price index has been derived from two sources: the consumer price index (CPI) (1990–92) and the producer price index (PPI) (1992–95).8 The quantity index used is the improved index of industrial production, which will be discussed in Section 4.
Table 3.2
Level adjustments to nominal MVA, 1960–95
Unadjusted MVA
OC-adj.b
NR-adj.c
OE-adj.d UC-adj.e (Millions TSh)
Change of MVAa due to adjustment for: Extrapolated
OC-adj.b
NR-adj.c
OE-adjd (%)
UC-adj.e
Total
32 35 34 30 33 34 33 35 36 33 50 45 29 34 3 8 10 14 21 88 12
52 49 45 38 39 37 36 35 36 33 50 45 29 34 3 11 25 47 83
243 272 276 350 267 295 319 378 475 561 643 806 914 1 157 1 246 1 480 2 075 2 186 2 842 2 927 2 891 3 108 3 204 3 620 4 417
282 297 323 390 497 571 657
2 842 2 927 2 900 3 148 3 333 3 994 5 269
2 842 2 985 3 279 3 983 4 862 5 706 7 241
307 327 344 402
405 441 460 522 659 766 874 1 087 1 244 1 537 1 863 2 143 2 678 2 926 2 926 3 238 3 622 4 555 5 873 6 812 8 094
6 1 1 3 5 2 2
0 0 0 1 4 10 19
0 2 13 27 46 43 37
9 10 6 3
19
83
81
1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1978* 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984
MVAa after adjustments for:
82
Table 3.2
(continued)
Unadjusted MVA
1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995
5 112 6 412 11 062 11 358 21 474 23 956
MVAa after adjustments for: OC-adj.b 6 373 8 525 14 545 15 866 32 443 37 478
NR-adj.c 8 915 11 714 20 790 25 849 32 653 38 681
OE-adj.d UC-adj.e (Millions TSh)
Change of MVAa due to adjustment for: Extrapolated
9 812 12 360 21 679 26 642 32 653 38 681
OC-adj.b
NR-adj.c
25 33 31 40 51 56
40 37 43 63 1 3
OE-adjd (%)
UC-adj.e 10 6 4 3 0 0
Total 92 93 96 135 52 61
48 128 53 473 63 535 82 159 98 818
Sources: Unadjusted data: 1965–74: ASIP; 1975–78: Economic Survey; 1978: Census; 1979–1988, 1990: ASIP; 1989: 1989 Census; adjusted data: Prins and Szirmai (1998) (appendixes A–G). a Change calculated as the percentage change of adjusted value compared to the pre-adjustment value. b Other costs based adjustment. c Non-response based adjustment. d Omitted establishments based adjustment. e Undercoverage based adjustment.
Table 3.3
Adjusted nominal value added, 1961–1995 (thousands TSh) Unadjusted
Adjusted ISIC Branch
131 318 135 661 12 627 180 020 202 029 235 746 286 292 310 905 334 000 390 272 403 249 477 801 627 467 694 642 800 919 774 318 1 134 567
32 Textiles & leather
93 178 144 031 152 849 143 557 193 533 278 753 300 707 368 850 448 992 481 125 572 779 675 596 900 910 892 085 970 942 1 227 974 1 345 426
33/34 Wood, furnitures & fixtures, paper, printing & publishing
42 032 42 794 45 803 47 739 55 176 70 593 64 198 61 144 89 133 122 775 150 762 177 831 213 552 287 409 323 294 359 672 494 176
35 Chemicals, petroleum, rubber & plastics
25 154 26 787 52 882 53 640 62 789 65 486 81 270 121 236 131 646 249 184 286 029 337 360 339 244 347 488 471 689 558 216 676 847
36 Non-metallic minerals
5 916 11 749 21 394 23 361 28 923 30 090 33 817 49 636 41 022 48 491 96 173 60 140 62 566 97 185 99 560 120 741 189 175
37/38/39 (Basic) metals, machinery & equipment and other manufacturing
107 189 79 507 65 912 73 202 116 294 84 841 107 580 174 880 199 329 245 445 354 489 414 570 534 159 606 824 571 271 581 366 714 357
3 Total manufacturing
243 439 271 745 275 520 350 061 404 787 440 530 460 466 521 519 658 743 765 510 873 864 1 086 650 1 244 123 1 537 293 1 863 480 2 143 298 2 677 899 2 925 632 3 237 676 3 622 286 4 554 547
3 Total manufacturing
266 701 295 162 318 625 378 324 475 411 560 616 642 871 806 328 914 327 1 156 652 1 245 622 1 480 345 2 074 758 2 842 316 2 927 333 2 890 897 3 108 206
83
1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981
31 Food, beverages & tobacco
84
Table 3.3
(continued) Unadjusted
Adjusted ISIC Branch
31 Food, beverages & tobacco
32 Textiles & leather
33/34 Wood, furnitures & fixtures, paper, printing & publishing
35 Chemicals, petroleum, rubber & plastics
36 Non-metallic minerals
37/38/39 (Basic) metals, machinery & equipment and other manufacturing
3 Total manufacturing
3 Total manufacturing
1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995
2 026 862 2 067 669 2 582 369 3 148 163 3 099 117 5 157 851 7 666 631 12 441 829 17 149 464 21 232 538 25 522 856 30 743 364 43 202 958 53 931 263
1 198 534 1 812 035 2 022 511 2 238 412 2 577 458 5 331 612 6 865 440 5 826 626 5 597 233 6 459 244 7 033 218 7 567 179 8 666 806 12 257 957
499 515 549 270 760 200 870 414 1 107 314 1 546 226 2 044 644 3 017 332 3 755 861 4 328 090 4 138 842 7 639 361 6 716 699 8 543 564
982 171 889 370 1 228 673 1 398 033 2 189 489 4 903 191 4 960 480 4 901 342 5 432 448 6 944 192 7 650 103 8 002 358 10 917 273 12 284 511
246 378 326 831 170 774 384 734 917 068 1 237 203 1 359 874 1 422 835 1 176 377 2 059 175 1 809 982 2 427 974 2 781 754 3 770 135
919 253 1 167 309 1 329 517 1 772 483 2 469 293 3 503 219 3 744 791 5 042 905 5 570 034 7 105 139 7 317 953 7 154 866 9 873 702 8 030 217
5 872 714 6 812 485 8 094 045 9 812 238 12 359 739 21 679 302 26 641 860 32 652 870 38 681 417 48 128 378 53 472 955 63 535 101 82 159 192 98 817 647
3 203 832 3 619 760 4 417 219 5 111 606 6 412 236 11 062 008 11 357 863 21 474 018 23 955 853
Source: Prins and Szirmai (1998).
Measuring Manufacturing Performance 85
3.4
Summary of adjustments
Table 3.2 provides a summary of all the adjustments to aggregate 10+ manufacturing value added. The adjusted figures for nominal value added by branch of manufacturing are reproduced in Table 3.3. In the right-hand columns of Table 3.2 adjustments are expressed as percentage changes relative to value added after previous adjustments. The overall level adjustments are substantial. The census year 1978 is the only year in which there have been but modest adjustments. The greatest upward adjustment to value added was made for 1988 (135 per cent). In 1990 the adjustment was 61 per cent. Over the whole period the adjusted series tend to be smoothed out, as jumps in coverage have been eliminated and the whole series have become more consistent.
4
New indices of industrial production
For most years official real value added series have only been constructed for total manufacturing. An exception is the index of industrial production (IIP), published in the quarterly survey of industrial production (QSIP) from 1985 onwards. Real value added series have been constructed at 1966 base prices (1960–80), 1976 prices (1964–94) and 1985 prices (1986–94). For 1976–84 an indirect approach has been followed, deflating current value added (1+) from the national accounts with a cost of living index of clothing and footwear (Bureau of Statistics, 1985a). For all other years an direct approach has been followed, in which quantity relatives have been weighted with base year value added shares. For the 1966 series no sources and methods are available. The 1976 series are based on quantity relatives for 14 commodities. The 1985 series are based on 120 commodities derived from the quarterly survey among 50+ enterprises. We constructed a new index 1965–95 based on the following principles: use of as much commodity information as possible, consistent application of the direct approach of weighting quantity relatives to calculate a Laspeyres fixed base weighted index, and construction of indexes for six branches of manufacturing as well as for total manufacturing. 4.1
IIP, 1965–85
For the construction of an improved index of industrial production as many quantity data as possible were collected for the period 1965–85 (see Prins and Szirmai, 1998, appendix H). To construct an IIP for a large time span it is preferable to rebase the index regularly. The choice of base years was mainly determined by the availability of quantity information and the availability of value added weights for 10+ establishments from the surveys and censuses. The following base years have been chosen: 1966 (coverage 16 commodities), 1970 (coverage 19 commodities), 1975 (coverage 25 commodities), and 1980 (coverage 33 commodities).
86 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
The method of constructing the IIP is to select commodities representing given industries and to weight the commodity quantity relatives with the value added of industries which the commodities represent. If no quantity relatives can be calculated for a given industry, this industry is combined with a related industry for which a quantity relative is available. That quantity relative is then weighted with the value added of the combined sectors. Since we construct a fixed base index, we need value added weights for base years. The following years have been selected as base years: 1966, 1970, 1975 and 1980. The weights are constructed as follows. In a few cases there is more than one commodity representing a four digit manufacturing industry. In such cases, so-called intra-industry weights are needed. For the years 1965–85 we have used the gross output values of commodities within an industry from the 1989 census as intra-industry weights.9 The four-digit industry indexes within a three-digit ISIC branch are weighted with their industry value added to get a three-digit branch index. Industry weights are taken from the ASIP, censuses and the 1976 input-output table. (see Prins and Szirmai, 1998, tables H-5 and H-6 for weights). Each three-digit branch index is weighted with its branch value added, to arrive at an index for six major branches of manufacturing and an index for total manufacturing. In the calculation of the index for total manufacturing, we use the adjusted nominal value added series presented in Table 3.3 as weights. 4.2
Silver’s chain index, 1965–72
In The Growth of Manufacturing Industry in Tanzania, Silver (1984) provides a sophisticated index of industrial production for the years 1965–72. Utilizing an impressive amount of data derived from the QSIP questionnaires, Silver constructs indexes for 38 subindustries conform the 1958 ISIC classification. The Silver index differs from our Laspeyres fixed weighted index. Silver uses a Laspeyres chain index which will yield higher growth rates, since industries growing more rapidly will get higher weights in a chain index. Although we are aware of the methodological differences, we have nevertheless chosen to integrate Silver’s index for 1965-72 into our index, because of the far better commodity coverage of Silver’s chain index compared to our IIP 1965–85. We have recalculated Silver’s chain index for our six branches for the period 1965–72, using our adjusted nominal value added weights for our base years (1966 and 1970). 4.3
IIP, 1985–95
For 1985–95 there is an index of industrial production published in the QSIP. We found that there were significant discrepancies between several of the 1985 base weights applied in the QSIP and the value added
Measuring Manufacturing Performance 87
data from the 1985 survey. Moreover, the analysis of the surveys made clear that the reliability of the value added data in the mid-eighties is questionable. In our opinion the most reliable source for reweighting the IIP (1985-95) is the data from the 1989 census of industrial production, as adjusted in this report (see Section 3.4). We have reweighted the index of industrial production utilizing (adjusted) 1989 census value added as base year weights. The weighting procedures are the same as explained above for the 1965–85 index (see Prins and Szirmai, 1998, appendix I and Table I-3). 4.4
The new index of industrial production, 1961–95
For the period 1961–65 no commodity information was available for the construction of an index. To get an estimate for total manufacturing, we have retropolated the index figure for total manufacturing in 1966, using a real value added index derived from national accounts real manufacturing value added data for the early period (OECD, 1971, Table 2-5). For the period 1965–72 we have used Silver’s chain index. For 1972–85 we have used our index; for 1985–95 we have used the reweighted QSIP index. The resulting indexes for the period 1961–95 are reproduced in Table 3.4. 4.5
Employment and labour productivity
As is the case for nominal and real manufacturing value added, no consistent long-run series of manufacturing employment is available at branch level from published statistical sources. We have reconstructed an employment series, consistent in time and consistent with the adjusted nominal value added estimates for 10+ manufacturing. For the period 1965–78 we have incorporated the level adjustments for non-response and undercoverage in the employment series, under the assumption that the labour productivity of the covered (or responding) establishments is equal to the labour productivity of the non-covered (or non-responding) establishments. Thus we can apply the ratio of value adjusted for coverage and nonresponse to non-adjusted value added to the employment figures. Similar adjustments to the employment figures have been made for the years 1978–89, for all branches except the textiles/leather branch. This branch was characterized by major discrepancies in employment figures between census and non-census years. For this branch we have applied an ad hoc adjustment, interpolating between the census years (see for details Prins and Szirmai, 1998, appendix M). The resulting employment figures for 1965–90 are consistent with our adjusted value added figures. Table 3.5 presents the employment figures for six manufacturing branches and for total manufacturing. Table 3.6 presents the corresponding labour productivity indices.
Indexes of industrial production 1965–95
ISIC Branch
31 Food, beverages & tobacco
32 Textiles & leather
33/34 Wood, furnitures & fixtures, paper, printing & publishing
88
Table 3.4
35 Chemicals, petroleum, rubber & plastics
36 Non-metallic minerals
37/38/39 (Basic) metals, machinery & equipment and other manufacturing
3 Total manufacturing
(1976=100) 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981
37 37 41 43 51 51 59 84 86 81 78 100 92 103 90 77 67
24 30 31 45 47 63 62 80 90 94 92 100 105 97 104 99 90
100 114 101 116 124 123 145 141 159 142 123 100 151 124 100 108 97
26 55 57 62 62 65 78 91 88 90 95 100 94 98 80 77 75
28 57 59 113 118 124 114 130 150 106 115 100 115 105 111 84 107
24 27 24 33 29 29 48 61 81 91 92 100 112 133 138 130 114
22 24 26 28 31 37 38 48 52 57 65 84 93 93 91 100 105 107 103 96 88
Table 3.4
(continued)
ISIC Branch
31 Food, beverages & tobacco
32 Textiles & leather
64 67 62 57 54 48 57 55 62 64 62 65 66 69
83 62 60 57 58 75 82 76 77 73 65 68 66 58
1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995
33/34 Wood, furnitures & fixtures, paper, printing & publishing 91 68 58 62 83 114 111 109 101 90 71 101 72 66
35 Chemicals, petroleum, rubber & plastics (1976=100) 71 70 120 77 71 70 64 76 84 84 78 72 79 75
36 Non-metallic minerals
92 68 102 103 121 126 133 136 157 214 154 164 139 153
37/38/39 (Basic) metals, machinery & equipment and other manufacturing
132 167 194 137 152 115 102 110 141 133 100 88 125 69
3 Total manufacturing
83 77 88 72 73 71 75 75 84 84 74 75 79 72
Source: Prins and Szirmai (1998), table K-2.
89
Persons engaged in 10+ manufacturing, by branch (1965–90)
ISIC Branch
31 Food, beverages & tobacco
32 Textiles & leather
10 038 9 767 12 666 14 930 13 478 16 340 17 652 21 334 18 880 20 035 22 026 22 333 24 793 28 111 28 455 30 291 32 437 38 041 34 885 30 458 29 138 38 641 39 858 43 200 45 282 47 397
12 102 14 504 14 265 19 033 21 770 22 791 24 245 24 795 28 609 33 200 34 140 34 661 38 168 43 926 43 072 45 407 48 670 45 308 49 642 44 545 42 191 43 499 43 426 41 069 38 128 37 674
1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990
Source: Prins and Szirmai (1998), table M-10.
33/34 Wood, furnitures & fixtures, paper, printing & publishing 9 203 9 597 8 235 9 596 9 737 8 885 9 635 10 896 11 117 12 219 13 125 13 302 15 308 14 781 14 909 14 637 14 513 14 852 15 793 14 262 13 722 14 452 14 211 15 229 16 930 24 360
35 Chemicals, petroleum, rubber & plastics 955 2 330 1 767 2 507 1 997 2 208 2 782 4 876 4 769 5 309 5 235 5 304 5 604 7 900 7 480 8 890 9 388 9 772 9 439 8 085 6 447 6 930 7 042 6 741 6 677 6 534
90
Table 3.5
36 Non-metallic minerals
652 1 744 1 422 2 380 2 622 2 572 3 511 2 866 3 343 3 061 2 942 2 982 3 476 3 773 3 333 3 218 4 247 3 300 3 687 3 614 3 821 5 344 4 517 4 484 5 069 4 237
37/38/39 (Basic) metals, machinery & equipment and other manufacturing 6 204 7 116 5 977 5 402 5 538 5 719 7 582 8 277 9 304 10 316 11 253 11 402 13 947 14 194 12 836 13 566 14 090 14 242 14 546 13 156 12 402 11 303 11 041 10 919 13 793 14 211
3 Total manufacturing
39 154 45 058 44 332 53 847 55 142 58 515 65 407 73 044 76 022 84 139 88 721 89 984 101 295 112 685 110 084 116 009 123 345 125 515 127 991 114 120 107 721 120 168 120 096 121 642 125 879 134 413
Table 3.6
Labour productivity index for six branches of manufacturing, 1965–90 (1976 = 100)
ISIC Branch
31 Food, beverages & tobacco
1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990
82 85 73 65 84 70 75 88 102 90 79 100 83 82 70 57 46 38 43 45 44 31 27 30 27 29
32 Textiles & leather
68 71 75 83 75 95 89 112 109 98 93 100 96 76 84 75 64 64 43 47 46 47 59 70 69 71
33/34 Wood, furnitures & fixtures, paper, printing & publishing
35 Chemicals, petroleum, rubber & plastics
36 Non-metallic minerals
37/38/39 (Basic) metals, machinery & equipment and other manufacturing
145 158 162 160 169 184 200 173 191 155 124 100 131 112 89 99 89 81 57 54 60 77 107 97 86 55
146 126 171 131 165 155 148 99 98 90 96 100 89 66 57 46 42 38 39 79 63 54 52 50 60 68
128 98 123 141 135 144 97 135 134 103 117 100 99 83 99 78 75 83 55 84 81 68 83 88 80 111
44 43 47 71 60 59 72 84 99 101 93 100 91 106 123 109 92 106 131 168 126 153 119 107 91 113
3 Total manufacturing
71 73 76 81 84 88 90 104 110 100 93 100 93 86 85 74 64 60 54 70 60 55 53 55 53 56 91
Source: Tables 3.4 and 3.5.
92 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
5
The 1989 benchmark
In this section we present a level comparison of real labour productivity in manufacturing between Tanzania and the world productivity leader, the USA, for 1989 (see Szirmai and Schulte, 1988). Level comparisons are a useful complement to time series analysis, because they provide information on the absolute size of the gaps in real output and productivity between economies at given points in time. The productivity gaps provide indications of the size of the technology gap between economies. The benchmark comparisons can also serve as an anchor for trend comparisons. International comparisons require adequate converters. It is well known that comparisons based on exchange rates can substantially underestimate levels of national income and product in developing countries (see Kravis et al., 1982; Ren, 1997; Szirmai and Ren, 1998). From the perspective of welfare comparisons, expenditure-based purchasing power parities are more realistic converters than exchange rates. However, expenditure-based PPPs are less suitable for sectoral comparisons of real output and productivity, because they are not based on producer prices and because final products include productive contributions of many different sectors of the economy. For sectoral output and productivity comparison, industry of origin converters are required. In this paper, industry-of-origin unit value ratios (UVRs) are calculated for branches of manufacturing, using the industry-oforigin methodology developed in the International Comparisons of Output and Productivity project (ICOP). The UVRs are used to convert 1989 Tanzanian manufacturing GDP into US dollars. So far data availability has been a major constraint for the application of the ICOP methodology to an African economy. The methodology requires reliable data on product quantities and ex-factory output values, which are seldom available in published form. In the case of Tanzania, the Bureau of Statistics has made the basic files underlying the industrial census of 1989 available to us. This allowed us to reconstruct the necessary data on production quantities and values, from a very basic level. It should be stressed that the benchmark results presented in this paper are preliminary. 5.1
Methodology for the 1989 level comparison
The ICOP methodology for level comparisons has been described in detail in several publications (see Maddison and van Ark, 1988, 1994; Szirmai and Pilat, 1990; van Ark, 1993; Timmer, 1996). In this paper, we apply the methodology as refined in Timmer (1996). Here, we provide only a brief outline of the methods used. The primary sources used in this study are the US 1987 Census of Manufactures (US Department of Commerce, 1990b), the 1989 Annual Survey of Manufacturing (US Department of Commerce 1990a), the Tanzanian Census of Industrial Production (vols. IV–V, Bureau of Statistics
Measuring Manufacturing Performance 93
1993a, 1994a) and the data files underlying the Tanzanian published census. These sources provide information on product quantities and corresponding gross output values, making it possible to derive unit values for products or groups of products for both economies. The basic approach is to make matches of comparable products or product groups from the two censuses and to calculate unit value ratios (UVRs) for each of the matches. Subsequently these are aggregated into average unit value ratios for industries, branches and total manufacturing. These unit value ratios are used as conversion factors. Matches were made in 16 sample industries. On the US side these consist of one or more four-digit industries. For Tanzania, the commodity and output information collected in the 1989 industrial census has not been published. The information from the basic census data files on products and their output value was rearranged into four-digit ISIC industries (1968 version of ISIC; see United Nations, 1968b). These were combined into sample industries comparable to those on the US side. The conversion factors are calculated in a number of steps. 1. For each product match, UVRs are calculated (TSh/$). The initial unit value ratios derive from 1989 Tanzanian unit values and 1987 US unit values. 2. UVRs are put on a 1989–89 basis, using US 1987–89 price movements for each product group from the Bureau of Labour Statistics (1998). The 1989/1989 UVRs are used in all the subsequent calculations. 3. All the UVRs are aggregated into average UVRs at sample industry level using output quantities of either countries as weights: S
UVR
XU ( X ) j
=
∑Q
S
X ij
∗ PijX
i= 1 S
∑
UVR
XU (U ) j
Q ijX ∗ PijU
i= 1
where UVRjXU(X)
=
∑ (Q
U ij
∗ PijX )
i= 1 S
∑
(3.2)
(Q Uij ∗ PijU )
i= 1
is the unit value ratio of the Tanzanian shilling against the US dollar in sample industry j, at quantity weights of Tanzania
UVRjXU(U)
is the unit value ratio of the Tanzanian shilling against the US dollar in sample industry j, at quantity weights of the USA
i = 1…s
is the sample of matched items.
4. Sample industry UVRs are aggregated into branch UVRs. Manufacturing branches in this study consist of one or more ISIC three digit major
94 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
sectors. Where there is more than one sample industry in a branch (as in food products), the 1989 sample industry UVRs are aggregated at manufacturing branch level by taking the weighted average of sample industry UVRs using 1989 sample industry gross output as weights: O
UVR
XU (U ) k
=
∑ [GO
U (U ) j
]
(U ) ∗ UVR XU j
j= 1
(3.3)
O
∑ GO
U (U ) j
j= 1 O
UVR
XU ( X ) k
=
∑ GO
X (X ) j
j= 1
∑ [GO O
j= 1
X (X ) j
(X ) / UVR XU j ]
where GOjU(U) GOjX(X)
is gross output in US sample industry j in dollars is gross output in Tanzanian sample industry j in Tanzanian shillings k is the branch of industry j=1…o is sample industries belonging to a branch k However, following Timmer (1996), if the reliability of the UVR for a given sample industry is too low, we weight the original UVRs of the matched items with their output in Equation 3.2.10
5. The branch UVRs are aggregated into UVRs for total manufacturing, using branch gross output weights according to Equation 3.2. However, if the reliability of branch UVRs is too low, we use the sample industry gross output weights of step 4 to weight sample industry UVRs. 11 The general rationale behind these stepwise weighting procedures is to ensure that unit value ratios in large sample industries and large branches receive heavier weights than in small ones (see van Ark, 1993). However, where the unit value ratios are insufficiently reliable, we use gross output of matched items in a sample industry as weights at branch level and sample industry gross output weights at manufacturing level (see Timmer, 1996, for more detail). Thus, the more reliable a UVR the heavier the weight it receives in the aggregation procedure. 6. At each level of aggregation – sample industry, branch and total manufacturing – the UVRs can be used to convert 1989 value added into the currency of the other country for purposes of real value added comparisons. In binary comparisons one gets two UVRs at every level of aggregation, one at quantity weights of country X, the other at quantity
Measuring Manufacturing Performance 95
weights of country U. We use the Fisher geometric average of the two UVRs as a summary measure. We have made 76 product matches in 16 sample industries, representing 11 of the 15 branches of manufacturing. The important Tanzanian food manufacturing branch is represented by 6 sample industries. Another 10 branches were represented by a single sample industry. No matches were realized in metal products, machinery, electrical machinery and other manufacturing. For these branches we used the calculated UVRs for total manufacturing based on 11 branches. Appendix Table A.3 shows the coverage ratios at branch and sample industry levels. The matched value of output represents 31.6 per cent of the total gross value of output in Tanzania and 7.1 per cent in the USA. The low coverage on the US side is due to the fact that we are comparing a tiny industrial sector with a very large one. 5.2 5.2.1
Data sources for the 1989 benchmark comparison Tanzanian product listing
For Tanzania our basic source for the calculation of unit values consisted of the unpublished data files of the 1989 Census of Industries (Bureau of Statistics 1993a/1994a). The questionnaire for establishments with ten or more persons employed (form 1C-89-1) contained a question D: ‘Principal products manufactured during the year’, requesting information on the names of products, the units, installed capacity, production quantities and production values in 1000 shillings. The commodity data thus collected have not been published. However, Bureau of Statistics made the raw data files underlying the census available to us.12 These files contain information on quantities of different products produced by establishments and their corresponding output values. We rearranged this list of products into ISIC four-digit categories and created product listings for each industry. First, firms were allocated to an ISIC industry on the basis of their most important products. However, firms tend to produce a wide range of primary and secondary products. Therefore, the next step was to reallocate products to the ISIC industry producing those products as primary products. In the course of the data screening it was found that product names were frequently misspelt and units, quantities or values were frequently incorrectly reproduced. For many products information on either unit, quantity or value was lacking. A process of checking and cross-checking resulted in a valuable listing of commodities and their quantities and values. The provisional nature of this listing needs to be stressed. 5.2.2
Tanzanian output, value added and employment
For Tanzania we use our revised estimates of gross output, value added and employment for 10+ manufacturing in 1989 (see Tables 3.3 and 3.5; for
96 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
gross output, see Prins and Szirmai, 1998, table C-2). These estimates, especially for value added, are substantially higher than the official ones. Gross value added in the US census is measured without deducting the cost of services purchased from outside the manufacturing sector. Thus the US census concept of value added involves a degree of double counting. To ensure comparability with the USA, the Tanzanian value added concept has been adjusted to the US census concept of value added, which is gross of service inputs from outside the manufacturing sector. This was done by adding bank charges, insurance costs, transport costs, communication services, accountancy and professional services (see Bureau of Statistics, 1993a, codes 408–411). The basic data for 1989 are reproduced in Appendix Table A.1. 5.2.3
US product listing
For the USA our basic source was the 1987 Census of Manufactures (US Department of Commerce, 1990b), which lists approximately 11 000 products. For most, though not all, products the US census provides both quantity and value information for 1987. First, unit value ratios were computed on the basis of the two censuses, using Tanzanian 1989 unit values and US 1987 unit values. Subsequently the 1989/1987 unit value ratios were adjusted to a 1989–89 basis using US price indices for each product category for the period 1987–89 from the Bureau of Labour Statistics (1998). 5.2.4
US gross output, value added and employment
The data for 1989 on gross value of output (here, value of shipments), gross value added and employment by industry derive from the 1990 Annual Survey of Manufactures (US Department of Commerce, 1990a). The Tanzanian census refers to establishments with ten or more persons engaged. To ensure comparability, the US data have to be adjusted to a 10+ basis. As the ASM data for 1989 only provide information on output, value added and employment for total manufacturing, we used proportions of 10+/total value added and employment from the general summary of the 1987 census to adjust the US data to a 10+ basis. The basic data for the USA are reproduced in Appendix Table A.2. 5.3
Unit value ratios
The UVRs for different branches of manufacturing are reproduced in Table 3.7. The aggregate UVR (geometric average) for total manufacturing is 120 shillings to the US dollar, lower than the 1989 exchange rate of 143. 13 The price level, defined as the UVR divided by the exchange rate, is 0.8. On first sight, this result is surprising given the general complaint that Tanzanian exchange rates tend to be overvalued. However, the discussion concerning overvalued exchange rates refers primarily to internationally
Measuring Manufacturing Performance 97 Table 3.7 Unit value ratios and price levels by major manufacturing branch Tanzania/USA (TSh/$), 1989 UVR (TSh/US$)
Relative price level Tanzania At US At Tanzanian Geometric (USA = 100) quantity quantity average weights weights Food manufacturing Beverages Tobacco products Textile mill products Wearing apparel Leather products & footwear Wood products, furniture & fixtures Paper products, printing & publishing Chemical products (incl. oil) Rubber & plastic products Non-metallic mineral products Basic & fabricated metal productsa Machinery & transport equipmenta Electrical machinery & equipmenta Other manufacturing industriesa
102 69 51 105 42 36 90
45 81 51 110 28 20 86
68 75 51 107 35 27 88
0.5 0.5 0.4 0.7 0.2 0.2 0.6
160
139
149
1.0
470 333 90 177 177 177 177
110 325 143 78 78 78 78
227 329 114 117 117 117 117
1.6 2.3 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.8
Total manufacturing, census weightsb Total manufacturing, implicit UVRsc Exchange rate
177
78
117
0.8
198
73
120
0.8
143
143
143
Notes: a No sample industries for this branch. We used the UVR for the total of branches. b The UVR for total manufacturing is the gross output weighted average of branch or sample industry UVRs (see Timmer, 1996). c Implicit UVRs calculated from the summed branch value added totals in Table 3.8. These are the preferred UVRs.
tradable goods. A considerable portion of Tanzanian industrial output is directed to the domestic market and does not enter into international trade. The finding that UVRs for developing countries are well below the exchange rate has been found in several studies (for example, on China, Indonesia and India). However, low UVRs in part also reflect unrecognized quality differences for identical products and a predominance of lowquality items in the product mix. Lowest UVRs are found for food, beverages, wearing apparel and leather, and highest UVRs for rubber, chemicals, paper products and textiles. UVRs at US quantity weights are much higher than at Tanzanian quantity weights. This is standard in comparisons between high income and lowincome economies. Products which are relatively cheap and common in
98 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
the USA will tend to be expensive and rare in a low-income country such as Tanzania. Products which are cheap and common in Tanzania will tend to be rare in the USA. Therefore matches with high unit values will have high quantity weights in the USA and low quantity weights in Tanzania. Matches with low unit values will have high quantity weights in Tanzania and lower weights in the USA. 5.4
Productivity comparisons
Applying the branch unit value ratios from Table 3.7 to the gross value added figures from Appendix Tables A.1 and A.2 results in real comparisons of gross value added. Dividing these figures by the employment figures from Tables A.1 and A.2 results in real labour productivity comparisons. These comparisons are reproduced in Table 3.8. Aggregate real labour productivity in Tanzanian manufacturing in 1989 is 3.7 per cent of that in US manufacturing. There is substantial variance in branch productivity performance, varying from 2.6 per cent in chemical products and 3 per cent in paper products to 12.4 per cent in leather products and footwear and 10.5 per cent in electrical machinery and equipment. These productivity differentials are an indication of the vast technology gap between a developing economy such as Tanzania and economies operating at the technological frontier such as the USA. Productivity in the tiny Tanzanian manufacturing sector is lower than that found for large and dynamic Asian developing economies such as China and Indonesia. Two qualifying remarks are in order. In the first place, the product listings are not sufficiently detailed to allow for quality adjustments. It is likely that Tanzanian products are of lower quality than the corresponding US products. More detailed analysis of each of the matches, using information from outside the census, should be performed. In the second place, the comparison excludes the important small-scale and informal sector in Tanzania, characterized by highly labour-intensive activities. In most developing countries, productivity in the informal sector is much lower than in the formal sector, so that productivity comparisons for total manufacturing need to be adjusted downward even further. At this stage, we can safely say that our unit values and UVRs are a lower bound and our productivity comparisons are an upper bound. In spite of the low levels of productivity found, real Tanzanian productivity will be even lower than our estimates, after adjustments for quality differences and inclusion of small-scale labour-intensive enterprises.
6
New insights
In this section, we discuss the new insights in Tanzanian manufacturing performance arising from revised estimates of value added, employment and comparative productivity discussed above.
Table 3.8
Gross value added (census concept) per person, Tanzania and the USA (1989) At Tanzanian prices (in TSh) Tanzania
Food manufacturing Beverages Tobacco products Textile mill products Wearing apparel Leather products & footwear Wood products, furniture & fixtures Paper products, printing & publishing Chemical products Rubber & plastic products Non-metallic mineral products Basic & fabricated metal products Machinery & transport equipment Electrical machinery & equipment Other manufacturing industries Total manufacturing
USA
At US prices (in US$) Tanzania/ USA (%)
Tanzania
USA
Tanzania/ USA (%)
Geometric average, Tanzania/ USA (%)
203 370 816 907 712 352 205 282 48 669 120 675 150 251
8 387 897 10 413 211 15 691 221 4 229 796 1 306 552 1 305 577 3 828 677
2.4 7.8 4.5 4.9 3.7 9.2 3.9
4 511 10 027 13 871 1 871 1 734 6 111 1 754
82 572 150 548 305 552 40 281 30 798 36 648 42 331
5.5 6.7 4.5 4.6 5.6 16.7 4.1
3.6 7.2 4.5 4.7 4.6 12.4 4.0
321 831
11 517 612
2.8
2 318
72 141
3.2
3.0
845 705 726 943 390 347 470 994 419 871 778 159 267 095
66 647 074 17 537 943 5 703 193 10 680 022 12 819 273 11 234 739 12 307 000
1.3 4.1 6.8 4.4 3.3 6.9 2.2
7 711 2 234 2 737 6 072 5 413 10 032 3 443
141 811 52 669 63 071 60 344 72 431 63 478 69 537
5.4 4.2 4.3 10.1 7.5 15.8 5.0
2.6 4.2 5.4 6.7 4.9 10.5 3.3
312 562
13 844 486
2.3
4 278
69 787
6.1
3.7
Source: Gross value added and employment from Appendix Tables A.1 and A.2; UVRs from Table 3.7.
99
100 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
6.1
Level adjustments in nominal value added
It is beyond doubt that the level of medium- and large-scale manufacturing performance has been underestimated in the published statistics of Tanzania. In Figure 3.3 our level adjustments are graphically presented for the series 1965–78 and 1978–90. Manufacturing value added increased for the entire period, but most pronounced adjustments appeared between 1982 and 1990. Value added increased by 83 per cent in 1982, 135 per cent in 1988 and 61 per cent in 1990. Between 1965 and 1978 value added increased on average by 40 per cent. Though the adjusted levels are much higher, it can be seen that for 1965–78 the adjusted nominal trend closely follows the unadjusted trend, while this is not true for 1978–90. Especially between 1986 and 1990 the level adjustments are more pronounced than is the case for earlier years. 6.2
Changes in the structure of manufacturing
Table 3.9 compares the adjusted and not-adjusted value added shares of six branches of manufacturing for the years 1966, 1978 and 1989. For 1978, there is no difference between the unadjusted and adjusted structure of production. In 1966 the adjusted shares for the branches ISIC 37/38/39 (basic metal, machinery and other manufacturing) and ISIC 32 (textiles and leather) are substantially higher, while they are much lower for ISIC 31 (food, beverages and tobacco). In 1989 the most marked difference involves ISIC 32 (textiles and leather), where the adjusted value added share increased is 18 per cent, compared to an unadjusted share of 8 per cent. Overall, there is much less structural change in the revised data compared to the unrevised data. Changes are less marked, and the textile sector remains a major contributor to manufacturing value added in the late Table 3.9
Structural changes in Tanzanian 10+ manufacturing (%) 1966
ISIC
Branch
31 Food, beverages & tobacco 32 Textiles & leather 33–4 Wood, furniture & fixtures, paper, printing & publ. 35 Chemicals, petroleum, rubber & plastic products 36 Non-metallic mineral products 37–9 (Basic) metal products, mach. & equipm. & Other man. 3
Total manufacturing
Source: Prins and Szirmai (1998), table G-2.
1978
1989
Unadj. Adj. Unadj. Adj. Unadj. Adj. 42 25 12
31 33 10
24 30 10
24 30 10
42 8 11
38 18 9
8
6
12
12
17
15
3 10
3 18
3 21
3 21
5 17
4 15
100
100
100
100
100
100
Measuring Manufacturing Performance 101 Figure 3.3 1965–90
Unadjusted and adjusted nominal value added for 10+ manufacturing,
Unadjusted and adjusted nominal value added,1965–1978
3 500 000
3 000 000
Unadjusted Adjusted
2 500 000 2 000 000 1 500 000 1 000 000 500 000
1978
1977
1976
1975
1974
1973
1972
1971
1970
1969
1968
1967
1966
1965
0
Unadjusted and adjusted nominal value added,1978–1990
Nominal value added in 1000 TSh
45 000 000 40 000 000
Unadjusted Adjusted
35 000 000 30 000 000 25 000 000 20 000 000 15 000 000 10 000 000
Source: Table 3.3.
1990
1989
1988
1987
1986
1985
1984
1983
1982
1989
1979
1978
0
1981
5 000 000
102 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
eighties. The light industries food, beverages, tobacco, textiles and leather together account for 56 per cent of value added, as against 54 per cent in 1978 and 63 per cent in 1966. 6.3
Trends in real growth
In Figure 3.4 the new index of industrial production for 1961–95 is compared with a national accounts based real manufacturing index for total manufacturing (Bureau of Statistics, 1995b) and the 50+ QSIP index (see Prins and Szirmai, 1998, table L-3). Inspection of Figure 3.4 reveals that real value added in 1961 is lower for the new index and that the BoS 1995 index shows less growth between 1961 and 1978. A steep decline in the early eighties is identified by the BoS 1995 index as well as by our new index. From 1985 onwards the various indexes show very divergent trends. Where the Bureau of Statistics (1995b) registers relatively rapid growth, the QSIP index indicates growth between 1985 and 1990 and decline after 1990. Our index shows the same pattern as the QSIP index: recovery from 1985–91, followed by renewed stagnation in the nineties. In general, the periods of growth and stagnation of the Tanzanian manufacturing sector are more clearly distinguished by our index. The main turning points in the industrialisation pattern of Tanzania are the years 1978 and 1985. The new index shows more rapid growth before 1978, and a more dramatic collapse between 1978 and 1985. After 1985 performance is uneven, though there is some slight improvement compared to 1985. Figure 3.5 combines our level and trend adjustments. The top line represents adjusted value added for 10+ manufacturing in 1989, extrapolated Figure 3.4
National accounts, QSIP and the new index of real value added, 1965–94
140
Index 1985 = 100
120 100 80 RMVA series BoS 1995b RMVA series QSIP New IIP
60 40
Sources: see text.
1995
1993
1991
1989
1987
1985
1983
1981
1979
1977
1975
1973
1971
1969
1967
1965
1963
1961
20
Measuring Manufacturing Performance 103 Figure 3.5 Manufacturing value added at 1989 prices, 1961–1995: comparison of the new index of industrial production with index based on the national accounts and QSIP 50 000
Million constant 1989 TSh
45 000
NA&QSIP New IIP
40 000 35 000 30 000 25 000 20 000 15 000 10 000
1995
1993
1991
1989
1987
1985
1983
1981
1979
1977
1975
1973
1971
1969
1967
1965
1961
0
1963
5 000
Sources: Adjusted and unadjusted nominal value added for 1989 from Table 3.2. Adjusted value added extrapolated with new index of industrial production from Figure 3.4, unadjusted value added extrapolated from 1985 to 1995 with QSIP index from Figure 3.4 and from 1961 till 1985 with the national accounts index (Bureau of Statistics, 1995b) from Figure 3.4.
with the new index of production. The bottom line represents unadjusted 1989 value added extrapolated with an unadjusted index of industrial production. This unadjusted index consists of the national accounts index up to 1985 (Bureau of Statistics, 1995; see Prins and Szirmai, 1998, table L-3), linked with the QSIP index available since 1985. Figure 3.5 has a double message. On the one hand, the rise and collapse of manufacturing are more dramatic in the new estimates than in the old ones. Real value added in 1995 is about the same as in 1972. But, on the other hand, the adjusted level of manufacturing value added in 1995 turns out to be substantially higher than in the old estimates. An important outcome of this research consists of indices of real output for different manufacturing branches for the period 1965-85. No such series were previously available. In Table 3.4 above we have presented the new indices for six manufacturing branches for the period 1965–95. The growth trends for the branches food, beverages and tobacco, and textiles and leather more or less correspond to the pattern for total manufacturing, represented in Figure 3.4. The trends for the branch wood are irregular and show long-term decline. Chemicals, petroleum, rubber and plastics show modest growth until 1977 and stability thereafter.
104 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
Non-metallic mineral products showed growth until 1973, stagnation between 1973 and 1983 and recovery in the post-1983 period. Real GDP in metals and machinery (ISIC 37, 38 and 39) increased until 1984, followed by a period of decline between 1984 and 1995. 6.4
Trends in labour productivity
Figure 3.6 presents the new index of labour productivity for total manufacturing. Initially, labour productivity increased rapidly after 1965, reaching a peak in 1973. Well before the turning point in real output trends in 1978, labour productivity started declining after 1973. The decline continued throughout the seventies and eighties, probably as a result of the inability of Tanzanian firms to shed labour as their output contracted. By 1990 labour productivity in total manufacturing was about one half the level in 1973, and 21 per cent below the level of 1965. Labour productivity trends by branch of manufacturing have already been presented (Table 3.6). Figure 3.6
Labour productivity index for total manufacturing, 1965–90 (1976 = 100)
120 110
Index, 1976 = 100
100 90 80 70 60 50 40 1965 1967 1969 1971 1973 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 Source: Table 3.6.
6.5
Comparative labour productivity
Figure 3.7 combines the benchmark productivity comparison for 1989, with Tanzanian and US time series on labour productivity. Comparative labour productivity trends show an interesting pattern. Starting from a fairly high level of almost 9 per cent of the US level, there is productivity catch-up until 1973. Increase in the amount of capital per worker is one of the causes of this. After 1973 one sees an extended period of comparative productivity decline. Initially, this is due to absolute declines in labour productivity in Tanzanian manufacturing, but the absolute decline evens out
Measuring Manufacturing Performance 105
Tanzania/USA (%)
Figures 3.7 Comparative labour productivity in Tanzanian manufacturing, 1965–90 (USA = 100) 12 11 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 1965 1967 1969 1971 1973 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 Year Source: 1989 Tanzania/USA benchmark from Table 3.8; index of GDP per person in Tanzania from Figure 3.6; GDP per person in USA from national accounts sources. 1965–82 GDP at constant prices from US Department of Commerce (1986); 1977–90 from Survey of Current Business, various issues; persons employed, 1965–90, from NIPA; 1959–88, US Department of Commerce (1992), and Survey of Current Business, various issues.
after 1983. After that year comparative productivity decline is caused by stagnation in Tanzania and increasing productivity in the lead country. The trend is also worth noting. In most productivity studies for Asian low-income economies, such as China, India and Indonesia (Timmer and Szirmai, 1999), we see productivity starting at lower levels than in Tanzania, little change in productivity performance over time and some catch-up in the nineties. Tanzania starts at much higher levels in the sixties and ends up doing much worse in the eighties, reflecting the inefficient pattern of industrialisation discussed in Chapter 1.
Table A.1
Basic data on output and employment for Tanzania, 1989 (establishments with 10 or more persons engaged) Number of Gross value establishments of output at factor cost (mill. TSh)
1 Food manufacturing (311/12) 2 Beverages (313) 3 Tobacco products (314) 4 Textile mill products (321) 5 Wearing apparel (322) 6 Leather products & footwear (323/324) 7 Wood products, furniture & fixtures (331/2) 8 Paper products, printing & publishing (341/2) 9 Chemicals products (351–3) 10 Rubber and plastic products (355/6) 11 Non-metallic mineral products (361–9) 12 Basic & fabricated metal products (371–81) 13 Machinery & transport equipment (382/4)
Gross value added at factor cost (mill. TSh)
Gross value added at factor cost, US census concepta (mill. TSh)
Gross value added in branch as % of total
Employment (person)
Gross value added per person employed TSh
146 19 3 83 54 21
24 531.6 8 959.6 6 237.2 17 701.0 519.5 1 883.2
5 630.9 3 003.1 3 359.7 5 256.4 105.8 401.1
7 177 4 116 3 528 6 367 136 520
18.24 10.46 8.97 16.18 0.35 1.32
35291 5039 4952 31014 2803 4311
203 370 816 907 712 352 205 282 48 669 120 675
214
4 399.7
1 115.4
1 454
3.69
9674
150 251
62
7 411.8
1 865.7
2 335
5.94
7256
321 831
51 15
11 680.3 4 900.7
3 515.8 954.0
4 201 1 243
10.68 3.16
4967 1710
845 705 726 943
22
5 608.1
1 413.7
1 979
5.03
5069
390 347
94
13 583.2
2 231.6
2 882
7.32
6118
470 994
72
8 062.1
1 768.3
2 234
5.68
5320
419 871
106 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
Appendix
Table A.1
(continued) Number of Gross value establishments of output at factor cost (mill. TSh)
Total manufacturing
Gross value added at factor cost, US census concepta (mill. TSh)
Gross value added in branch as % of total
Employment (person) person
Gross value added per employed TSh
6
2 303.4
710.0
830
2.11
1067
778 159
24
1 126.4
278.9
344
0.87
1288
267 095
886
118 907.7
39 345
100.00
125 879
312 562
31 610
Sources: Prins and Szirmai (1998): gross output and value added table A-4, employment table A-5. Original source: data files of 1989 census of production. Note: a US census value added defined as: gross value of output at factor cost minus intermediate inputs, except intermediate service inputs from outside the industrial sector.
Measuring Manufacturing Performance 107
14 Electrical machinery & equipment (383) 15 Other manufacturing Industries (385–90)
Gross value added at factor cost (mill. TSh)
Gross value of output (mill. US$) Food manufacturing Beverages Tobacco products Textile mill products Wearing apparel Leather products & footwear Wood products, furniture & fixtures Paper products, printing & publishing Chemicals, incl. petrol. refining Rubber & plastic products Non-metallic mineral products Basic & fabricated metal products Machinery & transport equipment
Annual Survey of Manufactures Gross value Gross value added added in (mill. US$) branch as % of total
Employmentb (1 000s)
GVA/person (US$)
310 109.7 49 695.9 25 789.9 67 072.6 61 451.2 9 757.4
106 053.8 24 103.4 18 916.2 27 123.1 31 361.7 4 543.6
8.31 1.89 1.48 2.12 2.46 0.36
1 284.4 160.1 61.9 673.4 1 018.3 124.0
82 572.0 150 547.9 305 552.2 40 280.7 30 798.2 36 648.4
108 550.5
47 791.0
3.74
1 129.0
42 331.0
271 117.7
152 708.2
11.96
2 116.8
72 140.8
415 580.0
168 705.0
13.21
1 189.6
141 811.3
96 725.5
46 850.0
3.67
889.5
52 668.9
60 938.3
32 895.4
2.58
521.6
63 071.2
308 697.4
132 557.2
10.38
2 196.7
60 344.0
618 891.6
282 524.5
22.13
3 900.6
72 431.1
108 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
Table A.2 Basic data on output and employment in manufacturing, USA, 1989 (establishments with 10 or more persons engaged)a
Table A.2 Basic data on output and employment in manufacturing, USA, 1989 (establishments with 10 or more persons engaged)a (continued)
Gross value of output (mill. US$)
Total manufacturing
Employmentb (1 000s)
GVA/person (US$)
190 906.6
105 044.9
8.23
1 654.8
63 478.2
150 519.0
95 611.5
7.49
1 375.0
69 536.7
2 745 803.2
1 276 789.4
100.00
18 295.6
69 786.6
Source: US Department of Commerce (1990a). Notes: a Ratio of 10+ to total manufacturing from 1987 Census of Manufactures, general summary (US Department of Commerce, 1990b). b Including head office and auxiliary employment. Totals distributed across branches using 1987 proportions from Census of manufactures.
Measuring Manufacturing Performance 109
Electrical machinery & equipment Other manufacturing industries
Annual Survey of Manufactures Gross value Gross value added added in (mill. US$) branch as % of total
Number of UVRs, coverage rates and reliability Number of UVRs
Food manufacturing Dairy products Preserved fruits & vegetables Fats and oils Grain mill products Bakery products Sugar & confectionary, food not elsewhere specified Beverages Malt and malt beverages Tobacco products Tobacco stemming and redrying Textile mill products Textile mill products Wearing apparel Wearing apparel Leather products and footwear Leather footwear Wood products, furniture & fixtures Wood products & furniture Paper products, printing & publishing Paper, printing & publishing
Coverage, USA
Coverage, Tanzania
Reliability PPP at US quantity weights
Reliability PPP at Tanzanian quantity weights
22 4 4 4 4 1 5
20.3 38.6 31.1 51.5 59.2 34.4 41.0
46.6 39.0 3.2 53.4 80.3 16.3 34.1
0.10 0.1 0.5 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.2
0.27 0.0 1.4 0.2 0.1 0.0 0.7
2 2 1 1 6 6 7 7 2 2 13
28.0 89.5 8.6 86.5 15.4 48.4 20.3 61.0 39.9 90.5 27.6
15.7 37.1 21.4 42.1 39.5 45.9 17.3 19.1 2.1 7.8 41.8
0.18 0.1 0.00 – 0.09 0.1 0.26 0.2 0.43 0.0 0.13
0.79 0.7 0.00 – 0.08 0.1 1.20 1.2 0.11 0.1 0.13
13 9
57.7 11.6
41.9 40.0
0.1 0.16
0.1 0.15
9
24.1
40.2
0.1
0.2
110 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
Table A.3
Table A.3
(continued) Number of UVRs
Chemicals, incl. petrol. refining Chemical products Rubber & plastic products Rubber tyres & tubes Non-metallic mineral products Cement & bricks Basic & fabricated metal products Machinery & transport equipment Electrical machinery & equipment Other manufacturing industries Total manufacturing
Coverage, USA
Coverage, Tanzania
Reliability PPP at US quantity weights
Reliability PPP at Tanzanian quantity weights
9 9 2 2 3 3
3.4 44.1 6.1 50.0 6.5 67.1
19.4 38.1 24.1 69.2 38.3 109.0
0.67 0.5 0.00 0.0 0.41 0.2
0.86 0.8 0.02 0.0 0.01 0.0
76
7.1
31.6
0.14
0.12
Note: Coverage refers to matched output as percentage of total gross value of output. The measure for reliability is calculated as the variation of unit value ratios divided by the UVR for the sample industry or branch. The 90 per cent confidence interval equals the UVR plus or minus a percentage equal to twice the reliability measure.
111
112 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
Notes *
1 2
3
4 5
6
7
8
9
10
Eindhoven Centre for Innovation Studies and Section of Technology and Development Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology. Menno Prins is currently working with Ericsson/Sweden, Wessel Schulte with UNIDO/Uganda. Thanks are due to John Komba and Russell Freeman for supervision and support in Tanzania, and to Marcel Timmer and Cees Withagen for valuable comments and advice. Unless indicated otherwise, GDP always refers to the factor cost concept. The work on Tanzanian time series is based on fieldwork carried out by M. Prins at the Tanzanian Bureau of Statistics, from April to October 1996 (M. Prins, ‘Manufacturing Statistics: Reconstructing Tanzanian Manufacturing Value Added 1965-1995’, MSc thesis, Technology and Development Studies, August 1997). Lex Lemmens collected the original data files for the benchmark study. We thank him for making these data available to us. We thank Marcel Timmer for advice and assistance with the calculation of unit value ratios and their reliability. This means that we can correct for price changes, but not for real output changes of the non-responding establishments. Inspection of the real index of industrial production discussed in Section 4 of this article shows that aggregate real output was more or less stable between 1983 and 1989. Therefore, our adjustment for price changes does not seriously underestimate aggregate value added. Note that this information is not available for the period 1978–90 for the full population of establishments in the census. The assumption here is that value added is roughly proportionate to the number of establishments. We have to make this assumption as no complete value added data are available for the sample for all the intervening years between 1978 and 1990. The important assumption here is that the degree of underestimation calculated from our sample of 50+ establishments is considered to be representative for 10+ manufacturing. Intermediate inputs or intermediate consumption consists of the value of the goods and services consumed as inputs by a process of production. (United Nations, 1993, 143). Cost categories such as interests costs, directors’ fees and donations are not intermediate inputs, but part of value added. The construction of a price index in this way derives from Mr R. Freeman, who has prepared a similar estimate in draft data files which he has kindly made available to us. The CPI is used for food manufacturing (food index), beverages and tobacco (beverages and tobacco index), textiles and apparel (clothing and footwear index), and furniture (furniture and utensils index) and for all other branches the total CPI is used. From 1992 onwards the PPI is available at industry level. The CPI and the PPI are spliced in 1992 to construct a series for 1990–95. Commodity gross output values were not available for the period 1965–85. We have used 1985 unit value data to cross check and incidentally adjust our 1989based intra-industry weights. The reliability of a UVR depends primarily on the variation in unit values within the given category. The smaller the variation of UVRS around the weighted average, the more reliable the calculated UVR is as a representation of the underlying UVR for the category. Reliability is measured as variation of unit value
Measuring Manufacturing Performance 113 ratios divided by the average unit value ratio; see Timmer (1996). We used .10 as the cut-off value for reliability. 11 If matched output value was taken as the sample industry weight in step 4 of the aggregation procedure, it is used as the sample industry weight in step 5 as well. 12 This file contained quantity information for approximately 720 enterprises. Though this is not explicitly indicated, we may safely conclude that this file refers to 10+ establishments. 13 There is a typical index-number type of discrepancy between the directly calculated UVRs for total manufacturing and the implicit UVRs calculated from summed branch values added at US and Tanzanian prices. We choose for the lowest degree of aggregation and therefore use the implicit UVR for total manufacturing.
4 The Role of Technological Factors in the Early Stages of Industrial Exports: A Note Charles Cooper*
1
Introduction
Over the past decade or so, the economic performance of the Southeast Asian NICs, particularly their performance in the export of manufactured goods, has exercised a considerable influence on policy thinking in developing countries. In many countries there is the hope that the remarkable demand growth generated in export markets might be emulated and lead to similar achievements to those of the NICs in terms of full employment accompanied by rising real wages and labour productivity. Admittedly, the desirability of an NIC pattern of development may be more questionable now, in the wake of the Southeast Asian financial and economic crisis, but the attraction of some, if not all, elements of what is seen as NIC exportpromoting policy still has strong influence elsewhere in the world. This paper is not about the economic and financial crisis. It proceeds from the assumption that, by and large, the crisis may be seen as a latterday phenomenon, afflicting the NICs in the past tumultuous two years, but not necessarily discrediting all past NIC industrialisation policies. After all, as many writers have pointed out, different countries have followed different economic policies, so that it is misleading to think that some generally defined group of common NIC policies have been put in question. Moreover, whatever may have been put in question, the reality is that there were historically unique successes in economic and especially industrial growth over a period of 30 years, and it remains relevant to ask how they were achieved, and especially (for present purposes), what role technological change and policies to induce it, played in the three decades of income growth which have so recently and abruptly come to an end. There are many new questions to be asked about the NICs at the moment, but the crisis does not gainsay the continuing relevance of the question which is asked in this paper. Particularly not, perhaps, because of the way it is intended to approach the question here. The first contention of the paper is that the technological 114
Technological Factors in Industrial Exports 115
and industrial policies followed in some Southeast Asian economies in the relatively recent past – particularly in South Korea, and particularly a group of interventionist policies which are described in various ways, but are often called ‘technological upgrading’ – have received far too much attention. They have exercised an influence out of proportion to their relevance in the rest of the developing world, including sub-Saharan Africa. The second and main contention is that earlier developments in various NICs of the ‘first generation’ may be much more relevant and important to developing countries of nowadays, than the more recent NIC experiences. And it can be argued that the earlier and by and large overlooked successes of policy in various NICs in relation to labour-intensive exports remain highly relevant to all developing countries, especially those in the subSaharan region that have faced difficulties in dealing with the rapid opening up of the world economy in recent years. There are two rather obvious and essentially empirical reasons why it makes sense to examine the immediate relevance of the labour-intensive manufactured export phase in the present sub-Saharan countries. The first is a matter of economic history. All countries that are currently active in world export trade in manufactures started out in the labour-intensive sectors, and it is to be expected that those that enter such trade in the future will go through a similar economic experience.1 The second point is about the current situation of the sub-Saharan economies as exporters of manufactures. In a 1995 UNU/INTECH discussion paper (Cooper, 1995), we established that out of 118 developing countries for which consistent data on manufactured exports are available, about 40 – or one third – showed evidence of sustained growth in these exports over the period 1970–90. 2 Out of the 118 countries, 34 were sub-Saharan. Of these only 4 or about 12 per cent, showed sustained growth in manufacturing exports. So there are proportionately far fewer sub-Saharan economies showing sustained growth of manufactured exports than in the rest of the world. If these countries are to achieve sustained growth of manufactured exports in the future they will have to pass through a phase of labour-intensive exports. It makes sense therefore to redress the balance of much recent writing, and to explore in more detail some of the main features of the labour-intensive export phase – as opposed to the process of ‘technological upgrading’ which has, perhaps for obvious reasons, attracted far more attention in the literature. In Section 2 there is an account of some important attempts to understand the role of manufactured exports in economic growth of developing countries. These grew out of the debates on the dual economy, whose point of departure was the seminal paper by Arthur Lewis (1954), which was developed by Fei and Ranis (1964, 1976). The paper examines the conclusions of the Fei and Ranis analysis. Section 3 outlines some of the problems that may be associated with entry into world markets for labour-intensive
116 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
manufactures. It takes the analysis beyond the limits of the Fei–Ranis model and considers the role of technological change in world market entry – even in labour-intensive manufactures. It also examines the longrun path dependencies this initial entry may generate. Section 4 gives the main conclusions.
2
The dual economy model and manufactured exports
The Lewis dual economy model and its development in an open economy form by Fei and Ranis had a profound influence on thinking about economic development. This part of the paper examines what these models of economic development had to say about technology. In particular it will deal with the implications which can be drawn from the Fei and Ranis form of the model for technology in the early stages of entry into world markets for manufactures. The Lewis ‘unlimited supplies’ model deals with the processes of capital accumulation in a labour surplus economy, leading to the emergence of a modern sector in the context of a large subsistence-oriented rural sector. There is a labour surplus in the rural sector in the sense that the migration of workers to the modern sector will not cause a fall in output. It is assumed that arrangements in the subsistence sector are such that all persons working there enjoy access to the average product of labour in the sector – and this average product of labour is what determines the minimum real wage in the modern industrial sector. This is one of the more debatable and debated assumptions of the model, but we will not enter into that. The level of output in industry is determined by the prevailing modern sector technology and the minimum real wage. Production is expanded to the point where the marginal product of labour is equal to the real wage. At this point the surplus value added in production above the wage bill accrues as profit to the owners of capital. It is this surplus, properly reinvested, which provides for reinvestment and expansion, and which therefore drives the economy. Reinvestment of surplus and the accumulation of capital stock will expand the modern sector so that eventually surplus labour will be fully absorbed. Lewis addresses the problem of international trade in his original paper, but it is probably fair to say that his main concerns are with the internal operation of the dual economy, and the process of accumulation of capital in the modern sector. Thus, a central matter for Lewis is the effect of movements in the internal terms of trade – between the urban and rural sectors – on profits and the capital accumulation process in the modern sector. In this particular sense, and despite the discussion of the international economy in the second half of the paper, it is probably fair to say that the Lewis formulation deals essentially with a closed economy. Twenty years
Technological Factors in Industrial Exports 117
later Fei and Ranis consider the implications of the Lewis type of accumulation in an open economy and apply their framework to the (early) development of Korea and Taiwan (Fei and Ranis, 1976). More recently Ranis (1988) has given a useful reformulation of the original ideas of the earlier paper. The centrepiece in both analyses is the onset of a phase of ‘export substitution’, starting at the point where traditional exports are replaced by exports of labour-intensive manufactured goods. 3 This is a key turning point, because thereafter the absorption of surplus labour is greatly accelerated. So much so, claim Ranis and Fei, that debates on trade-off between growth and employment, which were characteristic of the seventies, became largely irrelevant. Once the economy had got into the export substitution phase it was expected to move rapidly to the next turning point, called by Ranis and Fei the ‘commercialization point’. At the commercialization point, surplus labour is fully absorbed, the real wage is no longer ‘institutionally’ determined, but becomes equated to the marginal product of labour in the rural sector. What implications does this model of entry into the international market for manufactured exports have for technological change and factor productivities? The question is simply answered (in the model) and the answer follows from labour market conditions. After the process of export substitution has started, and up until the commercialisation point, the idea is that the institutionally determined low real wage will rule. Once labour is fully absorbed, that is, once the commercialization point is past, the real wage will naturally rise. In the first, ‘precommercialisation’ phase, ‘the existence of relatively constant (and low) … real wages … should induce labour-intensive technology choices and, more importantly, labour-using technology change … in the dual economy’ (Ranis, 1988, p. 82). Then, after the commercialization point and full absorption of surplus labour, ‘increase in real wages … is expected to be accompanied by a shift towards more capital and skill intensive technology and output mix’ (Fei and Ranis, 1976). In short, labour productivity and real wages will remain low and stagnant after the initial shift to what Fei and Ranis call ‘export substitution’, whilst manufactured exports will rise rapidly. Thereafter, when surplus labour is absorbed, wages and labour productivity will rise more rapidly. As Fei and Ranis tell the story, the key role of the labour-intensive export phase is to accelerate the rate of absorption of excess labour in the economy above the closed economy rate of the Lewis model in its early form. The implication for technology is simple: labour intensity will prevail until the commercialization point is reached and the real wage begins to rise. In broad outlines Fei and Ranis give a fairly convincing framework for understanding the actual pattern of development in Korea and Taiwan in the early stages of their post-war development. There was, of course, a shift away from primary product exports as these economies successfully
118 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
entered trade in manufactured exports. Also, just as Fei and Ranis predicted, basing themselves on the experience of Korea and Taiwan, the rate of growth of exports and employment was accelerated strongly by the shift. And finally, it is clear that in all cases the initial shifts in the pattern of trade and output in manufacturing were towards the simpler types of manufactures in the first two or three ISIC two-digit groups – in other words towards higher labour intensities as expected in terms of the Fei and Ranis analysis. In addition, some other countries bear out the Fei–Ranis expectations in a more detailed way. Countries such as Mauritius and Sri Lanka, for example, have had precisely the low and more or less constant real wages, and the low productivity growth, which were predicted for the period of continued surplus labour. Furthermore, the recent historical pattern followed by Malaysia also seems similar to the conventional anticipation. Over the whole period 1970–90 Malaysia had a low growth of productivity (1.7 per cent), and a slightly higher growth of real earnings (2.8 per cent). Manufacturing employment grew rapidly (at 7.5 per cent), and by the mid-eighties labour shortages were beginning to be felt, and an import of unskilled labour started from neighbouring countries. At the same time as the labour surplus phase came to an end, a technological shift took place. Labour productivity growth accelerated to more than 4 per cent per annum in the second period (1980–90). (Evidence on movements of the real wage in manufacturing in this period is not available.) This Malaysian pattern is very close to the expectation that technology will be predominantly labour intensive in the first period of manufactured exports, whilst there is labour surplus, and will then shift to higher capital intensity and higher labour productivities as full employment levels are reached. 4 It is also notable that countries which show no significant growth trend in the pattern of manufactured exports, have not – in the main – shown any significant trend in value added per worker. To this extent they conform to the Fei–Ranis prediction5 – which carries the corollary that, in the absence of manufactured exports, labour absorption will be slow, and, in the presence of surplus labour, there will not be much of an incentive for capitalists to invest in higher productivity technologies. All in all Fei and Ranis give a pretty clear picture of the role of labourintensive exports in the initial stages of entry into world markets, and in the process of absorption of excess labour. It is a simple picture, in which the technological behaviour of firms in the manufacturing sector is determined in a direct way by the labour market. Whilst there is excess labour, the real wage stays constant and labour-intensive technology prevails. It is only after the commercialization point that new technologies become necessary and labour productivities will rise.
Technological Factors in Industrial Exports 119
The model gives a helpful insight into the importance of labour-intensive exports at an early stage of development. There are, however, two major issues, which are to some degree empirical, which are not clearly addressed. The first is that Fei and Ranis give no clue as to why the crucially important ‘export substitution’ phase should have started. Other turning points – the commercialization point for example – have a clear economic rationale, but not the inception of the export substitution phase. That remains unexplained, and it is a crucial theoretical lacuna. Why do a group of firms that enjoy a fair degree of market protection (Fei and Ranis assume that there is a preceding phase of import substitution) suddenly launch themselves into the international market for labour-intensive manufactured goods? Indeed, the question is even more puzzling. It is well established that in most countries which are not NICs, in South Asia, Latin America or in present day sub-Saharan Africa, no such shifts to ‘export substitution’ took place. The import substitution process did not ‘incubate’ an export substitution phase. It created a vicious circle of economic inefficiency in which international competitiveness became virtually impossible for the individual firm to achieve. In a sense, therefore, Fei and Ranis beg a key question. One of the more important tasks for historians of the NICs is to elucidate what were the factors that led to an export substitution phase. Economists and economic historians of various schools of thought plainly join issue on this question. There are those who argue that the role of the state, in particular in Korea, was critical in the initiation of an export substitution phase. There are others who argue, often using Taiwan and Hong Kong as exemplars, that the state role was not necessary and indeed distorted the process. However, the latter kind of argument about the role of the state putatively slowing down a process that would have been even more successful without it is strictly counterfactual, and to that extent must be regarded as scientifically dubious. The fact is that we simply cannot know, in any normal scientific way, whether the processes of development and industrialisation in these economies would have been faster or more efficient without the intervention of the state. We can only observe that there were important state interventions, which certainly appear to have been positively influential in industrialization; and we can also observe that – though the comparisons are complex – some at least of the interventionist states seem to have had striking success. These points have a sounder historical and scientific foundation than the counterfactual arguments which at one point were very popular in Bretton Woods institutions, especially the World Bank. For the present, therefore, it seems sensible to rest on the commonsense view that the export substitution phase – where it happened – was importantly associated with state action and intervention. The second issue is that, on closer examination, the technological ‘predictions’ of the Fei and Ranis analysis are not borne out in all countries and are plainly wrong in some very important ones. The analysis predicts a
120 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
simple correspondence between labour market conditions and technology, whereby with an initial excess supply of labour, productivities do not change and export development is labour intensive. However, a closer look suggests that this correspondence is not always present. A number of countries have plainly experienced considerable technological advance and rising labour productivity, whilst still having large amounts of surplus labour. This is certainly true of China, India, Indonesia and Pakistan, and probably also Thailand. In addition to this, historical evidence on Korea also suggests rather strongly that there was a vigorous growth of labour productivity well before the point of full absorption of labour was reached. So we are left with the problem of explaining the apparently anomalous behaviour of the economies that, whilst they demonstrate the general importance of the export phase, have followed a growth path more characterized by technological change than the Fei and Ranis model would have supposed. The main question is: why did these economies follow dynamic productivity growth paths while they were still in the labour surplus phase of economic development? A number of reasons can be suggested. Firstly, the Fei–Ranis expectation that a commitment to labour-intensive technology would be sustained until surplus labour is fully absorbed is linked to strong assumptions about the working of the labour market, and in particular to the idea that, during this period, the real wage will be more or less constant – or ‘slow growing’ (Ranis, 1988). In practice, this assumption has not been borne out in many countries. In most countries there has been a strong upward shift in industrial real wages. A cursory examination bears this out. Amongst the high value-added growth countries there are a number which, throughout the period 1970–90, had excess supplies of labour in the Lewis sense. China, India, Indonesia, Pakistan and Thailand were certainly in this category. Despite this, the average rate of growth of real earnings per worker for these countries was 3.5 per cent per annum over the period. In addition, although surplus labour has been absorbed in Korea, the evidence shows that, in the early part of the period, before this had been accomplished, Korean real wages were already rising. So it could be argued that the reason why productivity increases in these economies took place so early (in the sense that there was still a labour surplus when they occurred) may be found in the ‘untimely’ increase in real wages. It might be argued that the only way to maintain competitiveness in the face of rising real wages was through a higher rate of technological change. There are, however, some problems with this argument. In the first place, it assumes that real wage rises took place independently of changes in technology. In fact, real wage increases could just as easily have been a result of the incorporation of technology that raised factor productivities. 6 On the other hand, this argument shifts the burden of explanation from one area to another. Differences in real wage growth between economies may have
Technological Factors in Industrial Exports 121
been the cause of differences in the rate of growth of labour productivity, but then what causes the differences in real wage growth between economies in the first place? A second possibility is that the acceleration of technological change during the labour surplus phase may have resulted from pressures generated by technological change in the international economy. In order to remain competitive, firms in the domestic economy must reduce costs or modify products, either through technological change, or through some other means of cost reduction. So some countries deal with the competitive threat by holding down real wages, or even reducing them, whilst others respond by technological advances. This may be a more plausible explanation than the first, but it still leaves unanswered questions. In particular it is not clear why the acceleration of technological change internationally should affect economies in the highly protected import-substituting phase. And for this explanation to work, we must suppose it did have effects in the case of countries such as China and India. Indeed, on consideration, there is every reason to expect that the combined influences of increasing capital accumulation and increasing capital per worker would lead to labour productivity increases, perhaps associated with changes in the pattern of outputs, without necessarily being associated with increasing real wages. Labour productivity changes do not need to be associated with changes in the real wage. They may be stimulated by the search for higher profitability without any change in wage levels. Thirdly, it may be that the early onset of higher productivity in some countries is due to important supply-side differences – in particular the fact that some countries might have a better endowment of factors of production that make it possible to adopt new technologies. So, if the technologies becoming available internationally require proportionately large demands for particular factors – such as skilled labour – they may become profitable in countries where there is a supply of relatively low-waged skilled labour, even though there is a large excess supply of unskilled labour. It is possible that the countries mentioned above, some of which have long and substantial traditions in scientific and technical education, and substantial science and engineering capabilities, are differentiated from the technologically weaker economies in this way. Evidence on the supply of scientific and technically trained people would support this idea in the case of countries such as China, India, Thailand and Singapore – perhaps also for other countries. But puzzles remain, since the large Latin American countries also have long traditions of technical education and a comparatively highly educated workforce, and have nevertheless shown very limited increases in labour productivity. In short, there is no single explanation which can easily encompass the comparisons between all the countries in the analysis. This is not necessarily a major problem, since contingent conditions may vary widely between
122 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
countries, and there may therefore be more than one explanation for the various differences. It is not surprising that such a complex set of phenomena cannot easily be reduced to a single simple pattern. Plainly, despite the basically sensible framework which the Fei–Ranis model provides, there are some complexities of the real world that it does not address in an adequate way, and some of the points made above point in their direction. These complexities indicate that the framework of the model, though convincing and in part empirically supported, leaves something out. Essentially the Fei–Ranis framework says very little about the implications of technological change for the process of entry into world markets in manufactures. In this respect it is in line with most development economics of its time. In fact, for the sub-Saharan countries seeking to enter international trade in manufactures there are conditions in the international market which strongly influence the nature and requirements of the Fei–Ranis export substitution phase. The next section touches on implications of generic technological change7 and innovative competition, as well as on the question of path dependencies resulting from development of labour-intensive export development. In the modern world economy these considerations are an essential complement to the preceding analysis.
3 Some problems for new entrants: generic technological change and path dependencies The preceding section suggests that, in reality, technological changes involving increases in labour productivity have been important at a much earlier stage than suggested by the Fei and Ranis framework. That framework gives the prediction that advances in labour productivity will become important only after the commercialization point is reached; experience suggests they are important at an earlier stage than that. The probable reason for this is that although the Fei–Ranis model is a valiant attempt to ‘open’ the original Lewis model, it remains, in certain respects, essentially focused on closed economy ideas. It does not take into account the importance of changes in the international environment, which begin to influence the economy as soon as it is opened. In particular, it does not consider the significant influence which technological change in the international manufacturing economy is likely to have on new entrants, even at the earliest stages of ‘export substitution’. So the first point to be made in the following discussion is about the impact of generic technological change and innovative competition in the international economy on the ‘export substitution’ phase. Although we have chosen to express the argument in these terms, that is, in terms of ‘generic technological change’ – a terminology appropriate to the modern discussions on technology – it is
Technological Factors in Industrial Exports 123
in fact a perfectly general point which can be made in a much more reductionist way; it depends only on the fact that Fei and Ranis leave out the fact that factor productivities in the world economy are changing all the time, mainly increasing, and that this has important implications for the new entrant developing country – that is for the country entering on the export substitution phase. Essentially it implies that improvements in factor productivities – labour productivity in the simplest case – have to be achieved from the very beginning of the export substitution phase and not just from the later ‘commercialization point’. So countries need to organise for technological change even when there is excess labour available. The problem of ‘generic technologies’ is tackled in Section 3.1 This need for technological advance and improvements in factor productivities at an early stage in the process of ‘opening up’ does not gainsay the argument that these early stages will be specialized in labour-intensive manufactured outputs. The important point to be made in the following is that precisely because technological changes are increasingly generic, the sectors producing labour-intensive outputs will not be exempt from technological change. These sectors – textiles, garments and the like – are for that reason no longer technologically stagnant, as they were generally considered to be in the period in which the Fei–Ranis paper was written. But the fact that the early stage of export substitution must still be labour intensive remains: labour intensivity characterizes the immediate source of static comparative advantage from which the economy must start. This, of course, is quite consistent with the fact that there is a need for improving labour productivity at the same time: there is no reason in principle why the factor productivities of labour-intensive technologies should not increase. The question is whether this initial commitment to technological change and technological learning processes associated with labour intensive outputs in the initial phases of export substitution may not set the economy on a trajectory of technological skill development, which creates a continuing commitment to a more labour-intensive, less skill-intensive and less capital-intensive path in the longer run. Does an initial entry into world markets for manufactures in labour-intensive lines of production create a continuing dependency on such lines of production, and restrict the skills available for technological upgrading at a later stage? In other words, to use the language of Paul David, does it not create a ‘path dependence’? Although this may seem to lie outside the line of sight of countries which are just entering the world market, it is sooner or later a question which they will be obliged to face. If there is likely to be such a path dependency, it is important to know about it from the beginning – in order to do something about it later on, when a shift away from labourintensive production may become desirable and necessary. So Section 3.2 of this paper deals with the question of ‘path dependencies’ which an
124 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
initial commitment to labour-intensive production may create, largely because of the pattern of technological skills it generates through ‘learning by doing’. 3.1
Generic technological change
It is no doubt risky to generalize about the rate and direction of technological change in the international economy. However, some of the trends which seem to be emerging are especially important – sufficiently so to justify a few generalizations, however risky they may be. A common generalization is that the international economy is increasingly influenced by generic technological changes. From the point of view of the developing countries, the appearance of generic technologies is potentially very important. This term is usually used to describe the fact that many of the new technologies have fields of application across a multiplicity of sectors. There is not much doubt that such a pattern is developing. Some examples: Alcorta (1995) has shown the way in which industrial automation technologies spread across sectors; a UNIDO paper (UNIDO, 1995) demonstrates with great clarity the generic nature of new materials technology; a paper by Steinmueller and Bastos (1995) shows the situation for information and communication technologies. Generic, or multisectoral, technological changes have many implications for the production system. One which is especially significant for the present discussion is that they have introduced innovative competition into sectors which were previously seen – especially in the Fei–Ranis scheme of things – as essentially stagnant from a technological point of view, and are therefore characterized by straightforward price competition of the Marshallian kind. Competition through innovation is distinctive and different to Marshallian competition as described in standard economics textbooks. Price competition – based on minimizing the costs of production on a given type of technology – is a mechanism for re-establishing an equilibrium in the economy. Innovative competition, as it was first described by Schumpeter (1912), is a means whereby firms create unique advantages for themselves through temporary sole possession of a piece of technological knowledge, and so profit from a temporary disequilibrium. The effect of a high rate of generic technological change in the economy is that this type of competition will prevail in many sectors of the economy. This has important implications for firms in developing countries seeking to enter international trade in manufactures, since it importantly affects the terms of entry. Christopher Freeman (1982) has classified the competitive responses of firms in industries which are characterized by innovative competition. At the leading edge of these industries (from the technological point of view) are the innovative firms, seeking to capture a lead over the rest of the industry by establishing a unique process or product. Follower firms may
Technological Factors in Industrial Exports 125
pursue different strategies in response. Some will seek to innovate themselves. Others will try to exploit the advantages of being a follower, by imitating the original innovator – if necessary by licensing its technology. Still others will seek alternative, more defensive strategies. For example, if the new product arising from the innovation is an imperfect substitute for the old, firms may continue to produce the older product. Or they may continue to use the old methods of production – if there is a process innovation. As Freeman points out (1982, pp. 169ff.), follower firms of this kind require some compensating advantages in order to maintain themselves in competitive production. Follower firms in developing countries usually attempt to exploit low labour costs, or advantageous access to materials in response to innovative competition, though in the more industrially advanced developing countries many firms will follow imitative strategies based on the international transfer of technology. An important aspect from the point of view of developing countries is that the generic nature of technological change has meant that patterns of innovative competition are appearing in many of the sectors which before were considered to be technologically stagnant. Amongst these are the sectors which have long been regarded as the ‘traditional’ sectors for early industrialisation, such as textiles and garments production, for example. It does not follow that firms in developing countries have to become innovators in order to compete; nor do they necessarily have to adopt new technologies at a high rate. It does mean, however, that even in the older traditional industries, which are so important in early industrialisation, the pressure of innovative competition will be felt. The terms of entry will be more severe than in the past, and the requirements for maintaining competitiveness will be more severe as innovative competition develops. Steinmueller and Bastos include some interesting reflections on what this means in practice (1995, p. 9). They point out that whilst the working out of comparative advantage means that countries will always have some sectors in which they are competitive, the terms of trade are determined by relative productivity of trading partners. So ‘if developed nations’ productivity advances substantially outstrip those in developing nations, the consequence is slow growth or even a decline in real wages offered in developing countries’. This has important implications for the terms on which industrialisation may take place in the technologically less advanced developing countries. Fortunately, the impact of innovative competition, even though generic in form, is uneven across sectors. It is probably a fair generalization that all sectors in the manufacturing system have experienced accelerated generic technological change, but it remains the case that it has been more pronounced in some than in others. The traditional sectors of developing country industrialisation have been less exposed to innovative competition than others. The route to industrialisation through initial production of technologically simple products in a comparatively labour-intensive way is
126 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
still open, though it is narrower than before. In these products, there is still a high degree of conventional price competition, which developing countries are in a better position to meet. 3.2
Patterns of path dependency
A particularly striking instance of path dependency and its implications for new entrants into international markets comes from some recent developments in trade theory. These developments are mainly derived from ‘new growth theory’, in which technological change is treated as an intrinsic part of economic activity. Their implications for trade theory rest on differences in factor productivities arising from differential learning, or from differences in the production functions facing different economies. A recent review is Grossman and Helpman (1995). Barros (1993) is an interesting attempt to draw conclusions from the new growth/new trade theory approaches for developing countries. For present purposes, the main point of interest is from Krugman (1987). The first point is that where learning effects are important in determining the relative productivities as between trading countries, there will be a tendency for the existing trading pattern to get ‘locked in’. Essentially countries become relatively more productive in those branches in which they are specialized, and the short-run pattern of comparative advantage is reinforced by this; to quote Krugman, ‘once a pattern of specialisation is established, it remains unchanged, with changes in relative productivity acting to further lock the pattern in’ (Krugman, 1987, p. 46). In some Latin American countries, for example, the relative efficiency of production of resource-based industries is probably reinforced by the exporting from them. In principle this presents advantages, of course, but it also means that it is increasingly difficult as time goes by to make changes in the trading pattern. Furthermore, if the learning elasticities in such sectors are lower than in the sectors where advanced country trading partners have a comparative advantage, the Latin American economies could be committed in a long-term sense to a low productivity growth trajectory. 8 The same points would apply, of course, to economies such as Mauritius and Sri Lanka, with their heavy commitment to ‘low’ technology, labour-intensive lines of production.9 This line of analysis could have special importance to the ‘low productivity exporters’ as they reach the point where labour is fully employed. If at that time they are locked in to a pattern of relative productivities inherited from the past, they could experience serious difficulties in shifting to new lines of production with higher labour productivity (in the way the Fei–Ranis approach suggests is necessary). 10 We will discuss this problem briefly in the next section.11 The idea that trade patterns may get ‘locked in’, as described above, is derived from the learning process. Once firms are committed to a particular
Technological Factors in Industrial Exports 127
line of production, the learning processes this sets in train – whether ‘automatic’ in the Arrow tradition (Arrow, 1962) or the result of conscious managerial decision and resource allocation12 – reinforce the inter-industry pattern of comparative advantages, and, since the same thing is happening in trading partner countries, it becomes increasingly difficult to change the pattern. This is an example of ‘path dependence’ – which might briefly be described as a recognition that ‘history matters’. Learning processes13 will, obviously, produce many situations of path dependence. From the present point of view, path dependence is important because it will influence the possibilities of shifting between the types of growth path (that is, high versus low productivity growth paths) which differentiate developing countries. There are two levels at which relevant kinds of path dependency may be set up. First, the technological learning processes within firms are path dependent. David recognizes this: ‘Because technological learning depends on the accumulation of actual production experience, short sighted choices about what to produce, and especially about how to produce it using presently known methods, also in effect govern what subsequently comes to be learnt’ ( David, 1975, p. 4). Dosi (1988) describes the cumulative learning processes which underlie the accumulation of technological capability in enterprises. 14 There are three distinctive features of these learning processes. First, they tend to have important firm-specific features. Although there may be spillovers of technological know-how between firms, a good deal of the learning process in a firm differentiates it from its competitors. Secondly, learning processes create a good deal of ‘tacit’ knowledge – that is knowledge specific to the application of particular processes inside the firm, and which is neither codified nor easy to codify. This is the type of technological capability that can only be acquired by ‘doing’. Thirdly, whilst some knowledge may accumulate ‘spontaneously’ through the experience of production, for the most part the accumulation of technological capabilities depends on the allocation of time and effort by the personnel of the firm, and depends on explicit management decisions. But though accumulation of technological capabilities takes place in the first instance within production units (and increasingly in service enterprises too), the broader institutional environment within which firms operate is also important. In recent times this environment has become called the ‘national system of innovation’, and important attempts have been made to describe it systematically (Nelson, 1993). The national system of innovation is the second level at which there are important path dependencies. It has a number of components other than enterprises. These differ in form from country to country, but are present in most. In the first place there is the education system – especially those parts concerned with scientific and technical education. The early creation of a highly skilled and educated workforce is generally agreed to have been a
128 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
key element in the success of the first generation of NICs. On its importance in Korea see Pack and Westphal (1986). Second, there are the various institutions engaged in scientific and technological research (outside of enterprises). These normally include the universities, as well as various national laboratory organisations. Sometimes, especially in developing countries, a large part of the scientific and technical capability of a country is ‘tied up’ in these institutions, and a major policy problem is how to relate this capability to national development objectives. Sometimes also, as in the United States for example, these institutions grew out of major national programmes – such as the space programme or defence programmes. Third, there is a set of important ancillary institutions – survey systems, technical information systems, standards systems, technology transfer organisations and so on. In most countries the institutions making up the national system of innovation play an important part in technological development within enterprises, whether through creating a supply of skilled persons, or through facilitating the acquisition of technology from abroad, or through provision of technological information, or through the support of university or other research activities on which enterprises can draw. It is important not only that the institutional structure of the national system of innovation should be present, but that it should be functionally related to the requirements of the enterprises which are at the sharp end of the process of acquisition of technological capability. The longterm development of these institutions and their organic relations to the enterprise sector has played a large part in the process of technological development in many of the high productivity growth developing countries. How then are high and low productivity growth economies distinguished from one another as far as the technological capabilities are concerned? We can give an impressionistic but probably reasonably accurate response along the following lines. First, we expect that in the high productivity growth economies we will find production and service enterprises, especially in the export sectors, in which there are considerable concentrations of technically skilled persons, and where – more importantly – there is a vigorous process of technical learning taking place within firms. Second, we would expect that there will be close links between production and the rest of the national system of innovation. In the low productivity growth economies we would expect to find firms which are solely concerned with repetitive production tasks, in which there is no concern with learning or change. Very little research has been done on these differences, but there is a good deal of impressionistic evidence to support the picture we have drawn. This hypothetical description will also make clear that the shift from low productivity to high productivity paths is not as easy as may appear. It will depend on generating learning processes within firms on the
Technological Factors in Industrial Exports 129
one hand, and on linking the key elements of the national system of innovation to services and production on the other.
4
Points in conclusion
This note explores the problem, especially important in the sub-Saharan economies, of entry into the world market for labour-intensive manufactured goods. It argues that this mode of entry into industrial markets is unavoidable for sub-Saharan countries. There has, however, been relatively little theoretical attention to how countries acquire initial entry into world export markets for manufactures – compared, that is, to the amount of attention given to the processes of technological upgrading which some countries have successfully followed after their initial entry. Indeed, the Fei–Ranis model, which puts strong emphasis on the importance of labour-intensive manufactured exports in generating employment in the industrial sector, gives no indication of the policies which countries may follow to initiate this process.15 There is much that is unknown on this topic. Focus on the latter-day technological accomplishments of the NICs in such advanced areas as large memory chips and the like has obscured the question that is much more important from the point of view of economies such as those of the sub-Sahara: namely, how did the whole process start? What policies did today’s NICs follow to initiate what Fei and Ranis call ‘export substitution’? Unfortunately Fei and Ranis do not address the question, despite its central relevance to their model. And we cannot, without a good deal more historical research, solve it ourselves. The discussion in Section 2 of this paper, however, does indicate that government intervention seems to have been one of the factors involved. The Fei–Ranis model is also weak in the treatment of technological change. There is a presumption that as the period of excess labour comes to an end (that is, as the commercialization point is reached), there will be a switch to more capital-intensive technology in the manufacturing sector, in order to deal with the need for increases in labour productivity. In fact, it is very likely that both labour productivity increases and new products will become important long before this. The circumstances of the world economy – in particular the incidence of generic patterns of technological change – will require new entrants to world markets for labour-intensive manufactured goods to follow more active policies of technological change than is usually assumed. And this requirement will assert itself at an early stage of industrial export development, well before the Fei and Ranis ‘commercialization point’ at which labour is fully absorbed in the industrial economy. Essentially, Fei and Ranis failed to encompass the relevance (indeed, the potential threat) of world technological change in labour-intensive outputs for new entrants to world
130 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
markets in these products. They do not address this point, perhaps because there was not much technical change going on at the time, in labour-intensive outputs. But there is now, mainly because of the generic nature of much technological change, and this is a fact that undermines some of the model’s predictions. Technological change and advances in labour productivity become important from the beginning of the Fei–Ranis ‘export substitution’ phase, not just from the point where excess labour has been fully employed. International patterns of technological change acting on the open economies of the modern developing countries make that inevitable. A question that lies outside the immediate range of the Fei–Ranis discussion is whether an initial entry into international markets through labourintensive exports, which is an inevitable point of entry for most sub-Saharan countries, implies a long-run commitment – through the path dependencies it creates – to a low productivity growth trajectory, and hence to slower rates of growth of factor productivity and real wages in the industrial sector. The kinds of technological capability which producers develop tend to determine the technological options open to them at their next round of investment. It must remain unclear for the moment how serious a problem this is for developing countries, and whether policy intervention or the market is needed to solve it, supposing it is important. The question, though, is highly relevant, because in the longer run a shift towards production and export of higher value added goods at higher real wages seems to be an essential part of economic development. Countries will not be satisfied with a permanent commitment to labour-intensive lines of production, however essential they may be to the initial entry into world markets.
Notes * The author is Director of the United Nations University Institute for New Technologies (UNU/INTECH). This paper draws heavily on two discussion papers in the UNU/INTECH series, which are referred to in the text. The author benefited from the comments of his colleagues at UNU/INTECH as well as from others including Prof. Ed Steinmueller of MERIT, Prof. Jorge Katz of ECLAC in Santiago, Prof. Larry Westphal at Swarthmore College, USA, as well as participants at the INTECH/ECLAC conference in Marbella, Chile, in 1995, and at the UNIDO Global Forum on Industrialisation in Delhi. Prof. Eddy Szirmai, of TU Eindhoven, as Editor of the conference volume in which this paper appears, gave invaluable comments which are acknowledged at various points in the text. 1. It seems to me likely that some people will see this observation as an example of a kind of determinism. If so, they have an ahistorical case to make, and it is their obligation to do so. 2. Sustained growth of exports is defined as follows. The growth rate of exports is determined by fitting the logarithmic form of the standard expression for com-
Technological Factors in Industrial Exports 131
3.
4.
5.
6. 7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
pound growth to the time series of manufactured exports (1970–90). The growth rate is determined from the coefficient of the logarithmic term. If this coefficient is significant for the whole time series, at the 1 per cent level, growth is defined as sustained in our term. Some more recent research will result in slight modifications to these statistical observations, but not sufficient to require modifications to the points made in the ensuing text. As Szirmai pointed out in a private note, the implicit symmetry between the terms ‘import substitution’ and ‘export substitution’ is potentially misleading. Import substitution refers to the competition between imports from abroad and domestic production for the domestic market. Export substitution refers to the increasing share of manufacturing in exports, but it is not clear whether there is a process of substitution. Nevertheless, in this paper, we will continue to use the accepted terminology. The data on which this conclusion is based are discussed in Charles Cooper, ‘Technology, Manufactured Exports and Competitiveness’, UNU/INTECH Discussion Paper no. 9513, December 1995. Although for these countries the matter is somewhat different since – as their export data indicate – they have not really entered the ‘export substitution’ phase. The data available are too weak to support tests of causality. The terminology ‘generic technological change’ is used very frequently in a certain part of the ‘technology’ literature, often in an unclear way. The dictionary definition of ‘generic’ is ‘pertaining to a class, not specific or special’. So generic technologies are not sector specific or unique to particular lines of production, but are widely relevant to many. They are technologically and not industrially defined. This is what Barros seems to have in mind when he writes of specialization having a ‘negative effect on productivity increase’ (Barros, 1993, p. 545), but his discussion is vague and unconvincing. The analysis is based on the assumption that whilst there may be international spillovers of technological capability within industries, there are no spillovers between industries. The lock-in effect would be much less severe if there were inter-industry spillovers. It might be argued that one of the implications of generic technological change is that such inter-industry spillovers will be important. Krugman’s analysis has not been extended to the case of labour surplus economies operating with a constant institutionally determined wage rate, but that does not change the validity of the present line of argument. The second point to emerge from Krugman’s analytics is that there is clearly a way out of the ‘lock-in’ – along lines which he identifies with Japanese industrial policy, and which is nowadays more commonly associated with the policies of selective protection followed by Korea. The idea is that governments may use ‘temporary protection to permanently shift comparative advantage’. The protection will be directed to goods which are just outside the present pattern of national comparative advantage, and applied for just so long as is necessary to raise relative productivities in their production to the point where a new area of comparative advantage is established. Krugman refers to this as the policy of a ‘narrow moving band’ of protection (Krugman, 1987, pp. 48–9). It is an interesting reflection of the notion of ‘technological upgrading’, and has considerable empirical foundation in the history of industrial policies in some countries.
132 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania 12. The recognition that learning processes involve important resources has a substantial history. As far as work on developing countries is concerned, Katz’s work in Latin America provided the essential empirical basis (Katz, 1987) and was the point of departure for a substantial literature. Much later the point became embodied in theories of endogenous technological change. 13. On the kinds of technological learning which are important in firms in developing countries see Dahlmann et al. (1987). 14. This and other basic material on accumulation of technological capability is surveyed in Cooper (1993). 15. There is an implication that the transition will be from import substitution to ‘export substitution’, but it is not clear what mechanisms will make this happen.
Part II Innovation, Technological Capabilities and Choice of Techniques
This page intentionally left blank
5 Public Choice, Technology and Industrialization in Tanzania: Some Paradoxes Resolved Jeffrey James*
1
Introduction
The public choice approach has already been used in the African context to explore the political rationality of policies that seem difficult, if not entirely impossible, to justify on purely economic grounds. A well-known study by Robert Bates (1981), for example, sought to explain why governments in Africa tend to adopt agricultural policies that are blatantly harmful to the interests of most farmers in the region. More recently, rent-seeking behaviour was used by Gallagher (1991) to explain variations in growth rates across a wide range of African countries. What has not been applied to any of those countries, however, is the area of public choice theory that deals specifically with the preferences and behaviour of government bureaucrats: the so-called political economy of bureaucracy. Yet, as we shall argue below, this important strand of the public choice literature helps to explain some of the most paradoxical aspects of technology and industrialization in the public sector of one particular African country, Tanzania. More specifically, our argument will be that these paradoxes can be explained by the following propositions. The first is that, contrary to what is almost always assumed in the literature on development economics, bureaucrats do not in fact have preferences defined over technologies (that is, they do not choose technologies in the usual sense of the word). Rather, their preferences are thought to be defined over projects and particularly those projects that enable the institutions to which they belong to grow as rapidly as possible.
2 Technological behaviour in the public sector – two paradoxes To a much greater extent than elsewhere in the Third World, the industrial sector in Tanzania (as in sub-Saharan Africa more generally) has been dominated by enterprises owned by the state and to a correspondingly greater 135
136 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
extent than in the other regions, therefore, the technological aspects of industrialization in Tanzania need to be understood in relation to the behaviour of those enterprises.1 This understanding is made more difficult, however, by several paradoxical features of public sector behaviour in the industrial sector of that country. One such paradox is the marked discrepancy between actual technological behaviour in the public sector and the behaviour that would have been consistent with the particular type of socialism pursued by Tanzania since 1967. For, whereas that type of so-called ‘African socialism’ laid considerable emphasis on small-scale, labour- and local-input-intensive technologies, the public sector has tended instead to use technologies with precisely the opposite features (that is, large-scale, capital- and import-intensive technologies). What is just as paradoxical, however, is that this apparent preference for certain types of technologies has not been uniformly applied across the public sector. Indeed, one can also find examples in the public sector of precisely the opposite forms of technological behaviour from those that have just been described. In some cases, these pronounced technological variations occur even within the same sector at around the same point of time.
2.1 The first paradox: planned versus actual technological behaviour in the public sector In order to make this first paradox as clear as possible, it is necessary to recognize that socialism in Africa after independence took a number of different forms. The first form, known as African socialism, is associated mainly with the governments of Nyerere in Tanzania and Nkrumah in Ghana during the 1960s. This form of socialism has been described as ‘Afrocentric’ and ‘non-aligned’, in that it purported to be adapted specifically to African conditions (Chazan et al., 1988, p. 150). African socialism needs to be contrasted with the ‘Afro-Marxist’ type of model that emerged in countries such as Mozambique, Angola and Ethiopia during the 1970s. In these and other countries that formed part of the ‘second wave’ of socialism in sub-Saharan Africa (Rosberg and Callaghy, 1979), the distinctiveness of the African situation tended to be rejected in favour of the established principles of scientific socialism (that is, of Marxism-Leninism). This distinction is important because it bears so heavily on the type of technology that the developing country is predisposed to select. Whereas socialism of the Marxist-Leninist variety demands the most modern, advanced technologies, this is not at all true of the African socialism that was practised in Tanzania after 1967. Immediately after the Arusha declaration, for example, President Nyerere made his position clear when he argued that:
Public Choice, Technology and Industrialization 137
even when we are building factories which serve the whole nation, we have to consider whether it is necessary for us to use the most modern machinery which exists in the world. We have to consider whether some older equipment which demands more labour, but labour which is less highly skilled, is not better suited to our needs, as well as being more within our capacity to build and use. (Nyerere, 1968b, pp. 98–9) There were indeed many cases, he believed, where the needs of society could better be met by labour-intensive, small-scale technologies than by large-scale mass production. These cases, furthermore, were closely in accord with his view that industry should be decentralized to the maximum possible extent. ‘In so far as there is a choice, we in Tanzania would infinitely prefer to see many small factories started in different towns in our country rather than one big factory started in any one of them’ (Nyerere, 1968a, p. 107). These early ideas were consistent with and indeed embodied in the key planning documents that were to form the basis of Tanzania’s industrialization strategy in the post-Arusha period (see Chapter 1). The second fiveyear plan, covering the years 1969 to 1974, for example, not only provided explicit encouragement of labour-intensive techniques, but also emphasized the importance of more decentralization and more effective linkages between large- and small-scale industries (ILO, 1982). For the period after 1974, the so-called ‘basic industry strategy’ strongly reaffirmed the principle of self-reliance, which played so central a role in the Arusha declaration and in subsequent policy pronouncements by the top political leadership. This goal was to be achieved, among other ways, by the encouragement of a local capital goods industry which would lessen Tanzania’s dependence on imports of foreign technology. Moreover, the major objectives laid down by the ‘basic industry strategy’, such as employment creation, equality of income distribution and dispersion of industry, suggested implicitly or explicitly that where a choice existed, technologies should generally be relatively low cost, labour intensive, simple and smallscale (Williams, 1976). Beginning in the 1970s, however, a long list of scholars in Tanzania and elsewhere pointed out that the technologies actually being used in the public sector typically had just the opposite features. That is to say, they were usually large-scale and inefficient, as well as being capital and import intensive.2 As such, therefore, these technologies also tended to have the effect of centralizing, rather than decentralizing, the location of industry in Tanzania. Far, therefore, from promoting the most important goals of the state, public enterprises in the industrial sector seemed to be doing just the reverse. It was not that there were no choices available to the managers of state-owned enterprises. On the contrary, over a wide range of
138 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
manufacturing industries a number of very different technological alternatives usually presented themselves. Table 5.1, for example, shows that the available techniques for ricemilling range from a small-scale huller (producing four to eight tons per day) to a large-scale roller (producing 120 tons per day), with the investment requirements per worker of the latter exceeding those of the former by a factor of around seven. Table 5.1 also shows that the estimated benefit–cost ratios vary inversely with the scale of the different techniques: the rice huller has the highest ratio of benefits to costs, while the rice roller has the lowest ratio. If the choice of the former could thus have been justified on the grounds of employment creation and efficiency, it was also preferable from the standpoint of industrial decentralization and self-reliance. Although one might have expected these considerations to prevail in the light of our earlier discussion, the state-owned milling corporation chose instead to expand its capacity on the basis of the largescale (120 tons per day) roller technology. Given the overriding importance that was apparently attached to the need for self-reliance in the period after 1967, one would also have expected state-owned enterprises, such as the milling corporation, to pay explicit attention to the acquisition of technological capabilities of various kinds. For there was certainly no lack of awareness on the part of national planners that a strategy of self-reliance had necessarily to be based on the substitution of domestic for foreign technological capabilities (an awareness that was perhaps most clearly articulated in relation to the ‘basic industry strategy’ in the 1970s), and the public enterprise, as an extension of the state, ought, one would think, to have been a key instrument in effecting that transformation. In practice, however, not only has there tended to be an increase rather than a decrease in the public sector’s
Table 5.1
Alternative rice-milling technologies Initial fixed cost (TSh 000)
Rice huller 4–8 tons per day Rice roller 24 tons per day 60 tons per day 120 tons per day
Total capital TSh per worker hour
Benefit–cost ratio (shadow prices, full capacity)
93.0
2.4
7.94a
1 752.5 4 410.0 7 927.0
14.3 11.9 16.7
2.52 1.69 1.52
Source: Bagachwa (1992), tables 1 and 5. Note: a 6 tons per day.
Public Choice, Technology and Industrialization 139
reliance on imported technology, but also a tendency for that technology to supplant rather than to stimulate the acquisition of indigenous technological capabilities (Wangwe, 1986, 1992a). 2.2 A second paradox: pronounced technological variations in the public sector Though these various departures from what one would have expected well describe the technological behaviour of the vast majority of firms in the public sector, they do not describe that of all of them. Indeed, one can also find examples in the public sector of precisely the opposite forms of technological behaviour from those that have just been described. And, especially when these pronounced technological variations occur within the same sector at around the same point in time, the possibility of a second paradox emerges, namely, that the state holds inconsistent technological preferences – preferences, that is to say, which, under similar conditions, lead to the choice of one particular technology at one point in time and to a completely different technology at another point in time. More formally, the paradox arises in that the state’s preferences for such sharply diverging methods of production need to be represented by intersecting rather than non-intersecting indifference curves, and the former, unlike the latter, violate the transitivity assumption of traditional micro-economic theory and welfare economics. Two examples describe this paradoxical type of behaviour especially clearly. Research on Tanzania’s textile industry, for example, has revealed a very wide range of factor intensities among state-owned enterprises, and in some of those enterprises, the choice of technology was made at approximately the same time and under similar conditions (see below). The other example comes from the brick-manufacturing industry, where, ‘The [Tanzanian] state has been involved in technological development, as well as in innovation. But what is especially interesting about this is the diversity of state actions. Two very different types of technological choice have been made by the ‘same’ state, one of an almost unbelievably inappropriate nature, the other much more relevant’ (Kaplinsky, 1990, p. 93). Mainly because it is the better documented of the two examples, we shall use data from the textile industry to illustrate the apparently inconsistent – and hence paradoxical – nature of the state’s technological behaviour. In particular, we shall confine ourselves to a comparison between two large-scale integrated textile mills, that, in spite of having been established more or less simultaneously at the end of the 1960s by the same public institution, the National Development Corporation, nevertheless exhibit a number of rather remarkable technological (and other) variations. One plant, for example, was highly labour intensive, whereas the other was highly capital intensive. One textile firm was one
140 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
of the most efficient in the entire industry, whereas the other performed poorly on virtually all the usual indicators. In one enterprise, indigenous technological capabilities were successfully acquired, while in the other they were not. Still another case that is difficult to reconcile with the general pattern of technological behaviour in the public sector is to be found in the farm implements subsector, for there is one state-owned enterprise in that sector that has used relatively simple labour-intensive technology (in conjunction with other factors) to attain a highly competitive position (as measured by domestic resource costs) (World Bank, 1987a). This firm is also unusual in the rapidity with which it was able to dispense with foreign technical expertise – that is, in the rapidity with which it was able to acquire indigenous technological capabilities of various kinds (Barker et al., 1986).
3
Existing explanations and their limitations
The earliest and most detailed attempt to explain the foregoing paradoxes was made by David Williams (1976) with particular reference to the textile industry. He showed, among other things, that the pronounced disparity between the technologies chosen in the industry could not be explained on the basis of the existing literature on the choice of technology in developing countries. It is often argued in this literature, for example, that technological differences between firms reflect differences in the types of products they manufacture (where differences refer to variations in the characteristics that the various products embody). In particular, it is commonly argued that labour-intensive technologies tend to produce goods with a higher proportion of functional or ‘low-income’ characteristics than capital-intensive techniques. Williams, however, found ‘no grounds for assuming that any particular type of technology in the observed range was dictated by product characteristics’ (Willams, 1975, p. 3). Nor was he able to find much evidence in support of another well-known category of explanations in the choice of technology, namely, those that impute various types of non-economic preferences to decision makers in developing countries. Perhaps the best known of these explanations is the ‘engineeringman’ hypothesis advanced by Louis Wells (1975). His contention, in brief, is that under conditions of imperfect competition the preference of ‘engineering-man’ for sophisticated automated technology and modern products dominates the concern of ‘economic-man’ to minimize costs of production. Yet, while there were certainly enough departures from perfect competition in Tanzania’s textile industry at the end of the 1960s to enable ‘engineering-man’ to hold sway, one would then have expected a uniform bias in favour of capital-intensive techniques, rather than the coexistence of techniques with markedly different factor intensities, as is most clearly
Public Choice, Technology and Industrialization 141
illustrated by the comparison between the two textile mills (see Table 5.2 below). As Williams puts it, ‘The engineering-man hypothesis would not predict that a single investor … would set up both capital-intensive and labour-intensive plants at the same time’. (Williams, 1975, p. 7). The same problem, one should note, would apply just as much to the various other technology-related objective functions that have been proposed in the literature, such as, for example, the sense of ‘national pride’ which is sometimes said to be evoked by the use of the most modern technologies in developing countries (Winston, 1979). 3.1
Project versus technological preferences
For this reason, Williams (1976) suggests that one should investigate instead the nature of non-technology-related objective functions in the public sector. He argues that managers are concerned essentially with projects rather than technologies, and that they are especially concerned with maximizing the number of projects that can be initiated and implemented. In seeking to meet this goal, managers tended to favour highly packaged projects – a tendency that was already present among parastatals by virtue of skill constraints and by lack of information about technology and other markets. The main reason was that highly packaged projects generally also offered distinct advantages, not just in terms of finance but also in terms of the relative ease and brevity with which they were able to be implemented (as is perhaps most obviously the case with turnkey projects). In fact, ‘a project package which included financing and which was “ready to go” would often be accepted with little question’ (Williams, 1976, p. 163). What evidence is available does tend to support the view that public enterprises favour packaged projects, at least in comparison with similar privately owned firms. A study of public and private sector industrial projects by Wangwe (1986), for example, found that it is mainly in the public sector that turnkey projects have been adopted in Tanzania. Under these circumstances, so the argument goes, the ‘choice of technique’ is just the ‘fall-out’ or residual from the particular package of foreign finance and other related project inputs that happen to be chosen. What seems to be decisive in this process, which, one should emphasise, actually excludes technological issues from the purview of the typical project, is not the value of one project in relation to others (as measured by the major development goals), but rather the demands made by each of them on scarce equity finance. For their part, The parastatals responded to the bureaucratic realities by presenting projects in a manner best calculated to ensure acceptance. Thus, a lowcost labour-intensive textile mill, completely financed outside the budget, would be preferred to any mill for which more financing from
142 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
the budget were required. But if circumstances were such that the more acceptable package available consisted of a high-cost capital-intensive mill, then that would be chosen. (Williams, 1976, p. 165) Let us now consider how this observation can be applied to the concrete case of the two textile mills that were established, as noted earlier, at more or less the same time by the National Development Corporation. 3.2
A comparison of the two textile plants
Table 5.2 sets out the main technological differences between these two factories. It shows that the one plant, Friendship, is considerably more labour intensive than the other plant, Mwanza, using as it does two and a half times as many workers per unit of output, together with an appreciably lower amount of capital. In circumstances where labour is comparatively cheap, as in Tanzania, it is not surprising that the labour-intensive alternative should be the more profitable of the two textile technologies, as shown in Table 5.2. What then were the particular circumstances that surrounded the more or less simultaneous selection by the same public sector institution of these two factories? Friendship, it seems, was originally conceived after high-level political contacts between the People’s Republic of China and Tanzania, and the project was financed entirely by a long-term interest-free loan from the Chinese government. Because the proposed textile factory was both politically sanctioned and externally financed it was approved without much ado. And the technology that resulted from this externally financed project in no way reflected any technological concerns on the part of the Tanzanian bureaucracy, whose objectives tended to be defined purely in terms of projects. Rather, the technology that was ‘chosen’ for the Friendship project appeared to reflect instead the conditions in the supplying country, and in particular the fact that the Chinese were familiar with older and relatively labour-intensive vintages of textile technology (indeed, the particular vintage used at Friendship happened to be the most labourTable 5.2
A comparison of two textile plants Friendship
Capital cost up to 1969 (million shillings) Production of woven fabrics in 1975 (million linear metres) Number of employees in 1975 Profit in 1975 (million shillings) Cost of carded cotton in 1973 (shillings per tonne) Labour hours per tonne of carded cotton in 1973 Source: Coulson (1982b).
61.5 24.0 5057 2.8 2512 247
Mwanza 106.5 22.5 2486 2.3 2910 98
Public Choice, Technology and Industrialization 143
intensive of the technologies that were being produced at the time in China). A year later, by contrast, a very different – albeit perhaps equally attractive – package of project characteristics presented itself to the Tanzanians in the form of the Mwanza textile mill. One reason why this project differed from the Friendship case was that is was financed by a supplier’s credit rather than by bilateral foreign aid. The most important difference, though, was that the financial source of the project was located mainly in France rather than in China, and ‘the latest and most automated equipment’ used at Mwanza tended accordingly to reflect conditions in the former rather than the latter country. It is thus by defining bureaucratic objectives over projects that Williams is able to resolve the second paradox. For the seemingly inconsistent technological preferences are replaced in his framework by a consistent set of project-related preferences, from which technological outcomes are derived rather than chosen. What this framework is unable to clarify, however, is the first of the two paradoxes described above. For whereas that paradox has to do with both an observed bias towards large-scale, capital-intensive and inefficient techniques and a systematic tendency towards sophisticated, ‘high-income’ products, Williams (1976) argues instead that the factor intensity of technologies associated with packaged, externally financed projects would be randomly distributed: that is, that there would be no systematic bias in any one direction. This particular weakness of the approach, however, can be overcome by a more realistic analysis of the relationship between the sources of external finance and the types of industrial technology that have been transferred to the public sector in Tanzania. For one thing, even after the Arusha declaration in that country, most of the foreign finance supplied to the public sector originated in the developed market economies (and took the form mainly of foreign aid, as shown in Table 5.5 below). And the types of products and processes associated with this type of finance are not randomly distributed, but are instead closely reflective of the socioeconomic conditions prevailing in the supplier countries (especially a relative scarcity of labour, high average incomes and large markets).3 On the other hand, though, when foreign finance originates instead in developing countries, the same historical line of argument leads one to expect the transfer of relatively appropriate forms of technology, an expectation that was clearly met in the case of the Friendship textile mill and also in the case of the labour-intensive farm implements enterprise referred to earlier. For in the latter case as well, what mattered was not ‘that the Tanzanian side took any greater degree of interest in the choice of technology than in any other project’ (Barker et al., 1986, p. 123), but rather that the finance was provided by the Chinese who (as in Friendship) favoured relatively simple technology. By thus combining the basic insight provided by Williams – that managers seek to maximize external project finance – with a historically
144 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
oriented view of how this behaviour leads to particular technological outcomes, one can account for much of what seems paradoxical about the behaviour of state-owned enterprises in Tanzania. Yet, for all its centrality to this composite argument, the foreign-exchange maximizing behaviour by the bureaucracy remains far from well understood. Most importantly, it is not at all clear how this behaviour actually enters the utility function of the manager of a public enterprise. What is lacking, in other words, is a detailed analysis of bureaucratic objectives and an assessment of the manner in which those objectives are furthered by foreign-exchange maximizing behaviour in the public sector. Though it was not designed to address this particular question, we shall now argue that the public choice approach to bureaucracy nonetheless throws considerable light on it.
4
The public choice approach to bureaucracy
The public choice approach to bureaucracy emphasizes the multiplicity of ways in which an expansion of the size of an institution promotes the particular interests of its members. In so doing, we shall argue, this approach provides precisely what was missing from the previous section, namely, an analysis of how the maximization of foreign exchange (and more generally budget maximization) promotes the objectives that were really pursued by managers of state-owned enterprises. Although an early contribution by Downs (1967) had emphasized how ‘The expansion of any organization normally provides its leaders with increased power, income and prestige’ (Downs, 1967, p. 17), and how those persons would therefore tend to favour organizational growth, the specific notion of a ‘budget-maximising bureaucrat’ is most closely associated with William Niskanen (1973). The latter makes essentially two claims, the first of them being that the manager of a public bureau has the following among his major goals: ‘salary, perquisites of the office, public reputation, power, patronage, output’ (ibid., p. 22). Niskanen’s second major claim is that since these goals are all assumed to vary directly with the size of the budget, the aim of the bureaucrat can be reduced to one of maximizing this financial variable during his time in office. This time-element bears emphasizing in part because most of the gains that accrue to the budget maximizing bureaucrat ‘are nearly unrelated to the ‘net worth’ of his organisation after his departure’ (ibid., p. 33), and in part because his tenure in office itself may be relatively short in many developing countries.
5 Foreign-exchange maximising bureaucracy and the political economy of Tanzania It is easy enough to show that these goals find frequent expression in the writings of political scientists who work on sub-Saharan Africa in general
Public Choice, Technology and Industrialization 145
and on Tanzania in particular. Indeed, one of those goals, bureaucratic power, is one of the most pervasive themes of that part of the political science literature which deals with the post-independence period in Africa. After noting how the phenomenal growth in the size of the civil service in Tanzania (and elsewhere) created ‘a privileged group’ with ‘corporate interests of its own’ and with considerable opportunities for ‘personal aggrandisement’, Chazan et al. (1988, p. 53), for example, are not alone in suggesting that the bureaucracy ‘emerged as the core of a new dominant class in the postcolonial period’. Moreover, in its analysis of how the economic and political power thus acquired by the bureaucracy is exercised, the political science literature almost uniformly assigns a paramount role to patronage, another of the goals emphasized by Niskanen (1973). There is, however, only one study that deals in detail with the political economy aspects of the growth in the public sector in Tanzania and which, at the same time, analyses the role played by foreign-exchange maximisation in that growth. This study (Mukandala, 1988) takes as its point of departure the notion that since 1969 the ‘political stratum’ of the Tanzanian state has been locked in an intense and prolonged conflict with the ‘managerial stratum’ of the state (where the former category refers essentially to those who make or design policy, and the latter refers largely to those who actually carry it out). It is not that there were no parastatals in Tanzania prior to the Arusha declaration, but it was only in the years thereafter, where the parastatal sector had emerged as a ‘strategic and complex branch of the state’ (ibid., p. 29) that the political and managerial strata came into direct and open conflict. For by then, following an extraordinarily rapid increase in their numbers and their net assets (see Table 5.3 below), parastatals had become ‘too big, diverse and strategic to be left to the managerial stratum yet proved too difficult to control through conventional government methods’ (ibid.) It was already all too plain, for example, that the parastatals were behaving less like vehicles in the transition to socialism and more like ‘bastions of capitalism’, with only a very tenuous connection to the political institutions of the state. What particularly concerned the ‘political stratum’ was the National Development Corporation (NDC), which accounted for no less than half the total investment by parastatals in new firms, and which was in control of the majority of the state’s assets in manufacturing and other sectors of the economy. (So rapid in fact was the growth of this institution that its total net assets almost doubled over the period from 1967 to 1969.) The ‘political stratum’s’ response to this situation was the introduction of a series of measures whose objective was to limit the degree of freedom then being enjoyed by the parastatal sector as a whole and the NDC in particular. These measures marked the beginning of what has been described as the ‘rationalisation’ phase in the parastatal sector (Mukandala, 1988, p. 29). According to one such measure, for example, particular groups
146
Table 5.3
The growth of the public sector in manufacturing Public sector fixed assets in manufacturing (million shillings)
1966 1967 1971 1979 1980 1981 1982
21a 971 2 851 3 278.4
Public sector employment in manufacturing (absolute numbers) 2 330 5 300 20 113 53 000
Share of public sector in manufacturing employment (per cent) 15.5 46.4 50.0 50.0 47.7 52.7
Share of public sector in manufacturing value added (per cent) 5 14 29 31 37.1 48.2 56.8
Sources: (Col. 1) World Bank (1988, p. 4); (Col. 2) Perkins (1980), Clark (1978) and World Bank (1987a); (Cols 3 and 4) Skarstein and Wangwe (1986). Note: a Refers to 1964.
Public Choice, Technology and Industrialization 147
of parastatals were to be placed under the control of newly created parent ministries. Other measures involved a heavier degree of reliance on some parastatals (such as the National Price Commission and the Bank of Tanzania) in the regulation of other parastatals, and a strengthened role for central ministries (such as the Treasury and the Ministry of Development Planning). By far the most extreme of all the measures employed by the ‘political stratum’ after 1969, however, was the attempt at ‘rationalization’ of the parastatal sector. What was intended by this was basically the fragmentation of the then existing corporations into increasingly smaller units, in the hope that they would thereby become less powerful and more manageable. The policy of rationalization did produce some results: between 1971 and 1974, for example, the NDC was stripped of 17 of its operating companies and 19 of its projects. On the whole, though, these and other attempts to limit the rapidly growing influence of the ‘managerial stratum’ met with only a very limited degree of success. To some extent this was a reflection of a somewhat predictable set of administrative and logistical problems (predictable because the relatively scarcity of administrative resources must have been apparent right at the outset of Tanzania’s attempted transition to socialism). To a large extent, however, the failure of the political stratum to achieve its objective was due to the vigorous countermeasures that the parastatal institutions themselves undertook. It is in these measures and their outcomes that one finds rather striking support for a public choice interpretation of bureaucratic behaviour in Tanzania, for what occurred was a particularly clear demonstration of the political advantages that accrue from an increase in the size of a public institution. Consider from this point of view Mukandala’s telling description of how the parastatal sector as a whole responded to what, in the guise of rationalization, was nothing less than a familiar ‘divide and rule’ tactic by the ‘political stratum’. Thus, On the one hand the managerial stratum established new subsidiary companies to replace those hived-off by the state … . This was deemed necessary because the more subsidiaries a corporation had, the bigger it was and consequently a) more resources were allocated to it in the national budget for developmental purposes; b) the more bargaining power it had when negotiating for higher salaries (especially for its management). Size showed ‘umuhimu’ or importance relevance; c) strengthened its hand in mobilising external finance on its own. … External finance was also useful because once obtained, it assured approval for the projects from the Treasury, the Bank of Tanzania and the Ministry of Development Planning. Foreign capital’s need to invest in new projects rather than expanding or rehabilitating old ones reinforced this trend. (Mukandala, 1988, p. 32).
148 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Table 5.4
The growth of the public sector in general Established posts in the civil service
1966 1967 1971 1980
65 708 80 239 99 564 295 342
Total number of parastatals 43 73 380
Sources: (col. 1) Mukandala (1985), (col. 2) de Valk (1992).
From the perspective of a sector engaged in a struggle for its very survival, therefore, what seemed to matter much more than its efficiency or profitability were its size and power. And it is from these political points of view, we suggest, that the central role of new projects and foreign capital needs to be understood. To what extent then did the public sector actually grow in Tanzania? Table 5.3 provides evidence on this question for the manufacturing sector, while Table 5.4 refers to the public sector more generally (in both cases the data cover the period from the 1960s to the early 1980s). As one would expect, the figures in the tables show a marked growth in the public sector after the Arusha declaration. For there was then a greatly enhanced need for civil servants and other officials to run the institutions that had just been nationalized (Mukandala, 1985). What is remarkable, though, is that the public sector continued to grow very rapidly after the early post-Arusha period, when no such obvious need for personnel was apparent and at a time when in fact the ‘political stratum’ of the state was bent on reducing the sector’s size and power. Between 1971 and 1981/2, for example, public sector fixed assets in manufacturing grew more than threefold, while the share of public enterprises in manufacturing value added almost doubled (see Table 5.3). These pronounced increases in the absolute and relative size of the public sector were closely related to the external sector, for in the ‘frantic spate of subsidiary creation’ referred to above ‘there was a renewed aggressiveness toward recruiting foreign project partners; the call for self-reliance notwithstanding. … This in turn led to a faster increase in the importation of capital rather than intermediate goods and over-installation of new industrial capacity’ (Mukandala, 1988, pp. 128–9). Tanzania’s increasing reliance on imported capital goods over this period was to a large extent made possible by growing amounts of foreign aid, which, as Table 5.5 shows, financed an ever-greater proportion of gross investment and government expenditure. The effect of all of this activity on the technological dimensions of the industrialization process was hardly surprising. On the one hand, the
Public Choice, Technology and Industrialization 149 Table 5.5
The growth of external sources of finance Total aid (million US dollars)
1960s 1970 1975 1980 1982
29.9 114.9 493.6 514.9
Total aid as percentage of monetary gross investment 11.4 25.3 46.6 54.3
Share of foreign financing in government expenditure (%) 30–35 40 45 50
Sources: (col. 1 and 2) Skarstein and Wangwe (1986); (col. 3) Wangwe (1992a).
powerful political pressure to grow as a means of institutional survival, with its attendant dependence on external sources of finance, meant that little time was available to public sector managers for consideration of factors such as labour intensity, self-reliance and industrial decentralisation that were described earlier as being important to the ‘political stratum’. Nor was there time for undertaking the various types of effort (such as search activities) on which the acquisition of local technological capabilities is known to depend. A management or technical collaboration agreement with a foreign partner, for example, was much more likely to have been seen by the parastatal as a way of overcoming short-run skills constraints on its expansion (via projects), than as an issue which carries important long-run implications for the acquisition of technological capabilities in the public sector. On the other hand, in its neglect of the managerial function the parastatal was further contributing to the inattention paid to capabilities issues, because it was effectively ignoring the range of issues that bear on technological learning and mastery at the operational level (that have to do, for example, with project implementation, repair and maintenance). 5.1
The size of the public sector under structural adjustment
If the public sector in Tanzania continued to grow rapidly into the early 1980s, in spite of attempts to curb its size and power, it also managed to withstand the privatisation schemes and other measures that were introduced a few years later by the World Bank, as part of the wider process of structural adjustment. On the one hand, some notable increases in the absolute size of the sector were recorded in the period after the reforms were introduced (that is, after 1986). The total number of state-owned enterprises, for example, grew from 380 in 1980 to 425 in 1988, 4 while the civil service as a whole increased in size by more than 5 per cent over the period 1985–92.5 On the other hand (and relatedly), some World Bank data show that with respect to most macroeconomic variables, the public sector share
150
Table 5.6
The public sector share in Tanzania before and after structural adjustment Share of state-owned enterprises in GDP
Share of state-owned enterprises in non-agricultural economic activity
Share of state-owned enterprise investment in gross domestic investment
Share of state-owned enterprises in employment
1978–85 1986–91
10.8 13.7
18.1 23.8
24.6 30.0
22.3 22.3
Change
+2.9
+5.7
+5.4
0
Source: World Bank (1995a).
Public Choice, Technology and Industrialization 151
increased rather than decreased in the reform period, as compared with the seven previous years. In particular, one can see from Table 5.6 that the state-owned share of the GDP, non-agricultural economic activity and gross domestic investment actually increased in the later period, while its share in employment remained unchanged between the two periods. Since the period covered by Table 5.6, however, the pace of liberalisation and privatisation has quickened somewhat. Between 1990 and 1995, for example, 34 of the 170 parastatals in manufacturing were privatised. This, in turn, will tend to have increased the share of the private sector in investment and other macroeconomic variables.
6
Conclusions
In this paper we have sought to explain several of the most paradoxical aspects of technology and industrialization in Tanzania since the Arusha declaration of 1967. Our explanation has turned mainly on two assumptions about bureaucratic behaviour in that country: the first is that bureaucrats have preferences defined over projects rather than technologies, and the second is that in their capacity as managers of state-owned enterprises these agents of the state have sought to initiate as many new projects as possible, mainly on the basis of foreign aid. Such behaviour, we suggested, was rooted in a political context where the drive to institutional expansion was viewed as a key element in the survival of the bureaucracy. It meant that the various branches of the public sector continued to grow very rapidly well beyond the early post-Arusha years, when there had been an initial need for large numbers of extra civil servants to manage and run the newly nationalised industries. In fact, as we showed in a number of tables, the public sector grew very rapidly throughout the 1970s and early 1980s, at a time when the ‘political stratum’ of the state was bent on reducing its size and power. It also meant that even from 1986 to 1992, during the period of structural adjustment reforms which began in 1986, the public sector share of most macroeconomic variables increased rather than decreased.
Notes * Department of Economics, Tilburg University, PO Box 90153, Tilburg, The Netherlands. This article was originally published in Public Choice, 89, 3/4 (1996), pp. 375–392, and is reprinted with kind permission of Kluwer Academic Publishers. 1. For details see James (1995). This book was the first attempt to apply public choice theory to African industrialization in general. 2. This was already clear from Clark’s study (1978) of the period from 1964 to 1973. He pointed to a ‘failure of the post-Arusha companies to distinguish themselves significantly and favourably from the pre-Arusha companies’
152 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania (Clark, 1978, p. 140), and concluded that ‘There has been as yet no developmental innovation on the part of parastatals to make themselves more consistent with the Tanzanian ideology’ (ibid.). Some years later a very detailed study by Perkins (1980, 1983) of more than 300 firms in ten industrial sectors arrived at a similar conclusion, namely, that despite the existence of efficient labour-intensive technologies and ‘Despite the rhetoric, Tanzania’s industrialization programme has in general promoted the establishment of [publicly owned] enterprises using large-scale capital-intensive, often technically and invariably economically inefficient technologies’ (Perkins, 1983, p. 231). 3. This argument is most clearly elaborated in Stewart (1977). 4. These data are taken from de Valk (1992), who does not cite his primary source. 5. See World Bank (1994a). This source does not however reveal the amount over 5 per cent by which the civil service grew over this period.
6 The Form and Role of Innovativeness in Enhancing Firms’ Productivity: The Case of Selected Manufacturing Firms in Tanzania Haji H. Semboja and Josephat P. Kweka*
1
Introduction
Development experience has shown that the countries that have undergone fast economic growth and structural change in the second half of the twentieth century are those that have based their productivity growth on rapid absorption of foreign technology and on increasing efficiency in the use of technology over time, and that have successfully developed and applied innovation through learning. Generally, the scale of operation, firm size, organisational structure, characteristics of the market, industrial policies, infrastructure, resource availability and the supporting institutions are crucial factors determining the nature and level of innovative activities. At the broader level, human resource development and access to finance and the legal and regulatory framework contribute to innovative achievement. At the firm level, technological development has occurred through innovation which has become not only an important determinant of the level of productivity but also of firms’ international competitiveness. However, during the pre-reform era innovation was never a major determinant of the level of productivity in Tanzanian manufacturing. Technological development has been limited. What development there was, has occurred through absorption and adaptation of foreign technology rather than indigenous technological change. It is upon this understanding that the process of technological development, the nature of innovations and the factors influencing innovative activities need to be understood as a basis of formulating policies for stimulating productivity and competitiveness of the manufacturing industry. This article intends to make a contribution in this direction.1 We set out to describe the various forms of innovative activities at firm level and to determine the factors influencing these activities,
154 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
assessing their role in enhancing the productivity of manufacturing firms in Tanzania.2 Section 2 discusses the form and role of innovativeness from a general and conceptual perspective. Section 3 maps the various forms of innovative efforts and activities in the selected manufacturing firms in Tanzania, while Section 4 deals with factors determining firm innovativeness. Finally, Section 5 provides conclusions and policy recommendations.
2 Forms and role of innovation from a conceptual and general perspective In this article we shall consider innovation in its broader sense, that is, as all that is new to the organisation. At firm level, innovation refers to both the technology of an enterprise and its products (Rothwell, 1977; Souder and Chakrabarti, 1980).3 Technical and innovative capability is an asset for adaptation to all sorts of societal changes. Innovation is caused through interactions between individuals, business units and social-economic sectors. In the developing world, public socioeconomic supporting institutions can make important contributions to importing, modifying and diffusing new technologies. Innovation contributes to the creation of wealth and induces growth, structural change and development. The innovative capacity of a country constitutes its ability to adapt to shocks, be they internal or external (DeBresson, 1994). This capacity may break the constraints of the internal and external environment, and enable a country to forge ahead, thus improving the market position of firms and challenging competitors and the external environment, making them adapt. According to DeBresson (1994), innovative activity is an aspect of competition, growth and development. Competition by technology is an important force for a firm and an industry in the context of both industrially developed and developing economies. With the opening of markets, for an organisation to survive, it is imperative to undertake innovative activities. Import substitution strategies or industrial protection introduced to enable an industry to learn and catch up often have the perverse effect of inducing inertia. Some forms of learning must exist in an organisation if it is to survive. Even the so-called traditional manufacturing industries are no longer exempt from the impact of new techniques. Innovation has also been identified as an important determinant of success in small-scale enterprises. It is through product rather than technological innovation that small-scale enterprises are able to develop their competitive edge. Romano (1990) found that, for high-growth firms, the determinants of product innovation that influenced the success of small business included technology, R&D, the product life cycle, market change, product/market mix and customer base. For low-growth firms, customer base was a major determinant of product innovation.
Innovativeness and Productivity 155
Innovations can be characterised on the basis of whether they are process or product innovations, and whether innovation is original to a specific country (say Tanzania) or to the world, or whether it is imitative. We also need to distinguish revolutionary/radical innovation from adaptive/ incremental innovation. Radical innovation is supposed to induce a new growth cycle in its sector and perhaps in the whole economy. It increases utility and dramatically reduces costs by setting up a totally new production function. Schumpeter postulated that important innovations always required the setting up of new productive units and new fixed investments. Adaptive innovation or adaptive technical change are those activities directed at modifying the technical basis of the production process prior to full-scale use, or changes to a product before it is introduced to the market. Adaptive innovations draw mostly on known techniques and the existing knowledge base. Incremental innovations are those evolutionary technical changes aimed at correcting technical imbalances, and modifying minor (yet significant) core or peripheral systems. In this analysis both adaptive innovation and incremental innovation are opposed to radical innovation. Technological knowledge is cumulative. There are no clear borderlines between imitation and creation. Both radical innovations and adaptations are essential elements of technological change. On the origins of technological innovation, two oversimplified theories of innovation have dominated the debate, ‘technology-push’ and ‘demandpull’. According to the demand-pull theory, innovation arises as a result of perceived and often clearly articulated market needs, which leads to focused R&D activities, creating a host of products for the market (Rothwell, 1985). The rationale behind the theory is that production units within the markets recognise customer needs and direct their efforts to fulfil those needs through technological activities (Dosi, 1984). The actors in the market, that is, the adopters, can be private firms, government or domestic consumers. Under the technology-push theory, discoveries in basic science and R&D eventually lead to technological development which results in the flow of new products and processes to the market place (Rothwell and Zegveld, 1985, cited in Diyamet et al., 1998). Innovations await technological progress. Thus, according to technology push proponents, the market initially plays a minimal role in the innovation process, acting only as a repository for R&D results. The entrepreneur occupies a central position. However, Fransman (1986) pointed out that it is a statement of the obvious to say that the market will influence a firm’s technological activity. Firms must market their products in order to survive. In the pursuit of innovation, firms need to lay down consistent strategies for achieving or acquiring the desired forms and types of innovation, or adopting certain technical advances. Some strategies develop in the drive to sharpen the competitive edge, others develop as guidelines for
156 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
implementing predetermined technological progress. We can identify two kinds of innovation strategies: offensive and defensive. An offensive innovation strategy is aimed at achieving technical and market leadership by being ahead of competitors in the introduction of new products and investing in technological advances. A defensive innovation strategy, on the other hand, may take the form described as ‘defensive’, ‘imitative’, ‘dependent’ or ‘opportunist’. A defensive strategy does not necessarily translate into a lack of research-intensiveness. Though the defensive strategist does not aspire to technical and economic leadership, he or she equally does not want to suffer the penalties of laggardness by being saddled with obsolete technology. Risk-taking and incurring financial losses are avoided. The defensive strategist aspires to benefit from the mistakes of the market leaders, and may lack the capacity to undertake the fundamental research necessary to assume and maintain technical leadership. Innovation capabilities consist of search capabilities and the capacity to integrate the results of such searches (Wangwe, 1994). Search capabilities are those required to find new ways of carrying out the firm’s investment, production, marketing and organisation, activities. The search for new routines is likely to be reflected in efforts to create new patterns of human resource development (through in-house or outside training), in R&D (formal and informal),4 in searches for technological information from local and foreign sources and in technological adaptations and market research (study of market trends and potential markets and of the possibilities of introducing new products). Given the circumstances existing in developing countries such as Tanzania, adaptive innovation is likely to be more prevalent than radical innovation. Sources of innovation are most likely to be foreign. Only the uses and applications may be new. The experience of Asian countries (or even industrial countries like Italy) has demonstrated that much growth, development and technical accumulation can be obtained without much invention or basic or applied research. Innovative activities need not always be related to intensive scientific and technological research. In this sense, innovative activity, as a social and economic factor of change, is not the monopoly of advanced industrial countries (as some of the recent trade and new growth models assume).
3 Innovative efforts and achievements in the manufacturing sector in Tanzania Tanzania aims to strengthen her technological capability for processing basic commodities and upgrading her export industries, in order to produce high quality goods that can withstand domestic, regional and global market competition. This has been done through endogenous capacity building in science and technology and efforts to create a conducive
Innovativeness and Productivity 157
environment for unleashing the creative and innovative potential of the people of Tanzania. The use of imported technologies provides learning opportunities and thus help to develop an indigenous technological base when these technologies are actively selected and acquired by users. A study by Wangwe (1986) on technology imports, technological learning and self-reliance in Tanzania found that technological changes and innovations have been limited by the localization of major technological decisions and a high degree of heterogeneity of technological imports. Technological change via adaptations resulting in the improvement of performance was limited. Evidence from various ESRF surveys of industrial performance 5 has shown that innovation-relevant types of linkages, such as inter-firm linkages, financial institutions linkages and business support linkages, do exist within the Tanzanian manufacturing sector. However, these have mainly been utilized on an ad hoc basis. Divestiture programmes in Tanzania have made it possible for some local firms to access and link with foreign firms in the procurement of technical expertise, machinery, equipment, product technology as well as new markets. These are mainly companies that have bought and invested in existing or former public/parastatal firms. For instance, in the case of the electrical equipment company ABB tanelec (by then tanelec) the design and production of transformers on one hand is based on the technology adopted from the ABB National Transformers, which has been producing electrotechnical equipment for more than 75 years.6 This has thus contributed to significant improvements in the firm’s technological capability and competitiveness through innovative efforts. In the case of Tanzania Breweries Ltd, a successful joint venture and divestiture process in 1993 was followed by a dramatic improvement in the firm’s profitability and performance (see Chapter 15). A more recent study by the World Bank, the Regional Program on Enterprise Development (RPED, 1994) covered four sectors, namely textiles, wood, food and metal fabrication. Given the quality of technical personnel in these firms, innovations were of a limited nature. Quality or refined technology design and innovation were generally beyond their capabilities and resources. Sources of innovation included both the ideas and information about innovation as well the technology and the support for carrying out innovation. Major sources are established business channels, personal contacts, inhouse R&D efforts, customers and research institutes (Chungu et al., 1994). There is a need for more emphasis on the absorption aspects of innovation, coupled with technical extension services from the producers and the management and maintenance of the technology. Studies by Semboja et al. (1997b) and ESRF-PSRC (1996) suggest that the sectors with the highest levels of innovation and strongest innovative linkages in the Tanzanian manufacturing sector are predicable by previous levels of domestic forward
158 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
and backward linkages. Also, the relative frequency of domestically initiated innovations rises with the level of firm performance. According to the RPED (1995) study, firms show marked differences as to the renewing or upgrading of their equipment. Between 1988 and 1992, 57 per cent of the firms surveyed undertook major additions to or changes in plant and equipment. The main reasons given for new direct investment were to increase capacity in existing product lines (50 per cent) and to improve the production process (35 per cent). Only 12 per cent of firms invested in a new equipment for producing a different product or a different type of a similar product. The metals branch is the leading innovative manufacturing sector. According to Semboja et al. (1997b) 7 larger firms and private firms in Tanzania have more innovative capability than small firms and public firms The more innovative firms concentrated on increasing capacity and to a certain extent on improving the production process. These additional capacities led to a reduction in the unit production costs and to improved product quality. Thus the larger firms managed to reduce costs much more than the smaller ones (an aspect of a defensive innovation strategy). This shows that large firms have a greater capability to adjust production processes in order to remain competitive under a liberalised economic regime. On the other hand, the involvement of large foreign firms in the construction sector may induce technology transfer, given the wellplanned integrated project management schemes. For example, the transfer or the acquisition of technology within the construction sector entails training efforts designed for local personnel at operational, functional and management levels, the involvement of local contractors and the provision of employment to local staff (Semboja et al., 1997b). The participation of local construction firms as subcontractors to foreign firms is an important element in enhancing innovation and the acquisition of technology. However, in general, production technology and market orientation predominantly focus on domestic demand, rather than on target export sectors. The case studies in ESRF-PSRC (1996) show that adaptive technological change resulting in the improvement of performance occurred least frequently and was relatively the most limited. Local manpower involvement in carrying out feasibility studies, choice and design of production methods, choice of product, participation in the installation of plant and machinery is limited. This deficiency has diminished the opportunity to kick-start serious innovativeness by imitation, adaptations or skill transfer by local personnel. Product technology improvements were substantial in leather (shoemaking), metal and engineering industries (ESRF-PSRC, 1996). Designs of a number of products had been made in collaboration with local institutions. In terms of the size of firms, many small- and medium-scale enterprises have been identified with product-centred innovative
Innovativeness and Productivity 159
capabilities, mainly owing to the flexible nature of their production and the significant role of the customer in product design. However, larger firms are more capable of carrying out innovativeness, given their relative abilities to purchase and adopt technological progress. Some studies (Niosi and Rivard, 1988) show that there has been an increasing tendency for the industrial nations to adapt and modify their exported technology to suit the conditions of host countries. The ESRF-PSRC (1996) study on the divestiture impact on industrial performance corroborates this phenomenon in the case study of Moshi Leather Industries, where most of the technological innovations in the company were the initiatives to adapt the foreign technology (from the parent company) to fit the local raw materials (skins and hides). In the case study of the G&T (shoemaking) Company, the management recruited a full-time technician with the ability to modify and adopt the machinery to suit the local conditions. Therefore, the need for major technical adaptations by foreign firms (for example, multinational companies) may be reduced. The acquisition of technological capabilities was restricted to the importation of foreign technology, adaptations to suit local conditions, that is, gaining mastery, making minor improvements. General key aspects of technology appear to be specifically relevant to product innovation. Small firms’ dependence on a number of larger suppliers of raw materials, components, and equipment or on subcontractors reduces their control over their production process, resulting in difficulties in maintaining product quality and the level of service. Evidence from the garment sub-sector shows that firms’ responsiveness to changing market conditions and policy changes (for example, import liberalisation) was reduced by the long periods of protection they had enjoyed before liberalisation. As a result firms were unable to develop the abilities and culture to respond dynamically to challenges, based on their own innovations and initiatives. In this regard, employee participation is considered to influence their commitment to firm initiatives for innovation. This article supports the thrust of recent trade and growth models which have focused more explicitly on the micro-foundations of innovation by addressing firm-level decisions to invest in product or process innovations. Some surveys and studies on manufacturing firms in Tanzania (ESRF-PSRC, 1996; Semboja et al., 1997b) have shown that the ceaseless search for improvements in technology (especially product quality and cost-lowering process innovations) has been instrumental in improving productivity. Productivity growth, in turn, was a most important factor enabling exporting firms to succeed in the changing technological and market conditions. Exporting firms maintained and improved their market position by investing in technology and continuing to improve on it. Improvements were made not only in the firms’ products but also in the processes of production, in order to cope with pressure to keep costs at competitive levels or to
160 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
improve product quality (level and consistency). These responses were derived from signals given in export markets. Experience in some large-scale and high-growth firms (Tanzania Breweries Ltd, Afro-Cooling, and so on) shows that productivity has steadily improved because of improvements in technology and management techniques. In areas where labour accounts for around 90 per cent of value added there have been many improvements in labour productivity as a result of managerial innovativeness. Both the large scale textile mills said that the wage cost of the conversion of raw materials into finished products has been kept low while volumes produced have increased. This has been made possible by a number of factors, including improved training of labour, improvements in production programming, and reducing the varieties and styles produced in the production runs.
4
Factors influencing innovativeness for productivity
As a result of liberalisation, Tanzania presently operates a virtual ‘open door’ policy towards foreign investment and technology. Capital goods, raw materials and technical knowledge can now be imported without hindrance. It is crucial to examine whether there are factors which determine the extent to which the previous import substitution regime or the current export promotion strategies result in absence of innovativeness or positive innovative efforts which contribute to technological capacity building. This section examines some of the critical factors influencing innovative behaviour of firms. The purpose of this examination is to identify these factors and reflect on the extent to which innovative efforts have been limited in the Tanzanian manufacturing sector. These factors include: human resource development, R&D efforts, finance, competitive market turbulence, institutional framework and linkages, access to technical information, and the legal and regulatory framework. 4.1
Human resource development
The various ESRF manufacturing studies show that the educational background of owners/managers of firms has been identified as an important factor in enhancing firms’ productivity. Interaction with other persons and educational experience can make management more receptive to change, and promotes its imaginative role in innovation. Significant numbers of firms in these surveys pointed to financial constraints as the cause of insufficient formal training.8 Most of the firms prefer in-house training as a cheaper option, mostly dealing with specific problems or process improvements. In this respect, innovativeness envisioned as a result of external training and exposure of technical workers is rather far-fetched.9 In-house training is done continuously to improve upon the initial skills and productivity of the workers. Some firms have in-house training
Innovativeness and Productivity 161
programmes for their employees while others do not. About 61 per cent of the surveyed firms in the ESRF Multi-Country Comparative Study on Private Enterprise Development survey (Semboja et al., 1997b) have indicated that they have in-house training programmes, whereas 39 per cent do not have them. The nature of such training is mainly on the job training, and its main objectives are to enhance/upgrade workers’ skills, equip them with new production techniques, and teach them better quality control and other machine operations. This is especially important for new recruits, and for improving productivity and the quality of goods and services. Many firms send their employees to local institutions, especially technical colleges or vocational training colleges, such as the Vocational Educational Training Authority (ESRF-VETA, 1998). Prior experience in business has been suggested as important in providing owners with knowledge of current operations. Training obtained in a successful innovative firm will make management responsible for innovation more progressive and open-minded (Rothwell, 1977). Without the support of previous managerial experience for innovation, it will be difficult to develop a successful innovation programme. In Tanzania, however, in most firms long experience of the workers or managers did not translate into significant innovation. This is because managers are preoccupied with routine tasks and responsibilities, where their work experience has made them capable of solving the day-to-day technical/managerial problems. However, the experience and exposure of the managers of highgrowth firms (for example Tanzania Breweries Ltd) are shown to be a dynamic source of innovation, high productivity and competitiveness (ESRF-PSRC, 1996). The Tanzanian manufacturing sector is characterized by a critical shortage of technical skills necessary to enhance firms’ innovativeness. As a result, some of the high-growth firms have resorted to hiring foreign experts. Besides foreign technical experts, some firms engage foreign consultants. The Semboja et al. (1997b) survey data showed that 22 per cent of the firms engage foreign consultants while 78 per cent do not. Those that engage foreign consultants seek expert advice in the technical and managerial fields. 4.2
Research and development efforts
Several empirical studies on innovation suggest that ‘effective coordination’ of R&D is required to enhance firms’ innovations (Souder and Chakrabarti, 1980). R&D initiatives include efforts to improve existing products, develop new products, develop new production processes/ methods or equipment and improve product quality. Tanzanian experience in terms of R&D activities is gloomy. While the institutional framework for R&D has been established, little has been achieved in the productive firms in terms of significant innovation. This problem has been exacerbated by
162 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
lack of finance to carry out scientific activities, and failures in the commercialization of R&D initiatives. The basic infrastructure for R&D is underdeveloped, and links between productivity/innovation centres and the users are weak (see also Chapter 7). The government role in this aspect is not very effective, given the modest expenditure allocations for such institutions/centres. In addition, firms have a tendency to invest in short-term profit-intensive plans, and shy away from long-term investment in innovativeness and R&D activities. Further analysis of the R&D efforts reveals a critical shortage of research and technological personnel, not only in the technological centres but also in the firms themselves. The impact of this shortage is aggravated by three other factors. First, there is an unfavourable ratio between the number of engineers and the number of technicians who are supposed to support and complement the work of those engineers. Most of the engineers have been offered administrative tasks in many technology institutions and have not been preoccupied with innovation activities. Second, there is a shortage of research inputs and facilities with which R&D activities can be done. Most of the funds allocated to research are used to pay staff salaries (which are themselves low), leaving little for basic inputs and facilities for research. Third, there is a weak link between innovative activities and production. One explanation of the weak link between R&D and production has centred around the problems of relevance of the R&D activities for problems facing production activities in the country (Mlawa and Sheya, 1990). The other side of the coin is the fragility of the productive sector and its limited financial capacity to engage in new investments, reinforced by the unfavourable economic environment in which enterprises have been operating. In general, however, there are but few industrial firms that engaged in R&D activities. The RPED (1994) survey categorized the number of firms engaged in R&D according to the size of firms: 3 per cent of smallscale firms, 12 per cent of medium-scale firms and 16 per cent of largescale firms engaged in R&D. Most scientists, engineers and technicians are found in the large firms (food industry). Of professionals employed by the firms, engineers are the most frequently engaged in R&D activities (RPED, 1994). 4.3
Competitive market turbulence and customer base
Successful implementation of technical change influences innovation and the productivity of a firm. The question is whether high levels of competition stimulate enterprises to innovate products more regularly in order to remain competitive. Experience with Tanzanian manufacturing enterprises shows mixed results on this, with some firms responding defensively and others offensively. Both strategies are innovative ways of surviving the intense competition. For instance, the garment firms (most hit by the
Innovativeness and Productivity 163
import competition) showed a defensive response where firms shifted from production activities to trading activities. Of course, such a shift does not really refer to innovation in the more strict sense of technological change. In a small- and medium-enterprise context, customers may play a profound role in influencing product design and development. This is more evident in the garment industry survey, and partly in the light engineering firms in the sample, where customer choice influenced the trend and intensity of product innovation. In most cases, customers (both foreign and local) were an important source of product design and innovation (Semboja and Kweka, forthcoming). Rothwell (1977) has argued that an effective marketing policy is essential for successful innovation. The choice by firms to expand their product supply to other markets or develop competitive products for emerging markets will effectively enhance innovations. This depends on whether or not firms are ready to take risks inherent in moving from traditional to new markets. However, Wangwe (1995) indicated that most of the exporting firms started by serving the domestic market. The strategy of exporting came later in response to developments in their domestic markets. The capabilities gained by serving the domestic market and developing competitive products helped them to be innovative and embark on the export market. The current ‘opening up’ market policies have to an extent contributed to a search for new markets and thus to firms’ innovativeness, in some cases a firm had only one major local customer, which collapsed. The response of the supplier firm was to turn to the export market (Wangwe, 1995).10 Nevertheless, various studies11 have indicated that the share of the export market in sales is usually small, around 5–15 per cent. 4.4
Financial capabilities
Maintaining an active product innovation process requires two basic things with regard to finances. First, the finances should be adequate to cater for such expenditures. Second, a careful monitoring of budgetary and cost control processes is required, so that financial resources are used effectively. Thus, an active product innovation process requires a constant flow of funds. Availability, adequacy and sources of funds of the firms were examined in most of the ESRF industrial studies, including assessments of the role of financial institutions in financing industrial investment. Enterprises’ own savings and bank loans are the major sources of funds. In all cases, funds are highly inadequate because of poor turnover and shrinking markets. In recent years, bank loans have become difficult to access, due to high interest rates and lack of development finance for the improvement of firms’ technological and innovative capabilities. In Tanzania firms differ much in their abilities and culture with regard to financing innovation. Firm size and financial strength are important variables in this respect. Lack of adequate financial resources has negatively
164 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
affected the extent of technological upgrading in firms. Firms in the engineering subsector, for instance, show that while there has been some upgrading of production technology following liberalisation, such upgrading has been rather limited in most other sub-sectors, and has mostly been confined to small groups of firms. At the national level the problem of underfunding of innovation and science and technology (S&T) activities has apparently been recognized. In 1984 it was proposed that S&T expenditure in GDP be raised from below 0.5 per cent in 1984 to 1.5 per cent in 1985/86, and further to over 3 per cent by the year 2000 (United Republic of Tanzania, 1985a). At present there is no sufficient evidence to show that this share has indeed changed significantly from that of 1984 (for example, Wangwe, 1994). This suggests the need for initiatives to mobilize non-government sources of finance to fund urgent S&T activities in the country.
4.5
Institutional framework
The institutional framework for S&T development is largely structured along sectoral lines, under the overall coordination of the Commission for Science and Technology. 12 R&D activities in Tanzania are mainly carried out by public institutions and are mostly agriculture oriented. Links between industrial R&D institutions and enterprises are weak, as indicated by the failure to commercialise many R&D results and the failure to tackle the major technological problems facing productive activities in the economy (Mlawa and Sheya, 1990, Chapter 7 in this volume). For productive sectors to carry out significant innovation, government support and commitment towards technological advances are crucial. In addition, institutional restructuring and reforms in the economy have also impacted on the innovation institutions. Some of the government-owned R&D institutions have been divested, and most of the others made to operate independently (or commercially) with little or no reliance on government support. As a result, the innovative efforts of these institutions have been severely hampered. In addition, the generally acknowledged weak link between the innovation centres (suppliers/supporters of innovation) and firms (users and developers of innovation) has been eroded even more by the weak interaction between the private and public sector institutions in Tanzania. Governments may support technological advance by providing incentives and support for companies to upgrade their technology. The ‘wait and take’ attitude towards technology acquisitions is common among enterprises in sub-Saharan African countries; many companies passively receive technology from foreign suppliers without controlling or trying to affect technology choice. The industrial/business supporting institutions are mainly state-owned. The links among and between these institutions and
Innovativeness and Productivity 165
between them and the final consumers (that is, the firms) are weak and rudimentary. 4.6
Access to technical information
One important aspect of promoting innovative activities is the access to technical information. As Semboja et al. (1997b) noted, the sources of technological information can be divided into following categories: information from other firms, educational/academic sources (bulletins, journals, books and scientific institutions/research and development centres) and finally information from the company’s own technological initiatives or R&D activities. The Semboja et al. (1997b) survey showed that other firms are important sources of technological information, via inter-firm linkages. This source is even more significant in special types of industrial organisation such as clusters, through collective efficiency and agglomeration economies (Musonda and Kweka, 1998). It is thus argued that relationships and cooperation between firms through some conventional linkage arrangements facilitate the flow of technological information, the net effect of which is an increase in innovative capability. Most firms obtained their information from two important sources, namely: copying from domestically made products (by other firms), and through local and foreign buyers/customers (Semboja et al., 1997b). Further details on the firms’ responses to the sources of information show that domestic and foreign consultants were important sources of technological information. In the specific case of product innovation, the sources of product technology are also important sources of technical information. There are various sources of product technology such as: copying domestically made products, copying imported products, foreign buyers, local buyers, own R&D, and foreign partners. The pattern of use of these sources has been changing over time. In the initial years after their establishment, metal and light engineering firms copied their product and process engineering technologies from foreign buyers (since most of the products were exported). After the adoption of economic reforms (for instance in 1990), product technology was acquired by copying from imports. Recently, most firms have diversified their sources of product technology. In general, all three sub-sectors covered under the ESRF-MCCPED (Semboja et al., 1997b) sample have shown that the major source of their product technology, particularly prior to trade liberalisation, consisted of copying from domestically made products. Inward-looking industrialization strategies coupled with restrictive trade policies discouraged linkages with foreign firms, and meant that local manufacturers had to link amongst themselves. After the reforms, firms had opened up to learning from foreign firms – hence copying from imported products became a significant source of product innovation. The percentage of firms with
166 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
domestic products as a source of their product technology declined from 31.3 per cent in the 1980s to 27.0 per cent in the early 1990s. The percentage of firms using imports as a source of product technology increased from 12.5 per cent in 1980s to 16.3 per cent in 1990s. 4.7
Legal and regulatory framework
There are few explicit laws governing and/or facilitating the development of innovative activities in Tanzania. As a product of the colonial legacy, most of these laws are outmoded. Existing laws are implicit in this regard, often regulating other socioeconomic and business activities or sectors, such as investment, international transactions, human resource development (education and training), labour market, industrial development and trade. Patents, trade marks and various licences used in technological innovations depend on the existing policy, the patents law and the possession of industrial licences. The patent system is often used as one method for rewarding innovators.13 In Tanzania, the patent law was formulated in 1930 (cap. 217 of Tanganyika laws). The law does not provide much incentive to local experts to develop innovative industrial ideas. For a long time, the Tanzania patent system was pegged to the UK system. This system was really meant to allow foreign companies to have access to the Tanzanian market rather than to cater to domestic innovators and investors. In fact, the analysis of patents issued has shown that the patents were largely granted to multinational companies which were mainly importing the products into the country while actual manufacturing was located in other countries. A new patent law endorsed by the parliament (Act no. 1 of 1987) was expected to give a challenge and much needed motivation to scientists and technologists in their efforts to develop industrial innovations. However, the law is not effective because of a lack of basic tools and scarcity of experts to implement the patent tasks (Sustainable Industrial Development Policy, 1996–2020; Ministry of Industry and Trade, 1996). Since the patent system started operating in Tanzania no more than six patents have been established in Tanzania under this act of parliament. The registration office only serves as a re-registration office for patents registered in London (Mlawa and Sheya, 1990), and still lacks the necessary facilities to search for patent information online. Therefore, the regulatory framework has not been effective in enhancing innovative efforts in Tanzania. An inefficient fiscal regime characterised by high tax rates and a multitude of taxes has implicitly deterred innovative efforts. According to the sustainable industrial development policy, 1996–2020 (Ministry of Industry and Trade, 1996; see Chapter 17 in this volume), the government will review the relevant regulations relating to industrial investment and business company management to take care of all the flaws that inhibit the process of industrial development.
Innovativeness and Productivity 167
4.8
The role of the government
Though economic reforms meant a significant retreat by the government from intervening in the economy and production, there are still important tasks for the government in enhancing innovation. The role of the government is to provide the conducive environment and initial conditions for the productive sector (firms) to carry out meaningful innovative activities. Such conditions are reflected in the government budget, the incentive structure, the provision of infrastructure, training, and human and nonhuman resources for the development of innovative capabilities of the firms. The other area for government intervention is the provision of an environment in which flexible adjustment of production structures in the face of changing demand conditions is made possible. The provision of efficient infrastructure in the form of functioning water and electricity supplies and efficient telecommunications and transportation facilities would reduce firms’ operating costs significantly. The government should also facilitate access to information about, and the acquisition of, technologies by domestic firms. It should promote contacts between domestic firms and foreign technology suppliers. Support in these efforts might significantly reduce search costs.
5
Conclusions and policy recommendations
As documented by the surveys discussed, innovative efforts and achievements in Tanzanian manufacturing are marginal. Most firms have not been able to carry out significant innovations related to R&D efforts. Where innovative efforts have taken place, they have taken the form of technological upgrading, introduction of new products, adaptations of the transferred technology to suit local conditions, gaining mastery over the process and making minor improvements. Such efforts have not translated into viable technological progress because of the lack of an institutional framework that would enhance the links between innovations and improvement of market performance at firm level. It is worth noting that innovative capabilities differ widely between firms of different size and ownership structure, on the one hand, and between various subsectors on the other. Large firms have achieved significant innovative efforts unlike the smaller ones. The light engineering subsector is shown to be more dynamic in terms of innovative efforts compared to other sectors such as garments and textiles. Various factors were identified as important in determining innovativeness at firm level. These include: human resource development, R&D efforts, financial capabilities, competitive market turbulence and customer
168 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
base, institutional framework and linkages, access to technological information, the legal and regulatory framework and the role of the government. Apparently, while innovativeness at firm level is crucial in enhancing productivity, the development of viable innovative activities depends much on the ability of the firm to carry out significant technological, organisational and human resource investment. It is thus recommended that appropriate institutional frameworks are sought for the mobilisation of various stakeholders (firms, government and related institutions) for the support of innovation efforts at firm and national levels. The major policy implication lies in the need to strengthen and promote sustainable industrial linkages among all units (institutions, and production and market systems) within the Tanzanian manufacturing sector. However, successful innovative performance also depends on the ability and commitment of the government to address the constraints related to these factors, and to create a technologically enabling environment for the innovativeness and competitiveness of the Tanzanian manufacturing sector.
Notes * Economic and Social Research Foundation (ESRF), Dar es Salaam. 1. There are no comprehensive studies on innovation in Tanzania. The few existing studies are based on micro-firm-level data and/or are founded on a sound theoretical framework (for example, innovative activity matrix). Recent industrial case- and macro-based studies show that both private firms and public innovation supporting institutions operate within an unfavourable economic environment (Wangwe, 1986; Watanabe, 1987; RPED, 1994). However, there are significant adaptive and incremental innovative activities conducted in some medium- and large-sized manufacturing firms. Direct foreign investment, expatriates and imported technology remain the major sources of acquisition of technology and industrial performance. 2. The article draws some insights from theoretical and empirical works on this subject and utilises data and information on various manufacturing sector surveys done by the ESRF and other institutions. The surveys of the manufacturing sector include the following: • the ESRF-PSRC (1996) study of the impact of divestiture on industrial performance (six case studies on Tanzania Breweries Ltd, ABB Tanelec, Morogoro Textile Mills, Moshi Tanneries Ltd, Tanzanian Parkers Limited, G&T Company) • the UNU-INTECH QEH-ESRF (1996) study (also referred to as Semboja and Kweka, forthcoming) on the impact of import liberalisation on the manufacturing sector, based on a survey of 47 light engineering firms and 17 garment firms • the ESRF Multi-Country Comparative Study on Private Enterprise Development, also referred to as the Semboja et al. (1997b). This study presents results of a survey of 74 firms from three sub-sectors, food, construction, and metal and light engineering, held in 1997.
Innovativeness and Productivity 169 • Regional Program on Enterprise Development (RPED, 1994); Development and Growth of Industrial Enterprise in Tanzania, focusing on textiles, wood products, food products and metal products. • RPED (1995), Dynamics of Enterprise Development in Tanzania, Final Report on Round II Survey Data, Helsinki School of Economics. 3. Cited in Romano (1990). 4. Research and Development (R & D) is defined here as any creative and systematic activity undertaken to increase the stock of knowledge, and use of this knowledge to device new applications. It includes fundamental research, applied research and experimental development work leading to new devices, products or processes. 5. See the studies listed in footnote 2. 6. The combination of the basic technology and the latest global technology from ABB National Transformers ensures the high quality of ABB Tanelec distribution transformers. ABB National Transformers has a long history in producing highquality switch gears. The combination of this with local expertise has resulted in high-quality medium- and low-voltage switch gears utilizing the latest technology. 7. This is the MCCPED study (Semboja et al., 1997b). 8. Innovative efforts at firm level are linked with training, because it is through training that technological information can be transferred. Thus, there is a need to improve training linkages to enhance innovative efforts. 9. Training requirements and availability of training programmes (in-house and external) were reflected in most of the surveys on the manufacturing sector. 10. Morogoro Canvas Mill was one of the cases in point. It had one customer, the Morogoro Shoe Company. The collapse of this company meant the loss of the entire market for the firm. The Canvas Mill adjusted swiftly by changing its product mix and entering the export market. The firm achieved this strategy by making the necessary investments in technology and innovation to meet the requirements of the export market. In addition, the firm employed foreign management consultants to manage the production. As a result the firm managed to raise its share of exports to output from less than 10 per cent to over 60 per cent in 1995. 11. Among others, Wangwe (1995), RPED (1995), Semboja et al. (1997b). 12. During much of the 1960s and 1970s the only R&D institutions in the country were the agricultural research stations. These focused on research on export crops such as cotton, coffee, tobacco and tea. Further developments in science and technology institutions came in the 1970s with the establishment of the Faculty of Engineering at the University of Dar es Salaam in 1973, and the creation in the late 1970s and early 1980s of R&D institutions such as the Tanzania Industrial Research and Development Organisation (TIRDO), the Tanzania Engineering and Manufacturing Design Organisation (TEMDO), the Institute for Production Innovation (IPI), the Centre for Agricultural and Rural Mechanization and Appropriate Technology (CARMATEC) and the Tanzania Bureau of Standards (TBS). In addition to the formally constituted R&D institutions there are some R&D activities that take place in institutions whose main function is not R&D but production or education. In this category one finds enterprises which have workshops or design activities as secondary activities complementing the principal production activities. In addition, universities and
170 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania other institutions of higher learning undertake R&D activities, besides their principal teaching function. 13. Innovative efforts may be rewarded with promotion, recognition and productivity bonuses. For example, rewards for innovative efforts are similar to and sometimes substitute those for productivity, that is, normally in the form of salary increments, with promotion coming only occasionally. Two companies in the garment sample report using an incentive bonus system to achieve higher levels of productivity. The management sets an output target for every section/department and for the entire firm. Any production above the target level is rewarded by a bonus system on a percentage basis. The second bonus system rewards the department that achieves the best results at the end of each year. A third is the general bonus, which is awarded to all the workers depending on the general performance of the firm.
7 Development and Diffusion of Technology: The Case of TIRDO Bartelt Bongenaar and Adam Szirmai*
1
Introduction
In the context of late industrialization the effective transfer and adaptation of technology is of great importance for economic development. International technology transfer is not a costless process, but requires considerable technological effort and investments in the development of technological capabilities (Lall, 1999). Ever since the Arusha declaration in 1967, the Tanzanian government considered a weak technological research and development base as one of the reasons for slow growth of the manufacturing sector (Kahama, 1982). To tackle this problem an aim of government policy was to set up centres of excellence in research and development. One of these institutes was the Tanzanian Industrial Research and Development Organization (TIRDO), which started operations in 1979. The basic functions of this organization are to carry out applied research, to provide technical services to industry and to manage a system of documentation and information designed to enhance industrial production. An important task of TIRDO is to adapt technology to local circumstances and to transfer it to domestic industrial firms. The technology projects of the institute make use of domestic resources and try to substitute for imported products. The aim of this article is to take TIRDO as a case study of technology development and technology diffusion in the context of an African developing economy. On the basis of an in-depth analysis of a large number of technology projects, the article tries to identify the factors contributing to or hampering the successful development and diffusion of technologies in the context of a developing economy.1
2
The Tanzanian R&D sector
The policies of the government research institutes are linked to wider government socioeconomic policies and policy goals (see Chapter 1). The 171
172 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
first national science and technology policy for Tanzania was formulated in 1985. The STP policy was derived from the general long-term Basic Industrial Strategy. The shift towards a more open and market-oriented economy since 1986 and the passing of the national investment act in 1990 necessitated the formulation of a new science and technology policy. Although a draft version of such a plan has been drawn up, a final version still awaits publication at the time of writing this article. R&D in Tanzania is mainly conducted within government organizations. R&D in firms is almost non-existent. The government of Tanzania is also the most important provider of funds to the R&D sector. Government spending on R&D is modest, varying between 0.99 and 1.34 per cent of total government expenditures (Mlawa and Sheya, 1990, table 3.4). Some institutes succeed in getting some form of external support from international donors or generate funds by offering consultancy, training and technical services to enterprises. Usually, the income thus generated is modest (Mlawa and Sheya, 1990, pp. 14–17).2 Eight institutes are primarily involved in industrial research, development and design. The organizations have similar or partly similar goals. Four of them have goals that overlap with those of TIRDO: the Tanzania Automotive Technology Centre (TACT), the Tanzanian Engineering and the Mechanical Design Organization (TEMDO), the Centre for Agricultural Mechanization and Rural Technology (CAMERTEC) and the Institute for Production Innovation (IPI).
The Tanzania Industrial Research and Development Organization (TIRDO) TIRDO was set up in 1979. With additional funding from the UNDP, the EEC and the World Bank laboratories and facilities were created between 1980 and 1990. The aim of TIRDO is to promote the manufacturing of industrial goods and to stimulate the use of local resources. Potential clients include small, medium-sized and large-scale enterprises. According to its statutes, TIRDO’s activities include: the training of technical personnel, development and adaptation of technologies, servicing domestic industries, monitoring technological developments, coordinating the execution of R&D and the promotion of new technologies. As a result of insufficient resources, and an overlap in goals with other organizations in Tanzania, TIRDO’s activities are more limited in practice. They focus on (TIRDO, 1993b, p. 2): consultancy studies for industry: the execution of feasibility studies for its own and other products to analyze economic viability of new products or processes • execution of technical (R&D) projects •
Development and Diffusion of Technology 173 • •
supplying specific technical information to industry technical services for industry.
In 1995 TIRDO employed 128 staff members of whom 26 were university graduates. Educational levels are represented in Table 7.1.
3
Theoretical background
The theoretical rationale for funding public research and development organizations is market failure. Given the semi-public nature and positive external effects of research and development, and the high degree of uncertainty involved in R&D, the volume of private investment will tend to be suboptimal. In the context of a low-income economy, this is compounded by imperfect information and lack of skilled personnel and financial resources in the private sector. This article examines whether a public research and development institute can fulfil its theoretically defined functions, through successful development and diffusion of appropriate technologies. In this section we present a simplified scheme of the technology development process to structure the empirical analysis of technology development projects in Section 4.3 The scheme involves two basic assumptions. The first is that a research and development institute in a low-income economy will not develop technology from scratch, but will use and adapt existing technology to fulfil technological needs: it innovates rather than invents,4 and it focuses more on specific techniques than on wider technologies.5 The second Table 7.1 Department
Educational levels of TIRDO staff in 1995a High High middle Low middle Low Unknown Total
Industrial technology department 11 Engineering department 7 Information department 2 DG/DRD/DAF officeb 3 Administration Accounts 1 Estates Dispensary Other 2
5 57
2
4 4 3 2 5 1 5 2
Total
19
29
26
2 3 2
6 3 3 23
1 2
9 2 1 51
3
26 23 8 10 32 6 14 6 128
Source: staff list, TIRDO (1/10/95). Note: a High: university; high/middle: higher vocational training; low/middle: form III and above; low: below form III or no education; DG: director general; DRD: directorate research and development; DAF: directorate administration and finance.
174 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
assumption, based on the charter of TIRDO, is that the target group of the research and development organization consists of domestic industrial enterprises. Figure 7.1
Phases in the technology development process
Identification ➛ Acquisition ➛ Adaptation ➛ Selection ➛ Technology ➛ Implementation and selection of of firms transfer of innovations of technology technology
Figure 7.1 presents the six main phases in a model of the technology development process, seen from the perspective of an R&D institute: identification and selection of technologies, acquisition of technology, adaptation, selection of firms, technology transfer to firms, and implementation of innovations. These steps have to be executed for each technology development project and will be analyzed separately. The phases are analytical rather than sequential. There are relationships of circular causation, from ‘later’ phases to ‘earlier phases’ (feedback) and from earlier to later phases, and activities in different phases can – and often should – be undertaken simultaneously. This article examines the innovation process from the perspective of the research institution. Thus, we examine the transfer of technology from the R&D institute to industrial organizations. It should be stressed that R&D is only one of the aspects of a more complex model of technological change and innovation developed by Kline and Rosenberg (Malecki, 1991, pp. 114–17). In that model the interactions between R&D, technology and markets are very important, as the market ultimately defines the technology needs and specifications, and is the customer for R&D outputs. Technological change only occurs if these different aspects are coordinated. The present analysis concentrates on the functioning of an R&D organization and tries to fill part of the black box of ‘research’ in the Kline and Rosenberg model of technological change. 3.1
Identification and selection of technology
The two main concepts in the identification and selection phase are assessment of needs and appropriateness. In order for a technology to be adopted by the R&D institute’s target group, there has to be a need for it. For a research and development institute the target group or market consists of domestic industrial firms and their needs. These needs, in turn, are based on the needs of the customers of the target group: consumers and other industries (Rogers, 1983, UNIDO, 1991, p. 167). Needs for a type of technology can be assessed through formal or informal needs assessment methods (Wissema and Euser, 1988, pp. 19–29).
Development and Diffusion of Technology 175
The second important criterion for technology assessment by an R&D Institute is the appropriateness of the technology. The chosen technology should be appropriate in terms of local market conditions, local resources, labour supply and quality of work force, environmental and geographic conditions, cultural features and national objectives and policies (Riedijk, 1987, p. viii; UNIDO, 1991, p. 167; van Egmond, 1995, p. 10). Two variables affecting appropriateness are technological distance and adaptability. Technological distance is defined as the technological sensitivity to differences in pertinent technological capabilities, and economic and physical circumstances. The greater the technological distance, the more difficult the transfer of technology becomes (van der Straaten et al., 1992; Westphal and Evenson, 1993, pp. 5–6; Caniëls, 1999). Adaptability refers to the question whether the research and development organization has the capabilities to engage in a given technology development process (Mourik et al., 1991). In the process of technology selection assessments have to be made by the management of the R&D institute concerning financial risks, technical risks and the availability of the necessary capabilities.
3.2
Acquisition of technology
Technology development as analyzed in this article involves the adaptation of already existing technologies. The technology will have to be acquired by the R&D organization on the international technology market, a market characterized by extreme imperfectness and a weak and dependent position of developing countries (van Egmond, 1993, p. 86).6 The R&D institute has to try to acquire the coveted technology in an imperfect market at the most favourable conditions. The direct and indirect costs of technology depend on the manner and the package in which it is transferred (United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, 1972, pp. 24–7). ESCAP (van Egmond, 1993, pp. 81–4) distinguishes five categories of technology flows: (1) free-flow of technology; (2) technology flows through the purchase of products; (3) sponsored flows, where third parties (for example, international agents, local governments) pay the costs of the technology transfer; (4) flows embedded in commercial contracts between parties, concerning the production of goods and services; and (5) flows through commercial technology acquisition contracts. The choice of flow mechanism depends on the unpacking possibilities of the technology and the unpacking capabilities of the organization. Unpacking involves the breaking down of a technology into its components and the separate purchase of every component, if possible from different suppliers (United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, 1978, pp. 11–13; van Egmond, 1995, p. 20). This strengthens the bargaining position of the R&D institute and increases the scope of choice between alternative technology flow channels.
176 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
3.3
Adaptation
The purpose of adaptation is to make a technology more appropriate to local conditions. The adaptation phase is an extremely important phase in the transfer of technology to developing economies (Dar, 1990, pp. 137ff.; van Straaten et al. 1992). Many innovations fail because of insufficient attention to differences in the socioeconomic and physical conditions in the originating and target environments. The basic goal of the adaptation process is to compensate for the differences between environmental conditions before and after the technology transfer. Therefore, the adaptation process depends on the characteristics of the environment of origin embodied in the design of the technology and the characteristics of the target environment for which the technology was designed. The differences between the circumstances in which the technology has functioned and those in which the technology has to function define the setting and need for adaptations. The adaptation of a technology not only requires the adaptation of knowledge to local factor conditions, but also the capability to modify and add products and processes to suit local preferences and requirements. Adaptation also involves measures to speed up absorption of a technology, by making it more appropriate for local use and specifying required methods for introduction (for example, training) (UNIDO, 1991, p. 177). In the adaptation phase the participating technical staff is the main input. But technical staff members cannot operate without non-technical capabilities within the team. Market knowledge, process control knowledge and knowledge of the social and economic implications of the technology also are essential for successful adaptation of technology (Mourik et al., 1991, pp. 111–112). Therefore, the characteristics of the adaptation team and its external partners are of considerable importance 3.4
Selection of firms
The interest of the R&D institute lies in successful transfers to firms of technologies developed at the institute. Therefore, it should select firms from the perspective of achieving the highest possible success rate in the transfer of the adapted technology. Pack (1987) emphasises that the successful functioning of a technology within a firm depends on the firm’s ability to incorporate the technology in its organization. The selection of firms should thus depend on the R&D institution’s assessments of the technological, organizational, information processing, managerial and educational capabilities necessary to incorporate a new technology into the organization (see also Laseur, 1989, 1991). The selection process also involves the process of getting firms interested in an innovation and persuading some of them to consider adopting it. In a model of innovation decisions, Rogers (1983, pp. 163–72) identifies two phases which determine the innovation decisions of firms: the knowledge
Development and Diffusion of Technology 177
phase and the persuasion phase. In the knowledge phase a decision making unit (DMU) is exposed to the existence of the innovation and gains some understanding of how it functions. In the persuasion phase the DMU develops a favourable or unfavourable attitude towards the innovation, based upon the information available to it. To influence these processes communication instruments can be used (Rogers 1983, p. 318; Wissema and Euser, 1988, pp. 75–80). These include informal communication with opinion leaders in innovation networks, the use of change agents, the use of financial and non-financial incentives, and approaching gatekeepers. 3.5
Technology and knowledge transfer
During the technology transfer phase the technology must be transferred to the selected firms, that have decided to adopt it. Two aspects are important in this phase: the knowledge gap and the organization of the knowledge transfer. The knowledge gap is determined by discrepancies between the knowledge required for the innovation, and the existing knowledge within the firm. A small knowledge gap simplifies the transfer process. The organization of the transfer refers to the instruments used: communication instruments, change agents and gatekeepers. 3.6
Implementation and diffusion
The knowledge and technology transferred have to be effectively diffused throughout the organization and built into a functional system. In the implementation phase special attention must be paid to problems arising during the implementation of the innovation and its diffusion to managers, engineers and production workers within the organization. In this phase the tacit knowledge necessary to make a technology function in a given environment has to have a chance to develop. The implementation of new technologies requires active support, both from within and outside the organization. During the implementation phase, further adaptation and reinvention may be necessary (Rogers, 1983, pp. 16–17). The organization structure and firm capabilities need to be aligned with the production system in which the technology functions (Laseur, 1989, p. 39; Westphal and Evenson, 1993).
4
The field research
Between 1979 and 1996, 25 technology development projects were executed by TIRDO (see Bongenaar, 1997, appendix C). Using the analytical framework discussed in Section 3, 12 of these projects were examined in this study. The unit of measurement is the project. On the basis of the analysis of projects, we draw conclusions concerning the unit of analysis, the research institute.
178 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
The first author of this article spent eight months doing fieldwork at TIRDO (from November 1995 until June 1996). Two projects – national dyes and caustic soda – were investigated in great detail. Research methods included repeated open interviews with project officers and document research. Another ten projects were examined with help of a standardised questionnaire completed by the project leaders, again supplemented by documentary research. (For more detailed discussion of the technical aspects of the projects, their output and the research findings, see Bongenaar, 1997.) With the exception of three projects (castor oil, satellite receivers and turkey oil), all projects were well documented. The 12 projects are briefly described in Section 4.1. In the subsequent sections, we discuss the different analytical phases of technology development, making use of the theories and concepts introduced in Section 3.
4.1
The projects
The twelve projects included in this study are: • Natural dyes project: an investigation into the possibilities for the use of natural dyes in Tanzanian industry. The project was executed between 1981 and 1990. The goals for the project were to conduct laboratory tests on procedures and techniques and give small-scale demonstrations on the extraction and use of these natural dyes. • Caustic soda project: a research project focusing on the possibilities of local production of caustic soda by Tanzanian industry. The project started in 1984 and ended in 1994, when the project was stopped after the creation of a pilot plant. Initially the project focused on the batch production of caustic soda. Later it focused on continuous production of caustic soda. The goals for the project were to identify the procedures for the production of caustic soda, to design an appropriate production plant, and to develop and demonstrate domestic commercial production using locally available resources. • Aluminium sulphate project: a project on the production of aluminium sulphate for the use in local water purification. The project started in 1988 and ended in 1993. It was shelved because of the lack of interest of the NUWA (the Tanzanian water company), the organization for which the investigation was started. The goals for the project were to identify and adapt processes for the production of aluminium sulphate, and to demonstrate the possibilities of using locally available resources. • Dehydrated castor oil project: investigation of the production of castor oil using local castor seeds, for the use in, for example, the textile industry. The project was stopped because of a lack of materials and interest from both entrepreneurs and TIRDO management. Goals for the project were to identify and adapt the process for the production of dehydrated castor oil.
Development and Diffusion of Technology 179 •
•
•
•
•
•
Activated carbon project: a research project into the production of activated carbon using local waste materials, used within the food and beverages industries. The project was executed between 1992 and 1994, until it was shelved because of a lack of results from the laboratory investigation. Goals for the project were to identify and adapt the process for production and demonstrate the quality of the local produced activated carbon. Pectin project: a project investigating the production of pectin using local waste materials for use by the food manufacturers in Tanzania. The project was executed between 1989 and 1992, and was stopped because of the insufficient quality of the pectin produced and the lack of funding. The goals for the project were to identify and adapt the process for the production of pectin and to demonstrate the quality of the pectin. Refractories project: investigation of the production of refractories using local materials. Refractories are widely used in all industries involving heating processes and heating facilities. The project was executed between 1988 and 1993, and was shelved because of the lack of outside funding. The goal for the project was to develop a process using specific available raw materials. School chalk project: a project on the production of chalk using Morogoro Ceramic Ware waste gypsum and precipitated calcium carbonate from the caustic soda pilot plant. The project started in 1990, and was still going on in 1996. Goals for the project are the identification and adaptation of a process for production, and the demonstration of its technical and financial viability. Wood adhesive project: Research into the production of wood adhesives using cashew nut shells. After initial research was finished, the project was extended with research into an effective, locally available and safe preservative against insects and fungal decay for wood products. Research was started in 1989, and was still continuing in 1996. Though there was national and international interest in the project, no diffusion took place to industry. Goals set for project are the identification and adaptation of a process for production using cashew nut shells, identification of locally and naturally available fungicides, and the demonstration of the technical and financial viability of the production of the wood adhesives and fungicides. Solar thermal systems project: research project of thermal energy for drying (as main purpose). Within the project, the investigators try to combine specific needs of users with specific solar systems available. The project started in 1991, and was still not officially ended in 1996, though no further activities were being undertaken because of a lack of funding and lack of commitment from entrepreneurs. Goals for the project were to design, produce and stimulate the use of local systems of thermal drying.
180 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
Satellite receiver project: project for the local design of a satellite receiver for televisions. The project was started as a follow-up to a satellite dish project. The project started in 1995, and was still going on in 1996. The goal was to produce simple receivers using the organization’s equipment. • Turkey red oil project: a project on the local production of turkey red oil using locally available castor seeds, used within the textile industry to dissolve dyes. The project was shelved because of a lack of funding and lack of interest from the target group. The goal for the project was to identify and adapt a process for the production of the oil. •
4.2
Technology identification and selection
Central to the process of the technology selection is the question ‘why’. What are the reasons for TIRDO to start with each of the projects and what is the justification for the project itself? To assess these questions, one also has to look at who took the initiative for a project, whether a needs assessment was made and who performed the investigation. For ten of the twelve projects examined, the initiative is taken by a member of the organization or one of its governing bodies. Industrial firms play only a marginal role in the process of project selection. Table 7.2 gives an overview of the reasons given for undertaking a project. The identification of a project is most frequently motivated by import-substitution considerations and the availability of indigenous raw materials. In four cases, pressure from the management of the institute to produce a ‘viable’ proposal is mentioned as a motivation. In three cases only is the initiative (partly) the result of contacts with (representatives of) industry. During the whole selection process entrepreneurs are hardly involved. At best, entrepreneurs are contacted by the investigator for technical information concerning the use of certain goods, materials and techniques within its production processes, both in terms of quality and quantity. This lack of involvement of productive enterprises is characteristic of all activities of TIRDO in the development of new technologies. Table 7.2
Motives for initiating projects
Motive National shortages Substitution of imports Availability of raw materials Contacts with industry Follow-up research Pressure to develop proposal Note: n = 12.
Times mentioned 2 9 10 3 3 4
Development and Diffusion of Technology 181
The project proposals are normally written by the principal researchers. They are responsible for the definition of the proposal, and they evaluate the technology and project as well. The quality of the proposals differs considerably because of the lack of standards for the writing up of projects. In some cases the principal researcher involves other members of the organization, such as members of the information department, but this is not the rule. All proposals give a short description of the technology involved, and occasionally discuss alternative technologies. The adaptability of the technologies by TIRDO – is TIRDO able to conduct the research? – is normally investigated. Taking into consideration the complexity and the type of technology and the capabilities of the organization, the time, equipment and funding needed to master and adapt the technology are estimated. Normally a distinction is made between laboratory investigations and pilot investigations. All proposals specify the tasks to be executed within the project. Normally only technical tasks concerning development, production and testing are included. With regard to the appropriateness of the project, two aspects are important: the technology’s desirability for solving certain problems, and its suitability to certain aspects of the environment. These aspects are hardly investigated by TIRDO. Using some characteristics of the technology, the expected effects are estimated by the principal researcher. It is rare for an economist, an entrepreneur or a social group from outside TIRDO to be involved in the investigation of appropriateness. Normally, only positive effects are mentioned; negative effects are simply ignored. Aspects of government policies and economic criteria such as import substitution, foreign exchange earnings and tax earnings are regularly considered. For some projects, socio-economic aspects such as income distribution and job opportunities are mentioned in the evaluation. Financial implications, for example, the earning and investments for future entrepreneurs, are sometimes evaluated. If a pilot plant is within the scope of a project, a division is made within the proposal (in the older projects the pilot plant is specified as a separate project). Since TIRDO does not have the budget to develop technologies itself, budgets are specified in terms of donor contributions and TIRDO contributions (with TIRDO providing the staff for a project). After the approval of the projects by the council of TIRDO, the proposals are used to secure funding from donor agencies. The projects start on a full scale only after funds have been made available; laboratory research normally starts earlier. 4.3
Acquisition of technology
The technologies involved in the projects have some typical characteristics. The technologies are mostly old, always above five years of age, already
182 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
studied worldwide and never considered to be of an advanced nature. In two cases, the technology are even not innovative for Tanzania. In the case of the caustic soda project, some components of the technology are found in the domestic economy. But this is an exception. In all other cases, acquisition of foreign technology is the rule. Normally, the aim of the project is process innovation. The technologies are mostly embodied in knowledge: knowledge concerning the process involved, its relation with the available materials and the desired output. Information needed for the project focuses on the process description, and information on the control of the process. Equipment consists of relatively simple locally available or locally producible equipment. In the acquisition phase it is mainly technical staff that is involved. Depending on the project and the activities within the acquisition process, chemical or mechanical personnel or a combination of both participate. The involvement of non-technical staff occurs in half the cases, and is mostly limited to members of the information department. Table 7.3 summarizes the technology transfer mechanism used in the acquisition phase. Two important sources of knowledge are TIRDO’s information department and public libraries. Foreign and domestic R&D institutes are also regularly used for the acquisition of knowledge and information, through training and documentation. The involvement of foreign or local companies is relatively low. When it occurs it is of a noncommercial nature.7 Regarding the technology flow mechanism, free flow is by far the most important. Product-embodied flow associated with the purchase of products occurs for projects in a pilot plant stage. Commercial technology acquisition occurs twice. Usually, the organization does not bargain with technology suppliers concerning the conditions for technology transfer, except in the case of Table 7.3
Suppliers of technology and flow mechanisms for transfer
Technology suppliera Information department Libraries Foreign companies Local companies Foreign R&D institutes Local R&D institutes Other
Times used 9 6 1 2 3 2 1
Flow mechanismb Free flow Sponsored flow Flow accompanied with products Commercial flow
Relative importance (%)c 71 14 10 4
Notes: a n = 12. b Importance of each flow mechanism measured on scale 1–5. c Relative importance based on average scores per mechanism (average score/summed average scores).
Development and Diffusion of Technology 183
acquisition of equipment. Costs for the acquisition of the technology usually seem to be low. Twice, larger expenditures were made for the setting up of pilot plants. A relatively small part of total project costs for the organization is spent during acquisition. Costs identified include expenditures on travel, photocopying and in some cases equipment. In two cases, some indirect costs of an acquisition were indicated. Equipment, only acquired if funding is available, is mostly acquired locally. TIRDO tries to use or adapt local designs for its specific purposes. Only complex equipment, for example, measuring equipment, valves and motors, is purchased from foreign suppliers. The project team approaches several suppliers, and selects on the basis of both technical and price specifications provided by prospective suppliers. In conclusion it seems that the organization acquires technology effectively, using an unpacking strategy. The technologies are acquired from different sources and mostly through free-flow channels. The technologies involved are suitable for this approach: old, well studied and embodied in knowledge and information. The organization has the capabilities to unpack the technology. Costs in this phase are relatively low, compared to total project costs. Bargaining activities are applied in the acquisition of equipment.
4.4
Adaptation
The purpose of the adaptation phase is to make a technology appropriate for its target environment. TIRDO’s main aim in this phase is the adaptation of a technology to locally available raw materials. This has always been the main goal for projects executed by the chemical department. Aspects of the technological environment (available knowledge and equipment), the social environment (special social benefit groups) and the economic environment (financial implications) are sometimes mentioned as secondary goals of the adaptation process. The adaptive criteria tend to be related to physical characteristics of the technology, and reflect the capabilities and areas of interest of the project team. These interests are chiefly technical in nature. Most staff involved in the adaptation process come from within the organization. Besides the project team other departments are sometimes involved, especially during the pilot plant stage. The first part of the research, the laboratory investigation, is normally executed by the project team itself: 80 per cent of the staff involved are chemical and mechanical engineers. Within the organization non-technical involvement in the adaptive work is very low. In two-thirds of the cases, actors from the environment (companies and other institutes) are involved in the work. This contribution is normally limited to the testing of materials. Only R&D institutes cooperate in the execution of the work itself.
184 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
In our study the success of an adaptation is measured as the extent to which the output of the project meets the expectations of the staff involved. We distinguish technical and non-technical expectations. Table 7.4 presents the scores on these items for the different projects. Whether a project has been shelved, or whether its goals have been realised within the projected time and budget, is also indicated. As indicated in Table 7.4, the realised technical result often meets prior expectations. However, non-technical expectations are frequently not realised. Many researchers expect that there will be interest for the technology developed on the part of industrial enterprises and donors (industries are more interested in profitability, while donors are interested in the direct applicability). In practice, however, projects often have to be shelved because of lack of interest on the part of donors and industry. Other reasons for shelving projects are insufficient attention on the part of TIRDO’s management, and problems in purchasing raw materials. Insuperable technical problems hardly ever occur, except during pilot plant construction.8 Budget overruns hardly every occur, because of strict financial project control. Only for projects in a pilot plant phase have minor overruns been recorded. In half the cases the research (or part of the research) extended beyond the initially proposed period. Reasons given for this are researchers’ inability to focus sufficiently on a project, acute financial problems, and lack of results. Table 7.4
Success of the adaptation process
Project
Result met expectationsa
Shelved Budget overrun Time overrun
Technical Non-technical Activated carbon Aluminium sulphate Castor oil Caustic soda Natural dyes Pectin Refractories School chalk Solar systems Turkey red oil Wood adhesives Average
6 5 5 8 6 4 5 7 6 6 9 6.1
3 3 1 4 2 2 3 4 4 1 5 2.9
Yes Yes Yes No No Yes Yes No Yes Yes No
No No No Yes No No No Yes No No No
No No No Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes No No
Note: a Project results meeting technical and non-technical expectations both scaled from 1–10, n = 11. In the case of shelved projects, the question whether results met expectations referred to the partial results. See Appendix A, variable IV, for details of scale construction.
Development and Diffusion of Technology 185
In sum, TIRDO usually executes the adaptations from a narrow technical point of view. From this technical viewpoint, the participation of staff is sufficient, the selection of aspects for adaptations is in line with the staff’s capabilities and the results are good. However, as a result of this one-sided input of capabilities, the technologies are not sufficiently adapted in a broader sense. Financial, economic and social aspects are not included in this phase, and the technologies are not appropriate for domestic industry. 4.5 Selection of firms This section focuses on one of the activities most underrated by TIRDO’s management: the ‘selling’ of a technology to local industry. Within the R&D organization there is still a widespread belief that sooner or later adequate technologies should and will sell themselves. Only a few projects reach the phase where TIRDO searches for entrepreneurs interested in adopting the innovation. Most projects are shelved before this phase is reached. Only in five projects have diffusion activities actually taken place (natural dyes, caustic soda, school chalk, wood adhesives and solar systems projects). In three other projects (aluminium sulphate, pectin and refractories) some promotional activities have taken place during an initial stage of the project. We divide the selection activities into activities to interest entrepreneurs in an innovation and activities to persuade entrepreneurs to adopt the innovation. Table 7.5 summarizes the different methods used. To create interest in the projects, TIRDO uses a combination of general and selective communication instruments. Selective communication instruments are preferred by the organization. The target group of firms is based upon the expected use of certain goods within their current production processes.9 For two projects, Table 7.5
Interest creating activities and instruments for persuasion
(a) Methods for initial interest
(b) Methods for persuasion
Method
Method
Publication Radio & TV Trade fairs Workshops Direct communication through extension officer Direct mailing Other Note: n = 8.
Times used
Times used
2 2 3 3
Free consultancy Technology ownership Support in loan securing Financial stimuli Private guidance
2 1 2 1 2
5 3 2
Tailor-made (re)design Result insurance Pilot plant implementation
4 2 2
186 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
the school chalk and the wood adhesives projects, a market survey has been performed to analyze a target group for the innovation. Some activities are undertaken to persuade the enterprises to accept an innovation by reducing entrepreneurs’ uncertainties. The tailor-made design of production systems based upon the specific needs of the entrepreneurs is mentioned in four projects. One method, though not specifically mentioned, is subsidizing the use of a technology. The R&D organization does not try to recover the total development costs of a technology, only charging direct costs and (usually) some fixed fee for development costs. Besides the project team, the information department is involved in 60 per cent of the projects. In some cases, members of the information department participate in the work of the project team; in some other cases their involvement is on request and is limited to selectively approaching some entrepreneurs. The number of interested firms differs considerably across the projects. The number of instruments TIRDO uses to interest and persuade also differs from project to project, and a relation between the instruments used and number of firms expressing interest seems evident. As indicated, the total activities for technology diffusion are modest. The organization does not put enough effort into interesting and motivating entrepreneurs. So far, no firms have been persuaded to adopt an innovation. One may conclude that TIRDO’s execution of the selection phase is not very effective.
4.6
Transfer and implementation
In the survey study the transfer and implementation phases have not been formally included, as no project had progressed up to the stage that the innovation was actually being transferred to firms in the target group. For the two case studies investigated in more detail, natural dyes and caustic soda, some remarks regarding transfer and implementation were made by persons involved. These remarks focus on the plans the R&D organization had formulated for the transfer of the innovations. However, at the time of writing no transfer had actually been realised. For the natural dyes project, it is indicated by participants that TIRDO assumed that SIDO (the Small Industries Development Organization), the organization with which they cooperated in this project, would take the lead in the transfer and implementation phase. TIRDO would only be involved in the transfer of the technical aspects of the innovation to SIDO. It was also prepared to give support in the implementation of the pilot plant. SIDO was to serve as a medium for technology transfer and it was expected to have sufficient capabilities and experience in technology transfer processes. For TIRDO, the main focus within the knowledge transfer phase was on the design of equipment and plant. Production management was not included. Apart from the fact that SIDO was expected to have the
Development and Diffusion of Technology 187
required management expertise, TIRDO itself certainly did not possess the knowledge of how to run a plant. In the case of the caustic soda project there was also no transfer of the innovation. The staff did indicate what the implications of technology transfer would be. They described the equipment and knowledge prerequisites for transfer in general terms. (for example, ‘are expected to have “feeling for chemicals”’). There was interest on the part of firms, a pilot plant was in operation and one entrepreneur seemed to be willing to adopt the technology. However, the worsening economic climate and decreasing prospects of protection of domestic industry prevented the entrepreneur from following up his interest. A few remarks are in order concerning two instruments of importance for the diffusion of technology in the last three phases of technology development projects: the use of change agents and use of contacts within industrial networks. Change agents are normally not used in TIRDO projects. Only in one case, the school chalk project, could a kind of change agent could be identified: one member of the project team 10 focused on supporting all entrepreneurs with the different aspects of the innovation decision. Contacts with firms and individuals within a well-developed industrial network can contribute positively to the selection of a technology for development and the subsequent success in the diffusion of the innovation.11 The involvement of networks in TIRDO’s projects turns out to be low. Direct influence of domestic industry on project content and on activities of project teams is lacking. Though there are some contacts with industrial firms in most of the projects investigated, the scope of these contacts is limited. 4.7
General characteristics of the technology development process
As no transfer or implementation of technology has taken place during the period studied, it is not possible to measure the overall success of the projects in terms of the numbers of successful adoptions. In this section, we use the interest expressed by entrepreneurs in a project, and the stage the negotiations between TIRDO and entrepreneurs have reached, as proxy measures of success. Table 7.6 summarizes five important variables characterizing the four evaluated phases of the technology development process: assessment of existing needs (I) and appropriateness (II) in the technology identification and selection phase, care exercised in acquisition (III), success in adaptation (IV) and use of diffusion instruments in the firm selection phase (V). The table also presents a rough proxy variable for project success (VI) based on the interest in an innovation and the stage the negotiations concerning the innovation have reached. The variables are based on the survey returns. The scaling of the variables is briefly described in the Appendix and in more detail in Bongenaar (1997). The scaling procedures are rough and
Table 7.6
Main variables for the success of the technology development process in different phases
Project Aluminium sulphate Caustic soda Natural dyes Castor oil Activated carbon Pectin Refractories School chalk Wood adhesives Solar systems Satellite receivers Turkey red oil Averagea
Assessment of existing needs (I)
Appropriateness (II)
Acquisition (III)
Adaptation (IV)
3 2.5 2 1.5 3 2 3 2 3.5 4 1.5 7.5 3
6 6 5 1.5 5 6 4 7.5 7.5 7.5 5 4 5.4
8 6 7 5 7 6 5 7 8 7 8 6 6.7
4 4 6 3 5 3 4 6 7 5 – 4 4.5
Activities for diffusion (V) 1.5 10 1.5 – – 1.5 1 8.5 6 1.5 – – 3.9
Success of project (VI) 2 7 6 1 1 2 3 8 7 7 1 2 3.9
Note: a Calculated with respectively n = 12, n = 12, n = 12, n = 11, n = 8, n = 12. The variables are roughly scaled from a negative pole of 1 to a positive pole of 10.
Development and Diffusion of Technology 189
ready, and should not be given any precise mathematical interpretation. Nevertheless, they do provide useful summary indicators of activities in different phases of the technology development process. Only the acquisition phase has an average score of more than six. Two variables have very low scores: the assessment of existing needs (I) and the variable relating to the diffusion activities in the firm selection phase (V). This indicates that the main problems in project execution are concentrated within these two phases. Both phases refer to the interactions between the institute and its environment and indicate that this interaction does not taken place as often and as intensively as required.12 Inspection of the individual projects indicates that their scores in the different phases tend to be related. ‘Good’ projects tend to score higher on most variables. The school chalk, wood adhesives and solar systems are examples of such projects. The castor oil, activated carbon and refractories projects are examples of ‘bad’ projects. This suggests that the inter-phase relationships are also very important. Nevertheless, irrespective of the project, specific phases of the technology development process tend to have much lower scores than the other phases.
5
Conclusions
The research and development organization TIRDO is successful in technology development to the extent that members of the organization succeed in developing technologies that meet their expectations in a technical sense. However, a measure of success in the technical sphere has not resulted in any transfer of the technologies to industrial enterprises, as originally intended. One possible explanation for this phenomenon is the general lack of innovativeness of Tanzanian industrial enterprises, struggling to survive in a difficult environment. During the period studied, many parastatals were being privatized, industrial production was stagnating and there were serious financial constraints which hampered innovativeness (see Chapter 6). Small-scale enterprises in particular lacked the financial and human resources to innovate. The innovativeness of enterprises was not the focus of this investigation, though it is obviously a relevant factor. However, the research reported on in this article indicates that lack of success in technology diffusion is also caused by insufficient efforts to align TIRDO’s activities to the expectations and needs of domestic industrial organizations. To start with our positive findings, both the acquisition and the technical adaptation activities of TIRDO are fairly successful. The acquisition of technology is performed reasonably well. Technologies involved in the technology development processes are normally old, and processes are described in publicly accessible information. The technical staff members involved are well educated in the field of their technical specialization and the
190 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
information department of the organization is experienced in the search for information on the international market. The technologies acquired are unpackable and the acquisition teams have the capacity to unpack technologies. In the adaptation phase, in most of the projects the implemented adaptations functioned according to technical expectations of the organization. Many projects can be regarded as technologically successful. One could argue that the experience of successful acquisition and adaptation of technologies in TIRDO has contributed to the building up of technological capabilities within the institute. These technological capabilities are of potential value in future stages of industrial development. Nevertheless, a successful technology development path involves more aspects than those mentioned above. The selection of projects is usually not based on formal or informal assessment of the technological needs of domestic industry. It is seldom related to specific requests from industrial firms. Initiatives for the identification of technologies are invariably taken by members of the TIRDO staff. They are based on national indicators and policy documents, or on needs as perceived by members of the staff. An effective R&D institute should use industry’s needs for technology as a starting point in the development process. The organization should take measures to intensify communication with industry and its management should formulate procedures to translate the needs of industry into viable projects. Direct influence of entrepreneurs on the definition and selection of projects should be encouraged. The organization does little to evaluate the appropriateness of technology for the Tanzanian environment. TIRDO does not make much use of instruments to interest entrepreneurs or to persuade them to adopt an innovation. Few efforts are made to interest and persuade entrepreneurs and there is no consistent policy underlying these efforts. As a result, there is little interest on the part of entrepreneurs, and few entrepreneurs are persuaded to adopt new technologies. The lack of activities in this phase is partly due to the institution’s assumption that good technologies should sell themselves. TIRDO does not consider it necessary to improve the process of diffusion, since, in its opinion, the lack of diffusion is mainly a problem of the domestic entrepreneurs. On the basis of the analysis in this article, the organization should focus on intensifying diffusion activities both in terms of quantity and quality. Diffusion activities should not begin at a late stage after the technology has been adapted. They should start at very early stages of the technology development process. Needs assessment and the selection of firms should be seen as part and parcel of the diffusion process. Research and development institutes should regard the marketing of technologies as an essential element of the research and development effort. An effective R&D organization should step up its efforts to extend its industrial network (cf. Meeus and Oerlemans, 1993). Frequency and intensity of contacts with enterprises
Development and Diffusion of Technology 191
should be increased. Technologies should not be regarded as successful on their own merits, but should be judged to the extent they succeed in serving even a technologically conservative industry’s needs and expectations. Several of the issues and problems discussed in this article are of wider relevance for technology development in research and development institutes in developing economies. Though our limited data do not allow for strong inferences, our results are consistent with findings in the literature. The importance of industrial networks, needs assessments, appropriateness of technologies and marketing are mentioned in many studies as essential to the successful diffusion of innovations. Giving higher priorities to these aspects of technology development could lead to a more effective use of scarce resources invested in research and development.
Appendix Construction of the variables The variables I–V in Table 7.6 are composite variables. The score of each project is the average of the composite variable scores calculated from the questionnaires completed by the principle project researchers and a questionnaire completed by the first author, based upon his analysis of the project files. For more details see Bongenaar (1997), appendix B. I: Assessment of existing needs (scale 1–10) The composite variable score is the average of scores on three variables, each scaled from one to ten: • initiative taken by the organization versus initiative taken by industry (scale 1–10; 1: TIRDO – 10: industry) • initiative motivated by expressed needs of firms or motivated from within the organization (scale 1–10; 1: no needs assessment – TIRDO internal need assessment – government – 10: expressed needs) • degree of influence of target group in this phase (scale 1–10; 1: no influence; 10: maximal influence). II: Appropriateness (scale 1–10) The composite variable score is the sum of scores for two variables: • extensiveness of the investigation of appropriateness, measured in terms of the number of appropriateness criteria mentioned (scale 0–5; number of criteria mentioned divided by 4, maximum number mentioned 20) • indicated appropriateness of the technology, measured by average indicated appropriateness of the technology on a maximum number of 20 criteria of appropriateness (scale 1–5, after rescaling of average scores to a 1–5 range). III: Careful acquisition of technology (scale 1–10) The composite variable score is the sum of scores for two variables: • unpackability: the possibilities of unpacking a technology (scale 1–5; 1: difficult to unpack – 5: easy to unpack). The unpackability scale scores are the average of
192 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
•
the scores on the following three items: age of technology (1: young – 5 old), familiarity of technology (1: hardly studied – 5: widely studied) and accessibility (1: mainly private – 5 mainly public). unpacking capabilities: the capabilities of the project team to unpack a technology reflecting technical capabilities and non-technical capabilities (scale 0–5, after rescaling of scores to a 0–5 range).
IV: Degree of success in adaptation (scale 1–10) The composite variable score is the average of two variables: • project result fulfilled technical expectations (scale 1–10; 1: did not fulfil expectations – 10: completely fulfilled expectations); these scores are based upon the scores of 8 items, with a scale of 1–4, which are averaged and rescaled to a 1–10 range) • project result fulfilled non-technical expectations (scale 1–10: 1: did not fulfil expectations – 10: completely fulfilled expectations); the score of this variable is based upon 8 items with a scale of 1–4, averaged and rescaled to 1–10. V: Use of diffusion instruments (scale 1–10) The composite variable score is the sum of scores for two variables: • use of awareness-creating instruments in a project, to create awareness of the technology amongst members of its target group (initial interest) (scale 0–5, number of instruments used divided by maximum number of instruments, rescaled to 0–5) • use of persuasion instruments in a project, to persuade members of the target group to adopt a technology (scale 0–5, number of instruments used divided by maximum number of instruments, rescaled to 0–5). VI: Success of the project (scale 1–10) This variable reflects the judgement of the investigator concerning the degree of interest of firms in an innovation (1: no interest expressed by any firm – 10: adoption by at least one firm). The score is in turn based on • the number of firms showing some interest in an innovation • the stage of negotiations reached regarding an adoption decision.
Notes * Section of Technology and Development Studies and Eindhoven Centre for Innovation Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology. Bartelt Bongenaar is now working at IBM, The Netherlands. We thank Emilia van Egmond, Leon Oerlemans and Henny Romijn for valuable comments. 1. This article is based on the MSc thesis of B. Bongenaar, ‘Analyzing Technology Development’, Eindhoven, Technology and Development Studies, March 1997. This thesis was based on eight months of fieldwork at TIRDO. We thank TIRDO and its former director Dr G. Njau for the opportunity to execute this research project. We should like to note the impressive degree of openness on the part of the staff of TIRDO to outside examination of their projects. The aim of this paper is not to offer facile criticisms, but to contribute to better understanding of the factors which may contribute to or hamper the success of technology development.
Development and Diffusion of Technology 193 2. Income from services in the R&D sector is estimated at 15 per cent of total income, external assistance at 30 per cent of total income. 3. For a more extended discussion of the relevant theoretical framework see Bongenaar and Szirmai (1999). 4. Invention is the output and the process by which a new idea is discovered or created. An innovation is an idea or object perceived as new by a group (Rogers, 1983). 5. There is much refined discussion of concepts and definitions in the literature, which we will try to avoid in this article. Technique generally refers to the total of means and procedures for the production and marketing of an existing good. Technology is the wider frame of reference (knowledge, ways and means) within which techniques can be applied to a set of objectives (van Egmond, 1993, pp. 15–16). However, the difference between the two concepts is a matter of degree. In this paper we will use the term technology in a rather rough sense, referring both to specific techniques and the knowledge required to make these specific techniques work. Where the wider concept of technology is referred to, this will be clear from the context. 6. TIRDO projects do not involve the acquisition of domestic technologies. 7. No costs being charged for acquisition, or knowledge being provided without profit. 8. Both pilot projects had problems with the designs and the implementation of the designs. 9. For example, in the case of caustic soda, TIRDO expected the producers of soap to use the technology in their production process; wood adhesives were expected to be used by the producers of particle board. 10. A Dutch student temporarily involved in the project. 11. Better contacts with firms and clients will also have positive effects in the acquisition and adaptation phases. 12. This problem is not limited to TIRDO. It is also mentioned in the literature on the Tanzanian R&D sector in general (Sinda, 1991; Kisimbo, 1994; Mageni, 1994).
8 Technological Capabilities: A Core Element for National Development Opportunities? A Study of Technological Capabilities in the Dwelling Construction Sector for Lower-Income Households in Tanzania Emilia van Egmond-de Wilde de Ligny*
1
Introduction
Only two decades ago the search for factors determining national economic competitiveness led to the introduction of the concept ‘technological capability’. Like technology, technological capability is a complex concept comprising both the utilisation and development of technologies, either through indigenous efforts or through international technology transfers. The search for useful definitions and operational indicators has yielded an extensive body of literature. First, the theoretical views underlying the definition of the concept of technological capabilities are reviewed. Then the preliminary results of investigations regarding the technological capabilities in the dwelling construction sector for lower-income households in urban Tanzania are presented.
2 Emergence of new theoretical views on technological capabilities Research findings on international development differentials, the laggard position of developing countries and the production technologies they use have lately become more or less common knowledge. It is only in the last two decades, however, that the question of which factors determine the competitiveness of nations is seriously addressed. 194
Technological Capabilities 195
By the late 1970s neoclassical economic theories began to lose much of their appeal in the field of technology-related development studies. An important reason for this was that neoclassical economics failed to explain convincingly the role of technologies in production and the processes and causes of technology development (Stewart, 1978; Lall, 1982, 1985, 1987, 1990; Nelson and Winter, 1982). Authors such as Nelson, Winter and Rosenberg even went so far as to claim that, based on neoclassical theories, highly unrealistic and misleading assumptions were made about the processes of technology development (Fransman, 1984). The new views that emerged were largely based on the common denominators in the history of the industrialization of the European countries in the 19th century, Japan after World War II and South Korea in the last decades of the 20th century. The successful industrial development of these countries was attributed to a number of interconnected factors, of which the accumulation of skilled human resources in the form of craftsmen, engineers, scientists, technicians and managers was thought to be of primary importance. These indigenous capacities, it was argued, were used to adapt and improve imported technologies and know-how to suit local conditions, and to develop entirely new and more appropriate ways of problem solving. This specific competence was attributed to a central element existing in the countries concerned: technological capabilities. By the end of the seventies it became clear that countries with hardly any endogenous science and technology also suffered from less favourable social and economic conditions (Stewart, 1978; Sagasti, 1979). Following these ideas, the bottleneck in the formulation and implementation of national development policies to support and improve production is formed by the absence of capabilities, capabilities that should exist in a network of interrelated organisations, institutions and enterprises. The ideas that emerged thereafter were based on the assumption that the conditions under which technology utilisation and technology development take place, either through indigenous research and development efforts or through international technology transfer, play an extremely important role (Lall, 1987). Technological capabilities, it was found, include the abilities of nations, organisations and enterprises to: (1) expand production output, (2) meet the demand for local and/or new products, (3) switch to new production lines, (4) make new investments, (5) upgrade managerial organisational skills, (6) eliminate deficiencies in skills and know-how in the labour force, (7) facilitate access to information and documentation, (8) enhance technological advancements and (9) make use of and upgrade existing (small-scale) production. In other words, the competitiveness of a nation and its ability to follow the rapid pace of social, economic and technological development depend on the status of its technology and its ability to maintain and upgrade this technology.
196 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
Owing to a lack of technological capabilities, embedded in a strong technology infrastructure, a country may fail to use its scarce resources efficiently, resulting in high costs to enterprises and the national economy. Inefficiency of utilisation of the existing facilities, declining productivity over time, a high and continuing degree of dependence on imported inputs and technologies, and a lack of local technological infrastructure are all indicators of a lack of technological capabilities. Consequently, it was recommended that nations should dedicate their efforts to the development of a creative technology system in order to decrease the technology dependency and create a technological self-reliance situation (Stewart, 1978; Lall, 1982, 1985, 1987, 1990; Fransman, 1984; Rosenberg, 1986, 1990). International competitiveness in technology-based industries, relying on indigenous technological capabilities, appeared to have become the new measure of national economic performance.
3 3.1
Technological capabilities: a review of the literature Definition of technological capabilities
In most publications the definition of technological capabilities is restricted to mentioning a number of activities without indicating the particular nature of the capabilities. Fransman, Lall and Stewart, for example, refer to technological capabilities in terms of the potential to efficiently and effectively carry out processes of technology utilisation and technology development. These become evident in the efficiency and effectiveness of (1) the technology utilisation in the execution of production processes, (2) the search for available and alternative technologies, (3) the selection of most appropriate technologies, (4) the adaptation of technologies to suit specific production conditions, (5) the improvement of technologies (incremental developments) and (6) the execution of basic research and development for technologies, either in-house or through institutionalised facilities. In the literature no precise indication can be found regarding the particular nature of the capabilities that are needed for technology acquisition, selection, utilisation and development. The only definition indicating which specific components constitute the complex of technological capabilities is the one given by Bell et al. (1984). They refer to (1) the stock of disembodied technical knowledge and information, (2) the human embodied knowledge and experience and (3) the institutional resources as the components of industrial technological capacity. The role of technology learning in the technology development process features quite prominently in literature. Improved production performance through technology development is undoubtedly related to sufficient skills and experience of the labour force. The level of human resource development, however, is certainly not the only indicator of technological capabilities. Technology development in itself should be seen as a production
Technological Capabilities 197
process in which at least four elements play a role: (1) technology itself, or ‘technoware’, (2) people and their skills and knowledge, or ‘humanware’, (3) information of all sorts, or ‘infoware’, and (4) the ways and means by which production is organised, or ‘orgaware’ (ESCAP, 1989). 3.2
Levels of technological capabilities
Rosenberg (1986) argued that technological capabilities appear to be embedded in the complex network of the social system: in institutions and their structural and cultural characteristics. He failed, however, to make the various concepts fully operational. At the same time he pointed at the existence of a number of levels of technological capabilities in countries to generate technological innovations suitable to their needs, and made an attempt to indicate the existence of a direct relationship between technological capabilities and the performance of production systems. He also mentioned the extreme variability in the willingness and ease with which technologies are adopted and utilised, as well as maintained and improved. In other words, technological capabilities will be positively affected by a national setting with (1) a physical infrastructure to support the production system and (2) national policies dedicated to technology development in support of productive activities. In addition, various authors have tried to determine the levels of technological capabilities in international perspective by associating them with: • • • • • • • •
the nature of the so-called national economic development status (Weiss, 1990) international trade and trade policies (Dore, 1984) trade orientation (Ranis, 1984) restrictions on trade (Lall, 1985) international competitive pressure (Stewart, 1984; Porter, 1985, 1986, 1990) international technology transfers (Dore, 1984) international technology status (Lall, 1982; Katz, 1987) technology gaps (Freeman, 1982; Kaplinsky, 1984).
3.3
Technological capability building
Most authors agree that, by taking the importance of technological capability as a starting point, capability building is the most obvious route to development. Also here, human and institutional capabilities feature prominently. This is why technological capability building is often defined as the accumulation of human and institutional capabilities and is also equated with learning. In this sense it is considered to include the set of processes by which firms accumulate technical knowledge, know-how and experience
198 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
relevant to the planning, construction, operation, adaptation, improvement and replacement of production processes, with the ultimate objective to increase production output, both qualitatively and quantitatively (Maxwell, 1977). Bell et al. (1984) indicate that technological capability building should take place in the form of learning by doing, changing, learning from performance feedback, training, hiring of expertise and searching for better solutions. They state that ‘technological capability building enables a firm or economy to produce change in the technical characteristics of the industrial production systems or at least play an active role in that process of technical change’. They make a distinction between the forms of knowledge, expertise and organisation – ‘technological capacity’ – and the knowledge, skills and organisation required for a production process operation and maintenance of an existing production system – ‘production capacity’. Last but not least, Bell et al. emphasise that to build up a significant capacity for generating technological change, additional investments in knowledge and expertise will be required, along with different kinds of institutions and organisations. 3.4
Assessment of technological capabilities
To be able to streamline and enhance technological capability building in the desired direction, the current state of the art of technological capabilities should be known. Among others, authors such as Lall (1982, 1985, 1987), Nelson (Nelson and Winter, 1982; Nelson, 1990), Weiss (1990), Westphal (1990) and Romijn (1996, 1999) have attempted to measure technological capabilities. The complexity of the concept, including the multidimensional aspects incorporated in activities of utilisation and development of technology, requires a multidisciplinary approach, an approach that makes the assessment of technological capabilities a cumbersome but interesting exercise. All definitions found include a number of activities involved in the process of technology utilisation and technology development. In most cases only the output of these activities was measured. 3.5
Conclusion
There is consensus with respect to the fact that improved production performance and further social development can be attributed to the status of technological capabilities and technology utilisation in production processes. In spite of this, there is no consensus yet on an all-comprising and workable definition for the various concepts. Neither is there consensus with respect to a successful way to make them operational.
Technological Capabilities 199
4
New definition of technological capabilities
In our view, technological capabilities refer to the totality of national resources which can be committed to the production system and provide the necessary inputs for efficient and effective production. This stock of national resources should supply the country with the required means, skills, know-how and knowledge. The stock is not only necessary to select, master and adapt the technologies that are needed and most appropriate, but should also enable the country to develop and generate its own new technologies (self-reliant technology generation). This definition differs from the majority of definitions formulated by other authors. In our definition the human and institutional capabilities are considered to be incorporated in the capabilities to produce, select, maintain and develop technologies, and are represented in the complex of four components: 1. Technology stock. This is defined as the total range of technologies available in the technology subsystem. A distinction is made between product technologies and process technologies. Product technologies refer to the features of the components that constitute the products produced by the sector. Process technologies refer to the features of the production-process components used to transform the raw materials and intermediate products into the required and specified products in the sector. The status of the technology stock indicates the level of technology advancement. 2. Human resources stock. The status of the human resources stock is taken to indicate (a) the availability of human resources relevant for the sector, (b) educational backgrounds and (c) occupational status. 3. Natural resources stock. The status of the natural resources stock relevant for the sector is taken to indicate (a) the availability of exploited natural resources relevant for and applicable in the production processes in the sector, and (b) the capabilities to exploit these natural resources judiciously. 4. Technology infrastructure of institutionalised research and development, education and documentation facilities, technology and intermediate products producing and supplying enterprises and organisations that supply the financial resources to the production system to support productive activities. The status of the technology infrastructure gives information on the complex and the outcomes of interactions between the technology-utilising organisations and firms of the sector and the other technology-supporting and -promoting agents and groups. All this implies that technological capability building means the increase of the quantity and quality of these components. The creation and
200 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
accumulation of technological capabilities can be reached through many mechanisms. Next to local development and improvement of the existing capabilities is the acquisition of industrial production systems from abroad, the international transfer of technology. Also for the execution of these processes of transfer and dissemination, technological capabilities are needed in order to search, select and acquire the desired technologies on equitable terms and conditions.
5 5.1
Dwelling construction industry in Tanzania Economic importance of the construction industry
The construction industry has a crucial role to play in a country’s socialeconomic development. First of all the industry is unique in its potential to provide one of the basic human needs: shelter. In addition, backward and forward linkages with other production sectors make the industry an engine of growth for the economy of a country as a whole. The linkages, however, work both ways and the construction industry is vulnerable with respect to developments in other sectors. With the objective to provide insight into the performance of the Tanzanian construction industry and its present and potential contribution to national development, studies were carried out on the technological capabilities of the industry. The focus in these studies was on the dwelling construction for the lower-income households in urban areas. This was justified by the fact that 75 per cent of the construction activities in Tanzania take place in this sector of the construction industry (van Egmond, 1996). In the research at hand, the construction industry embraces the formal and informal enterprises, institutions and individuals that are involved in the process of constructing civil and/or building works. Since small-scale and informal-sector construction activities are excluded from official statistics, data were collected by means of a number of field studies.1 These data were then compared with those found in the literature. 5.2 Current social-economic performance of the Tanzanian construction industry and its (potential) contribution to national development From a historical perspective, the construction sector went through an impressive development considering its state of affairs in colonial times. Foreign dominance, however, is still strong particularly in the fields of building materials and equipment. Over time the social-economic situation in the country affected the performance of the industry. In the early 1980s the industry was at the point of collapse. This was not only caused by the grim overall economic situation, but also by the long-term lack of policy attention for the construction
Technological Capabilities 201
industry. If policies were formulated at all, such as those formulated after the Arusha declaration (1967), they were not based on any factual insight into the actual situation in the construction sector. At present, lack of confidence in future developments prevents contractors from investing in process and product developments. The lack of investment capacity prevents the further development of the indigenous construction industry. The economic indicators on the current performance of the construction industry show that the potential of the construction sector to contribute to national economic growth has not yet been fully exploited. There is no structural link between the growth of the national economy (GDP) and the share of the construction industry in this growth (see Tables 8.1–3). The construction industry shows an unstable trend, and this points to activities in the informal sector. Small-scale (private) construction units fulfil a large part of the demand for construction resulting from the overall economic growth. Over time the percentage of investment in buildings has been low (8 per cent to 15 per cent of gross fixed capital formation) compared to investments in equipment and works. However, when we take into consideration the estimated average annual gross output of the informal construction industry and add this to the official GFCF figures, then the share of buildings in total GFCF rises from 10 to 42 per cent (in 1990). This figure is more in line with the 40 to 70 per cent figures mentioned in the literature (Moavenzadeh, 1987). The sector’s official role in employment, at less than 1 per cent, is more than modest. The informal construction sector, however, accounts for 64 per cent of the informal sector employment in the country (see Table 8.4). This makes the sector’s contribution to employment and income generation important in a country that has to face high official unemployment rates and an unfavourable income situation for a large part of the population. To a large extent the sizeable role played by the informal construction sector has, so far, been neglected. Official statistics still exclude the productive activities of the informal sector. Since our investigations have shown that the informal construction sector, in terms of the size of its contribution to GDP, is more or less equal to that of the formal sector, this results in a distorted picture. Also, the contribution to GFC is considerable, as is the contribution to employment. All this indicates the existence of a potential that can be better exploited and expanded to benefit the social-economic development in the country (see Tables 8.1–4). Our investigations also indicate that the construction sector has to deal with a number of deficiencies, particularly regarding the informal sector activities. The production output is of a rather low quality and is even formally considered to be of semi-permanent and temporary nature, with a lifetime of, on average, five years. Any investment in construction realized in the current way can thus be seen as a form of capital destruction.
202
Table 8.1
Relation between GDP and construction 1983–93
Average annual GDP growth (%) Share of constr. in GDP (%) Growth in constr. GDP (%) Contribution of constr. to GDP growth (%)
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
–2.4 2.4 –41.0
3.4 2.8 20.2
2.6 2.5 –8.9 –0.1
3.3 2.8 17.3 0.6
5.1 4.0 49.2 –0.2
4.2 4.3 11.9 0.5
4.0 3.3 19.2 2.0
4.8 5.4 69.8 0.5
3.9 4.4 14.1 –0.6
1992 3.5 4.6 9.4 0.4
1993 3.7 4.0 –10.3 –0.4
Source: Bureau of Statistics. National accounts of Tanzania 1976–1993. 1994c, p. 9/10. The data in the table are based on constant 1976 prices. The contribution of construction to GDP growth has been calculated as ‘growth of construction (%) × share of construction sector in GDP’.
Technological Capabilities 203 Table 8.2
Total GFCF in Tanzania 1983–91 in million current TSh 1983 1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
GFCF Buildings 1 847 2 510 3 096 4 339 6 057 6 802 11 618 20 423 22 101 Works 1 687 2 203 2 762 4 665 13 020 28 089 20 492 48 039 56 871 Equipment 4 218 7 260 11 014 19 675 45 998 62 410 96 912 149 942 183 406 Source: Bureau of Statistics. Selected Statistical Series 1951–1991. 1994e, p. 35.
Our investigations of the dwelling construction units revealed that they face a number of internal problems that prevent them performing their tasks efficiently and effectively. These include (1) the lack of availability of equipment and tools; (2) lack of access to capital and loans, particularly for small-scale and informal contractors; (3) lack of training facilities; (4) lack of assistance in acquiring new jobs; (5) the lack of availability of building materials, and (6) the prevailing government regulations. Also, external factors cause a weak performance of the construction industry. In general the Tanzanian operating environment imposes many bottlenecks on contractors, such as the unfavourable economic situation, the high and ongoing increasing costs of building materials and equipment, and the lack of skills and knowledge among the labour force (see Maro, 1991; Mwaiselage, 1992; NCC, 1992a, 1992b, 1995). The existence of these bottlenecks contributes to the comparatively bad performance of local contractors, and the presence of foreign contractors as a consequence. The literature indicates that the linkages in the actor network of the construction industry are not strong. Moreover, the performance of the various actors in the network leaves much to be desired (Maro, 1991). The Tanzanian government has an important task in alleviating the bottlenecks and in creating an environment to further exploit the potentials of the construction industry to contribute to the social-economic development in the country. The Tanzanian government acknowledges this (NCC, 1995). The overall development objective for the sector was formulated ‘to develop an efficient and effective, self-sustaining construction industry that is capable of meeting the diverse needs for construction, rehabilitation and maintenance of all building and civil works’. Most policy objectives mentioned were never met. Many strategies were formulated in a vague way, and implementation of the strategies was therefore hardly possible. A good example is the policy objective ‘increasing the level of technology’. It is not indicated what this technology should be, which level would be most appropriate and how exactly the current level could best be increased. That most policy objectives were never met is also partly due to external factors, such as increasing costs of imported building materials and tools. A positive aspect is the growing
204
Table 8.3 1983–93
Share of different type of construction activities in GFCF/growth rate of construction activities and total GFCF,
Growth in total GFCF (%) Growth in GFCF buildings (%) Growth in GFCF other works (%) Share of buildings in GFCF (%) Share of other works in GFCF (%)
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
–33.2 –32.7 –17.0 19.9 18.3
45.7 17.2 14.1 16.0 14.3
22.6 3.2 6.5 12.7 10.9
3.0 10.1 27.6 14.4 14.4
29.4 13.1 98.3 9.7 22.0
2.3 19.4 1.3 11.3 21.8
5.1 21.4 –25.3 9.3 17.2
6.5 29.5 136.2 12.9 43.4.
32.0 49.7 32.1 14.5 22.2
11.0 3.33 9.1 16.9 27.2
5.4 16.6 12.3 13.7 30.0
Source: Bureau of Statistics. Selected Statistical Series 1951–1991. 1994e, p. 35; Statistical Abstract: 1993. 1995, p. 31. The data in the table are based on constant 1976 prices.
Table 8.4
The formal and informal construction industry in Tanzania Informal sector
No of peoples employed (× 1000)
160 000 (TIS 1991)
% of total Annual gross output
64 14 577 million TSh 1991
Annual value added
10 864 million TSh 1991
Formal sector 91 649 (LFS 1991) 22 113 (WB 1994) 36 14 416 mill TSh 1991 88 554 mill TSh 1994 4 324 mill TSh 1991 26 420 mill TSh 1994
Total 251 649 182 113 100 28 993 15 188
Sources: Statistical Abstract 1991, Labor Force Survey 1990/1991, National Informal Sector Survey 1991 (Planning Commission, MLYD, 1991), Survey of Construction, Trade & Transport, Dar es Salaam1994.
205
206 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
attention now paid in policy documents to the potential of the informal sector. It is clear that an improved performance of the construction industry in Tanzania requires a number of actions to be taken. Judicious stimulation, application and further development of the available technologies should be based on more detailed, thorough and comprehensive insights in the technological capabilities available in the sector. Better insight and knowledge of the potential resources available for exploitation in the country will contribute to a better operating construction industry.
6 Technological capabilities in the subsector of dwelling construction for lower income households in urban areas The four components of the complex of technological capabilities were investigated by executing a literature study, a sequence of field studies in the construction industry and interviews with local experts. 6.1
Status of the technology stock
The data collected regarding the product technologies in the construction industry reveal that the production output and the level of product technological quality do not meet the basic terms of reference (see Tanzanian Building Regulations, BRU 1974–95). The current dwelling-construction sector, for example, provides for only 20 per cent of the actual demand for dwellings. A majority of houses are built in the informal sector. The number of houses built by the public housing sector dwindled to practically zero (Kyessi, 1995). The quality of the production output of the dwelling construction subsector in Dar es Salaam only met the basic requirements in at most 75 per cent of cases. In most cases houses are still built with traditional construction systems (Fereira, 1995; van Egmond, 1998). The characteristics of the complex of the process technology components were used as technology indicators to get an insight in the actual status of the process technologies utilised in the construction industry. Not many detailed data on these technology indicators were readily available. As a preliminary proxy for the level of production process technologies that are utilised within the construction industry, use was made of data on the quantity and type of equipment that contracting organisations owned. Such data were available at the National Board of Architects and the Quantity Surveyors and Building Contractors (NBAQS and BC, 1992). Formal sector contractors in Tanzania need to be registered with this Board. One of the registration criteria is the minimum amount and type of equipment a contractor owns. See Table 8.5. The criteria mentioned in Table 8.5, combined with the number of contractors registered per class, were used to get a first indication
Table 8.5
Criteria for registration of building contractors: the equipment component
Equipment item
Class I
Class II
Class III
Class IV
Class V
Class VI
Class VII
– 1 1 – – – – – – –
– 1 – – – – – – – –
– – – – – – – – – –
– – – – – – – – – –
70
157
146
650
Tower crane Concrete mixers Block making mixers Steel bending machines (set) Water pumps Concrete dumpers Heavy duty motor vehicles Compactors Compressors Concrete vibrators
1 3 2 1 set 2 2 3 2 1 2
1 2 1 1 set 1 2 2 1 1 1
– 1 1 1 set 1 – 1 – – 1
Total number of contractors registered (1990)
45
20
56
Source: NBAQS&BC, 1993 Dar es Salaam, Tanzania.
207
208 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
of the level of technology available among contractors. Table 8.5 only lists the minimum amount of equipment available at a construction company. The actual technology level may show a positive deviation from this. Only 10 per cent of the contractors formally registered in 1990 met the equipment criteria for registration. Of these, a considerable number were foreign contractors using foreign equipment. It appears that Tanzanian contractors, formal as well as informal, generally keep little equipment themselves. This can also be concluded from the statistics on capital investments in the construction industry (NBS, various issues). The major reason is that Tanzania has to import the majority of equipment. Only the higherclass contractors are able to finance the purchase of foreign equipment. Moreover, contractors work in project-based organisations and deal with the uncertainty of continuity of project assignments. The risk of investing in equipment is considered too high. Informal contractors do not have the capital to buy equipment at all. From the foregoing, a first conclusion can be drawn: the technology level of contractors in Tanzania, using the equipment criteria set by the NBAQS and BC, appears to be comparatively low. When taking the relatively large number of foreign contractors within the highest three classes into consideration, the indigenous technology level is even lower. The field studies on the process technologies in the dwelling construction industry revealed that construction projects are generally carried out with hand tools. The construction projects, in all cases, are built with hired craftsmen from the informal sector. The amount of information and documents on site is negligible, and the project organisation takes place on an ad hoc basis. The inputs in the construction processes involve, in the majority, raw materials. These findings confirm the earlier conclusion with respect to the low indigenous technology level. 6.2 6.2.1
Status of human resources stock relevant for the sector2 Availability of human resources
The population of Tanzania (30 million) shows the characteristic structure of most of the developing countries. The majority of the labour force, 84 per cent, is working in the agricultural sector. Only 1 per cent of the total population is officially employed in the construction industry. Urban population growth (20.7 per cent between 1991 and 1995), which was partly caused by migration from rural areas, contributed to a high rate of unemployment. The failure to create sufficient jobs in the public and private sectors was, to some extent, neutralized by the creation of employment in the informal sector: 95 per cent of dwelling construction takes place in this sector. With 40 per cent of the population younger than 15 years, the population is relatively young. This not only means an additional burden for the
Technological Capabilities 209
majority of households, but also puts pressure on social services such as education. If the educational system could meet the future demand of the various production sectors, however, the large percentage of young people would also be an asset. 6.2.2
Educational backgrounds
A positive effect of the policy focus on primary education is that Tanzania experienced a major increase in its literacy rate: from 46 per cent in 1978 to 76 per cent in 1993 (UNESCO, 1995). Unfortunately the quality of primary education deteriorated because of a lack of qualified teachers, instruction materials and schools. Tanzania is among the two countries with the lowest secondary education enrolment in the world: 4.7 per cent in 1990 (World Bank, 1995c). In the period 1986–8, enrolment in tertiary education was only 0.3 per cent (UNESCO, various publications). Training of project managers and entrepreneurs in the sector of dwelling construction for lower-income households mainly takes place in the informal sector. Here people are either trained on the job (34 per cent) or in a kind of apprentice system (57 per cent) (MLYD, 1991). Only a small percentage (9 per cent) is formally trained: 2 per cent in government service, 3 per cent in private enterprises and 4 per cent in training institutes. Our investigations revealed that 91 per cent of the labour force need training in the field of technical skills. In the fields of commerce and finance, 6 per cent of the labour force indicated a training need and 3 per cent needed literacy training (Mwaiselage, 1992; van Egmond, 2000). It was remarkable that none of the contractors or foremen expressed a need for training in managerial skills, whilst the lack of these skills was found to be a major bottleneck. A possible reason for this is that the project management, progress control, quality control (if any), and selection of materials, equipment and labour are normally in the hands of the owner of the house. The training needs show that the performance of the sector depends strongly on the country’s educational system. Only with an appropriate education system can the local construction capacity improve, both quantitatively and qualitatively. 6.2.3
Occupational status
Most of the labour force (84 per cent) in the construction industry work as a craftsman or technician. In the informal sector this percentage is even higher. Some 16 per cent of the labour force in the construction industry are employed as a professional or project manager. With regard to the available research and development staff, no comprehensive data were available. The available research and development statistics show a limited number of researchers in Tanzania. The research and development institutes are almost entirely staffed by Tanzanian nationals.
210 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
Mlawa and Sheya (1990) investigated a selection of research and development institutes, and their findings showed that the number of people involved stayed relatively constant over time. Government institutes under direct responsibility of the various ministries predominantly carry out the research and development activities. Relevant for the construction industry are staff carrying out research under the Ministry of Works, Ministry of Science and Technology and Higher Education, and the Ministry of Land and Urban Development. In 1990 some 84 persons were employed as research and development staff in these institutes. This is only 14 per cent of the total research and development staff in the country (Mlawa, 1990). Most of the persons were employed by National Construction Council (20), Building Research Unit (17) and the Ardhi institute of the University of Dar es Salaam (17). These numbers have most probably decreased after the liberalisation policies were introduced. In view of the construction GDP as a percentage of total GDP, and the construction labour force as a percentage of the total labour force, the potential in terms of human resources in research and development institutes appears to be reasonable. It can, therefore, be expected that research and development human resources are an enhancing factor in the improvement of the construction performance in the country, provided, of course, that this potential is fully exploited and that the technology infrastructure is adequate.
6.3
Status of natural resources stock relevant to the sector
The indicators used for the assessment of natural resources for the construction industry are the available quality and quantity of the major inputs in a construction process. It should be noted that the importance of the stock of certain natural resources is derived from the need for building materials. This, in turn, is derived from the demand for building and construction for the other economic, social and infrastructure sectors of the economy. In this context, the importance of the stock of natural resources can be considered as a direct function of the performance in the sectors of the economy mentioned earlier. The following review of the natural resources stock is based on a literature study which was complemented by interviews with a number of local experts. The share of the value of building materials in gross construction output averages 60 per cent. By value, some 70 per cent of the principal building materials used are purchased from Tanzanian producers. Some 30 per cent are imported. The import content, however, of the locally produced materials is rather high. Some 57 per cent, for example, of the costs of the locally produced cement consists of imported components. With some 90 per cent, this is even more for metal products (Kisanga, 1990).
Technological Capabilities 211
The availability of land is of basic importance to the construction industry. Land use in Tanzania is rather modest, and this is related to a relatively low population density of 33 persons per square kilometre. Natural resources in Tanzania include a variety of metallic and nonmetallic minerals, such as phosphates, tin, iron ore, coal, diamonds, gold and natural gas, as well as water, agro-based resources and forestry resources. Natural resources particularly relevant to the construction industry include clay, with an estimated production of 2000 metric tons in 1992; gypsum with an estimated production of 35 000 metric tons in 1992; limestone, pozzolanic materials, vermiculites, lateritic soils and stones such as marbles, basalt and granites. Especially lime can be of great importance for the Tanzanian construction industry. The current production is, however, inadequate, and uses primitive technologies. Kimambo (1984) listed several problems faced by the Tanzanian mining industry in the early 1980s. These, among others, include a lack of financial resources, a lack of skilled high and middle management, a lack of transport facilities, a very small internal market and a long distance to the main world mineral markets. After a decline in the 1980s, mining GDP increased during the early 1990s. A survey among 43 local building-material producers by the National Construction Council (NCC, 1992a) revealed a shortage of local raw materials as the major constraint for their production. This confirms the present inability of the mining sector to supply local building-material producers with the necessary raw materials. Forests and woodlands constitute 47 per cent of the total land area. The government reserved one third of the total forest area for industrial production. Currently, the share of the construction industry in total wood use is only 2.2 per cent. The local wood industry is able to fulfil the demand for wood from the construction sector in a quantitative sense, but not in a qualitative sense. Since natural regeneration is slow and replanting rare, the area under forest decreases. Particularly around settlements, fuel-wood consumption leads to serious deforestation (Iwaarden, 1997). 6.4
Status of the technology infrastructure (actor network)
Indicators used for the assessment of the status of the technology infrastructure are the type of activity of the technology-supporting and -promoting agents and groups, the policies, objectives and strategies, the source and availability of capital and the nature of the relations with the construction companies. Our investigations concerning the major actors of the technology infrastructure for the subsector of dwelling construction in urban areas led to the following conclusions. The technology infrastructure of the construction industry is rather diffuse by nature because of its fragmented character of operations, the presence of a diversity of different actors in the network and the
212 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
heterogeneity of inputs and output. Many bottlenecks in the operating environment contribute to the comparatively low-level performance of the construction units in the execution of construction projects. (Maro, 1991; Mutagahywa and Materu, 1992). The linkages within the actor network of the sector of dwelling construction are rather weak. Communications and relations of the major actors with the construction units that carry out the dwelling construction projects for lower-income households are practically non-existent. Materials and equipment are generally bought in the informal sector. Moreover, the performance of the various actors in the network leaves much to be desired (Maro, 1991). The most important causes mentioned were a lack of capital, skills, experience, equipment and management. 6.5 Conclusions with respect to the status of technological capabilities The technology stock shows a low level of technological advancement. Indicators are the low quantity and quality of the product technologies, and the limited quantity and traditional nature of the process technologies. The human resources potential for the construction industry is relatively large, provided that the education and training opportunities improve. At present the majority of the labour force is employed and trained in the informal sector, and has a lack of knowledge and skills. The number of research and development staff is promising and might form a reasonable basis for a further development of the construction industry. The Tanzanian natural resources stock has considerable potential to provide the necessary raw materials. The exploitation of natural resources by the mining industry is limited, given the high import content in the majority of building materials. The technology infrastructure is weak and has a number of bottlenecks (Maro, 1991; NCC, 1995). These are mainly related to the functioning and nature of the actors in the infrastructural network itself, and the communications and relations between the actors and the construction units building houses for lower-income households in particular.
7
Conclusions
The conclusion is that optimal performance of the sector of dwelling construction for lower-income households in urban Tanzania requires considerable efforts with respect to technological capability building. This implies an upgrading of the technology stock, the development and more efficient use of the available stock of human and natural resources, and an improvement of the technology infrastructure. See also Table 8.6. The work presented is based on an extensive study of the available literature and a number of field studies. The adoption and application of the
Table 8.6
Requirements for technological capability building Requirements for TC building
1. quantity of output of bottlenecks in the construction process
investment in the housing sector and its backward linkages for the alleviation
2. supply of facilities in the house
investment in physical infrastructure: access roads, water, electricity and sewerage
3. application of appr. materials and constr.systems
investment in establishment of local production of building materials with high local content
4. application of proper phys.-techn. constr. details
investment in training and education, information and documentation systems
5. simplification of production processes on site
investment in r&d of construction technologies and systems; investment in proper diffusion of available technologies
6. cost reduction
investment in r&d for the determination of solutions for improvements and lower costs of construction technologies and systems
Process technologies
Requirements for TC building
1. access to proper equipment and tools with high local content
investment in the establishment of local production of equipment and tools
2. knowledge and skills of project managers, general foremen, craftsmen, labourers
investment in the establishment of proper training and education systems adjusted to the needs with regard to: project management, supervision and technical control, crafts, training possibilities on the job and literacy
3. avail. of and access to proper info. and doc. regarding technical specific. and doc., planning and control systems, material and equip. data bases
investment in: (a) establishment of well functioning and accessible consultancy and advisory organizations (b) establishment, accessibility and diffusion of planning and control systems (c) establishment, accessibility and diffusion of materials & equip. databases
213
Product technologies
(continued)
214
Table 8.6
Process technologies
Requirements for TC building
4. project organisation and management
investment in: (a) training and education of enterprise management including planning, administration, cost control, personnel management (b) improvement of technology infrastructure, access, communication and relations (c) establishment and accessibility of financing system
Human resources
Requirements for TC building
quantity of required labour force
investment in education and training of an additional 4000–5000 peoples professionals (10% of total additionally required) supervisors & technicians (40% of total additionally required) craftsmen and labourers (50% of total additionally/required)
quality of required labour force
investment in: 1. improvement of existing educational system 2. (on-going) education and training of the existing manpower in (a) enterprise management, (b) project management, (c) supervision and technical control, (d) crafts, (e) specific training on the job and (f) literacy
Natural resources
Required TC building
land delivery system
investment in surveying and delivery system of dwelling construction plots
energy supply
investment in the establishment of an adequate energy supply system
mineral resources
investment in adequate r&d and production of local building materials with high local content of inputs
agro-based and forestry resources
investment in adequate r&d and production of local building materials with high local content of inputs
Table 8.6
(continued)
Technology infrastructure
Requirements for TC building
clients
investment in establishment and accessibility of info. and doc. systems for clients and house owners
consultants
investment in: (a) training and education (b) establishment and accessibility of financing investment in: (a) mining, quarrying, transport and infrastructure (a) r&d on product and process technologies (c) training and education of manpower (d) availability of equipment and tools
materials & equipment suppliers
r&d institutions
investment in: (a) training and education of r&d manpower (b) facilities and equipment (c) info. and doc. system for a proper diffusion of the results
information and documentation centres
investment in establishment and accessibility of info. and doc. facilities for the construction industry including all actors of its network.
educational institutions
investment in the establishment and accessibility of education and training programmes adjusted to needs.
financing organisations branch organisations
investment in establishment accessibility of financing systems for the construction industry investment in improvement and accessibility of branch organisations
labour organisations
investment in establishment of incentive systems 215
216
Table 8.6
(continued)
Technology infrastructure
Requirements for TC buildinggovernment
investment in:
(a) improved insight in the actual needs for an optimal performance of the construction industry through further research (b) establishment of an enabling environment for the improvement of the performance of the construction industry by judicious application of policies and strategies in terms of legal, financial or fiscal measurements. These refer, for example, to the establishment of adapted regulations, standards and norms, financing and saving systems, tax regulations on imports and investments
Technological Capabilities 217
concept of technological capabilities in technology and development studies appear to be useful. Though not yet elaborated on in detail, the assessment of technological capabilities, by using the indicators as applied in our studies, provides the opportunity to get a comprehensive and integral view of the opportunities, problems and constraints for the further development of a sector. More precise information is needed to be able to determine the details of the input that should be given by specific actors, and the sequence in which this input should be given. The sequence should be based on the assessment of possible costs and the effects of the efforts in the short, medium and long term. Also, here an integral multidisciplinary approach should be applied in which the social-economic, as well as the technological aspects, are determined, analysed and evaluated.
Notes * 1.
2.
Section of Technology and Development Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology. The field studies were executed from 1993 to 1996 by Dankers, Rijkenberg, Tegelaars and Treffers, MSc alumni of the Eindhoven University of Technology and supervised by van Egmond and Gaillard, senior lecturers in Technology and Development Studies, Eindhoven University of Technology. The data for this component of the technological capabilities are derived from Statistical Abstracts (National Bureau of Statistics, formerly Bureau of Statistics, various issues), UNESCO (1995) and World Bank (1995c).
9 Technical Education, Knowledge and Skills in the Metalworking Industry in Tanzania Raymond Duijsens and Paul Lapperre*
1 1.1
Education and technical education Importance of education for development
Although the nature and extent of the role of education in the successful transition from a dominantly agricultural society to a dominantly industrial one are still debated (Szirmai, 1997a), in general one can say that knowledge and skills – primarily gained by various forms of education – were among the key variables in achieving the second phase of the Western transition. Against the back ground of a dramatic increase in the pace of technological innovation in the industrial, agricultural and service sectors of the economy in the highly industrialized countries since the late 1980s, and the fact that many developing countries, particularly in Africa, cannot keep up that pace by far (Castells, 1997), knowledge and skills are probably more important than ever in developing countries. Here, only a well-educated and well-trained labour force will be able to help to adopt modern technologies and to adapt these successfully to local production processes. In this context, Tanzania is no exception. Education is, of course, not only important for the adoption and adaptation of modern technologies. Education can induce changes in the values and attitudes towards development and the environment. Education can be geared to help to improve people’s ‘social carrying capacities’. Schooling can enhance the level of tolerance required for living in an increasingly multiform world. Improved health, lower fertility and better nutrition depend, among other factors, on greater literacy (Graham-Brown, 1991). The UNESCO Statistical Yearbook 1995 (UNESCO, 1995) enables us to obtain a bird’s-eye view with respect to the state of education worldwide. Access to education and enrolment is increasing in almost all developing countries, and it is expected that it will continue to do so in the 21st century. It is encouraging that almost all the boys in the world nowadays 218
Technical Education, Knowledge and Skills 219
get some form of primary education. In Asia and Africa, however, enrolment for girls is much lower than for boys, and is likely to hamper the development process in the decades to come. Despite the growth in primary education, illiteracy continues to rise in terms of absolute numbers. A large gap still exists between industrialized and developing countries in enrolment rates beyond primary level. With respect to secondary education, most developing countries were not even expected to reach the 1960 industrial country levels by the year 2000. In the field of tertiary education, the situation is even more a reason for concern. In particular, enrolment in technical education stays behind, both at the secondary and tertiary levels. In most developing countries, education is provided publicly (by the government), and the determinants of demand (private costs versus expected private benefits: the demand is a derived demand) are generally more important than the determinants of supply (determined largely by political processes unrelated to economic criteria other than limitations to public expenditure) (Lapperre, 1993). UNESCO forecasts for the next century suggest a continuation of these trends. 1.2
Demography and education
Although Tanzania’s government expenditure on education per student at the primary, secondary and tertiary levels compares favourably to that of other countries in the ‘low-income economy’ bracket, its enrolment performance at all levels of education, but particularly at the secondary and tertiary levels, is poor. Its drop-out rates at all levels are high – between 25 and 60 per cent – and the percentage of students (in the specific age brackets) with the highest diploma is comparatively low (UNESCO, 1989, 1994, 1995). Tanzania’s educational system is under great pressure of a relatively large and rapidly growing population and a large and growing number of people in the age bracket of 5 to 24 years. Figure 9.1 presents Tanzania’s population (millions) in the period 1960–95 and the corresponding Dutch population as a comparison. Figures 9.2a–d present the age group division in respectively Tanzania in 1957 and 1990 and the Netherlands in 1960 and 1990 (Bos, 1995; Mitchell, 1995). From Figures 9.2a–d some relevant observations can be made with respect to the (volume) problems that Tanzania encounters in education now and will encounter in the years to come. In the Netherlands the population is still growing, but in the next decade is likely to begin to decrease. Tanzanian population growth exceeds the Dutch one by a factor of 3, and the growth is likely to continue. Hence the total number of people eligible for education in Tanzania will continue to grow rapidly. The age group division figures for Tanzania show that the percentage of the population under 25 years increased in the period between 1957 and 1990. The
220 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Figure 9.1 Population in absolute numbers (millions) in Tanzania and the Netherlands (1960–1995)
Tanzania Netherlands
Figure 9.2a
Age groups in Tanzania in 1957 in absolute numbers
1 500 000
1 000 000 Tanzania
Figure 9.2b
70–74
60–64
50–54
40–44
30–34
0–4
10–14
0
20–24
500 000
Age groups in the Netherlands in 1960 in absolute numbers
1 500 000 1 000 000 Netherlands
Figure 9.2c
70–74
60–64
50–54
40–44
30–34
20–24
10–14
0
0–4
500 000
Age groups in Tanzania in 1990 in absolute numbers
5 000 000 4 000 000 3 000 000 Tanzania
2 000 000 1 000 000 70–74
60–64
50–54
40–44
30–34
20–24
10–14
0–4
0
Technical Education, Knowledge and Skills 221 Figure 9.2d
Age groups in the Netherlands in 1990 in absolute numbers
1 500 000 1 000 000 Netherlands
500 000
70–74
60–64
50–54
40–44
30–34
20–24
10–14
0–4
0
absolute number of potential pupils/students (age bracket 5–24) almost tripled. In the Netherlands the percentage of the population under 25 years, between 1960 and 1990, decreased significantly and the absolute number of potential pupils/students (age bracket 5–24) remained virtually constant. In view of Tanzania’s financial constraints, bringing the educational infrastructure (buildings, teaching materials, teachers) in line with the demographic developments will raise serious problems indeed. 1.3
Educational structure and enrolment
Formal education in Tanzania is controlled by the state through three ministries: the Ministry of Education and Culture, covering primary and secondary education, the Ministry of Science, Technology and Higher Education, covering higher education, and the Ministry of Labor and Youth Development, covering vocational training (Ministry of Education and Culture, 1993). There are some private schools, mainly at the secondary level, established according to conditions set by the ministry. Private universities are a recent phenomenon (1997). Policy issues and curricula for all schools (government and private) are the responsibility of the respective ministries. Administration of primary and adult education is decentralized to local authorities. Except for private schools, where ministry-controlled school fees are paid, all primary education in Tanzania is paid for by the government, which allocates about 20 per cent of its recurrent budget to education. Increasingly, however, also a parent contribution is demanded. In secondary schools a government-stipulated fee is to be paid by the students. Furthermore, each school is meant to meet 25 per cent of its catering bill (expenses for food, boarding facilities, and so on) by school-owned workshops. This is typically a relic of socialist times. Primary education starts at the age of seven and lasts seven years, that is Standard I to VII. The teaching related to technology or preparatory subjects is restricted to calculus and (natural) sciences. At the end of Standard VII, pupils sit for a Primary School Leaving Examination. After this, a pupil may choose post-primary technical education, national vocational training or secondary school.
222 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
In post-primary technical education pupils are trained to be artisans for two years. After this, they may decide to work or to enter national vocational training (NVT) for two years. During the period at one of the NVT centres, there is a close interaction with industry. After finishing NVT successfully, pupils will have completed Trade Test 3. After several years of working experience, they may return to NVT to pass their Trade Test 2 and eventually even their Trade Test 1. Entrance to secondary education (O-levels) is open only to those selected on the basis of a specially designed formula after Standard VII. O-level education lasts four years. Students can choose the following orientations: agriculture, home economics, commerce and technology. Students who pass well the National Form 4 Examination at the end of their O-level education may enter Form 5: secondary education (A-level). The number of students admitted depends on the number of places available. The orientations are the same as for the O-levels. After two years, the students sit their National Form 6 Examination, which leads to the National Higher School Certificate, which is equivalent to ‘A-level’. Students who pass Form 4, after following technically oriented secondary education, may enter a technical college. When they pass after three years they obtain a Full Technician Certificate. After Form 6, or after technical college, students can apply for university admittance. Enrolment requirements include high academic qualifications and good character references. Technical courses (BSc) have a duration of four years. Figures 9.3a–c present the gross enrolment (percentage of age group) in primary, secondary and tertiary education in Tanzania and the Netherlands. Note that gross enrolment generally overestimates the actual enrolment in developing countries by some 25 per cent and in
Figure 9.3a Gross enrolment in primary education (% age group)
Figure 9.3b Gross enrolment secondary education (% age group)
120
140
100
120 100
80
80
60
60
40
40
20
20
Tanzania Netherlands
Tanzania Netherlands
1995
1990
1985
1980
1975
1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995
1970
0
0
in
Technical Education, Knowledge and Skills 223 Figure 9.3c Gross enrolment in tertiary education (% age group)
Figure 9.4 Technical students in secondary education (% total secondary)
45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 Tanzania Netherlands
industrialized ones by some 10 per cent. Figure 9.4 presents the technical students in secondary education in Tanzania and the Netherlands as a percentage of the total of students in secondary education (Centraal Bureau voor de Statistiek, 1995; Duijsens, 1995; Mitchell, 1995). Compared to the Netherlands, Tanzania has a low gross enrolment in primary education. The net enrolment is even more revealing: between 1980 and 1995, in the Netherlands, net enrolment was approximately 95 per cent. In Tanzania, between 1980 and 1995, it dropped from 70 to 50 per cent. Compared to the Netherlands, gross enrolment in secondary and tertiary education in Tanzania is extremely low. In the Netherlands, from 1980 onwards, there is an upward trend. In Tanzania enrolment was almost constant from 1980 onwards. Between 1960 and 1995, the percentage of technical students in secondary education (as a percentage of total secondary education) in the Netherlands dropped from almost 22 per cent to a mere 11 per cent. In Tanzania the percentage of technical students in secondary education remained almost constant between 1 and 2 per cent. 1.4
Demand and supply of technically educated manpower
Although it is beyond the scope and intention of this paper to make an analysis of the supply and demand of (technically) educated manpower at the secondary level, some preliminary calculations can be made. In 1988, approximately 120 000 students were enrolled in secondary education in Tanzania’s 19 regions (Bureau of Statistics, 1990). Assuming (see Figure 9.4) that approximately 2 per cent of these were receiving some form of technical education, this would bring the number of technical students to approximately 2400. This number – even without making allowances for drop-outs – is less than the unsatisfied demand for approximately
224 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
3500 qualified technical personnel as calculated from various sources, most of the demand being in communications, construction and manufacturing (Misanga, 1993). There is little reason to believe that the situation has changed since the early 1990s. In 1990 Tanzania was one of the least industrialized countries in the world, with only 5 per cent of its total labour force employed in industry. Assuming that industrialization will proceed and that Tanzania will reach the average industrialization level of the ‘low-income economy’ group of countries with 15 per cent of its labour force employed in industry somewhere early in the 21st century, the demand for technically qualified personnel at the secondary level will at least triple. In view of the present structure and capacity of the educational system, some 10 000 vacancies would remain unfulfilled. This, of course, tells us little about the levels of knowledge and skills industry needs, and the ways in which the technical educational system caters for these. This issue is pursued further in the next paragraphs for the case of the metalworking industry.
2 Nature and causes of shortcomings in knowledge and skills in the metalworking industry 2.1
Introduction
Metalworking enterprises play a small but significant role in the Tanzanian industry (Bureau of Statistics, 1994d). A state-of-the-art survey of 168 enterprises in the Dar es Salaam region was conducted in 1990 through the Development of Improved Production Systems project (DIPS) (Masuha et al., 1992). The main goal was to make an inventory of available technologies in the metalworking industry, and little attention was paid to knowledge and skills of employees. Not only did the researchers of the University of Dar es Salaam want to rectify this omission, also in the literature increasingly doubts were voiced with respect to the quality of (vocational) technical education (Psacharopoulos, 1991). At the request of the University of Dar es Salaam, the Eindhoven University of Technology agreed in 1994 to a research effort to investigate the nature and causes of shortcomings in knowledge and skills of employees with formal technical (vocational) education in the metalworking industry. Only employees who had recently completed their education were to be included in the research. The preparation of the research took place in the second half of 1994, and the fieldwork was executed from January to September 1995. 2.2 2.2.1
Methodology Identification of the nature of shortcomings in knowledge and skills
In order to identify the nature of shortcomings in knowledge and skills, these were defined in such a way that they could be judged by means of a
Technical Education, Knowledge and Skills 225
survey employing closed-question questionnaires. Irrespective of a worker’s educational level, knowledge was defined as ‘information stored in a person’s mind’, and skills as ‘actions and reactions (physical and intellectual) which a person performs in a competent way to achieve a goal’ (Romiszowski, 1984). For three reasons it was decided not to judge knowledge and skills separately, but to focus on skills. For applying skills one needs a body of knowledge and when measuring skills one will at the same time, though indirectly, measure knowledge (Romiszowski, 1984). In addition, skills contribute more to the improvement of the functioning of employees at the levels included in this research than knowledge. Last but not least, a focus on skills in vocational education will enhance a student’s job opportunities, which is particularly important in developing countries (Kessels, 1992). Once it was decided to focus on skills, four categories were distinguished: cognitive skills (decision making, logical thinking, planning), psychomotor skills (physical action, head–hand–foot coordination), interactive skills (attitudes, feelings) and reactive skills (dealing with others purposively). Each of these skills can be either reproductive (applying procedures or algorithms to known situations) or productive (depending on a present body of knowledge, built up through instruction or experience, which is composed of relevant general principles and which is structured into specific strategies of thought or action). In order to judge the nature of shortcomings in skills of employees in the metalworking enterprises, a questionnaire was drawn up. For this purpose a list, based on a breakdown of a flow chart applicable to any metalworking process, was compiled, including all actions which a person has to perform. For these actions all necessary skills were listed to be judged by scores on a scale ranging from ‘very capable’ to ‘not capable’. Each of the skills was judged both for its productive and reproductive state. One open question was included, referring to major shortcomings in the employee’s formal technical education. From the 60 enterprises (ISIC 3.8) included in DIPS, 28 were selected for a survey. These represented the size categories small (<10 employees), medium (11–99 employees) and large (>100 employees), the metalworking processes forming, removing, joining and coating, and the production workers’ educational levels vocational training centres (VTCs), technical secondary schools (TSSs) and technical colleges (TCs). In the 28 enterprises, 31 managers (small- and medium-scale enterprises) and foremen (large enterprises) were interviewed, using the questionnaire, with respect to the knowledge and skill levels of their immediate subordinates. 2.2.2
Identification of the causes of the shortcomings in knowledge and skills
For each of the selected institutes the shortcomings as found in the enterprise survey were checked against the goals of these institutes with the
226 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
purpose of determining shortcomings not relevant to the institutes (Goodlad, 1979). For this, each of the selected institutes was asked to rank its top five goals out of a total of eight. From these rankings it appeared that each of the indicated shortcomings was relevant with respect to the educational goals of the institutes and, therefore, each of them was included in the remainder of the research. Three types of institutes were covered: VTCs, TSSs and TCs. The total national number of these institutes, focusing on the teaching of metalworking processes, was 45, 12 and 3 respectively. With the assistance of the respective authorities and ministries, eight institutes were selected for further investigation, taking into consideration size (large or small with respect to number of students), ownership (public or private) and location (urban or rural). This resulted in the inclusion of three VTCs, three TSSs and two TCs. Additionally, teacher training colleges (for VTCs and TSSs), the respective ministries (TSSs and TCs) and authorities (VTCs), the Tanzania Institute for Education (responsible for curriculum development for TSSs) and the National Examinations Council (for TSSs and TCs) were visited to collect information. To relate the shortcomings found in the enterprise survey with characteristics of educational institutes, a distinction was made between institutional and instructional characteristics (Hammond, 1973). Aspects of the former are teachers, students, family and community and school management, while instructional characteristics comprise facilities, costs, organisation and contents and methods. The cost aspect was investigated separately and in more detail to see whether the level of financial means affects the level of knowledge and skills of the students. Private VTCs receive relatively generous donor funding and are financially better off than public ones (King, 1988; Syrimis, 1988). Private TSSs receive little or no donor funding and are worse off than public ones. Taking examination outcomes and pass rates as an indicator for the level of knowledge and skills, these were linked to ownership – private and public – and thus to the level of available finance. For the VTCs the pass rates of the 1994 Trade Test 3 examinations were analysed (all subjects included), for the TSSs the CSSE (Certificate of Secondary School Examination: O-level) examination results for 1993 and 1994 (mathematics, English and the combined technical subjects). Since there are no private TCs in Tanzania, a comparison could not be made for these institutes. 2.3 2.3.1
Results Nature of shortcomings in knowledge and skills
Table 9.1 presents the outcomes of the survey in 28 metalworking enterprises. From the table one may conclude that, for all educational levels, reproductive skills are consistently less developed than productive skills,
Table 9.1
Nature of shortcomings in knowledge and skills Skills (scores, 1–4 range)a based on closed questions
Educational level of employee Cogn
Psym
Knowledge and skills based on single open question
Inter
Rep
R
P
R
P
R
P
R
VTC
2.5
3.1
2.8
3.4
2.6
3.3
3.0
TSS
2.4
3.0
2.6
3.2
2.6
3.2
3.0
TC
2.6
3.2
2.8
3.2
2.5
3.3
3.0
Low understanding of English; low knowledge of basic metal working processes; low knowledge of modern metalworking processes; low attitude of striving for excellence; low awareness of safety-related aspects Low understanding of English; low knowledge of modern metalworking processes; low attitude of striving for excellence; low awareness of safety related aspects; low awareness of preventive maintenance Low understanding of English; low knowledge of modern metalworking processes; low attitude of striving for excellence; low awareness of safety-related aspects; low management and supervision capabilities
Note: aAll skills range from 1 (not capable of executing the specific type of skill) to 4 (very capable); Cogn = cognitive skills, Inter = interactive skills, Rep = reproductive skills, Psym = psychomotoric skills, R = reactive skills and P = productive skills.
227
228 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
and that cognitive reproductive and productive skills tend to be less developed than psychomotoric, interactive and reactive reproductive and productive skills (for reactive skills, the productive variant was not measured). In addition, and again for all educational levels, the understanding of English, the knowledge of modern metalworking technologies, the attitude to strive for excellence and the awareness of safety-related aspects in the working environment were found to be low. School leavers from VTCs, TSSs and TCs appeared to have respectively a limited knowledge of basic metalworking processes, a limited awareness of preventive maintenance, and a lack of management and supervision capabilities. 2.3.2
Causes of shortcomings in knowledge and skills
Table 9.2 relates the identified and confirmed shortcomings in knowledge and skills to the institutional and instructional characteristics of the various types of institutes. The relationships between observed shortcomings in knowledge and skills and the institutional characteristics are summarized as follows: Students. Many of the indicated shortcomings find their origin in the educational background of the students. Tanzanian education, especially primary education, is known for its high teacher/pupil ratios (1:40 and higher) (Ministry of Education and Culture, 1988; Dar es Salaam Technical College, 1995; Vocational Education and Training Authority, 1995). This forces teachers to use the most basic expositive methods and ‘tight rule’ over a class. This, in turn, makes students passive and less receptive to other methods in subsequent education. Furthermore, and although the selection of new students is, among others, based on their mastery of English, their knowledge of English is insufficient. This situation is even worse at VTCs, where the student population in all classes is a mixture of graduate O-level students and primary school leavers. Family and community. Generally, the student’s family and community do not foster the use of English: as soon as a student sets foot outside the classroom, the environment is predominantly Swahili. Teachers. At the TSS and particularly the VTC level, the mastery of English of the teachers is, in general, poor. In many cases, their educational background is hardly higher than that of their students, and family and community characteristics apply to them in a same way. Furthermore, at teacher training colleges emphasis is put on (technical) contents, rather than on the mastery of the medium of instruction. In addition, the teacher training colleges encounter the same instructional and institutional difficulties as the VTCs and TSSs. As far as TCs are
Table 9.2
Relation between shortcomings in knowledge and skills and institutional and instructional characteristicsa Educational levelb
Indicated shortcoming
VTC Reproductive skills Cognitive skills Understanding of English Knowledge of modern metalworking technologies Striving for excellence Awareness of safety-related aspects Theoretical knowledge (basic metalworking processes) Awareness of preventive maintenance Management and supervision
TSS
Institutional characteristicsc TC
t
√ √ √ √
√ √ √ √
√ √ √
x x
√ √
√ √
√ √
x
s x x x
f,c
sm
Instructional characteristicsd f
c
o,c
m
x x
x x
x x x
x
x
x x x x
x x
x
x x
x
x
x
x
x
√
x
x
√
x √
x
x
x x
x
Notes: a √ shortcoming related to and investigated at the particular educational level; x relationship (either direct or indirect) b VTC, vocational training centre; TSS, technical secondary school; TC, technical college. c t, teachers; s, students; f,c, family, community; sm, school management. d f, facilities; c, costs; o,c, organization, contents; m, method.
229
230 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
concerned, there is no teacher training course: all teachers either hold a BSc degree or are graduates from a technical college (advanced diploma in engineering). Most of them, however, have ample working experience in industry, and often combine teaching with working. Their experience, therefore, compensates for the lack of a formal teacher training course, and their mastery of English as well as their knowledge of metalworking technologies appear to be sufficiently high. School management. This has virtually no direct influence on the teaching of knowledge and skills to students. At all levels it is very restricted in its ability to set priorities according to the institute’s needs. The only influence it has on attracting financial means is by acquiring projects from third parties. The relationships between observed shortcomings in knowledge and skills and the instructional characteristics are summarised as follows: Facilities and costs. The educational facilities to teach the various kinds of knowledge and skills (books and machines) are desperately lacking in most institutes, and this is a direct result of a lack of financial means. At the VTC level, private institutes, depending fully on foreign donor organisations, have more financial means available per student than their public counterparts, which rely exclusively on government support. At the TSS level, donor organisations are hardly involved and here the private institutes are worse off than the public ones. Organisation, contents and methods. Other than by limiting attention and time for other subjects, tackling many of the indicated shortcomings by devoting extra attention and time will be difficult under the present conditions. An important reason is that the profoundness and scope of the teaching of skills are hampered by the language of instruction, English, which is not the native language for any of the persons involved in the teaching. As a result, the method of teaching is mainly expositive, a situation that is aggravated by a shortage of educational means. To relate the indicated causes of shortcomings in knowledge and skills to the availability of financial means, the examination outcomes of private institutes were compared with those of public ones (for VTCs and TSSs only: all TCs in Tanzania are exclusively public). At the VTC level, private institutes, cooperating with and sponsored by foreign donor organizations, are in general able to allocate more financial means per student than their public counterparts, which are exclusively dependent on government financing. At this level, the research included the examination results of 494 students at 19 public VTCs and 209 students at 26 private ones.
Technical Education, Knowledge and Skills 231
Contrary to the VTC level, at the TSS level private institutes in general hardly receive any donor funding and they can only partially compensate for this by student fees, since these are limited to a maximum. With respect to the per capita amount of money, private TSSs are at a disadvantage compared to public ones. At this level, the research included the examination results of 10 073 students at 8 public institutes, and 1749 examination results at 4 private institutes. The results of the comparison are presented in Tables 9.3 and 9.4. Although the average pass rates are higher for private VTCs than for public ones, the differences are not significant (–z95%
Analysis of results
From the confrontation of the shortcomings in knowledge and skills with the institutional and instructional characteristics of the various institutes, it has become plausible that shortcomings in knowledge and skills are to a large extent caused by the use of English as a medium of instruction. In addition, from observations made during the fieldwork, it became apparent that financial means also constituted a serious shortcoming. When comparing examination results of institutes on the basis of ownership (public versus private), the importance of adequate financing of institutes became all the more apparent. When considering future policies with respect to technical education in Tanzania, the two main causes of shortcomings in knowledge and skills will face policy makers with several dilemmas. The use of English as a medium of instruction affects both students and teachers and influences the teaching methodology (directly as well as via Table 9.3
Pass/fail combinations at VTCs Public VTCsa
Pass/fail combination Theory
Practical
Pass Pass Fail Fail
Pass Fail Pass Fail
Private VTCsa
Test z1
p
q
n
p
q
n
.490 .091 .337 .082
.510 .909 .667 .918
243 45 167 39
.550 .081 .282 .086
.450 .919 .718 .914
115 17 59 18
–1.064 0.047 0.796 –0.050
Source: Vocational Education and Training Authority, Tanzania (1994). Note: a p, proportion meeting a specific pass/fail combination; q, proportion not meeting a specific pass/fail combination; n number of applicants meeting a specific pass/fail combination.
232
Table 9.4
Average pass rates at technical secondary schools Public TSSsa
Subject p Basic mathematics English Technical subjects
.603 .796 .630
Private TSSsa
Test z1
q
x
s
n
p
q
x
s
n
.397 .231 .370
3.855 3.686 3.746
1.488 .946 1.592
2,123 2,108 5 842
.136 .468 .502
.864 .532 .498
4.788 4.403 4.175
.372 .516 .788
382 380 987
Pass rate
CSSE score
22.777 11.685 7.485
–22.798 –16.869 –6.393
Source: National Examinations Council, Tanzania (1994, 1995). Note: a p, proportion passing a specific subject; q, proportion failing a specific subject; x, mean score of the population; n, number of applicants per subject. s, estimate population’s standard deviations.
Technical Education, Knowledge and Skills 233
the teaching material), which in turn has its effect on the performance of students. Changing the medium of instruction from English to Swahili would seem to be a logical decision. However, there are a number of arguments against such a step. (1) Most (if not all) literature is in English. Cooperation with foreign countries in production requires a mastery of English. Introducing Swahili would frustrate this cooperation. (2) Introducing Swahili would make it necessary to translate almost all literature. Apart from the fact that this would take considerable time, the costs would be prohibitive. (3) Although Swahili is a complex and precise language it unfortunately has an inadequately developed technical vocabulary and developing a suitable technical vocabulary would again take considerable time and be costly. There are, however, also arguments against the present use of English as a medium for instruction: (1) teachers and students have insufficient mastery of the language, and, as a result, (2) the teaching methodology remains mainly expositive. Considering the wide use of English in science and technology, and the importance of these fields with respect to industrial growth and development, and considering the immense problems to overcome when switching to Swahili, the Tanzanian government should stimulate the use of English, inside as well as outside the educational institutes, much more intensively. The financial means of the educational institutes come from three different sources (government, donor organisations and school fees), and influence the quality of the teachers and the availability and state of books and machines, of which the latter is directly related to the most appropriate teaching methodology. Furthermore, the comparison of examination results of public and private institutes indicated that students at institutes which have ample financial means obtain better results than students at institutes which are financially less well off. At the vocational level, the private institutes have more ample spending possibilities, while at the secondary level the public institutes have more financial means than their private counterparts. For the latter these differences are aggravated by the fact that, with respect to selection of students, primary school leavers with the highest examination results are selected by the government to enter public secondary schools, while others (that is, with lower examination results) are free to enter private institutes. Also, with respect to the selection of teachers, private schools are at a disadvantage: teachers at public secondary schools are appointed, trained and allocated by the government, whereas teachers at private institutes have to apply on their own initiative – their employer (private school) and/or the teachers themselves having to pay for the bulk of their training. Since also at the teacher training college persons with the highest results at formal educational levels are allowed to enter, the private schools, unless they have ample financial means, are left with the less qualified teachers to teach the less bright students.
234 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
Because of these relationships it would seem a logical suggestion to raise the schools’ financial means by increasing funding from one or more of the sources mentioned earlier. However, for a number of reasons, this will cause severe complications. (1) The government’s ability to raise its contributions to the educational sector hardly exists. (2) Under present conditions, donor funding in general contributes positively to a school’s performance, and, therefore, both the Tanzanian government and the educational institutes themselves should be pressed to stimulate donor financing. This, however, should be accompanied by a more even-handed approach towards private secondary schools by the Tanzanian government, with respect to regulations concerning fees, appointment and training of teachers and the selection of students. (3) School fees should be collected and spent at the level where this is most efficient. Furthermore, although it could make the educational system more elitist, school fees could be raised, considering the fact that the number of applications outstrips the number of vacancies by far, at all levels included in the research. At the technical colleges an increase of fees is quite feasible. At secondary level, an increase of fees should refer to private institutes only, thus leaving entry to public institutes in essence meritocratic. Finally, at the vocational level, the number of public training centers is quite substantial. An increase of fees at these institutes, where deemed necessary, will probably not lead to restricted access at this level.
Notes *
Section of Technology and Development Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology.
Part III Environmental and Energy Aspects of Industrialization
This page intentionally left blank
10 Industry and Environment: Methodologies for Environmental Assessment in Data-Poor Situations Lex Lemmens*, Peter Scheren**, Harro Zanting*, Gregory Njau*** and David van Horen*
1
Introduction
The key environmental issues for Tanzania are: land degradation, lack of accessible water supply and poor water quality, deterioration of aquatic systems, loss of wildlife habitats and biodiversity, deforestation and environmental pollution (Division of Environment, 1995). These environmental problems have evolved over a long period of time throughout the country. The contribution of industry to these problems is relatively recent. Industry can be a cause for all of the problems mentioned, but is most often associated with environmental pollution. Indeed the impact of industry in the other problem areas is often through pollution. The determination of the relative importance of industry as a threat to the quality of the environment is one of the topics of this paper. The major problem when monitoring or assessing the environment in Tanzania is the structural lack of data (DANIDA, 1989; Lemmens et al., 1996). It is, therefore, of utmost importance to develop methodologies that provide the best possible environmental assessments in view of the limited information available. This article presents the rapid assessment methodology as a tool for making an environmental pollution inventory in datapoor situations. The tool was first developed, evaluated and applied to the case of Lake Victoria. The results of this research will be presented first. Then it will be shown that the methodology can also be used to get a first insight into the environmental situation of the entire country using data from the national census. To complete the available information on industry and environment, the last sections focus on industrial pollution in the two major cities, Dar es Salaam and Tanga, and on pollution caused by some mining activities.
237
238 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
2
The rapid assessment methodology
Most rapid assessment procedures can be generalised by the following formula: Waste Load = Functional Variable * Pollution Intensity
(10.1)
in which the pollution intensity represents the amount of waste produced per unit of a given functional variable. Examples are listed in Table 10.1. While data on the size of functional variables need to be gathered ad hoc, for example, through field surveys, the pollution intensities derive from literature studies. This study elaborates on the generally applied procedures. First, to complete the balance of nutrient input into a given water body, an evaluation of atmospheric deposition of nutrients is presented. Penetration factors are introduced to account for human (for example, treatment plants) or natural purification (for example, water purification in rivers and wetlands). In addition, any rapid assessment methodology obviously requires assumptions and generalizations introducing uncertainty in its results. In the proposed methodology a method for error analysis is introduced (Lemmens et al., 1998b). To put the results in their right perspective in this article, only the results of the error analysis are presented. In order to test the results, a simple verification model is applied. 2.1
Waste loads
On the basis of an extensive literature survey and the assumption of a linear relation between waste load and production size, the World Health Organization (1982) and Economopoulos (1993) report pollution intensities for quantification of industrial waste loads from the most polluting industrial branches. This information, together with locally acquired information on industrial production, government statistics on industries, previous industrial (pollution) surveys, discussions with civil servants and visits to industrial sites, led to an estimate of the waste load of the most polluting industries in the research area. Table 10.1 Functional variables and pollution intensities for the principle pollution sources Pollution source
Functional variable
Pollution intensity
Industries Households Agriculture
Annual production Population number Area of (non) cultivated land
Waste production per unit product Annual waste production per person Annual export coefficients of nutrients
Industry and Environment 239
As with industrial pollution, the World Health Organization (1982) and Economopoulos (1993) have defined pollution intensities for domestic waste loads. Additional sources for pollution intensities are Jørgensen (1980) and Vighi and Chiaudani (1987). It is necessary to distinguish between waste loads from urban and rural populations. Liquid waste from urban households ends up in watercourses via discharge of sewage, run-off, drainage, and so on. Especially for those towns bordering the lakeshore, this waste load directly infiltrates the lake. Rural households, on the other hand, are generally scattered over a vast area, in the case of Lake Victoria extending up to 250 km from the lake. Only a small fraction of household waste reaches water courses via runoff and the numerous seasonal and non-seasonal rivers (penetration factor ≈ 0). Waste loads from the rural population can, therefore, be considered part of land run-off as assessed under agricultural pollution. Per capita waste loads for urban inhabitants vary according to sanitary conditions. Is there a sewage system, are there septic tanks or only pit latrines? The method applied to determine agricultural nutrient loads uses the export coefficient approach of Jørgensen (1980), an approach widely used in many studies (for example, Scheren et al., 1995; Mattikalli and Richards, 1996). The loss of nitrogen and phosphorus to watercourses is estimated from the area of different land usage in the catchment area, multiplied by typical export coefficients for each land-use type. Based on Thomann and Mueller (1987), the identification of different land-use types was limited to two categories: cultivated arable land and non-cultivated (forest, pasture and fallow) land. In addition to the type of cultivation, other characteristics also control the magnitude of nutrient flux. These include precipitation run-off, soil texture, slope and fertilizer application. Livestock production is an important activity in terms of land-use pattern in many agricultural areas. It can, therefore, be expected that animal droppings, either left on the field during grazing or spread out over croplands as organic fertilizer, are an important factor affecting nutrient loading. An assessment of both organic and artificial fertilizer use in the catchment area served as a verification of the nutrient loading estimate based on export coefficients (Scheren et al., 1995). Data on artificial fertilizer use (or alternatively its distribution) and livestock population were used as a basis for calculations. In the case of Lake Victoria, artificial fertilizers are applied before or in the rainy seasons, which are also the main crop-growing seasons. Therefore, the total amount applied is subject to loss to watercourses. As leaching and run-off of nutrients from manure occur during the rainy seasons only (approximately five months per year for the Lake Victoria area), the load is estimated at 5/12 of the total amount of manure. The fraction of nutrients from (natural and artificial) fertilizers running off and leaching to watercourses is taken at 13 per cent for phosphorus and
240 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
30 per cent for nitrogen compounds (Orlova and Yaroshenko, 1976; Santschi and Schindler, 1977; Ministry of Health and Environmental Protection, 1980). 2.2
Wet deposition
During rainfall all kinds of dust particles are washed down to the surface of the lake. The relevance of this wet deposition lies in the presence of substances containing nitrogen and phosphorus in the air, which can contribute significantly to the total nutrient load. Human activities in a wide area around the water body can very well be responsible for an important part of the nutrient contents of rain water. Biomass burning, for example, is known to be an important contributor. The load of nitrogen and phosphorus as a result of wet deposition is estimated by multiplying average concentrations of N and P in rain with the average amount of annual rainfall over the lake. Selection of average concentrations can be based on local analyses (as done for Lake Victoria) or on typical values from the literature (see, for example, Jørgensen, 1980; Thomann and Mueller, 1987; Ritter, 1988). 2.3
Penetration factors
The annual industrial, domestic and agricultural waste loads calculated in the manner indicated earlier are the loads generated at the different pollution sources. In many cases these are higher than the loads eventually discharged into the lake. The difference in loading can be expressed by one or more penetration factors, each with a value between one and zero. This leads to the following adaptation of the general formula: Waste Load = Functional Variable * Pollution Intensity * Penetration Factor(s) (10.2) The most common penetration factors are the effectiveness factors of domestic and industrial waste-water treatment facilities. The efficacy of treatment facilities in reducing waste loads can be estimated from typical performances of normally operating plants, as reported by Economopoulos (1993). The efficiency of badly maintained or overloaded treatment plants (observed widely in the Lake Victoria basin) is lower than these typical performances. In such cases, approximate treatment efficiencies may be defined, based on effluent analysis data and selected site visits. The latter has been done for most domestic and industrial facilities in the case of Lake Victoria. Next to treatment facilities, there are other, often natural, conditions that reduce the waste load released by industries, cities or agriculture before reaching the water body of the lake. This study proposes the incorporation of the self-purification potential of rivers and streams, and the liquid waste
Industry and Environment 241
filtration of wetlands into the method. The biochemical oxygen demand (BOD) load from a distant source can be wholly or partly broken down when it is moving from the source to the lake. A first-order decay process can describe the breakdown of BOD5 in rivers: L − K× D = exp 86.4 × L0
(10.3)
in which L represents downstream BOD5, L0 represents BOD5 at the point of discharge, K is the decay rate (day–1), D is the discharge distance from the lakeshore (km) and v is the flow velocity (m s–1). The penetration factor L/L0 can be defined for each distance D from the lakeshore if K and v are known. K depends on many different river characteristics, such as bacterial composition, water temperature, water turbulence and stream velocity, and will be different for individual (parts of) rivers. Typical values for K vary from 0.2 to 0.8 day –1 (Thomann and Mueller, 1987; Metcalf and Eddy, 1991; Zanting, 1996), with 0.3 as a ‘most likely’ value. Thomann and Mueller (1987) present an equation that relates the river flow-through velocity to characteristics such as river volume flow, slope, drainage area and length. Based on this relation and the characteristics of several Kenyan rivers (Ministry of Water Development, 1992), the velocity v was estimated to average between 0.3 and 1.0 m s –1 for rivers around Lake Victoria. Calibration of Equation 3 with these ranges for K and v, and for several values of the distance D, results in BOD penetration factors. For five ranges of distances from the lakeshore these are presented in Table 10.2. Many rivers, and even sewage outlets, drain through swamp areas before discharging on the open waters of a lake. In this way the concentration of nutrients and oxygen demanding waste is reduced. The impact of wetlands on the reduction of waste loads before reaching the lake is incorporated by defining wetland penetration factors. The waste-water treatment capacity of wetlands is closely tied to various aspects of wetland hydrology, such as water depth, retention time and degree of channelization. Typical BOD penetration factors through natural wetlands, as reported by Richardson and Nichols (1985), range from 0.30 to 0.05. A rounded Table 10.2 Distance (km) 0–10 10–50 50–100 100–150 150–250
Selected distance penetration factors for BOD5 Penetration factors 1.00 0.90 0.75 0.60 0.45
242 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
mean factor of 0.20 is selected as the most likely value. The performance of wetlands in removing nutrients from waste loads depends highly on the average nutrient loading per wetland surface unit. Using studies of several (North American) wetlands, Richardson and Nichols (1985) present graphical relations between P and N removal rates as a function of average loading. These relations have been applied to estimate nutrient filtration by swamps in the Lake Victoria basin. Selected values are presented in Table 10.3. 2.4
Reference nutrient load from modelling
In this section a brief presentation is given of a theoretical model for the nutrient balance of a lake. A more detailed description and evaluation are presented by, for example, Scheren (1995). The model assumes complete mixing of the water, thus averaging concentrations over a lake or water. Although local situations or fluctuations are not explained in this way, the procedure is very useful in clarifying the overall nutrient balance. The three main assumptions of the model are: (1) nutrient concentrations are the same throughout the lake; (2) the volume and outflow of the lake are constant and (3) all processes involving nutrients (for example, sedimentation) are linearly related to the nutrient concentration. In a steady state situation, in which there is no accumulation of nutrients in the lake water, the total nutrient input in the lake is assumed to be equal to the sum of nutrient outflow through river(s) and the net loss of nutrients to the sediment. This mass balance results in Equation 10.4: WA = C A× Q+E
V
v SA H
(10.4)
in which WA represents the input of nutrient A (g yr–1), CA is the concentration of nutrient A (g m–3), QE is the river outflow (m3 yr–1), V is the lake volume (m3), VAS is the sedimentation velocity for nutrient A (m yr–1), and H is the average lake depth (m). Average data of these parameters for Lake Victoria result in a value for the nutrient load WA (for both nitrogen and phosphorus) that serves as a verification of the rapid assessment nutrient load estimate. Table 10.3 Nutrient penetration factors through wetlands (selected most likely values) Loading, g (N/P) m–2yr–1 2 10 50 500
N
P
0.3 0.7 0.9
0.4 0.6 0.75 0.8
Industry and Environment 243
3
Lake basin statistics
With a surface area of 68 800 km2, Lake Victoria is the largest lake in Africa. Its adjoining catchment area (Figure 10.1) of 194 000 km2 stretches out over five countries: Tanzania, Kenya, Uganda, Rwanda and Burundi. Only the first three border on (and share a part of) the lake. The relatively shallow lake (average depth is 40 m) serves its riparian population in the provision of fresh water and fish, as well as a depository for waste from different sources. The only outflow is the Victoria Nile, leaving the lake at Jinja in Uganda. Evaporation and precipitation dominate the water balance of Lake Victoria. The features of the catchment area of Lake Victoria that determine the functional variables for the waste load assessment are discussed in the following sections. Figure 10.1
The catchment area of Lake Victoria (source: Crul, 1993)
Victoria Nile
Victoria Nile UGANDA
Kampala
KENYA Kisumu
Lake Kagera
Victoria Bukoba
Mara Musoma
RWANDA
Muanza BURUNDI
TANZANIA
244 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
3.1
Industrial characteristics
Most industrial activity (Table 10.4) is located in the major towns bordering the lake, such as Kampala and Jinja in Uganda, Mwanza and Musoma in Tanzania, and Kisumu in Kenya. Important exceptions are the large sugar factories located at some distance from the lake on the Kenyan side. The discussion on industrial liquid waste is limited to BOD loads, because the discharge of N and P is negligible compared to other sources. For several industrial pollution sources, only penetration factors for distance have been applied as, with a few exceptions, industrial waste-water treatment is generally absent or inefficient because of poor maintenance. However, much of the Ugandan industrial effluent drains through wetlands before reaching the lake surface water. Wetland penetration factors have, therefore, been applied. The waste load from those urban industrial sites discharging to the domestic sewer system was corrected for the defined treatment efficiency of the municipal plants. 3.2
Population
With a population of about 30 million, the Lake Victoria catchment area is one of the most densely populated parts of Africa. Annual population Table 10.4 Estimated 1995 production of major industries in the catchment area of Lake Victoria by country and industrial (sub)sector ISIC
3111 3112 3114 3115 3118 3131 3133 3134 3211 3231 3411 3523 (1)
Industry
Slaughterhouses Dairy factories Fish factories Vegetable oil refineries Sugar factories Distilleries Breweries Bottleries Cotton mills Leather tanneries Paper mills Soap factories
Shared production of major factories, t yr–1 (number of major factories) Kenyaa
Ugandab
Tanzaniac
3 000 (1) – 18 000 (6) – 640 000 (6) 18 000 (1) 60 000 (1) 41 000 (1) 1 500 (1) 270 (1) 94 000 (2) –
14 000 (3) 25 000 (1) 12 000 (4) 3 300 (2) – 460 (1) 17 000 (1) 40 000 (2) – 60 (1) – 40 000 (2)
– – 6 630 (2) 31 400 (4) 3 500 (1) – – 11 100 (2) 1 320 (2) 220 (1) – 15 000
Notes: a Sources: Oerlemans (1985); Calamari (1994); Ministry of Planning and National Development (1994); Kirugara and Nevejan (1996), selected industrial site visits. b Sources: Droruga (1990); Ministry of Finance and Economic Planning (1993); Ministry of Natural Resources (1995); selected site visits. c Source: Scheren et al. (1995).
Industry and Environment 245
growth is 2–4 per cent in most parts of the lake basin, but urban population growth is over 5–10 per cent per year in most of the larger towns. Table 10.5 summarizes the population statistics of the lake basin. For each of the 40 towns larger than 10 000 inhabitants (held as a threshold for urban characteristics) in the Lake Victoria basin, information on sanitary conditions, domestic waste-water treatment, wetland drainage and distance from the lakeshore was gathered. 3.3
Agriculture
There are many densely cultivated areas in the Lake Victoria basin, especially in Kenya, Rwanda and Burundi. Important staple crops are maize and bananas. The main cash crops are sugar cane, coffee and tea. Application of artificial fertilizers is significantly higher in Kenya than in other parts of the catchment area. Agricultural characteristics are summarized in Table 10.6. Most data in Table 10.6 are extrapolations based on surveys from the early to mid-1990s. An annual growth rate of 1 per cent is assumed for the area of cultivated arable land (Ministry of Water Development, 1992). Wetland penetration factors have been applied for areas draining through wetlands, requiring considerable judgement of the investigators. 3.4
Rainfall
Average rainfall over Lake Victoria is 1450 mm yr–1 (±10 per cent), equivalent to approximately 100 km 3 yr–1. Regional rainfall varies between 895 mm yr–1 in Musoma (Tanzania) and 2216 mm yr –1 in Kalangala (Uganda) (Crul, 1993).
Table 10.5 (1995)
Domestic characteristics of the Lake Victoria catchment area
Total population (1 000 people) Kenyaa Ugandab Tanzaniac Rwandad Burundid Total
10 200 5 600 5 200 5 900 2 800 29 700
Urban population (1 000 people) Sewered 390 210 27 – – 627
Number of towns
Unsewered 630 870 340 400 140 2 380
18 9 4 5 4 40
Notes: a Source: Ministry of Water Development (1992). b Sources: Ministry of Finance and Economic Planning (1992), Ministry of Natural Resources (1993), National Water and Sewerage Corporation (1995). c Source: Scheren et al. (1995). d Source: Verlinden (1996).
246
Table 10.6
Estimated agricultural statistics of the Lake Victoria catchment area, 1995 Catchment land area (1 000 ha)
a
Kenya Ugandab Tanzaniac Rwandad Burundid Total
Cultivated
Non-cultivated
1 470 1 400 1 500 930 670 5 970
3 400 2 100 5 540 1 130 640 12 810
Livestock population (1 000 heads) Total
Cattle
4 870 3 500 7 040 2 060 1 310 18 780
4 890 1 630 2 800 480 200 10 000
Sheep & goats 3 140 1 590 1 900 310 180 7 120
Chicken 11 400 3 750 1 300 – – 16 450
Fertilizer use (t y–1) N 9 000 420 420 300 1 000 11 140
P 2O 5 14 900 210 130 80 800 16 120
Notes: a Sources: Lake Basin Development Authority (1987); Kenya Grain Growers Cooperative Union (1991); Ministry of Water Development (1992); Kirugara and Nevejan (1996); Ministry of Natural Resources (1996). b Source: Ministry of Agriculture (1992, 1995); World Bank (1993e), Bank of Uganda (1995). c Source: Scheren et al. (1995). d Source: Bullock et al. (1995); United Nations (1995).
Industry and Environment 247
Only limited data are available on nutrient concentrations in rainwater in the region. Average concentrations of total nitrogen (TN) and total phosphorus (TP) reported by Bootsma and Hecky (1993), Scheren (1995) and ICRAF (1995) range from 0.58 to 0.92 mg l –1 for N and from 0.07 to 0.11 mg l–1 for P (see Table 10.7). The N concentrations are similar to values reported from larger, North American, data sets. On the other hand, phosphorus concentrations from Lake Victoria rainwater are surprisingly high in comparison with reported values (for example, Ritter, 1988). A possible explanation for the observed high phosphorus concentrations in rain could be that, in all reported cases, samples were taken relatively close to the lakeshore. Here, dust and air pollution might be considerably higher than further offshore. It is debated, however, as to whether the high P concentration in rainwater might be caused by the extensive forest burning going on in the adjacent Rwanda and Burundi highlands (Bootsma and Hecky, 1993; Scheren, 1995b). 3.5
Wetlands
The largest wetland area in the Lake Victoria basin is in western Uganda. The entire drainage of the Katonga and Ruizi-Kibali river basins is through river channels that used to be more rapidly flowing in the past. Now, these channels are ridden with swamps and small swampy lakes (Beadle and Lind, 1960). Other important wetlands in Uganda are the small swamps on the lakeshore, receiving the domestic and industrial waste-water from Kampala and Jinja (Ogaram and Kalema, 1995). Furthermore, the Kagera river basin, draining through Rwanda, Burundi, Tanzania and Uganda, is covered with large areas of wetlands. Important swamps on the Kenyan side are at the mouths of the rivers Yala and Nyando. For all these wetlands, information on size and average nutrient loads where combined to determine the nutrient penetration factors on which Table 10.3 is based.
4 4.1
Results from the catchment area of Lake Victoria BOD loading estimates
Organic waste loads, represented by a BOD load, were assessed for domestic and industrial (point) sources. As the study focuses on the pollution of the
Table 10.7 Victoria
Selected average nutrient concentrations in direct rainfall on Lake
Average nutrient concentrations (mg l–1) TN TP
0.80 0.09
248 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
lake, the estimated generated BOD loads were corrected for purification in treatment plants, rivers and wetlands. Table 10.12 presents the results. The probability intervals presented in Table 10.8 and 10.9 result from an error analysis (Lemmens et al., 1998b). They account for the roughness of the data in presenting, more or less, a best- and worst-case scenario. The authors have chosen the values in such a way that they represent the most likely case. Breweries, sugar-cane factories and soap and oil factories display the largest amount of industrial BOD load. The most likely BOD loads are presented in Figure 10.2. The conclusion is that domestic pollution accounts for most of the BOD load. An interesting note here: 75 per cent of Uganda’s domestic BOD load originates from its capital, Kampala, while in Kenya 50 per cent originates from Kisumu. Further calibration of the Kenyan results shows that, if all the present treatment plants could perform optimally and meet the theoretical reduction efficiency, BOD loads could be brought down to 50 per cent of the presented most likely value.
Table 10.8
Results of the Lake Victoria BOD5 loading assessment
Unit: t yr–1
Kenya
Uganda
Tanzania
Source
Most likely
Most likely
Most likely
Industrial Domestic
1 810 5 700
540 4 000
820 3 100
Total
7 510
4 540
3 920
Prob >55% Prob >90%
5 100–10 700 2 700–13 800
3 800–6 000 3 000–7 500
3 400–4 500 2 900–5 000
Table 10.9
Results of the Lake Victoria nutrient loading assessment (t yr–1)
Source
Urban domestic Agriculture Wet Deposition Total Prob >55% Prob >90%
Total nitrogen –
Total phosphorus
Most likely
s
7 600 48 200 81 000
1 800 18 300 17 700
2 100 40 400 15 200
136 800
25 500
43 200
111 000–180 000 86 000–223 000
s
+
s–
s+
920 5 710 9 120
280 1 440 3 650
1 650 2 740 1 010
15 750
3 900
3 400
Most likely
11 900–19 200 8 000–23 000
Industry and Environment 249 Figure 10.2
Most likely BOD loads to Lake Victoria Industrial Domestic
8000
BOD (ton/year)
7000 6000 5000 4000 3000 2000 1000 0 Kenya
4.2
Uganda
Tanzania
TN and TP loading estimates
The results of the assessment of TN and TP loads penetrating to Lake Victoria are summarised in Table 10.9. The waste loads discharged into the lake are about 70 per cent of the generated loads, mainly as a result of wetland filtration. The role of domestic treatment in reducing nutrient loads is insignificant. The estimated most likely total nitrogen load is 136.8 × 103 t yr–1. The most likely P input is 15.75 × 103 t yr–1. Table 10.9 reveals that wet deposition is the most important source of both N and P. Domestic liquid waste plays only a minor role in nutrient loading. The most likely values for N loads are presented in Figure 10.3. For P loads, the picture is similar. Clearly, Tanzania, occupying the largest part of the catchment area, generates the largest agricultural nutrient load. Nutrient loads calculated from livestock population and artificial fertilizer application allow for verification of the presented loads estimated from land use (as described before). The verification shows that 66 000 t yr–1 of N originate from manure, while only 2900 t yr–1 originate from artificial fertilizer application. For P, these figures are 4800 t yr –1 and 800 t yr–1 respectively. For the entire lake basin, therefore, artificial fertilizer application plays a minor role in nutrient loading. Further data analysis revealed, apart from some Kenyan districts, that artificial fertilizer use is insignificant. As a final verification, the basic model, represented by Equation 4, was applied. Average lake water concentrations (CA) of 0.640 mg l–1 for N and 0.074 mg l–1 for P were applied, based on reported sampling studies from Gophen et al. (1995) and Lehman and Branstrator (1994). Combined with
250 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Figure 10.3 by country
Most likely nitrogen loads, by source, and agricultural nitrogen loads,
Burundi 4%
Wet Deposition 59%
Agriculture 35%
Urban Domestic 6%
Tanzania 44%
Rwanda 7% Uganda 13%
Kenya 32%
a lake volume (V) of 2760 km3, an average depth (H) of 40 m, a river outflow (QE) of 23.5 km yr–1 (Crul, 1993) and settling velocities (VAS)1 of 2.3 m yr–1 for both TN and TP, the nutrient input (WA) was calculated. The resulting WA are 117 000 and 14 000 t yr–1 for N and P respectively, which is only about 15 per cent lower than the rapid assessment results presented in Table 10.13.
5 Rapid assessment evaluation of the Tanzanian industry based on the 1989 industial census The rapid assessment methodology presented above can also be used to get a first impression of the environmental situation on a national scale. The data necessary can be extracted from national censuses or more specific surveys when available. In this study we attempted to analyse the contribution of different industrial sectors to the total environmental pressure on aquatic systems. The data used are those of the 1989 Industrial Census, referring to establishments with ten or more persons employed. As with the analysis in the Lake Victoria region, we limit ourselves in this study to organic, nitrogen and phosphorus pollution. As a departure for the analysis, we start with the 29 ISIC three-digit sectors as presented in Table 10.10, together with their total and proportional contribution to the value added in 1989. According to WHO
Table 10.10
Basic data extracted from the Tanzanian industrial census, 1989 Value added of polluting industries with complete data (000 TSh)
% of value added omitted because of incomplete data
Value added industries for which WHO conversions are available (000 TSh)
% of value added taken into account in the assessment
57 995 567 3 213 597 1 760 820
56 222 869 2 925 230 821 185
3.06 8.97 53.36
43 363 464 1 885 467 97 774
74.77 58.67 5.55
1.43
3 795 996
3 738 471
0.57
3 721 712
98.98
6 003 916
1.31
5 218 226
4 160 039
20.28
1 085 634
20.80
3 855 234 134 708 655
0.84 29.47
2 366 671 5 305 363
2 350 033 4 024 467
0.70 24.14
2 234 182 4 024 467
94.4 75.86
ISIC code
Sector
Value added (000 TSh)
Proportional contribution
311–12 313 331–32
Food Beverages Wood/wood products/furniture Paper/paper products/printings publishing Chemicals/ petroleum/petroleum & coal products Rubber/plastic All metal and metal products
58 526 087 3 213 597 32 161 429
12.81 0.70 7.04
6 531 744
341–42
351/354
355–6 371–2,381
Value added of polluting industries (000 TSh)
Source: Bureau of Statistics, data files of the 1989 Census of Industrial Production (10+ establishments).
251
252 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
guidelines (Economopoulos, 1993), not all four-digit ISIC subsectors contribute to the pollution of aquatic systems with organic material (BOD 5), total nitrogen and total phosphorus. Those sectors that do not contribute to any of the loads looked at are not included in the table. The total value of polluting industries adds up to 29 per cent of the total value of industry. The industrial census of 1989 contains many missing data and non-standardised information. These had to be omitted from further analysis. The industries that could be assessed together represent 68.7 per cent of the total value added of all polluting industries. The WHO guidelines introduce a further limitation to the assessment. Conversion values are not available for all subsectors. Sectors for which polluting data are not available are 321, textiles, and 323–4, leather products/footwear. This leads to a further reduction of industries. The remaining industries together produce 43 per cent of the total value added of all polluting industries. With the conversion values from the WHO report the contribution of different sectors to BOD5, total suspended solids, nitrogen and phosphorous can be determined. From Table 10.11 it becomes clear that from the industries taken into account in this assessment, the paper/paper products/printing/publishing subsectors account for almost all organic pollution (BOD5). The subsector food is, within the sample, responsible for most of the emissions which cause eutrophication (P and N). The wood/wood products/furniture subsector contributes significantly to environmental problems because of the nitrogen emitted. The other subsectors, including chemicals/petroleum and coal products and rubber/plastic, are not important for the environmental problems reviewed here. Of course, they could be responsible for important point pollution which could cause other important environmental problems (see next section). One step further in the analysis would be to analyse individual firms within a subsector with respect to their contribution to important emissions. With the data available from the 1989 census this proved to be possible. Because of the small number of firms within a subsample, the presentation of the results of such an analysis would be in conflict with the privacy that has to be taken into consideration.
6 Information on industrial pollution in urban areas and point pollution sources Although information on industrial pollution in urban areas is as scattered as environmental data in general, there is more relevant information on pollution in two of the major cities of Tanzania, Dar es Salaam and Tanga. In these urban areas industries are considered to be heavy polluters. This assumption is now assessed for water and air pollution.
Table 10.11 ISIC code
311–12 313 331–2 341–2 351/354 355–6 371–2 381 Total
Waste volumes and contribution to pollution for different sectors Sector
Food Beverages Wood/wood products/ furniture Paper/paper products/ printing/publishing Chemicals/petroleum/ petroleum & coal products Rubber/plastic All metal and metal products
Waste volume
BOD5
m3
%
[kg]
34 041 272 1 525 445 17 954
0.44 0.02 <0.005
97 654 796 845 081 17 516
7 603 316 996 – 64 142 154 296 491 7 793 262 300
97.56 – <0.005 1.98 100.00
Tot N % 16.35 0.14 <0.005
Tot P
[kg]
%
[kg]
%
5 908 0 1 051
84.90 – 15.10
1 207 0 0
100.00 – –
446 015 025
74.70
0
–
0
–
1 902 827
0.32
0
–
0
–
693 50 664 519
<0.005 8.49
0 0
– –
0 0
– –
597 100 457
100.00
6.959
100.00
1 207
100.00
253
254 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
6.1
Water pollution
Industrial development in Tanzania was pursued without environmental regulation, resulting in importation of industries without waste-water treatment facilities. In Dar es Salaam, as in all other towns with industries, liquid effluent is discharged directly into water systems or drainage leading into them. A study carried out in 1997 showed that 68 per cent of all industries surveyed in Dar es Salaam discharge into the Indian Ocean, either directly or indirectly through a total of 12 streams draining through heavily inhabited areas of a city with 2.3 million inhabitants (Mgana and Mahongo, 1997). Table 10.12 shows the effluent composition discharged directly into the Indian Ocean. The effluent consists of BOD5 2715 t yr–1 and SS (suspended solids) 15 454 t yr–1 representing 19 per cent and 55 per cent of all BOD5 and SS respectively. The rest comes from domestic sources. Tables 10.13 and 10.14 show the effluent composition discharged through Msimbazi stream, either directly or through the Vingunguti waste stabilization ponds. Msimbazi stream passes heavily inhabited areas. Tanzania Breweries Ltd, which accounts for about 60 per cent of the BOD5 and SS, discharges its effluents to the stream untreated. Most of the nitrate and phosphorus materials come from slaughterhouses. The situation is not so different in Tanga, where 675 tons of effluent are discharged directly into the Indian Ocean. Tanga is endowed with many big rivers, and most of the rural sisal estates discharge their industrial effluents into these rivers. A fertilizer company was spewing 700 m 3 of effluent per hour, containing acids, fluoride, phosphorus, nitrogen and cadmium, before it was closed down a few years ago. Together with other effluents from soap factories and textile mills, this resulted in an accumulation of anoxic sediments 2 mm below the surface in the area around the city of Tanga (USAID/Tanzania 1996). 6.2
Air pollution
Sources of air emission are mainly from industries, transport and domestic cooking. The survey carried out in the cities of Dar es Salaam and Tanga revealed that domestic combustion of biomass is the major source of air pollution, followed by industries and road transport (Mgana et al. 1997). As shown in Tables 10.15 and 10.16, 93 per cent of all the TSP and 96 per cent of all the CO and VOC emission in Dar es Salaam came from households. Cement factories in both Dar es Salaam and Tanga were leading industrial air pollution. The Dar es Salaam cement factory accounts for 40 per cent (2185 tons) of total TSP, 51 per cent (323 tons) of SO 2 and 60 per cent (323 tons) of NOx annually. The Tanga Cement factory annual emissions were 37 per cent (2354.6 tons) of TSP, 73 per cent (342 tons) of SO2 and 49 per cent (720 tons) of NOx.
Table 10.12
Pollution sources discharging into sea, Dar es Salaam Pollution loads (t yr–1)
Industry BOD5 Tiper Industry Twiga Chemicals SAPA Chemical Ltd Kioo Ltd Bobby Soap Banco Products Ltd Henkel Mifuku Ltd Tanganyika Tegry Ltd Simba Plastic Ltd Kwanza Bottlers Costal Oil Industry Tradeco Oil Industry Murzha Oil Mill Ltd Transtech Ltd Tanpack Industry Colgate Palmolive Medicare Industry Fahari Bottlers Co. Blanket Manf. Co. H.K. Foam Pan Africa Ltd Kibo Paper Mill JEJE Industries Ltd Twiga Paper Prod. Ltd Subtotal
2.0 1.4 9.8 31.9
SS
72.3 1 057.5 28.8 0.1 1.4 67.0 214.3 402.6 298.8 209.2 2.4 0.1 5.0 81.5 37.0 0.11 0.1 173.2
6.5 0.4 3.9 9 378.6 122.0 2 680.9 1 797 30.6 0.3 3.9 22.3 211.8 397.8 295.2 206.6 0.8 0.1 8.5 31.0 179.0 0.4 0.18 40.4
18.2 2 714.71
36.3 15 454.48
441.0 277.0 10 963.0 11 681
716.0 482.0 11 443.0 12 641
Grand Total
14 395.71
28 095.48
Putrescible
4.8 4.7 32.9
N
P
Phenol
S
0.7
0.02
0.03 0.3 2.1
0.004
Cr
Fe
Cl
48.2
0.2
20.3
2.7 241.9 454.4 337.2 236.0
40.5 76.0 56.4 39.5
0.6
1 335.5
212.4
0.7
887.0
221.0
68.0
887.0 2 222.5
212.4
3 099.0 3 320
410.0 478
3 320.7
478
2.42
0.03
0.004
48.2
0.2
2.42
0.03
0.004
48.2
0.2
255
Sewerage system Septic tank system Pit latrine Subtotal
Oil
256 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Table 10.13 Sample of industries directly discharging into Msimbazi stream, Dar es Salaam Pollution Loads (t yr–1)
Industry BOD0
SS
Oil
N
P
857.4 259.9 50.4 29.6 9.86 14.1
332.9 100.9 20.7 27.6 9.2 13.13
10.35 3.5 4.9
3.5 1.2 1.64
0.25 0.082 0.117
1221.26
504.43
18.75
6.34
0.449
Tanzania Breweries Ltd Dar Brew Ltd Friendship Textile Kimara Slaughter – Slab 2 Kimara Slaughter – Slab 3 Kimara Slaughter – Slab 4 Subtotal Source: Mgana et al., 1997.
Table 10.14 Sample of industries discharging liquid wastes into Msimbazi stream through Vingunguti ponds, Dar es Salaam Pollution loads (t yr–1)
Industry BOD0 ALUCO Ltd PIPECO Ltd GALCO Ltd STEELCO Ltd Steel Cast Ltd Vingunguti Abattoir
Oil
N
P
Cr
Zn
Fe
0.2 0.8
0.2 0.6
0.1 0.3
1.9
2.6
29.9
0.7
23.2 92.8 276.9 6.5 0.9
0.3
1.2
0.13
18.1
400.3
32.8
1.2
1.13
0.8
0.4
1.9
904.73
51.55
7.54
1.579
0.8
0.4
1.9
17.4
Subtotal Grand total
SS
1 239.56
Source: Mgana et al. (1997).
6.3
Point pollution sources because of mining activities
A pollution source which has to be mentioned because of its high toxical threat is gold mining. Small-scale gold mining is associated with mercury usage. The mines are found in many parts of the country, including areas around Lake Victoria. Between 1990 and 1994, the Bank of Tanzania encouraged small-scale miners to sell gold through the bank by providing them mercury. The Bank bought 17.8 tons of gold during that period (Bank of Tanzania, 1997). It takes two parts by weight of mercury to produce one part by weight of gold.
Table 10.15
Sample of stationary and mobile air emissions, Dar es Salaam region Pollution loads (t yr–1) TSP
A1: Stationary sources, industry Tiper Tanganyika Tegry Simba Plastic Ltd Berger Paints Ltd BANKO Products Ltd Ubungo Spinning Organic Chemicals Ltd Galasy Ltd Sadolins Ltd Kioo Ltd Kibo Paper Mill Kiuta (NCP) Aluco Tanzania Brew Com. Ltd Dar-Brew Con. Ltd Ubungo Garments Tanzania Fishnet Tanzania Portland Cement Ltd Ubungo Power Station Steel Cast DSM Agricultural Activities
12.4 36.5 11.1 0.7 0.6 2 185.1 8.73 124.2 3 038
Subtotal
5 569.3836
0.2 0.0036 1.14 4.95 6.31 1.3 2.28 0.37 6.6 23.6 105.3
SO 5.7
44.4 4.1
NO 1.6
CO
VOC 0.4
HC
0.25 0.0021 0.498 98.96 126.2 4.3 0.6 9.8 2.8 6.0 400.00
98.6
H 2S
Pb SO3 0.1
7.0
11.4 3.5
323.0 245.8 8.1
631.1
323.0 118.2
541.4
26.9 1 313 15 714 17 054.3
9.7 5.8 1 672.2 2 346.2101
7
5.8
0.1 257
258
Table 10.15
(continued) Pollution loads (t yr–1) TSP
SO
A2: Stationary sources domestic combustion Kerosine 19.8 LPG 0.4 Charcoal Manufacturing 77 780.9
11.0 0.04
Charcoal
46.8
3 275
CO
VOC
142.8 12.6 7 017.8
39.0 2.6 100 588.9
1.9 0.2 91 816.6
397.7
198 83.8
10 058.96
7 570.9
120 514.3
Subtotal B: Mobile sources Land transport
81 076.1 581.6
813.8
3 216.3
16 757.5
2 265.4
Grand total
87 227.1
1 502.7
11 328.6
154 327.3
106 489.2
Source: Mgana et al. (1997).
57.84
NO
H2S
HC
Pb SO3
0.2
101 877
0.2 37.3 7.0
43.1
0.2
0.1
Industry and Environment 259 Table 10.16
Sample of stationary and mobile air emissions Tanga municipal Pollution loads (t yr–1) TSP
A1: Stationary sources industry Amboni Plastic Co. Ltd 9.8 Tanga Cement Factory 2 354.6 Wood fuels (for salt 429.8 production) Subtotal 2 794.2
SO2
NO
CO
VOC 4.4
341.7 6.1
720.2 52.2
2 609.5
1 320.1
347.8
772.4
2 609.5
1 324.5
A2: Stationary sources, domestic combustion Kerosine 4.4 2.5 LPG 0.0014 0.00016 Wood fuel 3 511.3 50.2 (domestic) Subtotal 3 515.7014 52.70016
31.9 0.05 426.4
8.7 0.0097 21 318.4
458.35
21 327.1097 10 785.0039
B: Mobile sources Land transport Grand total
52.8
69.1
253.0
6 362.7
469.6
1 483.8
23 936.6
0.4 0.0039 10 784.6
12 109.5
Source: Mgana et al. (1997).
In Tanzania, gold recovery using mercury is estimated to be about 40 per cent by weight of the total production, the rest being mined by other methods such as cyanidation or pure nuggets from reef mines. Therefore, the amount of mercury released in the environment surrounding the gold mining areas, producing 17.8 tons of gold, is about 14.3 tons. These are the official figures. Gold being sold in the black market, often in exchange for mercury, is unrecorded. It is, however, estimated to be between 50 and 70 per cent of the total sold. Thus the amount of mercury pollution is higher than that officially recorded. The first stage of mercury poisoning occurs during amalgamation. The mercury is dispersed in the slurry, containing gold particles, with bare hands to form the gold alloy known as amalgam. The amalgam is then heated in an open container to vaporise the mercury at around 400–420 °C. The mercury vapour released is even more dangerous than other forms of mercury, because of the high reactivity with the body and other living organisms. It is easily absorbed by the body through the human skin and also inhaled through the respiratory tract. The rest of the mercury finds its way to animal and plant life as well as marine life, since panning is done near the rivers or dams. The study of mercury levels in humans in mining areas near Lake Victoria has shown that urinary mercury levels of those frequently exposed to mercury vapours when heating mercury–gold amalgam were quite high (mean 241 ng ml –1) compared to others not exposed to
260 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
mercury (mean 2.6 ng ml–1). Soil around the mining areas had an average mercury concentration of 3.4 ug g–1. This in contrast to the regional background concentration of 0.05–0.06 ug g –1. The study showed low mean levels of mercury in fish (8.9 ppb) in Lake Victoria. According to the WHO environmental health criteria (WHO, 1976), mercury concentrations in freshwater fish from non-polluted areas are commonly in the range of 10–100 ppb.
7
Conclusions
This paper proposes techniques for rapid environmental assessment of sources of water pollution. The suggested methodology elaborates on generally applied rapid assessment guidelines. Incorporation of penetration factors in the methodology not only refines the assessment, but also provides information on the current and potential reduction of total waste loads by domestic and natural treatment processes. By presenting the results of a basic error analysis, insight is given into the reliability of the results. The scarcity of information on (industrial) pollution intensities and treatment efficiencies, typical for developing economies, still generates major uncertainty that can only be overcome by multiple-year monitoring schemes. The Lake Victoria case study determines the main sources of organic pollution of this largest of African lakes. Oxygen demanding waste loads (BOD5) are highest on the Kenyan side of the lake, it being the most densely populated industrialized part of the catchment area. Industrial BOD loads create local problems, but their overall contribution is subordinate to domestic loads. The contribution to the total nutrient input of direct rainfall over the lake is surprisingly high. This outcome corresponds to the observed increases in chlorophyll-a concentration and algal blooms during rainy seasons, which can only partly be linked to a nutrient upsurge from sediments (Ochumba and Kibaara, 1989). The highest uncertainty in the overall nutrient balance relates to the uncertainty with respect to the land-use nutrient-export coefficients and average rainwater concentrations. The verification of the nutrient loads through the application of a simple nutrient-mixing model results in loading estimates only about 15 per cent below the most likely rapid assessment results. This close proximation enhances the reliability of the results of our rapid assessment estimations. The rapid assessment based on the national census shows that the instrument yields very valuable information, even though the results of this assessment have to be used with care since the data of the census are questionable. The results of the analyses are robust enough to justify the conclusions that the most important subsectors to include in a environmental policy concerning the Tanzanian industry are the paper/paper products/
Industry and Environment 261
printing/publishing sector for organic pollution and the food and furniture sectors for their contribution to the eutrophication problem. An interesting outcome of the case study is that an environmental policy directed at reducing nutrient loading, in order to eradicate eutrophication, should not concentrate on domestic liquid waste reduction. Rather, policies should be developed to reduce the leaching of nutrients from agricultural land (for example, the introduction of improved manure management and enhanced farm systems). Also, the exact causes for the observed high concentrations of nutrients in rainwater should be investigated (for example, forest and biomass burning, volatilization of N compounds in manure and wind erosion), and policies should be directed to counteract these. Although uncertainties remain, the outcome of the rapid assessment methodology has proven very useful. Also, the introduction of a basic error analysis, and several verification steps, has increased the method’s credibility. In order to further reduce the probability interval, several steps in the methodology should be investigated. In the case of Lake Victoria, research on waste loads from pit latrines and septic tanks, on run-off and leaching of nutrients from different types of cultivated and non-cultivated land, and on nutrient concentrations in rainwater would be the major focal points. Also, the evaluation of some other potential nutrient sources, such as that of dry deposition and nitrogen fixation by cyanobacteria, could be introduced. Especially the latter should be considered for the case of Lake Victoria, where algal blooms of cyanobacteria occur frequently, introducing a large potential source of nutrient input. Further evaluation would, however, require more advanced modelling techniques, incorporating also other nutrient processes such as nitrification and denitrification. However, such would be outside the scope of rapid assessment studies in general. Available data for industries in Dar es Salaam and Tanga justify the conclusion that urban industry contributes considerably to pollution. Gold mining is an important and dangerous source of point pollution.
Notes *
Centre for Technology for Sustainable Development, Eindhoven University of Technology ** UNIDO, Côte d’Ivoire *** Environmental Association of Tanzania 1. The settling velocity is calculated by applying: VSA = rS*SA/CA. The average values for the sedimentation rate rS (g m–2 yr–1) and the concentration of nutrient A in the sediment SA (mg g–1) (for both N and P) were taken from Hecky (1993).
11 Energy Conservation in the Industrial Sector in Tanzania Frank van der Vleuten*, Lex Lemmens**, Otto Bos***, Caspar Samplonius***, Dick Toussaint*** and Michel Yhdego****
1
Introduction
The Energy Policy of Tanzania (MWEM, 1992) clearly specifies the important role energy plays in the development process: ‘Energy is a prerequisite for the proper functioning of nearly all subsectors of the economy. It is an essential service whose availability and quality can determine the success or failure of development endeavors’ (par. 2). ‘There cannot be sustainable development and the satisfaction of basic needs of society without sufficient and efficient supply and use of energy’ (par. 26). Since Tanzania does not (yet) have at its disposal many indigenous energy sources, the use of energy, however, is a heavy burden on the balance of payments and thus on the national economy as a whole. While the long-term strategy of the National Energy Policy is the reduction of dependence on external energy sources and the exploration and rational management and utilisation of the country’s own resources, the short- and medium-term strategies include, among others, more efficient use of energy in the transport and industry sector. The Tanzanian industrial sector offers ample scope for energy efficiency improvement, in particular in case studies involving the cement and beer industries. However, in general opportunities have also been identified to ‘leapfrog’ to a cleaner production path, where industrial development can be better tuned to the available resources and the natural environment. This contribution discusses the energy dimension of the industrial sector of Tanzania and shows where and how energy efficiency can be enhanced.
2
Case for energy conservation in the industrial sector
The National Energy Policy of Tanzania recognizes the importance of energy conservation and mentions more efficient use of energy in the industrial sector as one of the main short- and medium-term strategies (MWEM, 1992). In the industry sector, a major policy objective of the 262
Energy Conservation in Industry 263
National Energy Policy is the progressive reduction of dependence on imported petroleum products. There are, however, more reasons to conserve energy: •
•
•
•
•
3
Reducing the cost of energy by conservation provides an attractive economic option at the macroeconomic level. For Tanzania as a whole, the cost of energy conservation may very well be significantly lower than the cost of energy production. In terms of delivering energy services for economic development in a cost-effective way, energy conservation may well be able to compete with the chain of energy production, conversion and distribution. At the company level, energy conservation may offer a viable investment opportunity. Pay-back times for such investments have been found to be as short as three to six months. This was confirmed by a preinvestment study addressing the industrial energy conservation potential, implemented by Environmental Resource Consultants in Dar es Salaam (van der Vleuten, 1995). In several other countries, investments in energy-efficient technology have been found to have additional benefits in production efficiency, production quality or volume. In many industries energy conservation is one of the priorities to attain cleaner production. This includes reducing environmental impact from direct energy use within the industry – CO 2, dust, NOx, SO2, etc. – as well as reducing emissions from energy production in, for example, power generation. Although anthropogenic emissions of greenhouse gases in Tanzania are relatively small, when compared to the emissions of more industrialized societies, the country offers an attractive potential for climate change mitigation. The Framework Convention on Climate Change (FCCC) emphasizes that international cooperation should be promoted in order to prevent climate change in the most cost-effective way. Cleaner production technology programmes within industry present the opportunity of a win–win situation in which greenhouse gas emissions are reduced in a cost-effective way. By enhancing the efficiency of the technology used in industrial processes and stationary combustion systems, the industrial sector of Tanzania can attract foreign investments. The Kyoto protocol to the FCCC includes this option under the Clean Development Mechanism.
Energy conservation in practice
The central concept of industrial energy conservation is to reduce the quantity of energy needed to produce a certain industrial output. Energy conservation necessarily takes into account the whole energy system:
264 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
energy sources, energy carriers (or fuels) and conversion technologies. The efficiency of the energy system should be enhanced in such a way that the same energy service can be supplied with less primary energy source/fuel, or that more energy services can be supplied with the same quantity of fuel. The cement industry, which will be discussed in more detail in Section 5, illustrates the various approaches towards energy efficiency. Table 11.1 presents the figures for an average cement plant in Africa (van der Vleuten, 1995). The cement industry is one of the most widespread energy-intensive industries in Africa. For the production of cement, raw materials are ground and burned in a kiln to produce clinker. The clinker is ground with gypsum, and occasionally other additives, to produce cement. The consumption of primary heat to produce one ton of cement not only depends on the efficiency of the technology and the management of the clinker manufacturing process, but also on the quantity of clinker used to produce cement. This illustrates that the energy and the materials used in production have strong interactions. From Table 11.1 it is apparent that: • significant energy saving can be achieved by better process management and good housekeeping without significant cost • energy efficiency of a cement plant not only depends on the energy efficiency of the kiln, but to a large extent on the materials used in grinding; this underlines that material efficiency (of energy-intensive materials) can be very important to attain energy efficiency.
Table 11.1 Primary heat
Heat efficiency in cement production
4200 MJ
3600 MJ
3600 MJ
3000 MJ
Clinker Technology
Typical dry
Efficient management
Efficient management
State-ofthe-art process
Product
1 t clinker
1 t clinker
1 t clinker
1 t clinker
Additives
5% gypsum
5% gypsum
5% gypsum, 30% fly ash
5% gypsum
Product
1.05 t cement
1.05 t cement
1.35 t cement
1.05 t cement
Process efficiency
4 000 MJ/t cement
3 429 MJ/t cement 2 667 MJ/t cement 2 857 MJ/t cement
Added costs
Baseline
Very low
Operational
Investment
Energy Conservation in Industry 265
In view of the strong case for energy conservation, it is surprising that it gets almost no attention in the industrial sector in Tanzania, particularly since studies have shown that a substantial saving potential exists in technically and economically viable projects. The first efforts to increase energy efficiency in Tanzanian industry, based on technical energy audits, date back to 1982. At present more than 70 firms have been audited by the Tanzanian Industrial Research and Development Organization (TIRDO) (Tarimo, 1995). Generally the audits were performed by outside experts who made recommendations to the management of the companies concerned. Apart from five industries that requested self-funded audits, all audits were financed by international donors. The various audits showed a vast potential for energy conservation, and TIRDO estimated the overall energy conservation potential at 30 per cent of industrial consumption. Despite the forecasts of good economic returns, however, very few companies have been able to implement the recommendations (Mwandosya and Luhanga, 1993). To analyse why Tanzanian industry has not yet capitalized on the vast potential for energy conservation, two case studies are discussed: the beer and the cement industry.
4 4.1
Beer industry Tanzania Breweries Limited
Owned by East African Breweries and under British management, the Dar es Salaam brewery was established in 1933. In 1966 a new brewery was commissioned on the same site. East African Breweries was nationalized in 1970 and became part of Tanzania Breweries Ltd. The capacity of the brewing and bottling facilities of the Dar es Salaam plant were increased in 1984 and 1991. Starting in the 1980s, however, the production process gradually deteriorated because old equipment was not replaced in time, and maintenance was insufficient. In the early 1990s the management started looking for a foreign partner. In November 1993 this partner was found in Indol International Holding, a Dutch investment organisation owning South Africa Breweries (SAB). SAB became directly involved in the management of Tanzania Breweries Ltd (TBL). The energy situation at TBL is analysed at the end of 1993, when the new management came in. 4.2
Energy efficiency at Tanzanian Breweries Limited
A general impression of the energy efficiency of the brewery can be obtained by looking at the overall specific energy consumption and comparing the results with performances in other breweries. Table 11.2 shows the specific energy consumption: the consumption of fuel oil and electricity per hectolitre (hl) of beer in 1992 and 1993. Since water consumption is related to energy consumption too, it is included in the table. The table
266 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Table 11.2
Specific fuel oil, electricity and water consumption at TBL 1992
1993
Fuel oil l/hl brewed beer l/hl bottled beer l/hl sold beer
8.0 10.5 11.0
8.8 9.4 10.1
Electricity KWh/hl brewed beer KWh/hl bottled beer KWh/hl sold beer
23.1 30.4 31.6
27.4 28.9 31.4
Water hl/hl brewed beer hl/hl bottled beer hl/hl sold beer
34.9 46.1 47.5
44.8 47.4 51.2
shows large differences in specific energy and water consumption between brewed, bottled and sold beer, implying significant losses in the production process. In Table 11.3 the specific energy consumption of TBL (1993) is compared with that of other breweries. TBL apparently consumes much more energy than the reference breweries. It should be taken into account, however, that TBL operates in a warmer climate than the European breweries listed. This implies that more energy, mostly electricity, has to be used for cooling. On the other hand, the total time cooling is needed – during fermentation and conditioning – is shorter. At TBL total cooling time is about 24 days per batch of beer. For most of the European breweries the cooling time is 4 to 12 weeks. From Table 11.3 it is obvious that TBL uses too much energy and water. The causes, and thus the possibilities for improvement, are analysed in the following paragraphs. First, however, an impression is given of the economic importance for energy efficiency improvement at the plant. 4.3
Energy costs
The importance of controlling energy costs is illustrated by looking at these costs as a percentage of total costs. Table 11.4 shows that the so-called semi-fixed costs (electricity, fuel oil, water, refrigeration and steam) add up to 21.6 per cent of the total direct production costs. If energy costs at TBL could be reduced by 30 per cent (including costs for water), direct production costs would drop by 6 per cent. Another way of assessing the importance of energy-cost reduction is the effect on the profitability of the company. In order to include all costs, including overheads at the TBL head office, the results are calculated for all
Table 11.3 Brewery
TBL (1993) Germany Germany Germany Ireland Turkey
Specific energy and water consumption at TBL compared to reference breweries Beer output (hl/year)
300 000 155 000 100–500 000 100–250 000 361 000 865 000
Specific fuel oil consumption (l/hl beer) 10.1 5.3 3.2 5.3 6.2 4.4
Specific electricity consumption (kWh/hl beer) 31.4 11.3 10.3 13.2 11.7 9.0
Specific total energy consumption (MJ/hl beer) 579 257 168 264 296 212
Specific water consumption (hl/hl beer) 51.2 – 6.5 8.5 – –
Sources: Ehrhorn (1982); Schu (1990); TIRDO (1990); Mayer (1992).
267
268 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Table 11.4 Cost attribution of direct production costs per crate of beer (TBL, 1994) Cost attribution Brewing materials Bottling materials Direct labour Semi-fixed costs Electricity Fuel oil Water Steam/refrigeration Repair & maintenance Total direct costs
TSh (1994)
%
692 269 36 297 113 103 62 18 82
50.3 19.6 2.6 21.6 8.2 7.5 4.5 1.3 6.0
1 377
100.0
subsidiaries of TBL rather than for the Dar es Salaam branch only. Table 11.5 shows that a net reduction of energy costs of 30 per cent causes a gross profit increase of 43 per cent. It is interesting to compare the specific energy costs of TBL with those of Western breweries. The average specific energy consumption and costs for German breweries in 1991 are used as a benchmark (Mayer, 1992). These breweries had a production between 100 000 and 500 000 hl per year. The specific energy consumption is based on 1993 figures, but to get a more upto-date profile energy prices of January 1994 are used. Figure 11.1a shows that specific energy costs for TBL exceed those of Western breweries by a factor of two. Energy prices for the reference breweries, however, are higher, and when this is accounted for the energy costs of TBL exceed those of Western breweries by a factor four. See Figure 11.1b. All this shows that the reduction of energy use by conservation is important from a financial point of view. 4.4
Energy conservation opportunities
A systematic inventory was made of direct and indirect factors affecting the energy use (Toussaint, 1994) and thus the energy costs. The factors with Table 11.5 Effect of cost reduction by energy conservation on value added and gross profit (TBL, 1994) Cost reduction by energy conservation (%) 10 20 30
Increase of value added (%) 2 4 6
Increase of gross profit (%) 14 29 43
Energy Conservation in Industry 269 Figure 11.1
Specific energy costs at TBL in comparison with Western breweries
Western brewery US$ 3.1/hl
extra at TBL + US$ 3.5/hl
a: at equal energy prices
Western brewery US$ 3.1/hl extra at TBL + US$ 8.7/hl b: at equal energy prices
the highest potential, expressed in high profitability, low investment requirements and a relatively small foreign currency need, were analysed. A review of these most important energy conservation opportunities (ECOs), together with their financial indicators (when available), is presented in Table 11.6. It is obvious that increasing the capacity utilization and decreasing the production losses are the most promising options for saving energy. Apart from these two ECOs the total energy-cost savings of the other opportunities could add up to 300 million TSh (US$590 000). This is an energy cost reduction of 1000 TSh per hectolitre, which equals a 30 per cent reduction. All measures together could reduce specific energy costs by around 50 per cent. Not all implementation costs and pay-back periods could be assessed. For the measures for which costs could be assessed, the average pay-back period is two months. The average foreign currency component of quantified costs is about 75 per cent. This percentage is quite high, but foreign-currency requirements as a percentage of total energy-cost savings is as low as 13 per cent. 4.5
Causes of energy inefficiency
The energy conservation opportunities are, in a way, also indicative of the problems at the Dar es Salaam brewery. Productivity has obviously been very low at TBL. In 1993 the Dar es Salaam plant produced about 300 000 hectolitres with 950 employees. A typical Dutch brewery, with a comparable production process, produces about 3.5 million hectolitres with 650 employees. One of the reasons for the inefficiency is a problem with the bottling lines. Two new bottling lines were installed at the end of 1991. Since their installation they never reached their expected output. Though they were bought as new, it was suspected that they were second-hand. Many breakdowns occurred, which delayed production seriously. Besides, the new lines consumed more water than the old ones. All this coincided with raw water supply shortages, resulting in even more production stops. Also, electricity power cuts decreased the beer output.
270
Table 11.6
Overview of quantified feasible energy conservation opportunities
Energy conservation opportunities 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19
Capacity utilization increase Switch off air cooling of rooms if not in use Mothballing old vertical fermenters Air cooling load reduction Decrease of production losses 16% to 8% Tightening leaks in refrigeration system Improvement of power factor Insulation of water pipe lines and tanks Water reuse in bottling hall Improvement of compressed air system Water from Wort cooling also to mash water tank Insulation of refrigeration piping Improvement of load factor transformers Removal of heat exchanger fermentation room 1 Improvement of water supply Wort cooler Condensate return mash vessel Tightening steam leaks Insulation steam pipe lines Insulation condensate pipe lines
Savings (000 TSh per year) 169 000 000 32 000 8 000 95 000 37 600 000 48 000 21 400 14 800 18 000 16 300 12 400 8 600 8 900 7 900 6 700 835 120/mm2 2 200 2 720
Costs (000 TSh) – 0 0 p.m. p.m. p.m. – 1 700 3 000 3 300 210 600 3 000 ? 680 220 20/mm2 4 000 5 420
Foreign currency required (% of costs) – 0 0 0 p.m. 0 100 100 20 30 50 100 100 0 65 70 0 100 100
Payback period – 0 0 – – – – 1 month 2 months 3 months <1 month 4 months 4 months ? 1 month 3 months 2 months 2 years 2 years
Energy Conservation in Industry 271
The brewing section had other problems. The refrigeration system was not able to keep all sections at the prescribed temperature. The main reasons were old age and bad maintenance of the refrigeration system. In particular, the compressors often broke down. Other problems related more to the performance quality. Filled bottles often contained too much air, reducing the shelf life of the beer and hence provoking customer complaints. Improvements requiring investments were often not possible because of a continuous liquidity problem. In addition, as can be seen in Table 11.2, beer disappeared during the production process. The conclusion with respect to this case study is that energy is an inherent aspect of the functioning of the entire plant. Energy use is closely linked to use and handling of water, steam and the product. The waste of energy in the brewery can, therefore, be largely attributed to the performance of the management. The major improvements that took place soon after South African Brewers took over the management support this conclusion (see also Chapter 15).
5 5.1
Cement industry Tanzania Portland Cement Corporation Limited
Until 1966 Tanzania imported all its cement. In 1959 the Tanzania Portland Cement Company Ltd (TPCC) was registered with the objective of importing bulk cement, and bagging it at its Malindi Packing Plant. This plant was situated at the Dar es Salaam harbour. In 1962 the Tanzanian government empowered the TPCC to put up a cement plant of its own. Subsequently, the first cement factory was constructed at Wazo Hill, some 20 km north of Dar es Salaam. Production started in 1966. The plant was owned and managed by Cementia Holding AG in Switzerland. It had one kiln with a production of 50 000 tons per year (tpy) in 1966 (Figure 11.2). This increased to 177 500 tpy in 1971. On the basis of a forecasted increase in the demand for cement, a second kiln was installed in 1972, increasing the production capacity to 270 000 tpy. In 1973 the Tanzanian government took over the ownership of the plant and transferred it to the State Mining Corporation. The Cementia management experts withdrew in 1973. The management of the plant was taken over by Indian expatriates. At the same time the international and thus national economic situation changed drastically, affecting also the foreign exchange availability for the TPCC. As a result, it became harder to buy spare parts and consumables. The capacity utilization started to drop, and by 1979 had reached 76 per cent. In 1979 a third kiln was added and the production capacity increased to 520 000 tpy. In 1980 the requirements with respect to foreign exchange for capital goods replacement, spares and consumables were around US$2.5–3.0 million per year. Hardly half of this amount was available
272 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Figure 11.2
Cement production of TPCC, 1966–1993 Total cement production 1966–1993
tonnes as ( x1000)
500 400 300 200 100 0 66
68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92 67 69 71 73 75 77 79 81 83 85 87 89 91 93
through the Bank of Tanzania and the aid from the Danish development organization DANIDA. Performance consequently dropped to 55 per cent of the rated capacity and further to 26 per cent in 1983. Early in 1983 the last installed kiln (kiln 3) suffered a major breakdown. A solution for these problems was found in contracting Cementia International AB (nowadays Scancem) from Sweden and foreign exchange support from the Swedish development aid organization SIDA. The capacity utilization slowly improved to about 80 per cent in the early nineties. The present energy analysis was made during the second half of 1993. 5.2
Energy efficiency at the TPCC
In view of the history of the factory, it can best be described in three units linked to kilns 1, 2 and 3, installed in respectively 1966, 1972 and 1979. The power use in the characteristic production stages of the different units is presented in Table 11.7. With respect to the table it should be noted that the collection of information was seriously hampered by the unreliability, Table 11.7
Power use of the three units in kWh/ton cement Unit 1
Crushing Grinding Blending Burning Finish grinding Packing Overhead Total
Unit 2
Unit 3
1.8 39 1.5 24 44 1.6 1.4
1.8 22 1.5 17 25 1.6 1.4
1.8 36 1.5 27 38 1.6 1.4
113.3
70.3
107.3
Energy Conservation in Industry 273
sometimes even absence, of kilowatt-hour meters. Therefore, the figures in Table 11.7 are not suitable for detailed conclusions. What can be concluded, however, is that unit 2 is performing much better than the other two. This can be explained by the fact that the mills of unit 2 were overhauled only a few years ago. Grinding and burning are using most of the energy. The analysis of the grinding stage is rather straightforward. The assessment of the burning stage needs a heat balance for the kiln. By combining production data and our own measurements, the heat balance for each kiln is calculated. The results are compared with the data of two reference kilns from the literature in Table 11.8 (Samplonius, 1994). From Table 11.8 it is clear that most significant heat losses occur in the pyro-processing department. The heat losses consist of exhaust gases leaving the system, radiation and convection losses, and the heat content of the clinker when leaving the system. The loss of heat in exhaust gases is Table 11.8 The heat balance for the kilns compared to two reference kilns in kJ/kg clinker Kiln 1
Kiln 2
Kiln 3
Reference kiln 1
Reference kiln 2
21 4 396
20 4 208
21 4 360
13 3 150
14 3 050
116 2
116 2
116 2
54 –
92 –
5
5
5
6
8
Total input
4 540
4 351
4 504
3 223
3 164
Output Heat of formation Evaporation of water from raw meal Exhaust gas sensible heat Dust sensible heat Incomplete combustion Clinker sensible heat Cooler exhaust gases Losses radiation & conv. kiln Losses radiation & conv. cooler Losses radiation & conv. Pre-heater Rest
1 750 12 1 854 – – 62 – 862 – –
1 750 12 1 295 23 – 62 0 903 65 241
1 750 12 1 353 23 – 62 0 759 62 483
1 750 13 636 18 – 63 423 297
1 789 17 595
Total output
4 540
Input Fuel From sensible heat From combustion Raw meal From sensible heat From sensible heat of water Combustion air From sensible heat of primary air
520 243
23 4 351
4 504
3 223
3 164
274 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
by a factor of two higher than in the reference kilns. The losses through radiation and convection are two to three times higher. The heat remaining in the clinker is comparable for all kilns. The reference kilns are a kiln with a four-stage pre-heater and a grate cooler with a capacity of 2000– 3000 tpd (tons per day) and a kiln with a four-stage pre-heater, a precalciner and a grate cooler with a capacity of 2800 tpd. The difference in size of these reference kilns, compared to those of the TPCC, accounts for part of the difference in radiation and convection losses. However, considerable savings can be expected from reducing heat losses in this part of the cement production process. In the course of processing, the factory loses energy. Much more energy is lost when cement production has to be interrupted. Whenever the kiln has to be shut down, heat is wasted in the product since this has to be rejected because it has not gone through the whole process. In addition heat is wasted in starting the process up again. Production will remain low until temperatures throughout the whole system are brought up to normal. It takes from thirty minutes to several hours to balance the system after an interruption. Factors that cause kiln interruption can be internal or external. For the TPCC, which gets its power from TANESCO, the external factor which causes interruption is power supply. These power interruptions affect not only energy efficiency but also production capacity use. In 1993 the kilns were down for about 600 hours because of power failure or power reduction, which accounted for the major part of the inefficiency. Internal factors that cause interruptions are unplanned maintenance and lack of raw materials. These were not so important, but since they can be directly affected by the management they provide important energy-saving opportunities. In Table 11.9 the most important reasons for unplanned stops (except power cuts) are presented. 5.3
Energy costs
Also in Tanzania, controlling energy costs is a major issue in the cement industry. This can be seen from Table 11.10, which indicates that 46 per cent of the total costs of the TPCC are energy costs. If one considers the part energy costs play in the actual production process (Table 11.11), the importance of energy savings becomes even clearer. Table 11.9
Unplanned interruptions in 1993 (except power cuts)
Loss of feed Cyclone blockage Waste gas fan tripped
Kiln 1
Kiln 2
Kiln 3
8 6 3
7 8 8
8 5 4
Energy Conservation in Industry 275 Table 11.10
Breakdown of costs of TPCC (million TSh)
Personnel Electricity Fuel oil Diesel, petrol, lubricants Paper bags Gypsum Maintenance Interest Local freight Export freight Fees Other
1 180 2 020 3 050 260 780 480 500 100 860 470 610 1 150
Total
10.3% 17.6% 26.6% 2.2% 6.8% 4.2% 4.4% 0.9% 7.5% 4.1% 5.3% 10.0%
11 460
Table 11.11
Breakdown of TPCC production costs (million TSh) Mines
Raw mill
Kiln
Cement mill
Packing plant
Total
Production costs Fixed costs Variable costs
805 530 275
1 240 280 960
4 040 455 3 585
1 320 265 1 055
1 085 260 825
8 490 1 790 6 700
Variable costs: Energy costs Other
175 100
920 40
3 340 155
550 505
45 780
5 030 1 580
Direct manufacturing costs in 1992 amounted to 8940 million TSh. The fixed costs were 1790 million TSh and the variable costs 6700 million TSh. The variable costs consisted for the larger part of energy costs: 76 per cent. The main production costs were made in the kiln section and consisted for the largest part of energy costs. It is clear that an energy saving of a few percent would already make an important contribution to the improvement of the economic performance of the TPCC. 5.4 5.4.1
Energy conservation opportunities Individual power station
The major problems of the TPCC consist of power cuts. To reduce unplanned kiln interruptions it is almost essential to acquire an individual power station. The reported 600 hours’ down time because of electricity problems can be converted to a production loss of 10 500 tons of cement or 155 million Tsh (Samplonius, 1994). The extra fuel, which is needed for the start-ups, costs an additional 122 million Tsh. An individual power
276 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
plant of 6 MWh would cost 1500 million Tsh. The anticipated pay-back period is five years. In view of the high energy prices of TANESCO, an additional advantage could be a lower kWh price for the self-generated electricity. 5.4.2
New measurement systems for the kiln
Fuel combustion systems in the kiln are major contributors to energy inefficiency and refractory damage. All three kilns have defective meters, of which the gas analysers are essential to control the kiln. With new measuring equipment an energy saving of 20 per cent would be easily feasible. The savings in one year would be 320 million Tsh, many times the investment needed. 5.4.3
Reduction of radiation and convection losses
To counteract the radiation and convection losses, insulation bricks can be used. The expected energy savings would be 122 million Tsh. The costs for the bricks would be 80 million Tsh. Taking into account the labour costs, the pay-back period for this measure would be close to one year. 5.4.4
Replacing electrostatic filters
The cement factory emits enormous quantities of dust through the exhaust pipes of the kilns. For kiln 3, the emission is estimated at 2.2 tons per hour. The other two kilns add another ton per hour to this discharge. Dust is neither crushed raw material nor clinker, but it has a value since it has been mined, crushed, milled and partly burned. If the value of crushed raw material is used to estimate the losses, the missed proceeds are at least 40 million Tsh per year. The costs for replacement or reparation of the electrostatic filters could not be assessed, but the pay-back period will not exceed a couple of years. Stopping the dust emissions is necessary in the first place because of the environmental pollution. 5.4.5
Long-term options
Since early 1970, more and more cement factories have had a pre-calciner. The essential factor of a pre-calcining process is the addition of a separate combustion chamber to a conventional pre-heater. The main accomplishment of the pre-calciner is to provide direct heat in the most effective manner possible where it is most needed: in the calcining stage of the clinker production process. Pre-calciners increase the production capacity of an existing kiln by a factor of two. They increase refractory life, reduce the production of NOx and make it possible to replace part of the energy input by waste fuels. The investment is considerable and the layout of an existing factory needs to be changed. However, the expectation is that for the TPCC the installation of a pre-calciner is financially viable.
Energy Conservation in Industry 277
5.5
Causes of energy inefficiency
The energy conservation opportunities presented in the last section already indicate that there are three major reasons for the energy inefficiency at the TPCC. First and foremost the basic instruments and management structure necessary to run the plant in an optimal way are not present. Better maintenance and a better attitude of the staff towards the use of energy would also increase efficiency. The technology used for processing is the second reason for energy losses. There is a need for the replacement and introduction of modern equipment. An important external reason is the dependence on an unreliable electricity supply by TANESCO, which is causing many kiln interruptions, with the reported consequences. The reasons for the lack of implementation of new technologies and the poor operation and maintenance are both internal and external. These reasons coincide with those for general inefficiency of public enterprises. The lack of foreign currency in the country is the major bottleneck to implement even those measures that have a very short pay-back period.
6
Conclusions
Both cases confirm the high potential for energy conservation suggested by earlier energy audits in Tanzania. Both in energy-intensive industries and less energy-intensive plants, energy conservation presents an opportunity to enhance the profits of the industry, to improve the manufacturing process and to improve the environmental performance. At the technical level, the main constraints with respect to more energyefficient industrial operations include the following: Poor plant management results in inefficient operation and poor maintenance of the present production technology. In addition, underutilisation of the production capacity causes a relatively high energy intensity of the production. • Production technology is generally relatively old and inefficient. Many cost-effective and indeed highly profitable energy conservation options exist. As a result of limited access to investment capital, the plants cannot capitalize on these opportunities. This results in a missed opportunity to enhance the energy efficiency and the profitability of the plant. • The energy infrastructure poses a serious obstacle to industrial development, especially for industries where energy is a crucial input. This is clearly illustrated by the case study in the cement sector, where unreliable power supply is a main obstacle on the road towards a stable, that is, energy-efficient and profitable, operation of the plant. •
278 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
The case studies illustrate that energy conservation demands an institutional structure that supports improved operations and investments in energy efficiency. Such a structure should include a mechanism of incentives for all people involved in production. The studies show that the inefficiency of energy use is, apart from the technical reasons mentioned, to a large extent a management issue. This explains why the vast potential for profitable energy conservation, as identified by previous audits, has hardly been exploited.
7
What can be done?
The previous outcomes of energy audits, as well as the case studies, underline the large potential for financially and environmentally profitable investments in energy efficiency existing in the industrial sector in Tanzania. This potential can be seen as a resource, the exploitation of which is in line with the sustainable development of Tanzania. 7.1
What can industries do?
The conclusions suggest that energy conservation should not start from investments in technical measures. Rather, the first point of attention should be to develop the management capacity and to put into place the incentives needed to enhance the efficiency of present operations, and to make use of the economies of scale offered by a full-capacity utilization. This is not to say that energy conservation can only take place after a full restructuring of the management of a plant has taken place. On the contrary, energy conservation may be a vehicle for enhancing the efficiency of a production plant, by primarily focusing on the efficiency of this crucial input to all phases of the production process. A first priority would then be to establish a functional unit within the institutional setting of a production plant that has the mandate and the capacity to enhance energy efficiency throughout the plant. This means that capacity building of sufficient staff is very important. Furthermore, the staff should receive the mandate and support of the plant management to identify, implement and evaluate changes to the operation. In this way, a sufficient energy-efficiency improvement can be achieved, mainly from better operation and maintenance. In the second stage, the industry should then focus on the identification of investment opportunities in energy conservation. Using an analysis of the energy flows, as well as the material flows of the production system, the plant management should identify the most attractive investment options in terms of profitability of the investment, contribution to energy efficiency and contribution to the total plant efficiency. The plant management should allocate an internal budget for low investment options. For high investment options, external investment capital sources have to be identified and developed.
Energy Conservation in Industry 279
7.2
What can policy makers do?
Policy makers have a variety of economic and environmental interests to promote industrial energy efficiency. Although the prime capacity for enhancing industrial energy efficiency in Tanzania lies with the management of the production plants, policy makers can certainly stimulate this process. In line with the priorities for industry, the following elements are suggested for a government policy on energy conservation: 1. The first is to create awareness with respect to the benefits of energy conservation. As a main target group, the production plant management should be involved in discussions on the benefits and costs of energy conservation, both from the perspective of the public interest and the perspective of the production itself. In this way, the right priorities can be set for the further cooperation between the public and the private sector (or semi-public sector) to attain higher energy efficiency. 2. The second aspect in which the government should have a role to play is the stimulation of capacity building of the people that have been empowered to implement the energy conservation programme within a production plant. This step should build on the experience that has been gained with the CEPITA (Cleaner Environment Production in Industry in Tanzania) cleaner production project in Tanzania. 3. A third aspect in which policy makers have a role to play is in stimulating the development of financial channels for industries to be able to access capital for investments in energy efficiency. To allow for effective financial channels, this should primarily focus on increasing the accessibility of already present financial institutions. In addition, policy makers should contribute to setting up new financial arrangements, such as an energy-efficiency revolving fund. 4. It is important to notice that foreign funding of an energy conservation programme may be very welcome in view of highly limited government resources. Policy makers should play a role here by enhancing cooperation with non-governmental organisations and by taking the initiative to acquire funding for this type of project. The climate change mitigation and technology transfer programmes (such as Activities Implemented Jointly and the Clean Development Mechanism) are very suitable instruments for this. If industry and policy makers succeed in developing an approach to energy conservation based on the elements of empowerment, capacity building and technology investments, industrial energy conservation offers a win–win–win situation. It will increase the economic and financial performance of the industrial sector, lower the dependence on expensive external energy sources and enhance environmental performance. Energy
280 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
conservation can be an important element in the sustainable development of the industrial sector of Tanzania.
Notes * Free Energy Europe ** Centre for Sustainable Development, Einhoven University of Technolog *** Section of Technology and Development Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology **** Environmental Resource Consultants, Dar es Salaam
Part IV Lessons from Past Experiences, Economic Reform, Prospects for the Future
This page intentionally left blank
12 Industrialization of Tanzania: Can Tanzania Learn from European History? Paul Lapperre*
1
Industrialization in historical perspective
Industrialization refers to the course of transition from a preceding dominantly agricultural society towards an industrial one. In the course of this transition large-scale industry becomes the most characteristic form of production, a form in which the simplification of work to make it better manageable (rationalization), the replacement of manual labour by that of machines (mechanization) and the shift of control, correction and feedback activities from peoples to machines (automation) become increasingly important. Rationalization, mechanization and automation usually go hand in hand with the concentration of labour in larger working units. Concurrent with the shift from agriculture towards large-scale industry, far-reaching changes take place in almost all other spheres of life (Lapperre, 1992). When Britain entered the industrial age in the late 18th century, and rationalization, mechanization and automation took hold, this heralded the end of the era of the traditional agrarian societies, societies which first came into being in the flood plains of the Euphrates and Tigris some 5000 years earlier. Although Britain was the first to make the transition, industrialization soon spread to the Continent and North America. Later, other parts of the world followed. Now, at the beginning of the 21st century, approximately one-quarter of the world’s population lives in highly industrialized societies and generally enjoys a level of material wealth and well-being never experienced in history before. Although most of the remaining three-quarters of the world’s population is affected by the industrial mode of production in one way or another, the transformation from agrarian to industrial society has been imperfect and is not, or only to a lesser extent, accompanied by a rise in material wealth and well-being. 283
284 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
2
Present industrialization worldwide
An idea of the present state of industrialization worldwide can be obtained by grouping countries, on basis of income per capita, in four categories – low-income, lower-middle-income, upper-middle-income and high-income economies – and by comparing these categories with respect to the percentages of the labour force employed in agriculture, industry and services, and the value added contribution to GDP in agriculture, industry and services (see Table 12.1). Table 12.1 shows that a rising per capita income goes hand in hand with a significant decline of the labour force in agriculture and an increase of that in industry and particularly services. When the per capita income grows, the value added percentage of GDP for agriculture declines. For industry it remains comparatively constant and for services it rises. In 1990, 47 out of 49 countries of the low-income economies employed more people in agriculture than in industry. Out of the 41 countries of the lower-middle-income and the 17 countries of the upper-middle-income economies, respectively 22 and 4 employed more people in agriculture than in industry. In all of the 26 countries of the high-income economies, the agricultural labour force was far smaller than the industrial one. Based on the labour force employed in agriculture, in 1990 a total of 73 countries were classified as dominantly agricultural and 60 as dominantly industrial. There is no reason to believe that the situation has significantly changed since.
3
Industrialization in Tanzania
The coming to power of conservative governments in many industrialized countries in the 1980s was accompanied by a free-market Table 12.1 Population, GDP per capita and economic structure for 133 countries, by income category Pop. (mil.) 1995 Low-income econ. (49) 3 180 Lower-middle income econ. (41) 1 153 Upper-middle income econ. (17) 438 High-income econ. (26) 902 Tanzania Source: World Bank (1997).
30
GDP Labor force, Value added, per cap., % (1990) % GDP (1995) US$ (1995) Agr. Ind. Ser. Agr. Ind. Ser. 290 1 670 4 260 24 000
69 36 21 5
15 27 27 31
16 37 52 64
25 13 9 2
38 36 37 32
35 49 53 66
170
84
5
11
58
17
24
Lessons from History 285
counter-revolution in economic theory and policy, a counter-revolution that drew additional credibility from the dramatic collapse of the economy of the Soviet Union and its allies. The renewed emphasis on free-market policies also led to a call for the dismantling of public ownership, central planning and excessive government regulation of economic activities in the low-income and the lower-middle-income economies. The central argument of the advocates of free-market policies was, and is, that problems encountered in the transition from agrarian to industrial society are the direct result of poor allocation of resources due to incorrect pricing policies and too much government intervention. Free-market economists insist that countries do not get bogged down in their development because of predatory actions by industrialized countries and international agencies, but because of an excess of state control, gross inefficiency, serious corruption, mismanagement and lack of economic incentives. What is needed, in their opinion, is certainly not a reform of the international economic system, a restructuring of dualistic development economies, more central planning or increased foreign assistance. Rather, it is a matter of promoting free markets and of governments creating preconditions for the ‘invisible hand’ of the market to do its work. In the mid-1980s Tanzania was forced to join the bandwagon of the freemarket counter-revolution. It adopted and implemented a series of changes in its approach to enhance economic development and speed up the transition from an agrarian to an industrial society. Now the 20th century has drawn to an end, it has become increasingly clear that the changes in economic policy have not yielded the expected results, and that the transition process is proceeding at an excruciatingly slow pace. Tanzania finds itself in the league of the 10 countries with the largest percentage of the labour force involved in agriculture. Its value added percentage of GDP for agriculture is the highest in the world. It is among the 12 countries with the smallest percentage of the labour force in industry, and among the 10 countries with the lowest value added percentage of GDP for industry. Tanzania, in other words, ranks among the least industrialized countries. There is little comfort in knowing that Tanzania shares its predicament with many other countries in sub-Saharan Africa.
4 Pre-requisites for industrialization: early European experience In order to industrialize certain prerequisites have to be met. So far, it has mainly been economists who identified and analysed the principles behind the transition from a dominantly agrarian to an industrial society, and who designed, with varying degrees of success, ‘development strategies’ for the laggards.
286 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
Using a literature survey on the early European transition, this section sets out to identify the structural and cultural prerequisites for industrialization, not only in the institutional sphere of the economy, but also in the spheres of politics, kinship and religion. In addition, education and health care are given some attention. The prerequisites found are then confronted with the prevailing structural and cultural aspects in relevant institutional spheres in contemporary Tanzania. 4.1
Politics
Achieving internal integration and external adaptation are the two fundamental functions of the institutional sphere of politics in any society, functions that can be summarized as ‘how can society, in face of a multitude of internal contradictions, conflicting interests and threats from outside, be kept together?’. Internal integration and external adaptation are achieved through system maintenance, conversion and government functions (Bertholet and Lapperre, 1991). The system maintenance function refers to aspects such as socialization, recruitment, mobility and retrenchment of the members of the political system – or, in other words, to the ways in which the allocation of positions takes place. The conversion function refers to aspects such as the articulation and aggregation of interests, and to communication. The government function refers to aspects such as rule making, rule application and rule adjudication. A number of aspects of the functions mentioned have played an important role in the transition process from agricultural to industrial society. In traditional European societies it was particularly aspects related to the allocation of positions and the articulation and aggregation of interests that hampered the transition towards an industrial society. The medieval European political system, embodied in the Three Estates (nobility, clergy and common citizens), was characterized by a relatively low social mobility. Position allocation almost exclusively took place on the basis of kinship ties: ‘one’s birth was more important than personal merits. By the end of the 18th century the political system gradually ceased to obstruct social mobility, and a new trading, commerce and manufacturing elite gained a say in the affairs of the state. In addition, be it reluctantly at first, the state also allowed alliances between various new groups active in the economic sphere (Jansen, 1991).’ The degree of political development of a society can be judged on the basis of a number of political system capacities (Lapperre, 1997). The extractive capacity of the traditional agrarian societies – the extent to which the political system is capable of mobilizing material and human resources as inputs – was relatively low. For an industrial take-off, the state has to be increasingly capable to manipulate taxes, subsidies and markets in favour of trade, commerce and industry, and to extract the necessary services. This was exactly what was achieved in a number of European countries,
Lessons from History 287
including Britain, in the early 19th century. The regulating capacity – the extent to which the thinking and acting of the members of a social system are governed by power and coercion, or the threat of coercion – in traditional societies was also low. A lot of coercion was usually necessary to keep society together. When transition gets on its way, the political system should be able to enforce its will without unduly alienating economically important groups and thus rendering them less valuable. For this purpose it is important that the symbolic capacity of the political system is high. The latter was achieved by most of European nations during the early stages of industrialization. As far as the internal and external response capacities – the measure and way in which the system serves its interests and the measure in which the political system succeeds to adapt to external pressures and to maintain its internal integrity – are concerned, all political systems throughout history have always tried to find the most favourable balance. At the onset of the industrialization process, the political system should be able to maintain its territorial integrity and to solve conflicting interests with the least possible damage to the emerging new economic system. In the late 18th century these prerequisites were already fulfilled in Britain. With respect to the distributive capacity – the way in which the system allocates the extracted goods, services, power, prestige and opportunities to persons and groups in society – the traditional situation was one in which the goods and services produced were allocated almost exclusively to the kinship-based elite. At the take-off of the transition, the political system has to be able to affect a significant transfer of extracted goods and services to new economically important individuals and groups. This was exactly what happened in Britain and Germany. In traditional agrarian societies, the productive capacity – the measure in which the system is effective in mobilizing and regulating the economic sphere for its own political aims – was relatively low. For the take-off of the industrialization process, it is imperative that the production capacity increases. For this purpose the political system has to provide, among others, collective facilities in the fields of transport, communication, trade, commerce and education infrastructure. It has to do away with obstructions such as, for example, toll barriers and unfavourable tariffs. It has to remove monetary and fiscal bottlenecks, and to allow a free movement of labour. In addition, it is important that it is able and willing to act as entrepreneur when no other possibilities exist. Already at the onset of the industrial revolution, Britain, Germany and France had taken extensive measures to improve their productive capacity by the means mentioned. The prerequisites for industrialization in the political sphere mentioned so far were all structural. The cultural prerequisites, among others, concern new skills and technologies, a high level of knowledge, individualistic, utilitarian and meritocratic ways of thinking and acting, thinking in terms of social classes
288 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
instead of estates, thinking in terms of the right to own property and to make profit, a positive attitude towards work and thinking in terms of economic systems. By the close of the 18th century, all these cultural prerequisites were already fulfilled in most of the European leading countries. In short, the major political prerequisite for a successful transition is a state that is both strong and flexible at the same time. 4.2
Economy
In a situation where four peasants can hardly maintain one person not involved in agriculture (Grigg, 1982) and shortages of staple foods are a recurrent phenomenon, there is little money available to buy all but the most essential manufactured commodities. The overwhelming majority of the population is bound to the land, and struggles to wrest a living from it and to satisfy the demands of land owners. For the industrialization process to take off, a productive agriculture and low staple food prices were among the most important prerequisites that were regionally fulfilled by the end of the 18th century and even much earlier (More, 1997). In the cottage industry that had already developed in the 14th century, production of, for example, textiles took place jointly with agricultural work. When making hay or at harvest time, spinning and weaving just took second priority. When production eventually started to concentrate in places where much was invested in machinery, buildings and infrastructure, part-time labour, as in the cottage industry, no longer sufficed, and manufacturers required and attained a steady and guaranteed supply of labour of sufficient quality. Capital is understood to mean produced means of production – capital goods – and the power of disposition, expressed in money, over these goods. In a metaphorical sense, it even means the disposition over people. When, at the end of the 18th century, the demand for manufactured consumer goods increased, this created problems of supply for the traditional manufacturing sectors, and brought about a fertile environment for technological change (Cameron, 1991). To finance innovations for mass production, in the long run, additional capital was needed over and above family capital and profit from one’s own enterprise. New forms of banking systems and enterprises developed, and were made legitimate by new laws and government regulations (Rosenberg and Birdzell, 1986; More, 1997). Mass production uses immense amounts of raw materials and energy, and it is more than convenient if raw materials and energy sources are at hand locally. If they are not, there should be a good transport and trade infrastructure. Before the end of the 18th century, prices of raw materials, agricultural produce and handicrafts were strongly affected by the distance to be covered between producers and consumers.
Lessons from History 289
Prices of grain, for example, tripled with every 150 km of transport over land (Thirsk, 1982). Manufactured goods, in so far as they were not made locally, were only available to the elite. Mass production of consumer goods, on the other hand, relies on a steady demand and this demand, certainly in the take-off phase of the industrialization process, depended to a large extent on relatively low prices. To achieve these low prices, a wellestablished network of roads, canals, harbours and, later, railroads was established and maintained. Goods, services and money can, however, only be made really mobile by a good financial infrastructure. By 1720 some 300 years of slowly expanding markets had been accompanied by a corresponding expansion of agricultural and craft production. The large-scale cottage industry and ironworks, which first emerged in the 15th century and expanded in the 17th, were indicative of the growing pressure expanding markets exerted on traditional production processes. In the cottage industry the entrepreneurs were usually merchants, and they supplied the materials to cottages and workshops, bought and distributed the final products, and, sometimes, provided the necessary equipment. In the iron industry the entrepreneurs were often connected to the landed gentry. In both the cotton and iron industries entrepreneurship had its roots in trade, commerce and agriculture (Pieterson, 1987). Although these traders and gentry were keen on profit and avidly looked for market opportunities, they were generally not quite prepared for a new situation in which they had to perform a host of functions at the same time. Products had to be designed and tested, and raw materials acquired and tooled. Parts had to made and assembled to yield a final product. Large numbers of labourers had to be trained in factory discipline, new regional, national and international markets had to be found and distribution networks established. By the end of the 18th century a class of entrepreneurs had emerged with the realization that manufacturing was not simply equivalent to efficiently operating a small workshop or factory, but involved the creation of changes – in product, distribution and organisation – that would increase the margins between costs and revenues (Righart, 1991). The transition from agrarian to industrial, of course, also required a demand for industrial products. Such a demand, however, could only develop in an environment in which there was enough purchasing power and in which consumers were willing and able to change their consumption patterns. When the first industrial revolution took off, new skills and technologies were required to make the change from cottage industry to the mass production of consumer and capital goods. Around 1760 the level of knowledge and skills was already high in many fields. Science, however, did not yet play a significant role in the industrialization process. In the beginning this process was predominantly fed by craft skills and knowledge.
290 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
Even in the late Middle Ages the world was still conceived as relatively static. The notion prevailed that God had given every human being its place in the world already at birth, and that the Three Estates were a Godgiven order. Private property and interest were guilt-ridden concepts (Evans, 1985). Work was considered more a curse than a blessing. Renaissance, Reformation and Enlightenment eventually contributed to the emergence of individualistic and meritocratic ways of thinking and acting, thinking in terms of classes instead of estates, thinking in terms of the right to own private property, the pursuit of profit and a more positive approach to work, cultural aspects in the economic sphere which can all be considered prerequisites for industrialization. Last but not least, in an environment which became increasingly complex, entrepreneurs had to think in terms of economic systems. They learned how to view the world as something which can be empirically researched and manipulated on the basis of research findings. 4.3
Kinship
Both overall population growth and urban population growth in an environment of declining rural populations were stimuli for developments that created preconditions for industrialization. Particularly urban population growth in an environment of declining rural populations, a common phenomenon in parts of 16th and 17th century Europe, brought about innovative behaviour of small farmers and increased their productivity (de Vries, 1984). In view of the importance of the size of the market for manufactured products, countries with a relatively large population and a high and evenly distributed population density had an advantage over countries which did not have these features. At a certain point in the development process, ascriptive attitudes were replaced by more individualistic and meritocratic ways of thinking and acting, and the paramount importance of kinship as the integrating element in society diminished (Hillebrand and Jansen, 1991). Estate society, with its reliance on ascription, gave way to forms of class society (Appelbaum and Chambliss, 1995). The production-oriented extended family gradually became a consumption-oriented nuclear family. 4.4
Religion
The zeal to convert the infidels to Christianity and religious faith in general, in different ways, had their role in the ‘slow revolution’ that brought about industrial society in Europe. When, during the crusades, European rulers tried to rid the Holy Land of the Arabs, this also meant the re-establishment of trade links with the Middle East – trade which contributed, in turn, to the revival of the economy in the 13th century (Runciman, 1994). Religious zeal was one of the motives behind the European expansion in the 15th century, and during the religious wars, in the 16th and 17th centuries, religion was instrumental to the coming into being of a variety of independent and
Lessons from History 291
competing nation states with their own social identity (Wright, 1984). Religion, and particularly Calvinism, it is argued by a number of scholars, was instrumental in the development of labour ethics which were particularly suited for industrial production (Romein, 1954). 4.5
Education
At the onset of the European transition from a traditional agrarian society to an industrialized one, education had been fully institutionalized in almost all European countries. Primary education was available to many but certainly not all, and literacy rates generally remained low. Practical training in crafts and early manufacturing usually took place during (long) apprenticeships and on the job. There were hundreds of universities in which a great variety of subjects could be studied. With a few exceptions, however, technology, industry and science were not yet linked in joint endeavours to increase productivity. The availability of skilled artisans, trained in apprenticeships and on the job, in almost all fields of economic activity was probably the only direct significant prerequisite for the transition to take place. 4.6
Health care
At the end of the 18th century, European health care was certainly not yet fully institutionalized. Medical science was still in its infancy and care for the sick was more often than not in the hands of the family, the churches or charity organisations. Life expectancy at birth was still relatively low. It is, therefore, hard to imagine any prerequisites in the sphere of health care for the industrialization process to take off.
5 Prerequisites for industrialization: early European experience and contemporary Tanzania The identified prerequisites for the early European transition in the institutional spheres of politics, economy, kinship, religion, education and health care can now be checked against relevant aspects of the same institutional spheres in contemporary Tanzania. The Tanzanian aspects are derived from literature and research findings of 14 postgraduate students of the Department of Technology and Development Studies of the Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology, in the Netherlands. All these students conducted their research in Tanzania between 1991 and 1997. 5.1
Politics
Table 12.2 presents an overview of identified prerequisites for the early European (E) transition in the institutional sphere of politics, and checks these against the state of relevant aspects in contemporary Tanzania (T).
292 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Table 12.2 Prerequisites
Overview of identified prerequisites in the sphere of politics E
Structural State able and willing to: • give the new (economic) elite a say in the political system + • let the old and new (economic) elite form alliances + • manipulate taxes, subsidies and markets in favour of trade, commerce and industry + • enforce its will without unduly alienating economically important groups + • maintain its territorial integrity and solve conflicting interests with the least possible damage to the emerging new economic system + • affect a significant transfer of extracted goods and services to new economically important individuals and groups + • provide collective provisions in the field of transport, communication, trade and education infrastructure + • do away with obstructions such as toll bars and unfavourable tariffs + • remove monetary and fiscal bottlenecks + • allow free movement of labor + • act, when necessary, as entrepreneur + Cultural State able and willing to promote: • new skills, technologies and a high level of appropriate know-how + • individualistic, utilitarian and meritocratic ways of thinking and acting + • thinking in terms of classes in stead of estates or other rigid entities + • thinking in terms of private property and profit + • thinking in terms of economic systems +
T
– – – + + + – + + + +
– – + + +
In the institutional sphere of politics, Tanzania does not (fully) fulfil the structural prerequisites of a system able and willing (1) to give the new economic elite a say in politics, (2) to let the new economic elite form strategic alliances, (3) to manipulate taxes, subsidies and markets in favour of trade, commerce and industry and (4) to provide collective provisions in the field of transport, communication, trade and education infrastructure. Certainly before the economic reforms of the 1980s, but also thereafter, Tanzania’s political system lacked the necessary flexibility to fully incorporate economically important individuals and groups, notably from the Asian community, in the various institutes of power. Although the state in theory advocates the free development of political alliances of (economically) important groups, in practice the possibilities are limited by the biased way in which parties are funded and the unequal access to the media. Both aspects are detrimental to the national economy, since they
Lessons from History 293
push actors into the illegal informal sector from which it is difficult to extract revenues (Schulte, 1996). Mainly because of its bureaucratic character and a widespread culture of bribery – in spite of the efforts to curb the latter – Tanzania’s political system lacks the strength to fully exploit an effective system of levying taxes in favour of important economic activities such as, among others, the provision and maintenance of an adequate infrastructure in the fields of transport, communication, trade and, to a lesser extent, education (Newberry and Stern, 1987). Contrary to many other African countries, Tanzania has been remarkably successful in its peaceful endeavour to forge a nation state from what in essence is a multiethnic society. It therefore meets the prerequisite of a system able and willing to enforce its will without alienating important groups. In the past decades it has also met the prerequisite of a system able and willing to maintain its territorial integrity with the least possible damage to the economic system, and a system able and willing to solve internal conflicting interests with the least possible damage. An exception was the military intervention in Uganda in the early 1980s, which caused prolonged grave harm to the economy. A cultural prerequisite that is not (fully) fulfilled is a state willing and able to promote (1) new skills, technologies and a high level of appropriate know-how, and (2) individualistic, utilitarian and meritocratic ways of thinking and acting. Although, in theory, the state promotes new skills, technologies and high levels of appropriate know-how, in practice the situation is less favourable. The budget limitations to enhance education and technological development are severe, and the actual priorities set are often at odds with formal policies. In the field of education, for example, vocational secondary technical education is high on the priority list but receives inadequate funds to fulfil the demand (Duijsens, 1996). Since the mid-1980s, educational programmes, among others, promote individualistic, utilitarian and meritocratic ways of thinking and acting (see also Section 5.3 on kinship) but the attitude of the state remains ambivalent, in the sense that the African Socialism ideologies (‘Ujamaa’) from the 1960s and 1970s are still pervasive in many government laws and regulations. 5.2
Economy
Table 12.3 presents an overview of identified prerequisites for the early European (E) transition in the institutional sphere of the economy, and checks these against the state of relevant aspects in contemporary Tanzania (T). In the institutional sphere of the economy, Tanzania does not (fully) fulfil the structural prerequisites of (1) a highly productive agricultural system, (2) relatively low real prices of staple foods, (3) a continuous and guaranteed supply of labour, (4) labour with sufficient skills and knowledge, (5) capital over and above family capital, (6) new banking systems,
294 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Table 12.3
Overview of identified prerequisites in the sphere of the economy
Prerequisites Structural Highly productive agricultural systems Relatively low prices of staple foods Continuous and guaranteed supply of labour Labour with sufficient skills and knowledge Capital over and above family capital New banking systems New forms of organization of production Locally available raw materials Locally available energy Good trade infrastructure Good network of roads, canals and harbours Entrepreneurs with the conviction that mass production is not simply equivalent to efficiently operating a small workshop or factory, but concerns the creation of changes – in product, distribution and organization – that increase the margins between costs and revenues Demand for industrial products Sufficient purchasing power Environment in which consumers are able and willing to change their consumption patterns Cultural New skills, new technologies and a high level of know-how Individualistic, utilitarian and meritocratic ways of thinking and acting Thinking in terms of classes instead of estates or other rigid units Thinking in terms of private property and profit Positive view on work Thinking in terms of economic systems
E
T
+ + + + + + + + + + +
– – – – – – + – – – –
+ + +
– + –
+
+
+
–
+
–
+ + + +
+ + + +
(7) locally available raw materials, (8) locally available energy, (9) a good trade infrastructure, (10) a good network of roads and harbours, (11) a class of innovative and cost-conscious entrepreneurs and (12) sufficient purchasing power of the majority of the people. The absence of a highly productive agricultural system – with the related relatively high prices for staple foods and their irregular supply – is one of the most notable bottlenecks in Tanzania for industrialization to proceed (FAO Yearbooks). This is particularly significant since the European experience shows that countries which seriously fell behind in the productiveness of their agriculture in the 18th and 19th centuries – for example Russia and to a lesser extent France – were also late to industrialize. A highly productive agricultural system releases labour for industrial employment and guarantees
Lessons from History 295
a regular supply of staple foods at affordable prices. Since less money has to be spent on food, more money can be spent on manufactured commodities. Although unemployment in Tanzania is high, the prerequisite of a continuous supply of labour with sufficient skills and knowledge, essential for industrial enterprises, is not always met. Most workers have extensive (extended) family obligations and, forced by the low wage levels, hold more than one job at a time. Absenteeism, therefore, is high and endangers the necessary continuity of work (ILO, 1992). Nationwide there is an insufficient supply of well-educated workers, particularly at the technical vocational levels (Duijsens, 1996). If the recent acceleration of the innovation rate in almost all sectors of the economy in industrialized countries is also going to affect developing countries, the availability of well-trained workers will become ever more significant. The lack of sufficient infrastructure in the fields of banking, trade, roads, railways, harbours and energy supply – although recently significant improvements have become visible – is probably the second most important bottleneck for further industrial development. Although part of the banking system has been modernized and liberalized recently, loans and bank guarantees at reasonable conditions are hard to get for those without ‘connections’ (Zijl and Lassche, 1997). Roads, railways and harbours have been significantly improved during the last decade, but funds for proper maintenance are lacking (Fleisheuer, 1994; Gnoth, 1994; Koenders, 1994; van der Ven, 1996). Hence, these facilities are deteriorating again. Hydropower-generated electricity is available in all major towns, but the supply suffers from frequent and prolonged cuts, notably in the dry season (Kers, 1997). Tanzania has a great variety of important raw materials, ranging from good-quality coal to different types of ore. Owing to a lack of capital and expertise, and transport difficulties, these resources have so far not yet been (fully) exploited. Tanzania has a small class of innovative and cost-conscious entrepreneurs, many of whom originate from the Asian community. The majority of indigenous African entrepreneurs have their roots in small-scale manufacturing and artisanal enterprises. Generally, and for a variety of reasons, they find it difficult to increase their margins between costs and revenues by means of innovations in product, organisation and distribution. They have little access to capital, lack managerial and technical skills, and carry the burden of extended family ties and communal attitudes connected with the long period of African Socialism (Zijl and Lassche, 1997). Last but not least, the per capita income of the overwhelming majority of the Tanzanian population is so low (US$170 in 1995) that the overall purchasing power is seriously impaired. Cultural prerequisites that are not (fully) fulfilled are (1) new skills, technologies and a high level of appropriate know-how and (2) individualistic,
296 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
utilitarian and meritocratic ways of thinking and acting (see comments in the sections dealing with the political and kinship institutions). 5.3
Kinship
Table 12.4 presents an overview of identified prerequisites for the early European (E) transition in the institutional sphere of kinship and checks these against the state of relevant aspects in contemporary Tanzania (T). In the institutional sphere of kinship, Tanzania does not fulfil the prerequisites of (1) relatively high population densities, (2) a population relatively equally distributed over the territory, (3) an urban population growth in an environment of a declining rural population, (4) consumption-oriented nuclear families and (5) individualistic, utilitarian and meritocratic ways of thinking and acting. Tanzania’s overall relatively low population densities and the unequal distribution of this population over the country are likely to impede industrialization. A transport and communication infrastructure – among others effectively linking market centres for specialized agricultural produce and manufactured products – is (too) costly to establish and particularly to maintain. The same applies to electricity grids and the electronic communication infrastructure. Although modern computer systems are available in Tanzania, the degree of their interconnectedness is extremely low, and hence the role of modern information technology in industry is small. Urban population growth in an environment of a declining rural population – bringing about agricultural innovation, increased agricultural productivity and an impetus to the development of ‘cottage industries’ – appears to be a specific European phenomenon, and is of little consequence for contemporary Tanzania.
Table 12.4
Overview of identified prerequisites in the sphere of kinship
Prerequisites
E
T
Structural Relatively large populations Relatively high population densities Population relatively equally distributed over the territory Population growth Urban population growth in an environment of declining rural populations Some kind of class society Consumption-oriented nucleus families
+ + + +
+ – – +
+ + +
– + –
Cultural Individualistic, utilitarian and meritocratic ways of thinking and acting
+
–
Lessons from History 297
The extended family still features prominently in Tanzania, and nuclear families are usually only found in high-income groups in urban areas. Even there, however, family links are still extensive. Extensive family obligations in a low-income environment hamper the possibilities of individuals to save, and are therefore detrimental to the economy as a whole. Extensive family obligations, in addition, are accompanied by significant expenditures of social time, and the latter is often in conflict with the requirement of a continuous labour input in industry. As a result of the extremely low average income per capita, Tanzanian families are as yet subsistence and not consumption oriented. In the cultural sphere, in present-day Tanzania, communal ways of thinking and acting still have, generally, preference over individualistic, utilitarian and meritocratic ways. Communal ways of thinking and acting have their roots deep in the ancient cultures of the (dominantly) subsistence peasant societies of East Africa. These societies were not classless, but lacked classes, certainly until the colonial domination began, in the capitalist sense (Shivji, 1975). Communal aspects dominated over class aspects at the family, village and tribal levels. After independence communal aspects were re-emphasised in the philosophy of ‘traditional ujamaa living’, as outlined for the first time in the pamphlet ‘Socialism and Rural Development’ by the first president of Tanzania, J. Nyerere. According to Nyerere, there are three basic assumptions underlying ‘traditional ujamaa living’: (1) respect – each member of the family recognizing the place and rights of the other members, (2) common property – acceptance that whatever one person has in the way of basic necessities, they all have, and (3) obligation to work – every member of the family, and every guest who shares in the right to eat and have shelter, taking for granted the duty to join in whatever work needs to be done (Hyden, 1982). The devastating economic and social effects of ‘ujamaa’, when it became a formal government policy, and the retreat from ‘ujamaa’ are part of Tanzania’s recent history. The attachment to communal ways of thinking and acting, however, lingers on even today. 5.4
Religion
Table 12.5 presents an overview of identified prerequisites for the early European (E) transition in the institutional sphere of religion, and checks these against the state of relevant aspects in contemporary Tanzania (T). The prerequisites in the institutional sphere of religion appear to be specific for the European transition from the agrarian to industrial society, and do not apply to contemporary Tanzania. From a historical point of view, they are probably coincidental. 5.5
Education
The influence of a high level of education and of science on the European transition has often been overestimated. In the first phase of the transition,
298 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Table 12.5
Overview of identified prerequisites in the sphere of religion
Prerequisites
E
T
Structural Religious competition (contributing to the establishment of independent nation states)
+
–
Cultural Zeal to convert ‘Calvinist’ labour ethics
+ +
– –
it was the artisans that led the way, and science did not play an important role as yet. In the institutional sphere of education, the lack of skilled artisans in key areas is, therefore, the only prerequisite not met. 5.6
Health care
A healthy labour force enhances productivity and is, therefore, important in a competitive industrial environment. Over the past two decades, health care in Tanzania deteriorated (Schulte, 1996), and this must have affected the productivity of the labour force in a negative way. The question, however, is whether a healthy labour force is a prerequisite for the transition from an agricultural to an industrial society. European history has shown that it is not (see Section 4.6).
6
Can Tanzania learn from European history?
In absolute terms this question cannot, of course, be answered. Europe around 1800 is not the Tanzania of today, and the social and physical environments differ. However, the lesson that can be learned is that all countries that were among the first to make the transition from dominantly agrarian to industrial society shared, right from the start, a number of important innovative aspects in the institutional spheres of politics, economy, kinship and religion. Innovative aspects in the institutional spheres of education and health care apparently played a lesser role. These shared aspects – and particularly the balance and interaction between them – to a significant extent determined the possibilities for success of an early take-off. Institutional development in Tanzania appears, compared to the early European one, to suffer from an imbalance. Important aspects in the political and kinship spheres are still those of a dominantly agrarian society, and they insufficiently support the further development of the institutional sphere of the economy towards a dominantly industrial one. In the sphere of politics, Tanzania finds it difficult to give members of the new economic elite a say in politics and to let them form strategic
Lessons from History 299
alliances. Even the present multi-party state is still dominated by the old elite. The state, for a variety of reasons, is not able to exploit the existing taxation system efficiently and effectively. This reduces the possibilities to manipulate tax revenues in favour of trade, commerce and industry, and to provide adequate collective provisions in the field of transport, communication, trade and education infrastructure. Additional political reform would appear to be necessary for further economic development. In the sphere of kinship, Tanzania’s development is hampered by relatively low population densities and an unequal distribution of people over the territory. This makes the development and maintenance of an adequate infrastructure in almost all spheres prohibitively expensive. In view of the low income per capita, consumption-oriented families are few, and the local market for manufactured goods remains relatively small. Extended family obligations weigh heavily on individual households, reduce their saving capacity and require significant investments in social time, all aspects that do not really enhance further economic development. Communal ways of thinking and acting – having their roots in the traditional East African subsistence peasant societies and re-emphasized in the philosophy of ‘traditional ujamaa living’ in the 1950s and 1960s – still linger on and, by and large, have not been replaced by more individualistic, utilitarian and meritocratic ways of thinking and acting. Cultural changes of this type are hard to enforce by political means, and a further change will take considerable time. In the sphere of the economy, Tanzania lacks a highly productive agricultural system and staple food prices that reflect the benefits of such a system. Further economic development is hampered by a large class of subsistence peasants who have great difficulties producing more than their basic family requirements. Reviewing the situation of this sizeable part of the population, and taking appropriate measures, would appear to be an important political priority. In addition, credit facilities are limited, essential raw materials are not (yet) locally available, energy production and distribution are inadequate, and a good trade and communication infrastructure is lacking. Various extended-family characteristics and the concurrent communal ways of thinking and acting do not facilitate further economic development, and will be difficult to change in the short term.
Notes *
Section of Technology and Development Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology
13 Macroeconomic Policy and Performance of the Manufacturing Sector in Tanzania: Has Liberalization Helped? An Econometric Approach A. V. Y. Mbelle*
1
Introduction
After a decade of ‘de-industrialization’ during the 1980s, there are new hopes for the Tanzanian manufacturing sector for the 1990s and beyond. The Sustainable Industrial Development Policy for Tanzania, 1996–2020 (URT, 1996a), spells out the mission of the sector as making contributions to the achievement of overall long-term development goals and enhancing the sustainable development of the sector itself. The Development Vision 2025 for Tanzania (8th version, URT, 1998) sets more ambitious targets. In 2025 Tanzania should be a diversified, semi-industrialized economy with the industrial sector (manufacturing, mining, construction and utilities) accounting for 40 per cent of GDP (against 16.5 per cent in 1998).1 In addition to this, the sector is expected to form the basis for broad-based growth, income generation, employment creation and foreign exchange earnings. The sector is also seen as a vehicle for eradicating poverty in Tanzania through informal industrial activities, rural industrialization and the emergence of processing establishments in villages (National Strategy for Overseeing the Implementation of Poverty Eradication in Tanzania, URT, 1997).2 The 1998/99 and 1999/2000 budgets for Tanzania promise a bright future for the sector. The high hopes for the manufacturing sector beyond the 1990s pose a number of questions. Is the sector prepared for this mission? Is the sector receiving sufficient attention (in substantive terms) to strengthen it for the mission? What is the news that warrants such hopes?
300
Macroeconomic Policy and Manufacturing Performance 301
This article attempts an assessment of the performance of the manufacturing sector in Tanzania in the context of broad (economy-wide or macroeconomic) policies with a view to gauging the impact of such policies on the sector. The article is organised into five sections. Section 2 highlights recent developments in the manufacturing sector in Tanzania. Section 3 presents a survey of the deployment of macroeconomic policies for industrial development to cover both the theoretical underpinning and evidence on the ground. The empirical results are reported in Section 4, with the last section being devoted to concluding remarks.
2 Recent developments in the manufacturing sector in Tanzania 2.1 Performance Table 13.1 below presents data on the performance of the sector in the 1990s. 2.1.1 Growth and share in GDP In terms of growth ‘sustained’ positive rates were realised after 1995, rising from 1.6 per cent in 1995 to 8.1 per cent in 1998, picking up from the negative growth rates experienced between 1992 and 1994. The share of manufacturing in GDP varies between 8.8 per cent, recorded in 1990, and 8.4 per cent, recorded in 1998, with a low of 7.9 per cent in 1995. 2.1.2 Export performance The growth of manufacturing exports increased dramatically from –19 per cent in 1993 to 48.1 per cent in 1994. This can partly be explained by Table 13.1 Performance of the manufacturing sector in Tanzania, 1990–98 (1992 prices)a 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 Real growth (%) Real mfg export growth (%) Share in GDP Share in total exports Average capacity utilization Share in NT exportsb Employment (000)
4.1 1.9 13.3 –27.7
–4.1 –0.6 –8.7 –19.0
–0.2 48.1
1.6 41.9
4.8 1.4
8.8 23.8 50
8.7 19.6 50
8.2 16.2 38
8.2 11.8 50
8.1 14.8 46
7.9 16.0 46
8.0 14.6 48
8.1 14.5 60
48.9 123
43.7 121
38.8 126
28.4 126
42.2 130
36.5 131
35.3 129
29.2 18.2 132 137
Sources: URT (1999a; 1999c). Notes: a For establishments with 10 or more employees. b Non-traditional exports.
5.7 8.1 –5.7 –42.6 8.4 8.8 55
302 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
changes in the management of the exchange rate, though exports ran out of steam by 1996. The share of manufactured exports in total exports declined from 23.8 per cent in 1990 to a mere 8.8 per cent in 1998. The dominance of manufacturing exports in non-traditional exports was greatly eroded by 1998. The factors accounting for this drastic decline include trade sanctions against Burundi, unrest in the Great Lakes region, and disruption of transport network caused by El Niño rains, thus hindering delivery of industrial exports to neighbouring countries, as well as leading to reduced inputs for agro-industries. 2.1.3
Capacity utilization
There was a marked stability in the average capacity utilisation rate between 1990 and 1998. This can mainly be attributed to a few industries which have shored up the average, following successful joint ventures with foreign investors in the ongoing privatisation exercise. Such industries include beer brewing (especially Tanzania Breweries Ltd), cigarette manufacturing (a single-firm industry, the Tanzania Cigarette Company), the cement industry, oxygen production (Tanzania Oxygen Ltd) and the soft drinks industry. These industries have benefited from injections of foreign capital, rehabilitation of plant and machinery, and improved management. 2.1.4
Employment
Trends in manufacturing employment were on the increase between 1991 and 1998. When compared to the sector’s real growth, the increase in employment was more rapid than is warranted by performance of the sector. Further analysis of the employment data indicates most employment is found in food and beverages (ISIC 31) and textiles and leather (ISIC 32). For example, in 1998, these two categories accounted for 67.1 per cent of total manufacturing employment: ISIC 31, 37.3 per cent, and ISIC 32, 29.8 per cent.3 For the food and beverages group, this reflects increased investments, especially after 1995, with an average of 31 per cent of all new industrial licences issued between 1995 and 1998.4 2.2
Other signs of recovery
One of the notable new developments is the participation of the manufacturing sector in the stock market. After the establishment of the Dar es Salaam Stock Exchange (DSE) on 15 April 1998, the first ‘firm’ which listed itself was Tanzania Oxygen Ltd, selling shares to the public (at about US$0.9 per share). Tanzania Breweries Ltd started selling its shares (10 per cent) to the public towards the end of May 1998, at about US$0.9 per share. Other industries (or firms) are in the preparatory stage for joining the stock market. These include the Tanzania Cigarette Company, Tanga Cement Company Ltd and Portland Cement (Wazo) Ltd. Again one notices that these are the industries (or firms) which have concluded successful joint-
Macroeconomic Policy and Manufacturing Performance 303
venture agreements with foreign investors, thus attracting foreign capital investments. 2.3 2.3.1
Manufacturing sector dynamics in Tanzania Export competitiveness
Dynamism in the export sector refers to the ability to penetrate ‘sophisticated’ markets where quality, delivery schedules and so on must be strictly adhered to. Such markets will mainly be the markets in developed countries (OECD, USA, and so on). There are different measures of such dynamism (see Rodriguez, 1998, for an extensive discussion). Rodriguez calculated export competitiveness indices for ten Sub-Saharan African countries, including Tanzania, and concluded that there were substantial declines in global market shares, and that market participation in advanced country markets declined even more. Compared to, for example, Latin American countries, sub-Saharan African countries failed to adapt to external markets between 1985 and 1995. These results point to issues of price competitiveness, quality and aggressiveness in marketing. It is not surprising that an increasing proportion of African exports is channelled to regional markets, partly because of the success of regional arrangements but mainly as a result of loss of competitiveness in advanced markets. 2.3.2
Technological dynamism
Studies by Mbelle and Bagachwa (1995) and Wangwe, Semboja and Kweka (1997) show some evidence of dynamism in manufacturing for a few firms. ‘Offensive Strategies’5 have been adopted with encouraging results. This is true even for firms which have not concluded successful joint ventures with foreign investors (see also Alange, 1987).
3 Macroeconomic policies for industrial development in Tanzania In this section we review the deployment of macroeconomic policies in Tanzania and discuss existing evidence on the effect of such policies on the manufacturing sector in Tanzania. Policies are dealt with in Section 3.1, while the evidence concerning the impact of policies is presented in Section 3.2. 3.1
Macroeconomic policies for industrial development in Tanzania
Macroeconomic policies are those that have an influence on aggregates in the economy. Typical policies will deal with, for example, aggregate expenditure and consumption, government deficits, money supply, investments, exchange rate policies, interest rate policies, and so forth. Results are reflected in GDP growth rates, inflation and so forth. Although generally sound macroeconomic policies are good for economic performance, their
304 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
impact on industrialisation may not be directly beneficial. This depends to a considerable extent on the characteristics of the industry (whether it is a net exporter or a net importer), its financial standing and so forth. For example, a tight monetary policy, while credited with checking inflation in many developing countries, may lead to decreased credit in the economy, which may impact negatively on industrialisation. A liberalised exchange rate regime, while providing incentives to exporters, may harm high-import content manufactures, as they spend more in local currency terms for the same volume of imports. Pieper (1998) demonstrates extensively how policies, especially exchange-rate-based policies, favour industrialization. 3.1.1
Recent trends in selected macroeconomic aggregates
Table 13.2 shows selected macroeconomic variables in Tanzania for the period 1990–99. The picture of macroeconomic performance emerging from the table is quite impressive. For some aggregates, however, the targets set for the 1990s were achieved late or only partially, for instance single-digit inflation, a real annual GDP growth rate of 5 per cent and a growth of money between 8 and 10 per cent. With regard to the exchange rate, the unification in August 1993 seems to have had an impact in reducing the foreign exchange premium to singledigit figures in 1993 and to less than 1 after 1995. On the other hand, the liberalisation of interest rates in 1993 seems to have led to one queer result: widening the spread after 1993 (for example, 1990: 5 per cent; 1993: 15 per cent; 1997: 24.7 per cent; 1999: 15 per cent). This has the potential impact of discouraging investments in the real sector of the economy by making credit too expensive compared to interest earned on deposits. Table 13.2
Selected macroeconomic indicators in Tanzania 1990–98
Variable
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999d
Growth in money supply (M2) Inflationb Forex Premiumc Savings rate 1 yr av. Lending rated GDP growth (real)
45.4 32 66.7 26 31 5
26.1 34 43.8 26 31 6
38.5 24 36.0 26 31 4
28.8 24 5.3 24 39 4
32.5 27 1.9 24 39 3
26.2 34 <1 15 40 4
11.6 15.4 <1 11 38 4.2
11 15.4 <1 7.3 32 3.3
11.1 15.2 <1 8.7 24.3 4.0
Notes: a As of 30 June, 1999. b Headline inflation. c Defined as the difference between the parallel exchange rate and official exchange rate expressed as proportion of the official rate. d Maximum, medium and long term. Sources: Bank of Tanzania, various issues; Mbelle (1998).
7.9 7.8 <1 10 25 n.a.
Macroeconomic Policy and Manufacturing Performance 305
3.1.2
Discussion
Prudent macroeconomic policies are supposed to provide an overall environment which is benign for economic agents to take advantage of. Tanzania has gone a long way towards improving the macroeconomic environment (for example, liberalizing the exchange rate towards a market-determined rate). However, the extent of growth of GDP does not reflect the intensity and extensiveness of the policies being pursued. 3.1.3
Future prospects for the sector
Since 1998/99, the government has introduced a number of measures which have potential benefits for the manufacturing sector. Such measures include: (a) Introduction of value added tax (VAT) on 1 July 1998, replacing sales tax and stamp duties for firms registered in the VAT system. This will simplify taxation procedures (depending on co-operation of agents and good record-keeping). (b) Depositing duty draw-back funds in a special account instead of in the general account of the government where the money had been used for other purposes, thus discouraging exporters. (c) Further liberal tariff reforms with only four bands: a low tariff rate of 5 per cent to be imposed on raw materials, replacement parts and investment goods; a 10 per cent tariff for semi-processed inputs; a 20 per cent tariff for fully processed inputs and a top rate of 25 per cent for consumer goods. A zero rate for strategic and leading investment sectors continues to apply as well. (d) Pre-shipment inspection to be introduced for textile materials, in order to curb illegal imports. (e) Reduction of duties for COMESA (Common Market for Eastern and Southern Africa) goods to 20 per cent.6 By June 1999 the rate averaged 7 per cent. An informed assessment of the benefits is not easy, given the short time span. However, casual observation of economic performance in 1998 would point to a positive impact of these measures. 3.2 Evidence of the impact of macroeconomic policies on the Tanzanian manufacturing sector There are several studies in Tanzania that have attempted an assessment of the impact of these policies right to the level of firms – assessing the impact of structural adjustment policies, the break point being the adoption of the first Economic Recovery Programme (ERP) in 1986. ERP had
306 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
‘promised’ to revive capacity utilization rates in manufacturing from the obtaining levels of 20–30 per cent to levels of 60–70 per cent, through rehabilitation of plants and machinery, and increased resources (URT, 1986a). It is only in 1997 that 60 per cent capacity utilization was achieved (URT, 1999a). Studies which have reflected on some adverse impacts include Mbelle (1988), RPED (1994), Wangwe, Semboja and Kweka (1997), Mbelle et al. (1998a,b), and Engblom and Veres (1998) for the worst scenario in the textile industry. Areas of concern include: (a) expensive credit, implying that the liberalisation of the banking sector has not helped; in the survey by the Regional Programme on Enterprise Development (RPED) 64 per cent of the industries ranked this as the most severe constraint (b) ‘expensive’ foreign exchange – accessibility is mainly guaranteed to those with connections to foreign investors (c) ‘excessively’ restricted circulation of money in the economy (d) markets swamped by cheap imports from abroad, which have, for example, adversely affected the textile industry (e) increases in general unemployment brought about by retrenchments in the civil service and in the manufacturing sector (though for this sector it doesn’t show so much), as privatisation of public enterprises is taking its course (market forces) (f) still too many taxes and too high levels of taxation. 3.2.1
Discussion
Looking at Tanzania’s history since independence, one sees differences in the reliance on macroeconomic policies for improved production (see the overview in Chapter 1). While in the 1970s sectoral policies were given equal weight (for example, in agriculture and industry in the Basic Industry Strategy see Skarstein and Wangwe, 1986; Musonda, 1992; Ndulu and Semboja 1994, 1996; Parker et al., 1995), the 1980s witnessed an absence of such meso-policies following up on macropolicies with concrete targets. The SIDP for Tanzania points out this fact. In the introductory remarks it is acknowledged that one of the reasons for launching SIDP 1996–2020 is that the Basic Industry Strategy (1975–95) had expired (in 1995). In fact it had already expired in late 1970s, when the economic crisis unfolded. It is only now that a vision for the sector, and one for the country as a whole, is being formulated again. Against this background, the following section presents an econometric investigation of the impact of macroeconomic policies on the manufacturing sector in Tanzania.
Macroeconomic Policy and Manufacturing Performance 307
4 Empirical analysis of the effects of macroeconomic policy on manufacturing in Tanzania In this section we report the results of the estimation of macroeconomic policy impacts on manufacturing. The section covers methodological issues, modelling, results and comparison of the results with the results of other studies. 4.1
Methodological issues
4.1.1
The models and their justification
Following the discussions in Section 3, two macroeconomic instruments were selected on the basis of their important potential impacts. These are the exchange rate (for the external sector) and the domestic interest rate (for the domestic sector). We did not estimate the determinants of manufacturing output growth since this has been tackled in many studies, for example, Mumburi (1998). (a) Effect of the exchange rate on manufacturing exports Here we estimate the responsiveness of manufacturing exports to exchange rate incentives. Such incentives include streamlined administrative procedures for acquiring foreign exchange, leaving the market to determine the exchange rate, and freedom of retention of foreign exchange. It is expected that exporters of manufactures will increase exportation, also to take advantage of increased earnings in local currency due to more favourable exchange rates. (b) The effect of interest rates on manufacturing investments In economic theory high lending rates discourage borrowing for investment. Thus investments in the real sector, for example, manufacturing, will be discouraged. The liberalisation of interest rates in 1993 is expected to have a negative effect on investments in manufacturing. 4.1.2
The models and expected signs (hypotheses)
(a) The determinants of manufacturing exports log CMAE = + 1 log CMAO + 2 log CRERM + 3 log TOT + 4 DU84 + 5 DU86 + 6 DU93 + e where: CMAE = changes in real manufactured exports CMAO = changes in manufacturing output (supply capacity variable) (+); as manufacturing output increases, we expect manufactured exports to increase also
308 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
CRERM = changes in real exchange-rate misalignment, as a measure of real overvaluation; this is done so as to assess the objective of maintaining an equilibrium exchange rate (eliminating overvaluation) in Tanzania (–)7 TOT = net barter terms of trade (–), with 1977 as the base year; the better the terms of trade, the more expensive exports become compared to imports – hence a hypothesised fall in the volume in exports DU84 = dummy to capture the influence of the partial liberalisation measures instituted in 1984 with the introduction of the own funds window (1 after 1984, zero before 1984) (+) DU86 = dummy for the ‘true’ liberalisation carried out in 1986 (1 after 1986) (+) DU93 = dummy for the unification of the exchange rate in 1993 (1 after 1993) (+) e = error term , = parameters. (b) Manufacturing investment The objectives of liberalising the financial market include deepening the market. This can be achieved, for example, through interest rate deregulation. However, existing evidence is conflicting on whether interest deregulation leads to increased savings, and hence an increased supply of loanable funds, especially in countries where credit markets are undeveloped, and inflation rates are high. One of the key aspects of liberalisation of the financial sector thus becomes the relationship between capital and domestic investment. In countries such as Tanzania, where historically the government has led industrialization, it becomes a question of policy priorities – how much of capital is invested in different activities. This then becomes a macroeconomic issue. Tracing changes in the absolute values of the investments themselves will miss the policy-priority aspect where a single investor is dominant. Below we therefore hypothesize that it is the proportion of total investible funds devoted to manufacturing that counts and reflects macroeconomic policy. The use of ratios, for example investments to GDP, is commonly resorted to in many econometric works in such cases. In economic theory investment is mainly determined by the interest rate. The government in this case is then seen as the saver and investor (for example, through parastatals which acquire investible money in normal ways and thus face the lending rate). Our assessment of liberalization pits both government and private-sector agents against each other in the financial market. Here the lending rate is supplemented by general
Macroeconomic Policy and Manufacturing Performance 309
liquidity (money supply) and effectiveness of banking facilities (how the numerous commercial banks under liberalisation can influence public holding of money). If money in public hands increases, then the banking facilities are less effective. Hence marshalling of investible funds becomes less and the potential for borrowing from the banks for investing (for instance in manufacturing) becomes less. This will be true for other sectors as well. Lynch (1995) uses the same relationships (though with more variables) to estimate investments. We thus formulate our investment equation as follows (with expected signs between brackets): log CMAI = + 1 log CARE + 2 log CAMS + 3 log EFB + 4 DU86 + 5 DUP93 + e where: CMAI = CARE = CAMS =
EFB =
DU86 =
DU93 =
e 4.1.3
=
changes in investment in manufacturing as a proportion of total investment changes in real lending rate (–); the higher the lending rate, the less borrowing there will be for investment purposes changes in money supply (broad money, M2) (+); this has the potential of increasing the supply of loanable funds (for investment) the ratio of narrow money to broad money (M1/M2) (–); this measures the effectiveness of banking facilities, that is, the extent to which money is held in public hands (circulation outside the banks); in the estimation procedure, we deal with changes in the variable. liberalisation in 1986 (1 for period 1986–96, else 0) (–); this is intended to capture the expansion of activities in the economy and whether manufacturing was still an attractive avenue for investment; we hypothesize that manufacturing will compete with emerging activities for loanable funds, hence manufacturing investments will suffer liberalisation of the interest rate in 1993 (1 for 1993–96 or else 0) (–); we expect interest rates to rise with deregulation, hence discouraging manufacturing investments error term.
Estimation techniques
The ordinary least squares method (OLS) was used for its simplicity and wide use. The logs were preferred so that the regression coefficients can be interpreted directly as elasticities. The equations are (log) linear and additive.
310 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
4.1.4
Data sources
Official published data sources were consulted mainly from the (Central) Bank of Tanzania.8 The periods covered are 1964–96 for the export equation and 1966–96 for the investment equation. For the latter, 1966 cut-off was used, as this was the year in which Tanzania established its own Central Bank following the break-up of the East African Currency Board, which issued the East African shilling. Thus actions by Tanzania’s Central Bank, for instance in money supply, are traced. There were no data gaps, hence we are confident of the information. Supplementary sources included Economic Surveys. Real exchange-rate misalignment data were obtained from calculations in Elbadawi’s study (1998).9 4.1.5
Time series characteristics of the data
It is becoming common practice in econometric estimations to analyse the time series characteristics of the data when trends are used (time series data). This will be done in the following section. 4.2
Time series analysis
(a) The determinants of manufacturing exports Since most macro-variables are likely to be non-stationary, we begin by testing for the order of integration. This means that the variables may have a mean that changes with time and a non-constant variance. Working with such variables in their levels will give a high likelihood for spurious regression results. Furthermore, no inference can be done since the standard statistical tests such as the F-distribution and the t-distribution are invalid. Hence the first step is to test the level of integration through the unit root process by using standard testing procedures, such as those developed by Dickey and Fuller and Sargan and Bharghava. The results of these tests are presented in Table 13.3. After establishing the order of integration, the next step is to test for cointegration. At this step, we seek to establish whether a linear combination of a set of non-stationary variables is stationary. As can be seen from
Table 13.3
Time series characteristics of the dataa
Variable
SBDW
DF
ADF
Order of integration
CMAE CMAO RERM TOT
1.661 1.168 0.1195 0.3073
–4.508 –3.806 –0.8245 –2.572
–3.026 –3.475 –1.713 –2.839
I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1)
Notes: a The critical values are –3.556, –3.575 respectively for the, DF and ADF. All variables are in log levels.
Macroeconomic Policy and Manufacturing Performance 311
Table 13.4, we cannot reject the null of cointegration in all three cases. We then proceed to estimate a static regression involving all the variables and the residual generated therefrom. One period lag is included in the general autoregressive distributed lag (ADL) model as the error correction term. After estimating the general model, 10 we went through a series of simplification procedures. We proceeded principally by eliminating those variables with t-values of less than one in absolute terms, the efficiency of which was assessed at each stage using the F-statistic, the information criterion and the model diagnostic tests, until we arrived at a preferred and a certainly more parsimonious characterization of the data. By reducing the model, the F-statistic increased from 3.1555 to 5.4806 in the general and preferred models respectively. The standard error of the regression declined from 0.965761 in the general model to 0.903656 in the preferred model. The information criterion11 also showed a decline, starting with the SC from 0.903278 to 0.480687, HQ from 0.44081 to 0.183386, and FPE from 1.39904 to 1.07907 in the general to the preferred model respectively. The model diagnostic tests are insignificant at the conventional test levels starting, with the AR test for higher order autocorrelation. The ARCH test for autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity, the Bera–Jaque test for residual normality, Whiter test for heteroscedasticity and the REST test for functional form misspecification were carried out. There is nothing to suggest that our model is misspecified in any way. The error correction term (Res4_1) has the expected sign and is significant at the 1 per cent test level. This is a further confirmation that the variables CMAE, CMAO, TOT, and RERM indeed co-integrate. In addition, we ran the estimation excluding dummy variables to test for parameter constancy. The insignificant Chow test value and the forecast test value all point to parameter constancy over the period 1988 to 1996. The model can thus be used for forecasting. The preferred model results are presented in Table 13.5. 4.2.1
Interpretation of the results
With respect to the signs output of manufactures, real exchange-rate misalignment and the liberalisation measures of 1984 and 1993 behaved as Table 13.4
Testing for Co-Integration
Variables
SBDW
DF
ADF
CMAE v CMAO CMAE v TOT CMAE v RERM
1.829 1.681 1.654
–3.885 –3.702 –3.690
–3.711 –3.562 –3.625
Note: Tests are applied on residuals.
Co-integration accept/reject Accept Accept Accept
312 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Table 13.5 Variable
Results: the determinants of manufactured exports in Tanzania Coefficient
Constant DLCMAO2 DLRERM DLRERM_2 DLTOT Res4_1 s1984 s1986 s1993
0.19995 0.35357 –3.8352 –2.9556 3.1427 –1.1777 1.1233 –2.8081 1.6063
Std error
t-value
0.28903 0.19950 1.3399 1.2872 1.5071 0.20160 0.71479 1.0382 0.74558
0.692 1.772 –2.862 –2.296 2.085 –5.842 1.572 –2.705 2.154
Note: R2 = 0.697666; F(8,19) = 5.4806 [0.0011]; s = 0.903656; DW = 2.25; RSS = 15.51529265 for 9 variables and 28 observations.
postulated. This suggests that increased manufacturing output leads to increased export of manufactures. The exchange rate variable confirms the hypothesis that overvalued exchange rates act as a disincentive to exporters. This is the macroeconomic policy instrument we were interested in. The variable is significant at the 10 per cent level. The terms of trade variable came with an unexpected sign. This can be explained by the fact that in Tanzania’s history agricultural exports have been the main source of foreign earnings, while manufactures have been relatively unimportant. Thus manufactured exports are not likely to respond significantly. However, the variable is insignificant at the conventional test levels. With regard to liberalisation measures the behaviour of the 1986 dummy is as is to be expected. While the 1984 and 1993 measures were more targeted to foreign exchange holdings and dealings respectively, the general, economy-wide reforms of 1986 led to a greater inflow of imports, which in the final analysis probably led to a reduced output of manufactures and thus less ability to invest in exporting. 4.2.2
Comparison with other results
The positive responsiveness of manufacturing exports to foreign exchange incentives corroborates the results of many such studies in Tanzania, for example, Ndulu and Semboja (1996) and Rutasitara in 1996 (cited in Mbelle et al., 1998 a,b) as well as the results of Pieper (1998): (b) The determinants of manufacturing investments While reporting these results we will not repeat the procedures outlined in the estimation of the first model. 12 Only a few tests are given (Tables 13.6 and 13.7). The rejections in Table 13.7 may point to problems with the
Macroeconomic Policy and Manufacturing Performance 313 Table 13.6
Test for unit roots: the manufacturing investment equation
Variable
SBDWa
DFa
LAMS LARE LMAI LEFB
1.432 0.7079 0.3202 0.5424
–4.039 –2.165 –2.331 –4.206
ADFa,b
Order of integration
–2.857 –1.364 –1.355 –1.788
I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1)
Notes: a Critical values at 5% level are: DF –3.567; ADF –3.587; SBDW 1.72. b Lags were used in the auxiliary equation for ADF.
Table 13.7
Testing for co-integration
Variables
SBDW
DF
ADF
LMAI v LEFB LMAI v LARE LMAI v LAMS RES5
0.5098 0.5136 0.3747 0.8633
–2.261 –1.91 –1.553 –3.238
–0.1391 –0.8599 –0.436 –0.9949
Co-integration accept/reject Reject Reject Reject Reject
Note: Tests are applied on residuals.
testing statistic when the error correction term is also rejected. With this assumption we then proceeded to include the error correction term in the general model and re-estimated the equation. If the ECT turns out to be significant and bearing a negative sign, then our assumption is correct. The results of the general model confirmed the correctness of our assumption. 13 In Table 13.8 we present the final results. 4.2.3
Interpretation of the results
The real lending-rate variable came out with an unexpected sign, though the coefficient was insignificant. This may reflect the fact that the rate has been negative for quite a considerable period of time. This is documented in Appendix Table A.2. Thus changes in real lending rate (DLARE), even when lagged, did not deter manufacturing investments. Partly, this is also due to the fact that investment in manufacturing was government-led. Changes in the money supply (DLAMS), though not significant, did not favour manufacturing investment (counter to the hypothesized positive relationship). The same conclusion holds for the effectiveness of banking facilities. Increased effectiveness of the banking system was not positively related to manufacturing investment. The influence is however insignificant. As expected the liberalisation measures instituted in 1986 resulted (initially) in a declining share of industrial investment. This variable is significant at the 1 per cent level.
314 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Table 13.8 Results: the determinants of manufacturing investments in Tanzania, preferred model (sample 1969 to 1996) Variable
Coefficient
Constant DLARE DLARE_1 DLARE_2 DLAMS Res5_1 s1986 DELFB_1
0.32713 0.39923 0.64201 0.57344 –0.24067 –0.58199 –0.96219 –53.804
Std error
t-value
0.14338 0.23991 0.27986 0.21624 0.17319 0.18704 0.29241 41.971
2.282 1.664 2.294 2.652 –1.390 –3.112 –3.291 –1.282
Note: R2 = 0.534871; F(7,20) = 3.2855 [0.0172]; s = 0.414869; DW = 1.74; RSS = 3.442327352 for 8 variables and 28 observations.
4.2.4
Comparison with other results
Though, to the best of our knowledge, no similar analyses exist for Tanzania, our finding on the significant negative impact of liberalization corroborates the results of many non-econometric studies, for example those reported in Section 3, and the general impression that investible funds tend to be channelled more into the non-real part of the economy, for instance, services.
5
Concluding remarks
We set out to estimate the impact of macroeconomic policies on manufacturing performance in Tanzania, with special attention to liberalization measures (a policy regime shift). Our main interest in carrying out this exercise was to determine the influence of liberalization (a regime shift away from a command and control economy). As our analysis has shown, the impact of liberalization on manufacturing performance is not unambiguous. Some policies are counterproductive. This leads to the conclusion that in order to ameliorate some of the negative sectoral impacts of macropolicies, sector-specific policies have to be designed and targeted, and subsequently implemented.
Macroeconomic Policy and Manufacturing Performance 315
Appendix Table A.1
1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996
Data for manufacturing exports equation MAE
MAO
176 200 271 390 336 389 378 459 416 439 498 566 667 673 625 1 003 1 229 802 708 791 1 217 1 425 1 641 4 036 7 938 11 430 11 282 7 672 7 012 5 680 8 406 11 852 12 208
1 186 1 203 1 289 1 315 1 269 1 523 1 744 2 113 2 516 3 048 3 888 4 546 5 517 6 524 9 332 9 832 10 377 10 828 11 038 12 768 16 944 20 562 28 171 43 521 51 759 95 825 124 572 135 783 168 371 207 096 238 515 267 137 278 081
RERM
TOT
29.1 29.0 29.0 29.0 29.1 34.9 34.2 35.0 39.3 34.9 36.3 43.2 55.3 53.2 42.6 49.3 58.8 74.8 87.3 94.5 92.0 99.7 72.3 34.1 25.5 23.0 18.9 19.0 16.4 16.7 15.6 15.6 15.6
69 68 69 69 66 82 80 70 68 84 77 66 90 100 82 82 71 61 63 65 68 64 74 64 62 58 50 50 45 45 46 50 54
Sources: Bank of Tanzania, various; URT, Economic Surveys, various issues.
316 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Table A.2
1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996
Data for manufacturing investment equation MAI
ARE
AMS
EFB
14.8 16.2 13.2 17.0 13.4 11.0 11.8 15.6 15.6 17.9 26.6 37.2 36.7 36.9 33.8 21.7 21.3 15.1 13.2 12.2 2.6 11.8 6.7 2.4 3.0 4.8 4.6 4.0 2.4 2.5 2.7
4.3 4.3 4.3 4.4 4.5 4.5 –0.5 –1.5 –11.5 –17.5 1.5 –3.5 –4.5 5.5 –18.0 –14.0 –15.5 –18.5 –25.5 –17.0 –16.0 –1.0 –2.0 1.0 –4.9 2.2 9.1 13.8 4.9 10.7 22.6
3.0 2.0 –3.0 23.0 20.0 16.0 16.0 14.0 21.0 22.0 21.0 18.0 12.0 38.0 24.0 17.0 18.0 16.0 4.0 25.0 26.0 28.0 30.0 26.0 36.0 26.1 38.5 28.8 32.5 26.2 11.6
10.22 10.38 10.29 10.27 10.28 10.30 10.29 10.29 10.28 10.26 10.26 10.27 10.26 10.25 10.28 10.28 10.30 10.27 10.27 10.33 10.34 10.35 10.35 10.35 10.33 10.29 10.31 10.28 10.27 10.31 10.29
Sources: Bank of Tanzania, various; URT, Economic Surveys, various issues.
Notes * Department of Economics, University of Dar es Salaam 1. The shares for manufacturing, mining, construction and utilities being 8.4%, 2.0%, 4.4% and 1.7% respectively (URT, 1999a). 2. ‘Mkakati wa Taifa wa Kusimamia Utekelezaji wa Sera za Kuondoa Umaskini’ (National Strategy for Poverty Alleviation) (URT, 1997). 3. Computed from URT (1999a), table 60, p. 150. 4. Computed from URT (1999a), table 64, p. 154. 5. Introduction of new products, higher expenditure in R&D and product development.
Macroeconomic Policy and Manufacturing Performance 317 6. Tanzania recently (July 1999) announced it was pulling out of COMESA. 7. Real exchange rate is defined as the ratio of the consumer price index (CPI) to the nominal effective exchange-rate index multiplied by the weighted price indices of major trading partners. A misalignment thus shows the extent of departure from the equilibrium (of a chosen base year) for which the economy is considered to be in equilibrium. For extensive treatment see for example Elbadawi (1998). 8. This is the most reliable source in Tanzania (accepted by all). 9. ‘Real Exchange Rate Policy and Export Competitiveness in Sub-Saharan Africa’, paper presented at the UNU/WIDER Conference, Addis Ababa, 16–20 March 1998. 10. This model can be obtained from the author. 11. A decline in the value of these statistics is an indication of increased model parsimony. 12. These can be obtained from the author. 13. This can be obtained from the author.
14 The Urban Informal Manufacturing Sector in Tanzania: Neglected Opportunities for Socioeconomic Development Herman Gaillard and Amber Beernink*
1
Introduction
This chapter discusses the potential contributions of the urban informal sector to socioeconomic development. It presents a discussion of studies of the Tanzanian informal sector in the context of a review of comparative data on the informal sector in developing countries. First, in Section 2 we explain why there is increasing interest in the urban informal sector during the past decades, both in Tanzania and elsewhere. Then, the state of theoretical and empirical research is addressed in Section 3. Methodological problems and shortcomings in research on the informal sector are identified in Section 4. In Section 5 empirical evidence is presented with regard to the following research questions: the degree of empirical support for the formal–informal dichotomy (5.1) the nature of the relations between the informal sector and the formal sector (5.2) • the potential contribution of the Tanzanian urban informal sector to socioeconomic development (5.3) • constraints for the future growth of the urban informal sector (5.4). • •
Finally, Section 6 contains policy recommendations with regard to the urban informal sector in Tanzania. Studies of the urban informal sector in Tanzania are rather scarce (for an overview see References, ‘Relevant informal sector studies in Tanzania’). Furthermore, most surveys are either very global or very restricted in scope and content. This is not typical of Tanzania, but applies to most informalsector studies in developing countries all over the world. The still scanty 318
Urban Informal Manufacturing Sector 319
detailed information concerning the urban informal sector of Tanzania will become more meaningful, when compared – whenever possible – with data from other case studies and surveys (see References, ‘List of case studies’, for material included in this survey). It should be stressed, however, that all the data about urban informal sectors in developing countries should be interpreted with caution. Most of them are estimates based on limited samples. The data in the Appendix indicate that urban informal sector studies in Tanzania are basically quite typical of studies performed elsewhere. The scores for Tanzanian studies are either similar to the average scores of case studies and surveys in a wide range of countries, or they are within the ranges observed in these other studies. Thus, by and large, the same characteristics can be observed in Tanzania as in the majority of urban informal sector studies carried out elsewhere.1
2
Interest in the urban informal sector
In most developing countries in the post-war period, increasing population pressure and insufficient job creation in the formal sector, together with rural–urban migration due to a variety of push and pull factors, have created a spillover of employment into the urban informal sector. According to some observers, the activities in this sector are illegal, marginal, parasitic or even criminal; according to others this sector represents productive, small-scale ‘self-employment’ and therefore should be considered as a potential for stimulating growth, employment and achieving a less skewed income distribution. The interest in the meaning of development and how a developing country may reach higher levels of welfare started after World War II. Nowadays, there is general agreement on the fact that the first priority in development is to combat poverty and its causes. Opinions on how to realize this, however, still diverge widely. In the 1950s the opinion dominated that development was only a matter of more investment in capital, as was expressed by the use of the wellknown capital–output ratio. By the beginning of the 1960s it was realised that this magic formula, so successfully applied in West European countries after World War II, would not have the same effects in developing countries, because the necessary knowledge and know-how were lacking there. More schooling (‘investment in human capital’) seemed to be the answer, but soon it was demonstrated – among others by Galtung (1968) – that the effects of improved schooling can only be modest in a global situation characterised by an ossified international division of labour between rich and poor countries. Nevertheless, until the end of the 1960s people were still convinced that there was only one road to development. All investments should be directed towards the growth of the modern industrial
320 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
sector. Only this sector was supposed to be capable of achieving real progress. This one-sided, implicitly unilinear way of thinking is most clearly recognizable in the ideas of Rostow (1960) concerning the stages of economic growth through which every country has to pass. Thus, in development thinking attention was mainly directed to large-scale, capitalintensive industries concentrated in urban areas. This strategy was doomed to fail. In terms of employment the modern industrial sector concerns a rather small sector, which often grew only slowly. Employment creation in this sector lagged behind the growth of production because of rising productivity. In the meantime, the population was increasing rapidly along with rural–urban migration, leading to a growth of the urban population by about ten per cent per year. Furthermore, the modern industrial sector remained an enclave: forward and backward linkages were limited. Also, there was attention for the infrastructural development of only the largest cities – frequently only the capital city – in order to attract industry and tourism. Smaller cities and rural areas were neglected. At the end of the 1960s, it was more and more clear that this strategy had resulted in a widening not only of the gap between the rich and the poor countries, but also of the gap between the poor and the rich within each developing country separately. It is only then that international organisations – and to a much lesser extent governments – began to show some interest in agriculture as a possible engine for development. When the results of this strategy also turned out to be disappointing, to say the least, interest was directed to a number of target groups, such as the working poor, small farmers, the landless, the unemployed, slum-dwellers and the urban informal sector. The interest in the urban informal sector can therefore largely be explained by the failure of other strategies. As Bromley (1978) puts it rather cynically: ‘the informal sector concept was adapted because it arose through effective communication channels at a convenient moment, and because it embodied policy implications which were convenient for international organisations and governments’.
3 Current theoretical points of view and suggested major research topics We would rightly be accused of being overly pessimistic if we were to state that no progress can be observed during the past years, whether in theory or in research, with regard to the phenomenon of the urban informal sector. However, we would – also rightly – be accused of gross exaggeration, if we stated that recently brilliant progress has been made with regard to theoretical issues, in the field, or with regard to policy formulation. The international theoretical debate is still largely concentrated on a rather limited number of different approaches. Hardly any progress can be
Urban Informal Manufacturing Sector 321
noted in the debate. The advocates of the so-called sectoral approach (among others, Souza and Tokman, 1976; van Dijk, 1980; Sethuraman, 1981; Liedholm and Mead, 1987; De Soto, 1989) still demonstrate little consensus, not only with regard to the number of sectors that should be distinguished (two or more), but also with regard to the criteria on the basis of which such distinctions should be made. Neo-Marxist authors (for example, Lebrun and Gerry, 1975; Davies, 1979; Guerguil, 1988) make a distinction between different modes of production within one capitalist system, and try to prove that ‘petty production’ is subordinated to – but also integrated in – the capitalist mode of production. This approach is not very convincing in the light of the (scanty) empirical evidence. The third theoretical approach, the so-called continuum approach (see, for example, Bromley and Birbeck, 1984; Tezler and Molenaar, 1989), seems more promising. In this literature, the assumption is made that it makes sense to distinguish two sectors (formal and informal). However, instead of supposing that the two sectors operate essentially independently of each other, it seems more probable and realistic according to these authors that the two sectors interact with each other in a continuous fluctuating manner, and that parts of the informal sector can be dominated or even created by parts of the formal sector. Since the introduction of the formal–informal dichotomy (Hart, 1971) some progress has certainly been made in empirical research. For example, empirical research has demonstrated quite convincingly that it is incorrect to declare the informal sector synonymous with the urban poor. In most cases, paid workers in the formal sector earn considerably less than entrepreneurs in the informal sector (see Table A.27). Nevertheless, one may legitimately conclude that still relatively little is known about the urban informal sector in developing countries. The following major and often related research topics are frequently mentioned in the literature: What exactly belongs to the urban informal sector? What are the specific characteristics of this sector? To what degree do these characteristics differ from those of the formal sector? • What is the effect of the informal sector on income distribution and poverty alleviation? To what degree and how does absorption of labour take place? What are the advantages of the informal sector for the urban economy or, put in more general terms, what is the relevance of the urban informal sector for socioeconomic development? • What kinds of relationships exist between the formal and the informal sector? Do the two sectors function in relative isolation from each other? Do they compete with each other or are they complementary to each other? Should one speak of exploitation or mutual interest? • What are the constraints on further growth of the informal sector? •
322 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
4
Methodological problems
Our answers to the above questions can only be approximate and preliminary, mainly because of the methodological problems facing urban informal sector research. We will briefly discuss the main methodological problems with regard to urban informal sector research as observed in most of the case studies collected (see References). The scientific and the social value of research results is mainly determined by their degree of comparability, generalization and replicability. The first issue is concerned with conceptual definitions, units of research and theoretical frameworks. A large majority of case studies typically does not give any definition at all of the concept of the urban informal sector or provides only a vague description. Furthermore, different units of research are used: sometimes individuals, sometimes households, and sometimes production units. A theoretical framework, indicating what exactly is to be investigated and how these elements are expected to be interrelated to each other, is hardly ever given. The second issue is mainly concerned with sampling. The large majority of the case studies typically does not give any information at all about the applied sampling method. Furthermore, samples are usually very small. The population distribution according to economic activity is very seldom taken into account, resulting in substantial bias that is mentioned only very rarely by the researcher. The third issue is especially related to the operational definitions. Hardly any of the case studies provide the research instrument used, indicating how different concepts actually have been measured. In conclusion, much of the research on the urban informal sector in developing countries is still of a predominantly pre-scientific nature. As a result – as stated above – many of the relevant major research questions can so far only be answered partially and in a preliminary fashion. Although quite a few case studies have been executed, these studies are largely of a pre-scientific nature. The lack of generalisation power and the scant possibilities for comparison and replication seriously hamper theory formation.
5
Empirical evidence
Nevertheless, an attempt will be made to give (preliminary) answers to the major research questions mentioned in Section 3. These answers are based on the results found in the case studies, summarised in the References and the tables in the Appendix, grouping these questions under four different headings. In the tables unweighted averages of the case study results are presented for three continents. Results for Tanzania are reproduced in a separate column.
Urban Informal Manufacturing Sector 323
5.1
Empirical support for the formal–informal dichotomy
Appendix A.1 indicates that many basic characteristics of informal-sector organisations seem to be quite different from those of formal-sector organisations. Observed differences concerned location, type, size, age, ownership, mode of production, product mix and product variation. Typically, informal-sector organisations: • • • • • • •
have a variable location or a fixed location with a temporary structure (Table A.2) are predominantly one-man firms (Table A.3) have recently been established (Table A.5) have only one or two employees, frequently apprentices (Tables A.3 and A.4) have machines and tools among their own property, but not the workshop (Table A.6) produce mainly to order (Table A.7) demonstrate a very limited product mix coupled with large product variation (Tables A.8 and A.9).
On the basis of these findings, one may cautiously conclude that the informal-sector organisation does have specific characteristics, diverging substantially from those of the formal-sector organisation and that, therefore, the distinction formal–informal is a meaningful one, as stated by protagonists of the sectoral approach (see Section 3).
5.2 The relations between the informal sector and the formal sector Various different kinds of relationships have been investigated in the case studies: output and input relations, sources of capital, competition, type of output market, actual and desired types and degrees of government interference and formal education received (see Appendix A.2). Looking at the data one can hardly maintain that in general the informal sector is overwhelmingly exploited by the formal sector. To a substantial degree ‘exploitation’ seems to occur by formal sector households, not however by formal sector organisations (Table A.10). One could state that the informal sector to a large extent fulfils the basic needs not only of informalsector households but also of many formal-sector households. Inputs originate primarily from other informal-sector organisations (Table A.11); formal sources of capital are hardly available and/or used (Table A.12); government intervention is only marginal (Table A.16), although specific kinds of government intervention are frequently desired (Table A.17). All in all, it seems that relationships between the formal and the informal sector are rather limited. Only the following relations have been
324 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
observed. Formal education is frequently obtained by members of the informal sector (Table A.15). Much competition from formal-sector organisations is experienced by a large majority of informal-sector organisations (Table A.13). However, it should be noted that this competition is not felt to be more fierce than competition between informal-sector organisations, and it occurs in the context of still expanding markets (Table A.14). One may conclude that these rather limited relationships are consistent with the view expressed in Section 5.1, namely, that it makes sense to distinguish between formal and informal sectors. One could even speak of two societies in one country, each developing rather autonomously. 5.3
Relevance for socioeconomic development
Various aspects of the informal sector which are of relevance for socioeconomic development have been assessed in the case studies. They include: the share of the informal sector in the urban working population, the share in urban income generation, the growth of employment, the type of employment created, the use of capital, sources of training, costs and duration of informal-sector training, income distribution and income generation (see Appendix A.3). There can no doubt that both with regard to urban income and especially with regard to urban employment creation the contribution of the informal sector is considerable, notably in African countries. In Tanzania 56 per cent of the urban active population is working in the informal sector, generating 32 per cent of total urban income (Table A.18). It is also well known – and supported by the data – that the continuous intra-regional and inter-regional migration (Table A.24) is largely absorbed by the informal sector, as indicated by its average annual growth of employment of about 15 per cent. The figure for Tanzania is 16 per cent (Table A.19). It also seems clear that employment creation not only concerns selfemployment but also wage-workers, apprentices and (unpaid) family workers. In Tanzania the latter category strongly predominates: 52 per cent of informal-sector workers consist of unpaid family workers (Table A.20). These large amounts of different types of employment are created with only a minimum of capital outlay. Initial investments per person are astonishingly low and only a fraction of those in the formal sector, though there are differences between (sub)sectors. Data for Tanzania, as far as available, do not deviate substantially from the observed patterns for other countries (Table A.21). Although very limited use is made of capital, urban informal-sector entrepreneurs manage to create an income for themselves that on average is well above the legal monthly minimum wage in the formal sector. Differences between the various (sub)sectors of economic activity are substantial, but in all (sub)sectors – on average – the income of the entrepreneur in the informal sector is above the legal monthly minimum wage in the formal sector (Table A.27).
Urban Informal Manufacturing Sector 325
Although employees and apprentices on average earn less than the legal monthly minimum wage in the formal sector, it should be noted that the income distribution within the informal sector is much more equal than in the formal sector of developing countries. In Tanzania on average employees in the informal sector even seem to earn more than the legal monthly minimum wage (Table A.25). Furthermore, the training of informal-sector entrepreneurs, workers and apprentices is overwhelmingly done within the urban informal sector at ridiculously low costs, again in comparison with the formal sector. Thus, in Tanzania 91 per cent of the informal-sector entrepreneurs received their training in the informal sector, either ‘on the job’ (35 per cent) or via an apprentice system (57 per cent). The latter system seems predominant in Africa (Table A.22). Summarising, the available data clearly demonstrate the relevance of the urban informal sector for socioeconomic development. The urban informal sector generates substantial amounts of employment, income and training, absorbs migration and provides a relatively more equal income distribution, all this at only minimal capital costs. Thus, on the basis of our survey of the available empirical evidence, we may conclude that the urban informal sector – much more than its formal counterpart – can create a substantial middle class, ensuring socioeconomic development, not only for the happy few in the formal sector, but for larger segments of the whole population. 5.4 Constraints for future growth of the Tanzanian urban informal sector In Section 5.3 we emphasised the relevance of the urban informal sector for development. If our conclusion is correct, the logical consequence should be to support this sector. In order to arrive at meaningful policies, the first step should be to identify the major constraints to the further development of the informal sector. Next, stimulating policies can be formulated accordingly. In the Appendix some indications have been gathered concerning the major constraints experienced in the Tanzanian urban informal sector. Unavailability of capital or credit is reported as the most important problem (mentioned by 41 per cent of the respondents) for starting informal-sector enterprises (Table A.28). Potential starters have difficulty in starting businesses because they have little capital or credit to purchase inputs and raw materials, and have limited access to credit. Credit institutions often set difficult conditions which have to be fulfilled in order to get credit, but which rarely can be met. These include possession of fixed assets or leasehold land title deeds to act as securities, or the preparation of detailed feasibility studies for the proposed projects. Lack of equipment and spare parts is the second most important problem for starters: it is mentioned by 16 per cent of the respondents. The other problems mentioned seem far less important.
326 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
Unavailability of credit is again mentioned (by 32 per cent of the respondents) as the major problem which hinders the day-to-day operation of informal-sector enterprises, followed by non-payment of debts (mentioned by 20 per cent) and, again, unavailability of capital equipment (mentioned by 15 per cent) (Table A.29). Non-payment of debts means that net profit is eroded by customers who do not pay their debts promptly, and this reduces the amount of capital for further investment. It is not surprising then that by far the most important form of assistance needed – stated by 61 per cent of the respondents – is access to loans (Table A.30). As mentioned earlier, the present conditions for loans cannot be met by most informal entrepreneurs. What seems to be required at the least, therefore, is to simplify the procedures and to soften the credit terms in order to enable the entrepreneurs to secure the loans within a short time. Permanent sites were the second most important form of assistance needed, stated by 16 per cent of all respondents. It is therefore also necessary that municipal and city councils reserve a certain number of plots for setting up informal-sector enterprises. It should be noted that training is the least important form of assistance needed, mentioned by only 2 per cent of the respondents. This finding seems congruent with the conclusion in Section 5.3 that the informal sector is self-supporting with regard to training. Thus, most entrepreneurs do not recognise it (yet) as a needed form of assistance. However, it does not seem wise to conclude from this that training for upgrading should not be part of any assistance programme. The few respondents that did indicate that training was a form of assistance needed overwhelmingly mentioned technical training, both on the job (46 per cent) and formal (45 per cent).
6 Policy formulations for the urban informal manufacturing sector in Tanzania As stated in the introduction, urban informal sector studies – both surveys and case studies – are either very global or very limited in scope and content, both in Tanzania and elsewhere. As a consequence, policy recommendations for the urban informal sector can only be very global, since specifications cannot be made, or very limited, since the content of the research has been very limited. In 1972 the Kenya mission of the ILO (1972) already suggested a number of global measures to stimulate the development of the urban informal sector. Since then similar ideas have been put forward, in a multitude of publications, albeit in different combinations. One can safely conclude that, generally speaking, the attempts to formulate a policy for the urban informal sector have been either non-existent or too global. For example, in the Tanzanian informal sector studies it also becomes clear that access to credit facilities is of vital importance (see Section 5.4). However, the most
Urban Informal Manufacturing Sector 327
important questions have not been asked: How much credit? All at once or in phases? How much in kind and how much in money? For which activities? For which enterprises? Credit for what (which equipment, which raw materials, which semi-manufactured products, which tools, which premises)? How must credit be supervised and be repaid? In short, specification of the measures according to activity and phasing in time is lacking. Furthermore, the mutual relationships between the measures are often obscure, and alternatives are seldom formulated. It is even more rare for alternatives to be compared with each other on the basis of explicit criteria, as is necessary for deciding on policy priorities. When a government has only limited resources – a rather typical situation not only for most governments in developing countries – it seems obvious that it should distribute these scarce resources as optimally as possible, in the sense that the expected contribution to future growth and development is as high as possible. However, this will only be possible with the help of a detailed selection procedure based on questions as outlined above, resulting in alternative congruent packages of mutually supporting measures for specific sectors and subsectors. As long as such efforts are not made, only global policy formulations will be possible, leading to a suboptimal allocation of scarce resources.
Appendix Table A.1
Classification of urban informal sector enterprises according to ISIC Tanzania
Agriculture Manufacturing Food Clothing Wood Non-metal Metal Other Construction Trade Transport Services
8 24 2 5 6 2 1 8 7 51 2 6
Case studies X
R
5 15 5 6 1 1 1 1 6 53 6 15
10–3 28–10 8–2 10–3 7–<1 3–<1 4–1 10–0 11–4 68–46 8–1 20–6
Sources: Tanzania: References 1, 2, 3, 6, 7; (case studies) 19–21, 26–28, 32, 34–36, 39, 44–48, 53–54, 57–58, 63–64, 67–68, 75. Notes: (Tables A.1–A.27); x = average of the case studies; (x) = variable included only when or more case studies provide data; R = range of the case studies.
328 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Table A.2
Location according to type
% of organisations with
Tanzania Africa (x) Asia (x) LA (x)
Variable location Fixed location, temporary structure Fixed location, permanent structure
24 32 39
24 46 30
15 41 39
41 11 48
R (x) 75–7 70–7 88–10
Sources: Tanzania: References 2, 4, 5; Africa: References, 20, 25, 34, 36, 53, Asia: References 44–45, 48, 54, 57–58, 63, LA: References 19, 21, 27, 32, 47, 51, 67, 75.
Table A.3
Type of organisation
% of organisations
Tanzania
Africa (x)
74 1 26
51 6 44
One man firms Partnerships Master and apprentices/employees
Asia (x)
LA (x)
R
63 10 27
90–15 15–1 82–10
78 5 17
Sources: Tanzania: as Table A.2; Africa: as table A and 37, 39 50, 66, 70; Asia: References 42, 48, 54, 57, 58, 63–64; LA: as Table A.2, and 25, 55, 58, 62, 65.
Table A.4
Size of organisation, entrepreneur included Africa (x)
No. of persons per unit
3.3
Asia (x)
LA (x)
R
1.8
2.0
5.9–1.1
Sources: Africa: as Table A.3, Asia: References 24, 44–45, 48, 54, 57, 58, 53, 64, 72; LA: as Table A.3.
Table A.5
Age of organisations
% of organisation <1 year 1–2 years
Tanzania 16 23
Africa (x) 17 16
Asia (x)
LA (x)
R
10 12
9 10
28–7 25–7
Sources: Tanzania: References 2, 4; Africa: 20, 26, 33, 34, 35, 36, 46, 49, 50, 54; Asia: References 44, 45, 48, 58, 54, 57, 75; LA: References 24, 27, 38, 47, 55, 67.
Urban Informal Manufacturing Sector 329 Table A.6
Ownership
% of entrepreneurs with
Africa (x)
Machines/tools in own property Workshop in own property Hired workshop Free use of workshop
Asia (x)
87 15 61 24
LA (x)
80 28 50 22
R
95 43 38 19
100–74 65–4 81–20 35–5
Sources: Africa: References, 20, 34, 35, 36, 37, 40, 49, 50, 53; Asia: References 44, 45, 48, 54, 57, 63; LA: References 19, 21, 24, 51, 62, 65.
Table A.7
Mode of production
% of organisations that
Africa (x)
Produce only or mainly to order Produce only or mainly in stock
Asia (x)
LA (x)
R
62 38
64 36
80–62 60–20
67 33
Source: Africa: References 2: 20, 34, 36, 49, 50, 53; Asia: References 2: 48, 58, 54, 59, 63; LA: References 2: 17, 18, 21, 27, 41, 67, 71.
Table A.8
Product mix
% of organisations with
Africa (x)
1–2 kinds of output >2 kinds
Asia (x)
LA (x)
R
76 24
72 28
92–64 36–8
85 15
Source: Africa: References 20, 34, 36, 39, 50, 53; Asia: References 48, 58, 54, 59, 63; LA: References 17, 18, 21, 27, 41, 67, 71.
Table A.9
Product variation
% of organisations with Only or mainly standard output Only or mainly output to customer specification
Africa (x) Asia (x) LA (x) 22 78
26 74
Source: Africa: References 20, 34, 36, 49, 50, 53; Asia: References 48, 58, 54, 59, 63; LA: References 17, 18, 21, 27, 41, 67, 71.
28 72
R 36–12 95–64
330 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Table A.10
Type of customers
% of output going to
Tanzania
Individual households in informal sector in formal sector Industrial organisations in informal sector in formal sector
Africa (x)
93
75 35 40 25 17 8
7 5 2
Asia (x)
LA (x)
R
85 35 50 15 8 7
81 32 49 19 13 6
100–20 60–15 72–17 80–0 32–4 49–0
Source: Tanzania: References 16, 18, 19; Africa: References 20, 25, 34, 35, 36, 37, 49, 50, 53, 70; Asia: References 26, 38, 48, 58, 54, 57, 59, 63; LA: References 15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 21, 32, 57, 67, 71, 75.
Table A.11
Type of suppliers
% of inputs coming from
Tanzania
Africa (x)
75 25 0
66 33 1
Informal sector organisations Formal sector organisations Importation
Asia (x) 79 21 0
LA (x)
R
66 34 0
90–22 78–10 2–0
Source: Tanzania: References 16, 18; Africa: References 20, 25, 34, 35, 36, 50, 53, 70; Asia: References 26, 38, 43, 48, 58, 54, 57, 59, 63; LA: References 15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 21, 32, 57, 67, 71, 75.
Table A.12
Main sources of capital
Income from sales Money lenders Personal networks (family, friends) Advance from customers Credit from supplies Banks, government
Tanzania
Africa (x)
Asia (x)
LA (x)
R
47 0 52 0 0 1
74 1 17 2 4 2
79 2 12 1 2 4
78 1 11 1 1 8
93–51 3–1 29–2 5–1 15–1 8–1
Source: Tanzania: References 16, 17, 18; Africa: References 20, 22, 25, 28, 34, 35, 36, 39, 49, 66, 70; Asia: References 26, 38, 42, 43, 48, 58, 54, 57, 59, 63; LA: References 15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 21, 24, 27, 32, 38, 55, 71, 75.
Urban Informal Manufacturing Sector 331 Table A.13
Competition
% of entrepreneurs that experience much competition with Informal sector organisations Formal sector organisations
Africa (x) Asia (x) LA (x) 72 67
65 75
58 60
R 84–50 94–40
Source: Africa: References 25, 34, 37, 53, 60, 66; Asia: References 42, 48, 58, 59, 62; LA: References 15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 21, 24, 27.
Table A.14
Type of output market
% of entrepreneurs that mention
Africa (x)
A decrease in demand A constant demand An increase in demand
17 17 67
Asia (x)
LA (x)
R
22 38 40
23 35 42
40–4 50–10 86–40
Source: Africa: References 20, 25, 28, 34, 35, 39, 40, 46, 53, 68; Asia: References 48, 58, 54, 57, 59, 63; LA: References 17, 18, 19, 21, 38, 71, 75.
Table A.15
Formal education received Tanzania
No. of school years % with no formal education % with primary education % with secondary education % with vocational education
Africa (x)
– 17 77 2 2
Asia (x)
LA (x)
R
5.2 24 65 11
5.5 39 46 15
9–3 74–3 97–12 60–0 9–0
4.3 54 29 16 4
Source: Tanzania: References 16, 17, 18; Africa: References 20, 22, 28, 34, 35, 36, 46, 49, 54; Asia: References 26, 43, 44, 45, 48, 54, 57, 59, 63, 64; LA: References 17, 18, 21, 57, 65, 75, 73.
Table A.16
Actual government interference
% of enterprises With a government licence With inspection by government That pay taxes With government as a customer
Africa(x) 20 14 15 4
Asia(x)
LA(x)
R
25 21 20
12 12
25–12 21–12 20–15 20–0
Source: Africa: References 20, 28, 34, 35, 39, 40, 49, 68; Asia: References 26, 48, 54, 57, 59, 64; LA: References 17, 18, 21, 32, 67, 71, 75.
332 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Table A.17
Desired government interference
% of enterprises that desire on the part of the government
Africa(x)
Professional training courses Credit facilities Infrastructural provisions Measures to stimulate demand
Asia(x)
34 62 46 34
R
58 76 59 23
90–0 80–55 66–40 55–10
Source: Africa: References 20, 28, 34, 35, 52, 53, 68; Asia: References 34, 48, 54, 57, 59, 64.
Table A.18
Size of urban informal sector Tanzania
% of urban active population working in informal sector % of urban income originating from informal sector
Africa
Asia
LA
(x)
R
(x)
R
(x)
R
56
50
73–31
40
69–19
42 60–24
32
40
55–28
29
45–16
29 40–14
Source: Tanzania: References 15, 16, 18, 19, 20–23; Africa: References 20, 28, 33, 34, 35, 36, 37, 39, 40, 46, 49, 52, 53, 60, 61, 68, 70; Asia: References 34, 38, 42, 44, 45, 48, 54, 57, 63, 64, 72, 74; LA: References 15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 21, 32, 57, 67, 71, 75.
Table A.19
Growth of employment, average annual
% growth, average annual
Tanzania
Africa(x)
Asia(x)
LA(x)
R
In formal urban sector In informal urban sector
16
5 15
9
9
28–6
Source: Tanzania: References 16, 18, 23; Africa: References 20, 22, 28, 34, 35, 36, 37, 39, 40, 46, 53, 68; Asia: References 26, 44, 45, 48, 54, 57, 63, 64; LA: References 15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 21, 32, 57, 67, 71, 75.
Table A.20
Type of employment
% of workers that are Wage workers Unpaid (family) Appentices
Tanzania
Africa(x)
Asia(x)
LA(x)
R
20 52 28
40 10 50
60 35 5
77 16 7
83–7 50–7 86–0
Source: Tanzania: References 16, 18, 23; Africa: References 20, 25, 34, 35, 36, 37, 39, 50, 53, 66, 68, 70; Asia: References 38, 43, 44, 45, 48, 58, 54, 57, 59, 63, 74; LA: References 15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 21, 67, 71, 75, 73.
Urban Informal Manufacturing Sector 333 Table A.21 Use of capital (initial investments per person/legal monthly minimum wage, formal sector) Tanzania
Africa Informal sector (x) R
All activities Manufacturing Food, beverages Textiles Apparel Leather Wood Paper Metal Other Construction Trade Transport Services Repair/maintenance
1.4
1.4
1.8 2.5 1.4 1.8 2.2 1.2 2.6 7.9 4.7 5.0 5.4 1.3 4.0 2.3 0.7
10.0–0.5 8.5–0.9 1.5–1.2 3.4–0.5
Formal sector (x)
FS/IS
25.0
13.9
50.0 20.0
35.7 11.1
1.7–0.9 5.4–1.0
64.0
53.3
6.0–2.3 8.5–2.0 10.0–0.7 2.0–0.5 6.4–1.6 3.0–1.5 0.8–0.5
20.0
4.3
Source: Tanzania: References 16, 18; Africa: References 20, 28, 34, 35, 39, 40, 53.
Table A.22
Training, sources of training for informal-sector entrepreneurs
% of entrepreneurs that received their training In the informal sector ‘On the job’ By the apprentice system In the formal sector Government Private enterprises Training institutions
Tanzania
Africa(x)
LA (x)
R
91 35 57 9 2 3 4
88 23 65 12 3 6 3
85 70 15 15 4 8 3
94–82 70–0 92–15 18–6 4–3 10–2 8–0
Source: Tanzania: References 16, 18, 20; Africa: References 20, 22, 28, 34, 35, 36, 39, 49, 50, 53, 68; LA: References 15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 57, 71.
Table A.23
Training, costs and duration of informal-sector training
Total costs (US dollars) Duration (no. of years)
Africa(x)
R
78 2.7
125–50 4.5–0.4
Source: Africa: References 20, 28, 36, 37, 53, 68.
334 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
Table A.24 Migration, overall (% of enterpreneurs not born in town of actual residence) and according to type Africa(x) Overall International Inter-regional Intra-regional
76 7 32 36
Asia(x)
LA(x)
R
37 0 10 27
64 3 11 50
98–14 13–0 42–6 60–4
Source: Africa: References 20, 36, 37, 53; Asia: References 48, 54, 57, 63, 64; LA: References 17, 18, 32, 57, 75.
Table A.25
Income-distribution, wage structure in the informal sector Tanzania
Payment, apprentice Wage, employee Income, entrepreneur Legal minimum wage in formal sector
1.22 2.60 1.00
Africa(x)
Asia(x)
LA(x)
0.14 0.71 2.14 1.00
0.33 1.33 1.00
0.50 1.50 1.00
Source: Tanzania: References 16, 18, 19; Africa: References 20, 34, 35, 36, 37, 53; Asia: References 43, 48, 54, 57, 49, 63; LA: References 15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 21, 55, 71, 73.
Table A.26 subsector
Income-Distribution, wage structure of employees according to
Trade Services Construction Manufacturing
Africa(x)
Asia(x)
1 1.3 4.9 2.4
1 1.8
Source: Africa: References 20, 34, 35, 36, 37, 53; Asia: References 43, 48, 54, 59, 63.
Urban Informal Manufacturing Sector 335
Table A.27 Entrepreneur income informal-sector (monthly income owner/legal monthly minimum wage, formal sector)
All activities Manufacturing Food Textiles Apparel Leather Wood Metal Other Construction Trade Transport Services Repair/maintenance
Tanzania
Africa(x)
Asia(x)
LA(x)
2.6
2.1 2.7 3.5 3.8 2.2 1.3 3.4 2.4 4.0 7.0 1.6 3.8 2.5 1.3
1.4
1.5
Source: Tanzania: References 16, 18; Africa: References 20, 34, 35, 36, 37, 53; Asia: References 43, 48, 53, 54, 57, 59, 63; LA: References 15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 21, 55, 71, 73.
Table A.28
Most important problem faced when establishing enterprises Tanzania (%)
1. Capital or credit 2. Lack at equipment/spare parts 3. Finding premises 4. Market/customers 5. Government regulations 6. Raw materials 7. Transport 8. Skilled workers 9. Service, e.g. water 10. Other
41 16 12 11 6 6 3 1 1 3
Source: (Tables A.28–A.31) Planning Commission, Ministry of Labour and Youth Development (1991).
336 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania Table A.29
Most important problem encountered during day-to-day operation Tanzania (%)
1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13.
Credits Non-payment debts Unavailability of capital equipment Raw materials Transport Space Management skill Regulations/law Taxes/licence fees Thieves Spare parts Skilled personnel Other
Table A.30
32 20 15 7 5 4 3 2 2 2 1 0 8
Most important form of assistance needed Tanzania (%)
1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10.
Loans Permanent site Raw materials Transport Marketing Modern technology Government regulations Training, self Training, workers Other
Table A.31
61 16 6 5 4 4 2 2 0 0
Training needed by type Tanzania (%)
1. 2. 3. 4. 5.
Technical skills – on the job Technical skills – formal Commercial/financial Literacy Managerial
46 45 6 3 0
Urban Informal Manufacturing Sector 337
Notes * Section of Technology and Development Studies, Faculty of Technology Management, Eindhoven University of Technology 1. The list of Tanzanian studies in the References (1–14) is complete and updated. The list of case studies in the References (15–75) contains only two references after 1990. Thus the comparative database refers to studies from the period 1975–90.
References Relevant informal sector studies in Tanzania Informal sector: surveys 1. Aboagye, A. A. (1985), An Analysis of Dar es Salaam’s Informal Sector Survey, Addis Ababa: Jobs and Skills Programme for Africa. 2. Planning Commission, Ministry of Labour and Youth Development (1991), The National Informal Sector Survey, Dar es Salaam. 3. Planning Commission, Ministry of Labour and Youth Development (1995), Dar es Salaam Informal Sector Survey, 1994/5, Dar es Salaam. 4. Tegelaars, M. (1994), ‘Performance Upgrading of Informal Building Contractors in Dar es Salaam (Tanzania)’, Eindhoven: MSc Thesis, Technology and Development Studies, Eindhoven University of Technology. 5. Treffers, M. (1996), ‘The Informal Building Process in Dar es Salaam, Tanzania. A Contribution to the Upgrading of the Informal Construction Sector and the Formulation of a Management Plan for Hazard Land’, Eindhoven: MSc Thesis, Technology and Development Studies, Eindhoven University of Technology.
Informal sector: estimates 6. Bagachwa, M.S.D. (1993), ‘Estimates of Informal Parallel and Black Market Activities in Tanzania’, paper for the International Conference on Development Challenges and Strategies for Tanzania: An Agenda for the 21st Century, Dar es Salaam: Economic Research, October 25–1993. 7. Bagachwa, M.S.D. and A. Naho (1995), ‘Estimating the Second Economy in Tanzania’, World Development, 23, 8, 1387–99. 8. Maliyamkono, T.L. and M.S.D. Bagachwa (1990), The Second Economy in Tanzania, London: Eastern African Studies. 9. Mtatifikolo, F.P. (1995), ‘The Subterranean Economy in Tanzania. Its Structure and Annual Aggregates mid-1970s to mid-1980s’, unpublished paper.
Informal sector: policy 10. Bagachwa, M.S.D. (1983), ‘Structure and Policy Problems of the Informal Manufacturing Sector in Tanzania’, ERB Paper 83.1, Dar es Salaam: Economic Research Bureau. 11. Bagachwa, M.S.D. (1995), ‘The Informal Sector Adjustment in Tanzania’, in: L.A. Msambichaka, A.A.L. Kilindo and G.D. Mjema (eds), Beyond Structural Adjustment Program in Tanzania, Successes, Failures and New Perspectives, Dar es Salaam: Economic Research Bureau.
338 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania 12. Bienefield, M. (1975), ‘The Informal Sector and Peripheral Capitalism: The Case of Tanzania’, Institute of Development Studies Bulletin, 6, 3, 33–73. 13. ILO (1993), The State and the Informal Sector in Tanzania: Report of a Study on the Development Policies and Institutional Environment for the Informal Sector in Tanzania, Addis Ababa: Jobs and Skills Programme for Africa. 14. Vitta, P.B. (1985), ‘The Informal Sector in Eastern Africa: Selected Policy-Related Issues’, Africa Development, 10, 4, 59–71.
List of case studies 15. Alba Vega, C. and D. Kruyt (1988), Los Empresarios y la Industria de Guadalajara, Guadalajara: El Colegio de Jalisco, Mexico. 16. Alonso, J. (1979), ‘The Domestic Seamstresses in Nezahualcoyad: A Case Study on Feminine Over-Exploitation in a Marginal Urban Area’, New York: PhD Thesis, New York University. 17 Alonso, J. (1983), ‘Domestic Clothing Workers in the Mexican Metropolis and their Relationship’, International Labour Review, 131, 3, 161–172. 18. Arias, P. (1985), Guadalajara, la Gran Ciudad de la Pequena Industria, Michoacan: El Colegio de Michoacan. 19. Arizpe, L. (1977), ‘Women in the Informal Labour Sector: The Case of Mexico City’, Signs, 3, 1, 25–37. 20. Aryee, G. (1981), ‘The Informal Manufacturing Sector in Kumasi’ in S. Sethuraman (ed.) (Reference 69). 21. Arocena, M. (1982), ‘Forms of Production in the Shoe Industry in Léon, Guanajuanto’, Austin: PhD Thesis, University of Feras. 22. Baron, J. and W. Bielby (1984), ‘The Organization of Work in a Segmented Economy’, American Sociological Review, 49, 4, 454–73. 23. Beneria, L. and R. Roldan (1987), The Crossroads of Class and Gender: Industrial Homework Subcontracting and Household Dynamics in Mexico City, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 24. Birkbeck, C. (1978), ‘Self Employed Proletarians in an Informal Factory: The Case of Cali’s Garbage Dump’, World Development, 6, 9–10. 25. Bosch, E. (1983), Marktvrouwen van Bobo, het Leven en Werken van Handelaarsters in de Stad Bobo-Dioulassa in Boven Volta, Leiden: Instituut voor Culturele Antropologie. 26. Bose, A. (1974), The Informal Sector in the Calcutta Metropolitan Economy, ILO, WEP 2-19, WP 5. 27. Bromley, R.J. (1978), ‘Organization, Regulation and Exploitation in the So-Called Urban Informal Sector: The Street Traders of Cali Columbia’, World Development, Sept.-Oct., 1161–86. 28. Bromley, R. and C. Gerry (ed.) (1979), Casual Work and Poverty in Third World Cities, Chichester: Wiley. 29. Bunster, X. and E. Chaney (1985), Sellers and Servants, Working Women in Lima, Peru, New York: Praeger. 30. Calleja Pinedo, M. et al. (1980), Unidad Doméstica y Organización del Trabajo de la Industria Calzado en León, Guanajuato. 31. Conradi, P. (1988), Los Campamentos: Huishoudens en Overlevingsstrategieën; een Exploratief Onderzoek naar het Functioneren van Overlevingsstrategieën in een Lage Inkomenswijk in San Louis Potosi (Mexico), Geografisch Instituut, Rijksuniversiteit Utrecht.
Urban Informal Manufacturing Sector 339 32. Defranco, S.D. (1980), Employment and the Urban Informal Sector: The Case of Managua, Ann Arbor, Michigan: Xerox Univ. Microfilms. 33. Diemer, G. and W. van der Laan (1981), ‘The Informal Sector in Historical Perspective: The Case of Tunis’, Cultures et Développement, 13, 1–2. 34. Dijk, M.P. van (1980), ‘De Informele Sector van Ouagadougou en Dakar’, Amsterdam: PhD Thesis, Vrije Universiteit. 35. Effron, L. (1980), The Informal Sector in Abidjan (Ivory Coast) in: S. Sethuraman (ed.) (Reference 69). 36. Fapohunda, O.J. (1981), ‘Human Resources and the Lagos Informal Sector’ in S. Sethuraman (ed.) (Reference 69). 37. Fowler, D.A. (1981), ‘The Informal Sector in Freetown: Opportunities for SelfEmployment’, in S. Sethuraman (ed.) (Reference 69). 38. Gelder, P. van (1985), Werken onder de Boom: Dynamiek en Informele Sector: de Situatie in Groot-Paramaribo, Dordrecht: Foris Publications. 39. Gerry, C. (1974), ‘Petty Producers and the Urban Economy: A Case Study of Dakar’, Working Paper, World Employment Programme Research, no. 8, Geneva: International Labour Office. 40. Gerry, C. (1978), ‘Petty Production and Capitalist Production in Dakar: The Crisis of the Self-Employed’, World Development, 6, 9/10, 1127–60. 41. Gonzalez de la Rocha, M. (1984), ‘Domestic Organisation and Reproduction of Low-Income Households, the Case of Guadalajara, Mexico’, Manchester: PhD Thesis, University of Manchester. 42. Guisinger, S. and M. Irfan (1978), ‘Pakistan’s Informal Sector: The Case of Rawalpindi’, Journal of Development Studies, 412–426. 43. Harris, J., ‘Character of an Urban Economy; Small-Scale Production and Labour Markets in Coimbatore’, Economic and Political Weekly, 17, 23, 945–54, 24, 993–1002. 44. ILO (1974), Calcutta, see A. Bose (Reference 26). 45. ILO (1975), Djakarta. 46. ILO (1975), Abidjan. 47. ILO (1976), Sao Paulo. 48. Jurado, G.M. et al. (1981), ‘The Manilla Informal Sector: In Transition’, in S. Sethuraman (Reference 69). 49. Kennedy, P. (1981), ‘The Role and Position of Petty Producers in a West African City (Accra, Ghana)’, Journal of Modern African Studies, 565–94. 50. King, K.J. (1974), ‘Kenya’s Informal Machine-Makers: A Study of Small Scale Industry in Kenya’s Emergent Artisan Society’, World Development, 2, 4, 9–28. 51. Laenen, A. (1988), Dinamica y Transformacion de la Pequena Industria en Nicaragua, Dordrecht: Foris Publications, series: CEDLA Latin American Studies, 42. 52. Livingstone, J. (1991), ‘A Reassessment of Kenya’s Rural and Urban Informal Sector’, World Development, 19, 6. 53. Mabogunje, A.L. and M.O. Filani (1981), ‘The Informal Sector in a Small City: The Case of Kano’, in S. Sethuraman (Reference 69). 54. Marga Institute (1981), ‘Informal Sector without Migration: The Case of Colombo’, in S. Sethuraman (Reference 69). 55. Merrick, T.W. (1976), ‘Employment and Earnings in the Informal Sector in Brazil: The Case of Belo Horizonte’, Journal of Developing Areas, 10. 56. Middleton, A. (1981), ‘Petty Manufacturing, Capitalist Enterprises and the Proces of Accumulation in Ecuador’, Development and Change, 12, 4, 505–24.
340 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania 57. Moir, H. (1981), ‘Occupational Mobility and the Informal Sector in Jakarta’, in S. Sethuraman (Reference 69). 58. Mosselman, L. (1992), Kleine Ondernemers in Kerala (India), Rotterdam: Erasmus Universiteit Rotterdam. 59. Naponen, H. (1987), ‘Organizing Women Petty Traders and Home-Based Producers: A Case Study, India’, in Singh A. et al. (eds), Invisible Hands, Women and Home-Based Production, New Delhi: Sage Publications. 60. Nihan, G. and R. Jourdan (1978), ‘The Modern Informal Sector in Nouakchott’, International Labour Review, 117, 6, 709–719. 61. Nihan, G., et al. (1979), ‘The Modern Informal Sector in Lomé’, International Labour Review, 118, 5, 631–44. 62. Pansters, W.G. (1985), De Dialektiek van Mikro en Makro, een Onderzoek naar het Funktioneren van Kleinschalige Bedrijvigheid in Ciudad Juarez, Mexico, Rijksuniversiteit Utrecht: Geografisch Instituut, Diskussiestukken van de vakgroep Sociale Geografie van Ontwikkelingslanden, nr. 30. 63. Papola, T.S. (1978), The Informal Sector in an Urban Economy: A Study in Ahmedabad, New York: PhD Thesis, New York University. 64. Papola, T. (1981), Urban Informal Sector in a Developing Economy, New Delhi: Vikas. 65. Pfeiffer, P. (1987), Politische, Sozio ökonomische und Urbanistische Aspecte der Favelas und ihre Sociale Organisation in Rio de Janeiro, Stuttgard: PhD Thesis, University of Stuttgard. 66. Regt, M. de (1990), Tapijtknoopsters in Rabat-Salé (Marokko), Nijmegen: PhD Thesis, University of Nijmegen. 67. Sanchez, C.B. et al. (1981), The Informal and Quasi-Formal Sectors in Cordoba in S. Sethuraman (Reference 69). 68. Sethuraman, S.V. (1977), ‘The Urban Informal Sector in Africa’, International Labour Review, 116, 3, 343–352. 69. Sethuraman, S. (ed.) (1981), The Urban Informal Sector in Developing Countries, Employment, Poverty and Environment, Geneva: ILO. 70. Simon, D. (1984), ‘Urban Poverty, Informal Sector Activity and Intersectoral Linkages: Evidence from Windhoek (Namibia)’, Development and Change, 15, 4. 71. Smith, S. (1988), Een Studie van de Ontwikkelingsmogelijkheden van de Informele Kleding- en textielnijverheid in Aguascalientes (Mexico), Nijmegen: Katholieke Universiteit Nijmegen. 72. Sit, V.F.S. et al. (1980), ‘Ambulatory Labour in Hong Kong’, International Labour Review, 119, 4, 505–514. 73. Suarez, R. (1988), Informal Sector, Labour Markets and Returns to Education in Peru, Washington D.C.: World Bank. 74. Tom, J. (1987), De Inschakeling van Vrouwenarbeid in de Zijde-Industrie in ZuidIndia: de Dynamiek van de Informele Sector Belicht, Amsterdam: Vrije Universiteit: Geografische en Planologische Notities, no. 51. 75. Tosta Berlinck, M. et al. (1981), ‘The Urban Informal Sector and Industrial Development in a Small City: The Case of Campinas’, in S. Sethuraman (Reference 69).
15 The Impact of Reforms in Tanzania: The Case of Privatized Manufacturing Industries Humphrey P.B. Moshi*
1
Introduction
The main objectives of public-sector reforms, including the restructuring of public expenditures and reforming the framework for public enterprise management, ownership and operation, are: to increase the efficiency of the productive sector and raise economic growth; to reduce government budgetary costs and increase revenue, thereby improving the fiscal balance; to broaden direct private ownership and control of productive assets; and to reduce and reorient the role of government to that of providing social and economic infrastructure and implementation of economic policy, rather than to being involved in direct production. This article focuses on privatised manufacturing industries with a view to analyse the trends in capacity utilization, productivity and technological acquisition with reference to a selected sample of industries.
2
Conceptual framework
Privatisation is a term used to describe a wide range of policies designed to effect a transfer of activity from the public sector to private sector. However, privatisation does not necessarily require total divestiture. Franchising, contracting out and leasing, whereby public-sector activities are undertaken by the private sector, are widespread forms of privatization (Hemming and Miranda, 1991). For the purpose of this study privatization will embrace cases of partial and total divestiture. Partial divestiture refers to the creation of joint ventures between public and private sector organizations, with the private-sector organization holding majority shares and assuming management responsibilities. The principal rationale for privatization is the assumption that the private sector will be able to increase the efficiency of production. 341
342 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
Therefore, the sale of state enterprises is designed to prevent the private sector from being squeezed out by the public sector. It can also reduce the channels and therefore possibilities for public-sector corruption (Biersteker, 1991). In the above context, it can be argued that reform of the state enterprise sector and privatization are mutually supporting strategies aimed at achieving wider objectives of creating a more efficient, market-oriented and more productive economy. Broadly speaking, two sets of conclusions emerge from the literature on privatization. The first finds private enterprises clearly superior. There is robust evidence that state enterprises and mixed enterprises are less profitable and less efficient than private corporations (Boardman and Vining 1989, p. 17). • There is virtually universal consensus that privatisation improves efficiency (Boyco, et al., 1993, p. 1). • Without exception, the empirical findings indicate that the same level of output could be provided at substantially lower costs if output were produced by the private rather the public sector (Bennett and Johnson, 1979, p. 59). •
A second body of literature draws rather different conclusions. The earliest (to our knowledge) and most influential formulation of this position is that of Caves and Christensen (1980, p. 974): ‘Contrary to what is predicted in the property rights literature, we find no evidence of inferior efficiency performance by government owned railroads … public ownership is not inherently less efficient than private ownership … the often-noted inefficiency of government enterprises stems from their isolation from effective competition rather then their public ownership per se.’ The first set of theories links privatization to increased productive and allocative efficiency. Privatization is expected to reduce the productive inefficiency arising from public ownership. However, representatives of the second perspective caution that improvements in allocative efficiency will generally only be achieved when privatization goes hand in hand with increased exposure of firms to competition (Hemming and Miranda, 1991).
3 3.1
Reforms and industrial performance The reforms
The drive to address the socioeconomic crisis began in 1981 and focused on four main programmes (see also Chapter 1): the national economic survival programme (NESP, 1981/82); the structural adjustment programme (SAP, 1982/83–1984/85); the Economic Recovery Programme (ERP, 1986/87– 1988/89); and the economic and social action programme
Impact of Reforms in Tanzania 343
(ESAP, 1989/90– 1991/92). The overall performance of NESP and SAP had been very poor because these programmes failed to improve the domestic production capacity of the economy. The critical weakness of the pre-1986 reforms was their failure to address fundamental constraints inherent in a highly controlled and state dominated socioeconomic system. In the subsequent reform efforts, however, these impediments did receive adequate attention. In an attempt to improve the performance of the industrial sector two policies were adopted. The first policy shift was in favour of financing improvements in utilization of existing capacities rather than in creation of new capacities. This shift was informed by the realization that the speed at which capacity was being created had outstripped the ability to finance recurrent inputs, especially imported inputs (Wangwe, 1992b). Therefore, resources were directed towards rehabilitation of productive sectors as well as of the infrastructure. To that effect donor initiatives took the form of balance of payment support, import support and commodity import support. The overall impact of this policy shift is reflected in fairly modest real growth rates of investment. The second policy shift, which was adopted in the early 1990s, was that of privatisation of public enterprises as a way of turning around the performance of the economy in general. At this juncture it was realized that there was a need to redefine the roles of the state and the private sector in the national economy in order to achieve an appropriate balance, supportive of growth and efficiency. The response of the private sector to the new policy environment has been quite positive as far as investment is concerned. The share of private investment in total investment increased from about 50 per cent in the mid-1970s to 60 per cent in 1986, and further to 70 per cent in the early 1990s. This partly reflects the slow-down of investment in the parastatal sector and partly the private-sector response to economic liberalization and an improved government attitude towards private enterprise. An analysis of the investment behaviour of both the private and public sector for the 1967–95 period suggests that public investment reduced its contribution to GDP to 8.1 per cent during 1981–85 and rose slightly to 10.3 per cent in the reform period. In the case of private investment, a different pattern is observed. Its share of GDP depicts a rising trend, rising from a low 11.3 per cent in 1967–80 to 17.6 per cent during the reform period (Likwelile, 1997). The public-sector trend observed with respect to GDP is also reflected in the case of gross fixed capital formation. Having contributed significantly to GFCF during the pre-reform period (54.1 per cent), the public sector share fell to 32.8 per cent (1981–85) and then slightly rose again to 37.6 per cent (1986–95), the average for the entire period being 41.5 per cent. The contribution of the private sector to GFCF rose from 45.9 per cent (1967–80) to 62.4 per cent during the reform period, with an average of
344 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
53 per cent for the whole period. The decrease in public investment should be celebrated with some caution, however. Whether or not public investments crowd out private investment depends very much on the nature of those public investments. For instance, investment in infrastructure tends to complement private investment (Moshi and Kilindo, 1995). This points to the need for public investment to concentrate on those projects which demonstrate positive relationships between private and public investment. On the privatization front, evidence shows that the privatization exercise has not been very successful in terms of speed and numbers of enterprises involved. So far only about 68 per cent (270 out of 395) of the firms targetted for divestiture have actually been divested. Further, the privatization exercise has not been able to attract the envisioned massive amounts of foreign direct investment (FDI). The performance of the industrial sector shows some improvement. Overall manufacturing output expanded as access to foreign exchange improved, and trade and exchange-rate reforms reduced the prevailing anti-export bias. Capacity utilisation has increased to an average of 50 per cent. Nevertheless, the share of manufacturing GFCF has almost remained the same, at 22.2 per cent of GDP for the last five years. Further, in the recent past (1991–95) the growth of industrial output declined to around two per cent (Wangwe, Musonda and Kweka, 1997). 3.2
Privatised firms: some insights
In this section we analyse the performance of two firms (one consumer goods and one capital goods producer) which were hitherto under government ownership. The analysis should help us assess whether or not privatised firms are ‘bearers’ of hope for industrial revival and competitiveness. 3.2.1
Tanzania Breweries Limited (TBL)
Background. Prior to its privatisation in 1993 TBL was 100 per cent owned by the Tanzanian government. At present TBL is a joint venture of the government (40.4%), INDOLL International B.V. (45.9%), International Finance Co. (9.8%), PROPARCO (1.8%), Dresdener Bank Luxembourg S.A. (1.6%) and the Dutch Financing Corporation for Development (FMO) (0.8%). Recently, the government has shown interest in selling 20 per cent of its shares to the public. TBL’s main line of business is that of the production, distribution and sale of malt beer in Tanzania. It operates breweries in Dar es Salaam, Arusha and Mwanza. The management of the firm is under contracted management with INDOLL, a South African company Performance. The performance of the firm prior to privatization in 1993 shows negative growth. In 1992 output was six percentage points below
Impact of Reforms in Tanzania 345
the 4.2 million crates produced in 1988. The post-privatisation period depicts an average annual growth, in terms of production, of 34.1 per cent. Production increased threefold from 4.2 million cases in 1993 to 13.6 million crates in 1997.1 During the period of total government ownership, capacity utilization at TBL was very low. It averaged 20 per cent for the Dar es Salaam and Arusha plants and 0 per cent in the case of the Mwanza plant. After privatisation the utilization rate rose to 65 per cent (over 90 per cent in 1997) for the former plant and 85 per cent for the latter two plants. Productivity and efficiency levels have improved when compared to the situation before divestiture. In this context the number of productive manhours increased from 30 per cent (1993) to 40 per cent (1994) and further to 42.2 per cent (1995). Likewise, the productivity of labour increased from 177 hectolitres per employee (1993) to 592 hectolitres per employee (1995). The target is to produce 1000 hectolitres per employee. Further, efficiency in terms of utilisation of raw materials and consumption of water and electricity has been enhanced, and beer losses during brewing, packing and distribution have been significantly minimized. The financial performance of TBL has been positive. In 1993 the firm earned a profit of US$15 million, and all subsequent years have witnessed increased profits. Thus, the firm contributed positively to the government budget both through taxes and dividends. The financial soundness of the firm has made it possible for the management to offer an attractive financial package to its workers as an incentive for further enhancement of productivity. Thus, a virtuous circle of higher profitability, enhanced productivity and higher wages emerges. 3.2.2
ABB TANELEC
Background. The Tanzanian Electrical Goods Manufacturing Company (TANELEC) started operations in 1981. It produces transformers, switch gears, cookers and light fittings. It was a joint venture owned by the National Development Corporation (60%), Tanzania Electricity Supply Company (TANESCO, 20%) and the National Industry of Norway (20%). The firm was divested in 1995 and the new ownership structure is as follows: ABB sub-Saharan Africa (50%), ABB Norway (20%), TANESCO (20%) and NDC (10%). The management contract is with ABB Norway. Performance. The production performance of transformers, switch gears, cookers and light fittings for the 1983–91 period was quite erratic, but generally showed a declining trend. For example, the production of transformers declined from 217 units to 201 between 1983 and 1984. It later rose to 456 units in 1985 and further to 638 units in 1990. The production of switch gears increased from 86 units in 1983 to 114 in 1985, dropping
346 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
drastically to only 7 units in 1990. The production of cookers declined from 9393 units in 1985 to 6646 units in 1990. There are no data on trends of production per product line after privatization. However, management claims that capacity utilization has increased from below 50 per cent (pre-divestiture period) to 100 and 80 per cent in the case of transformers and switch gear, respectively. The increase in capacity utilization should also mirror improved efficiency in terms of productivity as well as higher profitability rates. On the export front the firm has performed quite well. The firm exports over 70 per cent of its products compared to the pre-divestiture period when it used to export about 30 per cent of its output. The enhanced competitiveness of the firm underscores the positive effects of the privatization exercise.
4
Factors accounting for the turnaround
The two case studies of successful privatisation efforts discussed above should not be seen as isolated cases. Evidence (Due and Temu, 1996; Moshi, 1996) shows that the majority of the privatised industrial firms have turned around. These include the Tanzania Cigarette Company (TCC), Bora Shoe Company, Morogoro Shoe Company, and Tanzania Portland Cement. There are also examples where turnaround was initially not successful, but is expected to take place over time. These include African Tanneries Ltd (AT), Mwanza. Indeed, one needs to appreciate the fact that the pace and the magnitude of the turnaround of the divested enterprise will vary depending on the nature of the sector or subsector in which an enterprise operates, and on the initial condition of an enterprise at the time of divestiture. A number of factors have accounted for the successful turnaround of the divested enterprises. These are the following: Improved access to finance via foreign direct investment for the companies which were sold to multinationals. This accounts for about a dozen cases. The establishment of private-sector financial institutions in Tanzania has further improved the accessibility of finance. • Acquisition of modern technology, which improves both labour and capital productivity and the quality of product(s). Massive investment by the new owners of breweries (US$ 48.5 million) and of TANELEC (US$ 2.5 million) facilitated the acquisition of modern machinery and equipment. • Competent and accountable management that is cost conscious and flexible, and adheres to a ‘management by objectives’ approach. The post-privatisation retrenchments are indicative of management’s quest for profits through cost-reduction initiatives. •
Impact of Reforms in Tanzania 347
Improved workers’ welfare. This includes better pay packages, which boost the morale of the labour force and consequently improve productivity. • Targeted training of employees as a way of enhancing their capabilities by exposing them to modern organisational and production technologies. • An improved policy environment that is more friendly to the private sector, coupled with wide-ranging complementary reforms. That is, a market-oriented environment. • Near monopoly positions of the firms studied. For example, TANELEC controls 90 per cent of the domestic market as far as transformers are concerned. In the case of switch gears it has a total (100%) monopoly. Likewise, TBL is a giant in the beer industry, having a market share of about 85 per cent in 1998. Though there are small competing breweries, a monopoly exists at the level of brands. They belong exclusively to a particular brewery. In the case of TBL the brands are Safari, Ndovu, Kilimanjaro and Bingwa. The Associated Breweries has a monopoly in the production of Serengeti and kick brands. •
In spite of the performance-enhancing factors listed above, there are also constraints which have either increased the transaction costs of doing business or have hindered the privatised firms from realising performance targets. These constraints include the following: • •
• • • • •
5
Inadequate and unreliable supply of infrastructural services especially transport, telecommunication, water and energy. Lack of credible public supporting institutions, arising from unclear definition of the roles of the Tanzanian Investment Centre (TIC), the Ministry of Trade and Industries (MIT) and the Treasury. Competition from cheap but poor-quality imports, which are either not taxed at all or lowly taxed. High interest rates, which tend to discourage borrowing and thus hinder capacity expansion or the acquisition of modern technology. Lack of an effective legal and institutional framework for prompt recovery of debts, especially from government ministries and parastatals. A weak private sector and the concomitant narrow and shallow character of interfirm business linkages. A civil service that is inefficient, poorly paid, unmotivated and corruptive, failing to deliver services adequately and efficiently. The mindset of the civil servants is far from being in tune with an economy which is private-sector led.
Concluding remarks
It is evident from the two cited case studies that the privatisation of public enterprises in the context of ongoing macroeconomic policy and
348 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
institutional reforms has impacted positively on the manufacturing sector. This has resulted in higher output, better utilization of capacity, higher productivity, improved product quality and increased competitiveness. Thus, it needs to be underscored that privatization has made it possible for enterprise adjustment to take place. This has taken the form of changes in the product mix, switching to new markets, restructuring of costs, establishing more efficient operations, shedding of labour, and internal reorganization of enterprises and their management. Nevertheless, the analysis shows that the environment in which the divested enterprises are operating is still far from enabling. Consequently, the full realization of potential benefits of privatization has been inhibited. It needs to be emphasized that if an enabling environment were in place, the positive performance aggregates would have been much more pronounced. To this effect the following policy recommendations can be formulated. First, there is a need to continue to reform the socioeconomic and institutional environment, with an emphasis on the selection of appropriate policies, the proper sequencing of policy reforms, and the effective implementation of such policies. In the second place, the capabilities for managing the privatization process have to be enhanced, and the institutional arrangements such as the Parastatal Sector Reform Commission (PSRC), the Tanzania Investment Centre (TIC), the Ministry of Industry and Trade, the Treasury and the Planning Commission have to be well targeted in terms of clarity of mission, and effectively coordinated. These institutions should strive to see that the divested enterprises are a success. Third, privatization is most effective when it is part of a broader programme of economic reform and private-sector development. Therefore, there is an urgent need to develop and strengthen private-sector entrepreneurs through an adequate provision of the necessary business services and infrastructure. Such provision will in turn elicit private-sector participation in the economy. Finally, the ongoing reforms in the civil service sector should also aim at creating a market-oriented bureaucracy that is not only competent in the articulation and implementation of private-sector-friendly policies, but also capable of identifying and redressing the economic, legal and institutional constraints that inhibit private sector development.
Notes * Economic Research Bureau, University of Dar es Salaam. 1. Source: TBL data files.
16 Economic Reforms, Industrialization and Technological Capabilities in Tanzanian Industry Samuel M. Wangwe*
1
Introduction
The post-independence period was perceived by African countries as an opportunity to develop their economies. Impressed by the development experiences of advanced economies, where the patterns of development had demonstrated the increasing importance of industry and manufacturing, in particular as income per capita rises, industrialization came to be perceived as an integral part of the development agenda. The desire to replicate development patterns in the advanced countries was supported by dual economy models portraying the desire to replace traditional sectors of the economy by modern sectors, which were supposed to possess characteristics, institutions and values similar to those found in developed economies. Industrialization was expected to facilitate the structural transformation from predominantly agricultural economies to modern industrial economies, and to enhance realization of high labour productivity and its continued growth. In addition, industrialization was perceived to have the ability to realise technological development. In the external sector, it was envisaged that industrialization would bring about a restructuring of the predominantly primary export sector to a more diversified export sector in which exports of industrial products would increasingly play an important role. Industrial exports were associated with dynamic products in which specialisation and technological learning were attained. Tanzania has been no exception to the general desire to industrialize. Industrial development was expected to lead the process of modernization and transformation to high productivity and high growth. All development plans since independence, therefore, envisaged a substantial increase of the share of industry in GDP. Policy choices in the post-independence period were influenced by the desire to replicate development patterns in the advanced countries. At the 349
350 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
same time, it was perceived that circumstances in which development was to take place had changed. Factors such as the rejection of colonial policy tools, the legacy of the Great Depression, the legacy of the Russian Revolution and economic thought favouring planning, government ownership, intervention and control featured quite conspicuously at that time. The Great Depression had exhibited pervasive market failures, a situation which led to considerable mistrust of markets. That experience undermined the core of traditional economic theory based on efficient allocation of resources and comparative advantages (Krueger, 1992). When most subSaharan African countries were getting their independence in the 1950s and 1960s, conventional wisdom then guided them to mistrust markets and adopt the conventional idea that failures of markets contributed to their underdevelopment. They also believed that their economic structures were biased towards primary products. This reflected weakness in domestic activities and an inability to compete in international markets, the latter reinforced by elasticity pessimism (Krueger, 1992). These considerations influenced the choice of development policies and industrialization strategies, and the associated forms of state intervention in development. These experiences and ideas led sub-Saharan African countries to adopt planning using input–output based models and other planning models to address the problems of a dual economy, focusing on the elasticity pessimism and the need to industrialize through state-led import substitution. The policies which were adopted largely discounted the value of traditional commodities, gave a large responsibility to government and adopted import substitution industrialization with protection as a response to weak domestic activities, lop-sided economic structures and an inability to compete. The logic behind ISI is that developing countries such as Tanzania needed to alter the structure of their economies towards industrialization. ISI was adopted during the 1960s at a time when development thinking was sceptical about the functioning of markets, when capital accumulation occupied a central position consistent with the Harrod-Domar model and development was largely perceived as replicating development patterns of the advanced countries. The key role of capital accumulation meant that foreign aid was a logical option to facilitate development in countries with low saving rates. To industrialize in an environment where more industrialized economies already existed would require protection from imports from these economies. Hence, the implementation of ISI came to be buttressed by protection of all kinds. Approaches to implementation of ISI gravitated around planning, protection (using tariffs, quantitative restrictions and exchange rates) and efforts to increase savings and investments. Further policy distortions occurred in capital markets (with subsidised interest rates), labour markets (with fixed minimum wages) and goods markets (with widespread
Economic Reforms and Technological Capabilities 351
price controls). The share of agriculture in GDP was expected to decline with the level of development. In practice, surplus was squeezed from agriculture for investment in other sectors. This was done through price controls, exchange rate overvaluation and taxation. The process of import substitution industrialization was given further impetus in the 1970s by enhancing the role of the state, in what came to be known as the basic industry strategy (BIS). The BIS approach put greater emphasis on structural change and self-reliance. The basic industry strategy was formulated in the early 1970s and was supposed to guide the industrialization process in Tanzania for two decades (1975–95). This strategy emphasises industrial activities which transform the economy so that domestic demand would be met primarily by domestic resources (Wangwe, 1998). The basic industry strategy therefore emphasized two sets of industrial activities. The first set consists of industries which meet the basic needs of the people. Important components of the selected industrial activities in this set include food processing, textiles, clothing, footwear, building materials, and materials and facilities to meet the requirements of education, health services, transportation and water supply. The second set of industries consists of activities which can use domestic resources to produce and supply intermediate inputs and capital goods to industries in the first set. In doing so, one can identify a core group of industries whose products are consumed by most other industries as suggested by Thomas (1974). This core group, which constitutes the base of industrial production, consists of industries such as iron and steel, metalworking and engineering, industrial chemicals, paper, textiles, leather, construction materials and electricity. In this context, for example, the metalworking and engineering industry receives considerable emphasis because of its capacity to supply machinery and equipment, while iron and steel is a priority industry in its capacity as a supplier of inputs into metalworking and engineering industries. The logic of the BIS is fundamentally different from that of ISI. In practice, however, its implementation did not show any significant departure from the practice of ISI (Barker, et al., 1986; Skarstein and Wangwe, 1986; Wangwe, 1990, 1993).
2
Performance of industry
At independence in 1961, there were fewer than 400 manufacturing establishments (with 10 or more workers). Consumer goods industries accounted for 70 per cent of total manufacturing sector employment, while capital and intermediate goods accounted for the rest. The GDP share was 4 per cent, meeting less than 15 per cent of the national demand (Ministry of Industries and Trade, 1996). It is important to address industrial performance in the perspective of an activity that started from a very low initial base.
352 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
The number of manufacturing enterprises employing more than 10 workers increased from 101 in 1946 to 380 in 1964, employing 30 000 people, and in other sectors mechanization began to have effect in this period. Productivity increased. Asian capital continued to expand quite rapidly in the postindependence period, even though it received little government support (Barker et al., 1986). A major stimulant of this growth was the Kampala agreement of 1964, reinforced by measures towards protection. The year 1964 marks the beginning of a period of expansion, with manufacturing value added growing over 10 per cent per year between 1964 and 1972, and the share of industry growing from 7.1 per cent to 11 per cent of GDP. In terms of structure, 74 per cent of manufacturing value added comprised consumer goods, mainly food and beverages, whereas intermediate goods and simple capital goods accounted for 23 per cent and 3 per cent respectively. Processing of agricultural products consisted mainly of sisal decorticating and cotton ginning industries (Ministry of Industry and Trade, 1996). Despite the adoption of the basic industrial strategy in the early seventies, which aimed at raising the share of producer goods, the sector continues to be dominated by simple consumer goods in the food, beverages, tobacco, textile and leather subsectors (Wangwe and Semboja, 1997). The manufacturing sector remains small (about 8 per cent of gross domestic product), and has remained largely untransformed and undynamic, still dominated by primary processing and simple consumer goods industries and some simple intermediate goods. In the reconstructed series of data, included in this volume, the degree of structural change between 1966 and 1989 is found to be even less pronounced than the unadjusted data would suggest (Prins and Szirmai, 1998). Towards the end of the 1970s, with variations across sectors, there were indications that the high expectations from industrial development were under threat. The main indications for this were low returns, inefficiency, low capacity utilisation and low labour productivity. Infant industries were not growing up as envisaged. As it turned out, the manufacturing sector in Tanzania has performed poorly in terms of output, employment, structural change and competitiveness. The accuracy of statistics on manufacturing has been known to be very fragile. Data on growth of manufacturing and its contribution to the GDP differ from one source to another. The best work that has been done to date in addressing these weaknesses and reconstructing the data is by Prins and Szirmai (1998; see also Chapter 3 of this volume). They have suggested adjustments to existing data taking into account new information on coverage, non-response and conceptual issues, calculated new indices for six major branches of industry, and reconstructed employment series that are consistent over time with data on manufacturing value added. These reconstructed series are a major improvement on the previous rather incomplete and inconsistent data.
Economic Reforms and Technological Capabilities 353
According to the series generated by Prins and Szirmai (1998), manufacturing output peaked in 1978, having risen about five-fold from the 1961 level. The industrial production index fell from 100 in 1976 to only 72 in 1985, picked up to 84 in 1990 and 1991, after which this recovery seems to have petered out. This observation is consistent with the finding that exports of manufactures recovered after 1986, but that by 1990 this recovery had run out of steam. The overall picture of growth of manufacturing shows that it continued fairly steadily until 1978 when it faced a decline until 1985, after which the declining trend was reversed. This recovery has not been sufficiently strong to date, because it has largely been based on increased levels of utilisation of existing capacities, rather than investments in new capacities based on improved technology and training, which are essential for attaining international competitiveness (Bagachwa and Mbelle, 1995; Wangwe, 1995). With the coming on-stream of new investments in the recently privatised industries, such as Tanzania Breweries, and new investments, such as those in soft drinks, especially Coca-Cola and those in the soap industry, there are indications that the growth of manufacturing may be picking up (Ministry of Industries and Trade, 1999). According to the Minister’s speech to Parliament in June 1999, growth of manufacturing increased by 5.7 per cent in 1997 and 8.1 per cent in 1998. Productivity in manufacturing increased steadily up to 1973, after which it declined in spite of continued capital investments. Thus labour productivity (in terms of manufacturing value added at 1989 prices per person engaged) is shown to have declined from a peak of TSh 520 000 in 1973 to a low level of TSh 250 000 in 1987 (Prins and Szirmai, 1998). By 1990 labour productivity in manufacturing was 21 per cent lower than in 1965. The major contributor to the decline in labour productivity was the parastatal sector that dominated the manufacturing sector. As many studies have demonstrated, productivity in the parastatal sector faltered. For example, Coulson (1979) examined several parastatal projects (for example, fertilizer and bakery projects) and found their performance weak and riddled with bureaucracy and inefficiency. Productivity in parastatals was found to be low (Clark 1978; Shao, 1978; Barker et al. 1986). In particular, Clark (1978) found that large parastatals had low profit rates, standing at only a quarter of smaller companies in 1971. Shao (1978) found that output per employee was higher in Asian-run enterprises (for example, textiles, grain milling and sawmills) than in parastatals. Jedruszek (1979) found that productivity in industry declined by 14 per cent between 1967 and 1977. Manufacturing productivity was below average over the period in spite of large capital investments. Jedruszek suggested that productivity was low because managers had no incentive to control production costs and to promote efficiency and productivity, while workers exercised their rights and not their responsibilities. Overall productivity in the manufacturing sector was very low to the extent of making it difficult for the sector to compete with
354 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
imports. Poor competitiveness is also reflected in labour productivity. In 1990 labour productivity in spinning measured in terms of number of man-hours required to produce 100 lb or 45.4 kg of yarn averaged 66.2 hours in Tanzania. This is about two to three times that obtained in Kenya, Turkey and India. Labour productivity in weaving measured in man-hours required to produce 42 m 2 of cloth was 18.2 in Tanzania. This again compares unfavourably with 4.0 in Kenya, 3.5 in India or 1.6 in Turkey (Komba, 1999). The comparative analysis of productivity in Tanzania and the USA in 1989 revealed that aggregate labour productivity in Tanzanian manufacturing was as low as 3.7 per cent of that in US manufacturing (Szirmai and Schulte, 1998, and Chapter 3). This is an indication of a large technology gap and wide differences in the level of competitiveness between industrial operations in Tanzania and the USA. The above indicators of performance underscore the emerging problems with ISI. These problems surfaced more conspicuously in the early 1980s in terms of slow growth of employment, low productivity growth (or even decline after 1973) and balance of payments problems as imports were rising faster than exports. Transfer of technology and knowledge (administrative and marketing) proved to be more complex than had been expected. Indigenous learning processes were not forthcoming in ISI. Structural change was not leading to an automatic change in the capacity to learn and to accumulate knowledge. These problems and disappointments with the performance of ISI influenced the decision to undertake policy reforms in 1986, in response to the deterioration of the economy in general and of industrial performance in particular.
3 3.1
Restructuring the industrial sector Rationale of economic reforms
One implicit assumption of economic reforms and industrial restructuring is that enterprise level inefficiencies are a reflection of distorted or inappropriate macroeconomic policies. It is suggested that if appropriate adjustments could be put in place at the macro-level, enterprises would receive the right signals through the market. In response to these signals, enterprises would restructure appropriately. According to this approach, appropriate changes in policies (for example, with respect to market prices, realistic exchange rates, interest rates, competition) are expected to induce restructuring by favouring the expansion of efficient enterprises and contraction of inefficient ones. This approach has been associated with the World Bank, especially as reflected in its earlier publications (World Bank, 1981, 1989). According to this approach, reform and restructuring of industry are essentially a macroeconomic issue. Policy aims are restructuring the supply side by putting in place appropriate macroeconomic and sectoral policies.
Economic Reforms and Technological Capabilities 355
This approach has been adopted by the ‘adjusting countries’ in Africa, and the outcome is still debatable (see also Chapter 13). During the 1970s, 10 countries in Africa experienced de-industrialization and 11 others in the early 1980s (World Bank, 1989). According to the World Bank (1989), adjustment programmes have both positive and negative effects on industry, with the net effect varying widely by product and firm. The World Bank’s assessment is that the overall effect has been positive (World Bank, 1994c). 3.2
Recovery of industry?
The policy reforms of 1986 were accompanied by a release of donor funds that had been withheld pending agreement with the international financial institutions (IFIs). In the case of Tanzania, at the level of the manufacturing sector as a whole, the shift of resources towards capacity utilization coupled with a greater inflow of foreign resources seems to have had a positive influence on output. This influence occurred within the same industrial structure under which the decline of industry had occurred in the first place. The question yet to be answered is whether this recovery is sustainable. It would appear that it is more of a capacity utilisation boom, the sustainability of which will largely depend on the capacity of the economy to shift away from dependence on donor financing towards greater reliance on export earnings. Even more important, sustainability of industrial recovery will require that industrial restructuring be effected in the direction of efficiency and competitiveness. This situation cannot be attained unless macroeconomic reforms are accompanied by appropriate action at industry level and at firm level (Wangwe, 1995, 1998). 3.3
Restructuring entails more than macroeconomic reform
Various industrial studies have revealed that restructuring the industrial sector entails much more than macroeconomic management. For instance, findings of various enterprise-level and sectoral studies in Tanzania in the 1980s lend support to this observation. Findings made by the Tanzania Industrial Studies and Consulting Organisation (TISCO) of the technoeconomic review of eight Tanzania Investment Bank (TIB) client companies in the mid-1980s revealed many operational problems other than those calling for mechanical rehabilitation in the engineering sense. Specifically, the review brought out problems of the exchange rate, government priorities, project planning and programming, linkages, financing, organization and rationalization, quality of management, incentive structures, and infrastructural requirements. These broader concerns are also quite explicit in the findings of six subsectoral studies on the industrial sector in Tanzania. Studies of the industrial sectors in several African countries (UNIDO, 1988b, 1990) confirm that the problems of industry cover all levels (macrosectoral and plant level) and involve all aspects of performance, including
356 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
economic, financial, managerial, technical and marketing. In this context, three challenges are recognized: to identify enterprises suited for rehabilitation; to combine plant rehabilitation with a restructuring programme of the industrial sector to ensure growth and dynamism (this would entail mainly new investments); and to adjust the policy and administrative framework. In his study of the performance of Tanzania’s textile sector, Peter de Valk (1992) has demonstrated that performance of enterprises is determined not only by macroeconomic factors but also by international factors, sectoral policies and characteristics at firm level, and that all these interact in a rather complex way (de Valk, 1992). These findings indicate that macroeconomic policy may be a necessary component of industrial restructuring but it is by no means sufficient. It has to be complemented by actions at sectoral and enterprise level, with due consideration of developments at the international level. 3.4
Restructuring and technological capabilities
One major determinant of international competitiveness is investment in technology. This implies that technological learning and acquisition of technological capabilities cannot be ignored in the process of industrial deepening and structural change. The industrialization strategy adopted should provide an impetus to the demand side as an inducement mechanism for technological change. The particular type of industrialization which has so far been implemented in Tanzania has not provided a strong inducement mechanism for technological change on the demand side. During the import liberalization phase there has even been a tendency to establish more and more of the finishing types of industries. Industrial deepening and technological change have not received any notable priority (Wangwe, 1993). A study of the early phase of industrial restructuring (1985–90) showed that technological capabilities remained low. Four indicators of technological learning were used in that study (Wangwe, 1992a): the degree of local participation in the identification and implementation of the rehabilitation programmes; the balance between output and learning objectives; the extent of upgrading of technical and managerial skills through training; and the implications for the domestic capability to manufacture spare parts and components. On all four counts the rehabilitation programmes were found to have paid little attention to the issue of raising the level of local technological capabilities. These findings point to the possibility that rehabilitation under the current economic reforms may not address the problems which have inhibited technological learning in the manufacturing sector (Wangwe, 1993). These findings suggest that although changes in the macroeconomic environment have introduced competitive pressures among manufacturers (for example, injecting a sense of quality consideration), many of the earlier
Economic Reforms and Technological Capabilities 357
weaknesses in technological development have not been resolved. Changes in macroeconomic policy and enterprise-level rehabilitation programmes alone are not sufficient for industrial restructuring to be realised. Action at the intermediate level (below macro-level and above micro-level) is still insufficient (Wangwe, 1993). Some sectors (for example textiles and garments) have even suffered considerable de-industrialization (Semboja and Kweka, 1998). During the trade liberalisation phase there are signs that even the modest degree of product complexity has been further eroded by imports (Lall et. al., 1997; Semboja and Kweka, 1997; Wangwe and Semboja, 1997). This is a reflection of the persistence of weaknesses in the institutional mechanisms for the support of industry and in the incentive framework relating to the building of technological capabilities. The importance of action at this level is well demonstrated in the case of the textile sector (de Valk, 1992). More recent studies of the industrial sector have confirmed this point in the textile and clothing and engineering sectors (Bagachwa and Mbelle, 1995; Lall et al., 1997; Semboja and Kweka, 1997). Such action needs to be generalised to the whole industrial sector in the framework of an industrial strategy.
4
Why a competitive industry has not been realized
The envisaged industrialization process has not been realised on account of policy failures, inadequate institutional capacity, poor infrastructure, insufficient commitment to make the necessary investments to cope with technological change, and failure to invest in the required human resources. 4.1
Policy failures
The state-led industrialization programme was implemented in a policy environment which was riddled with macroeconomic imbalances. Inwardlooking import substitution policies shielded firms from competitive pressures. The incentive structure was not conducive to developing a competitive industrial structure. Investors were securing niches and preventing rivals from entering the domestic or regional market, characterised by monopolistic relationships. In addition, first-comer investors obtained guarantees from the state that no other company would be licensed to manufacture or import the same final product for several years. Profitability was assured irrespective of the level of efficiency, because of price controls whereby output prices were set on a cost-plus basis supported by high tariffs. The exchange rate was overvalued, rendering imports cheaper than under free market conditions and making exporting unattractive. Interest rates were set at below inflation, and credit was rationed in rather unpredictable ways. The actual allocations of credit have been shown to have favoured large-scale parastatal firms (Bagachwa and Mbelle, 1995).
358 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
Resource allocation favoured expansion rather than efficient utilisation of the capacities which had already been created (Wangwe, 1979). The resulting imbalances exerted strains on the resources for implementing the BIS. One aspect of the macroeconomic environment in the last two decades has been that of pressure on the limited investment and foreign exchange resources. These became major factors in determining the pace and pattern of project implementation during this period. At enterprise level this pressure was manifested in project implementation delays and cost overruns (Wangwe, 1993). The foreign finances available for industrialization were channelled into industrial expansion in the form of ill-designed projects and choice of technology that required high levels of foreign exchange to sustain it. The crisis was deemed to be temporary. Longer-term decisions in investment did not take the impinging balance of payments crisis and future implications of the burden of debt servicing on the balance of payments into consideration. The phenomena of pressure on investment resources and a large proportion of foreign finance in industrial financing are not necessarily bound to cause problems. However, the particular form that foreign finance took in Tanzania had far-reaching implications for the pace and pattern of project implementation. 4.2
Inadequate institutional capacity
The institutional capacity to programme, monitor and provide supportive services to industry has been a constraining factor in industrial development. In particular, the institutions which had been created to provide technological support services to industry (for example, the Tanzania Industrial Research and Development Organization, Tanzania Bureau of Standards) were not allocated the resources needed to provide the requisite support to industrial enterprises. The allocation of resources to supportive services became even more difficult with the budget cuts during the period of structural adjustment. The restructuring of the providers of industrial support services has not been completed as yet. This delay has continued to afflict the process of industrial recovery. 4.3 Weak linkages between industry and other sectors and support institutions Linkages between industry and related sectors were not articulated, and complementary investments were not made to ensure integrated development of major sectors. For example, investments in mining, agriculture and infrastructure were not articulated in line with the BIS (Wangwe, 1993). Although technology institutes were established in the late 1970s and early 1980s, they did not function in ways which served the needs of industry. For example, in their study of TIRDO, Bongenaar and Szirmai
Economic Reforms and Technological Capabilities 359
(1999) found that out of twelve projects, ten were initiated by TIRDO officials themselves or by one of its governing bodies, rather than by enterprises, which are the main clients. Entrepreneurs were not involved in the project selection process, and insufficient attention was paid to the transfer of technologies to the users. For these reasons TIRDO could not pay adequate attention to the appropriateness of technologies to the Tanzanian environment. In general industrial linkages between TIRDO and domestic industry were found to be weak (Bongenaar and Szirmai, 1999, and Chapter 7 of this volume). 4.4
Inadequate infrastructure
The level and cost of infrastructure become obstacles to efficient industrial development. The roadmap study comparing Tanzania with Uganda, Namibia and Ghana showed that Tanzania was in a disadvantaged position relative to other countries (TSG, 1996). Subsequent studies have shown some improvement, and prospects for further improvement are bright, but the situation is still quite bad (HIID, 1998). In particular the inadequate availability and high cost of energy, transport and communication and institutional infrastructural support services (technical, marketing, informations flows, finance) have inhibited the development of an efficient industrial structure. The poor state of infrastructure has contributed to the high cost of doing business. 4.5
Low level of human resource development
The positive role of human resources in development of a competitive industry has been recognized. However, human development is one area where Tanzania has lagged behind many countries. The level of tertiary education in Tanzania is one of the lowest in Africa. The wrong mix of different levels of technical skills aggravates the low quantity of technical education that is offered. While the normal ratio of engineers to technicians to craft workers is 1:5:25 in advanced countries, it was found to be 1:5:13 in a sample cross-section of modern enterprises in Tanzania. The same ratio was 1:2:5 in the actual output of formal education in Tanzania in the late 1970s (Barker et al., 1986). There are no indications that this ratio had changed significantly by the late 1990s. There is no coordinated effort to link training to imported machinery. In general, the level of investment in human resources for industrialization has been unable to cope with the challenges of technological development of a competitive industry. The level of tertiary education in general, and technological and engineering personnel for industrial development, has remained low. The quality and relevance of technical education that is offered in local vocational training centres and technical schools and colleges is not adequate (Chapter 9). Industry-specific training institutes were established, but even these were geared to basic and low-level skills oriented towards
360 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
operation of existing plant, rather than to adaptations, innovations and improvements of imported technology. With regard to training, it seems that Tanzanian firms do not attach due importance to training, especially formal and long-term training for the low cadre employees. A study by ESRF (1997) in the metal subsector indicated the need for upgrading of production skills for all levels of employment if firms are to install new production technology. This is despite the fact that about 90 per cent of the industries in the sample of 74 firms conduct informal in-house training (less than 20 per cent of the firms were found to conduct long-term and formal training) (Wangwe et al., 1997b). Other studies, such as that of Masuha (ESRF, 1997), indicated that in many metal engineering companies little thought is given to designing training programmes for employees in activities such as quality control and maintenance. Additionally, according to the competitiveness strategies of nine industries studied by Bagachwa and Mbelle (1995), only one company (Matsushita Electric Co., which is a subsidiary of Matsushita Electric, Japan) adopted all forms of training at all levels as one of their very important competitive strategies, which is typical of Japanese companies Despite the diversity of final products generated in manufacturing, it has been found that most of the jobs undertaken require skills of a very low order usually associated with attending machines and doing repetitive part work (Barker et al., 1986). However, Barker et al. (1986) identified a few enterprises that demonstrated that development of worker skills is only partly determined by the type of machinery and its technological level. An important role is also played by the way the labour process itself is organised. For example, enterprises that organised their workers in coordinated teams of workers, engineers and managers in performing a set of operations seem to have achieved higher levels of skills. Policies towards management of the labour process are an important dimension of building up technological skills. The low level of skill development in Tanzanian industry is partly a function of the technology employed and partly a function of management of the labour process. In this respect it has been shown that in Tanzanian industries most of the workers are excluded from planning, designing and control tasks. They are largely confined to activities relating to repetitive tasks, quality control, and repair and maintenance work. Engineering functions related to design work are performed in the countries from which equipment is imported. (Barker et al., 1986). The manner in which the labour process is organised is not particularly conducive to learning and the development of human resources through learning by doing. It has been found that technicians in Tanzania have a tendency to spend most of their time in offices at a distance from the shop floor, instead of liaising between engineering design and planning on the one hand and implementation by shop-floor workers on the other. This
Economic Reforms and Technological Capabilities 361
white-collar mentality is an influence from an education system that does not provide sufficient practical training (Barker et al., 1986). The managerial strata were separated from the shop-floor workers by huge gaps in education, training, salaries, privileges and power. During the time the parastatals were dominant, the learning process of Tanzanian managerial and technical personnel was impaired by the preponderance of foreign personnel in key positions in top management. Top management in parastatals largely consisted of expatriates who outnumbered local counterparts by a factor of two to three (Barker et al., 1986). Most of the Tanzanian managers were trained in fields other than engineering or science and technology. Most of them were trained in finance and administration. The industrial skilled, semi-skilled and unskilled workers were mostly first-generation industrial employees. They required concerted efforts to mould them into an industrial culture before they could contribute to technological development activities. A sample of employment in modern industrial enterprises in the late 1970s showed that employees were largely unskilled (20.6 per cent) and semi-skilled (57.5 per cent) workers, with only 10.5 per cent being skilled workers; 4.7 per cent were supervisory personnel, 4.6 per cent administrative personnel, 1.1 per cent middle-level management and 1 per cent top management. Most of the unskilled and casual workers had no school education, so their tasks were limited to unskilled physical work, such as moving, sorting, cleaning and packing. No provision was made for their training to enable them to learn skills. Most of the supervisory level and skilled and semi-skilled workers had only primary education. This educational composition of the labour force demonstrates that the level of education, and in particular secondary and higher-level education, could have been a limiting factor in the processes of technological learning. Bureaucratisation of industrial management was institutionalised in the parastatal sector, whereby management lacked initiative towards the design of new products, processes and maintenance systems. In some cases there were even instances of obstructing useful innovations, such as local manufacture of enzymes for the breweries. The bureaucratised management in the parastatals shied away from addressing critical production problems. Instead it either called in experts from abroad, or top management travelled abroad supposedly to learn how similar problems were solved elsewhere. The environment in which industry was operating was not putting competitive pressure on firms to train workers with a view to attaining competitiveness. As Pack and Paxson (Chapter 2) have indicated, the simple existence of trained and experienced managers and workers does not guarantee high firm productivity. They need to be complemented by competitive pressures to induce firms to innovate and by inflows of new technologies.
362 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
4.6
Low investment in technology and technological learning
Investments in industry favoured initial capital investments, but investments in technology were not made on a continuous basis with a view to keeping pace with the challenges of building a competitive industrial structure. The parastatal holding corporations which were responsible for coordinating several public enterprises in specific industrial branches, and for the promotion of new projects in those branches, became increasingly engaged in the mobilization of investment resources. In particular they gave high priority to mobilization of foreign finance. This tendency has not been conducive to promoting the utilization of local capabilities and technological learning, and building of indigenous technological capabilities through learning by doing. Instead, it has pre-empted the mobilization and utilization of local resources and capabilities. One consequence of this is that the question of choice of technology was accorded low priority. The main public-enterprise development institution, NDC, usually left the choice of technology for its projects entirely to the foreign partner (Barker et al., 1986). The foreign partner had considerable flexibility in the way management agreements were framed. They usually stated rather vaguely that the foreign partner would select modern processes, taking into account the objective conditions of Tanzania. Feasibility studies were preoccupied with the range of products to be produced and their market and financial viability, rather than with implications of technology development issues. Several factors explain this laxity in choice of technology: Foreign partners were generally unwilling to participate in a project unless they were given leeway in the choice of technology. This was done under the pretext that they could otherwise not be held responsible for performance of the project. However, even when they were given freedom to choose the technology, there was no mechanism put in place to hold them responsible for performance. Most of the time the management fees were not related to any performance indicators. • Tanzania did not have qualified and experienced engineers and other professionals who could unpackage the technology and negotiate terms and conditions under which different parts could be supplied. • The Tanzanian state had little access to global information on technology sources and costs, and did not put in place policies and mechanisms to build the capacity to acquire the necessary information. The incentive structure encouraged the top bureaucracy in the parastatals to give high priority to setting up as many enterprises as possible in the shortest time. The number of projects implemented was equated with a high rate of industrialization. The high propensity to speed up implementation of projects has tended to overshadow more important concerns with regard to technological learning. Concerns with speed of project implementation •
Economic Reforms and Technological Capabilities 363
have been overriding, and the engagement of foreign finance packaged with foreign personnel has been deemed more appropriate for the attainment of this objective. James (Chapter 5) has invoked the publicchoice approach to bureaucracy to make two main arguments related to this observation. First, bureaucrats had preferences defined over projects rather than technologies. Second, managers of parastatals sought to initiate as many projects as possible, mainly on the basis of foreign aid. Nationalization and the use of foreign partners did not lead to successful restructuring and improved technological performance of the firms inherited from local private entrepreneurs. • Nationalization alienated the former owners and other actors who possessed detailed knowledge of the history and developments in the factories. The new group, which took over, inherited technologies they did not choose and lacked the experience and background information about the plants. A situation of discontinuity was forced onto the operations and technological learning. In this connection, it is observed that the experiences of parastatals can be contrasted with those of the smaller private-sector enterprises. For example, in the case of firms owned by domestic and East African private capital, the owners kept a close watch on the choice of technology by participating directly or engaging experienced expatriates for technical help (Barker et al., 1986).
5
Towards developing a competitive industry
Industrial development in the 21st century needs to accommodate the changing external and internal environments. External conditions have changed towards openness and competitiveness. The industrial drive needs emphasis on competitiveness. Theories of long-term development have shifted from stressing the problems of capital accumulation and are now singling out technological development and growth of productivity (Pasinetti, 1981; Romer, 1986; Pasinetti and Solow, 1994; Ruttan, 1998). It has become increasingly recognised that long-run growth is primarily driven by the accumulation of knowledge. Internally, there are concerns about creating a dynamic economy which not only grows fast but places high human development high on the agenda. To the extent that different ways of generating growth of real income may have different effects on the possibility of conversion of real income growth into achievements that are highly valued for human development, there is a case for worrying about other aspects of human development. For example, the nature of employment orientation in GDP growth and the role of education and learning have a clear bearing on the promotion of good living conditions (Sen, 1994). The kind of industrial development that is desirable should be able to generate broad-based employment and incomes directly or indirectly through strong linkages with sectors which engage the bulk of low-income
364 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
earners. In the case of Tanzania, 92 per cent of the poor live in rural areas where the majority of them depend on agriculture for a living. Industrial development will need to have a positive influence on agricultural incomes, if poverty is to be reduced considerably. 5.1
Developing a dynamic and competitive industrial structure
The following industries have achieved higher productivity and quality and can therefore effectively compete both locally and in export markets: beverages, such as beer, soft drinks and bottled water, which take more than 80 per cent of the local market, and cigarettes and food, which take 50 per cent and 35 per cent respectively (URT-budget speech, 1999c). This is partly due to reorganisation in capital plants and management and also due to local availability of a significant part of production inputs. On the other hand, industries which seem the least competitive are those in the textile sector. The fact that 35 out of 37 establishments were closed right after liberalisation justifies this contention. Local garment firms have been unable to compete with the vast second-hand trade (mitumba). In general, the available evidence suggests that in Tanzania manufactured exports constitute a dismal share of total exports and gross manufacturing output (Komba, 1999). According to Wangwe et al. (1997b), the share of exports in the total output of the sampled manufacturing firms in Tanzania averaged no more than 5–15 per cent. There is a need to put in place a dynamic industrialization programme based on the technological revolution in industrial production and organisation, to ensure faster growth of high technology manufacturing. Industrial policies in the 21st century will have to be made in full consideration of the emerging technological setting driven by globalization and rapid technological progress (Wangwe, 1998). Industrial policy will be expected to cope with the new paradigm of new technologies, new product ranges, new management and organisational techniques, and linkages and networks. In order to tap the opportunities arising from this process, it will be necessary to break the constraints relating to institutional weaknesses, inadequate infrastructure and low levels of human resource development. 5.2
Focus on technological learning and building competitiveness
The accent will need to shift towards technological learning and building of capabilities for attaining competitiveness in the domestic market and in exports to the region and to global markets. There is a need to acquire and maintain competitiveness in local-resource-based industries, agro-industry, industries producing agricultural inputs, mining and tourism, which are capable of generating employment and incomes broadly in the economy, while developing the capability to seize existing and new opportunities in export markets. Exploiting initial comparative advantages will provide investible surpluses and capacities to develop into activities with dynamic
Economic Reforms and Technological Capabilities 365
comparative advantages. The strategy will promote regional industrial partnerships with a view to tapping economies of scale and attaining competitiveness in regional and international markets. 5.3
Priority of agro-based small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs)
The industrial strategy should focus on agro-based small and medium industries capitalizing on the dynamic synergies between industrial and agricultural development. This approach should effectively address poverty, unemployment or underemployment and food insecurity. It should provide broad benefits to society. Factors that have proved to explain the dynamism of SMEs in recent years need to be made the driving forces of this development. Three key factors are identified as driving forces: the internal configuration of enterprises must take advantage of efficient organisational and production technology; the economic and social context in which the SMEs will function must reflect a competitive environment; and linkages to other enterprises must attract deliberate focus. Support should be provided to rural industry as a means of generating rural non-farm employment and income. Rural non-farm activities should be able to generate further farm income through various linkages. The potential of rural industries for employment and income generation and export growth lies in the production of labour-intensive and local-resourceusing products, and a continuous upgrading and improvement of organisational and production technologies. 5.4
Enhance the role and capacity of government support
The experience of Tanzania in the reform period clearly demonstrates that while opening up the economy to competition from imports may be a necessary condition for developing a dynamic and competitive industrial sector, it is in itself far from sufficient. There is need to complement the process of opening up with government intervention through supportive policies aimed at helping enterprises upgrade their technologies and competitiveness, guided by a clear strategy. The pace of opening up should be geared to the learning needs of different activities in the economy. The role of government will need to be enhanced to support and promote the restructuring of subsectors and the potential for growth and competitiveness, and to support human resource development and technology programmes. Government intervention will need to be directed towards promoting the building of institutional infrastructure to meet requirements for finance (especially development finance), training, development of quality standards, generation of the necessary information, promotion of investments and technology flows, and the development of applied research in appropriate fields for industrial development. Government intervention will be necessary in the following areas to:
366 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
identify and facilitate the pursuit of dynamic comparative advantages with a view to attaining an optimal industrial structure which is competitive ensure that the balance of payments is sustainable Ensure long-term growth of domestic demand: a large domestic market, assisted by some degree of protection, could facilitate generation of high profits, which could provide conditions for high rates of investments, learning by doing and improving product quality facilitate the acquisition of foreign technology through facilitating FDI, licensing and or other means of channelling foreign technology to promote competitiveness in economic activities in the country facilitate exporting.
•
• •
•
•
6
Conclusion
The rapid changes in market and technological conditions pose a great challenge for industrial transformation. The implementation strategy must place top priority on building the capacity for industrial competitiveness. The main components of this strategy are: •
•
•
•
•
industrial policy based on economic analyses of industrial competitiveness and identification of dynamic comparative advantages on a continuous basis nurturing and promoting public–private sector consultation mechanisms based on industrial subsector surveys and analyses, as well as industrial development experiences in the country and in other countries human resource development through restructuring education, training and entrepreneurship for micro-, and small- and medium-sized industries development of industrial institutions and services to support enterpriselevel efforts towards attaining competitiveness in regional and international markets linking industry and agriculture to enhance productivity and competitiveness in agro-industries.
Notes * Executive Director, Economic and Social Research Foundation, Dar es Salaam.
17 Highlights of the Sustainable Industrial Development Policy in Tanzania, 1996–2020 A.K. Maziku*
1
Introduction
In 1996 Tanzania launched the Sustainable Industrial Development Policy (SIDP), 1996–2020, to succeed the basic industrial strategy (BIS), 1975–95. The BIS was Tanzania’s first long-term industrial development strategy since independence in 1961. However, the government had already began to pay serious attention to industrial development during the second fiveyear development plan (1969–74), when it designated ten towns as urban ‘growth centres’ to which ‘suitable new factories and employment opportunities will be diverted’ (URT, 1969). The expiry of the BIS in 1995, and the economic crisis facing the country, necessitated the formulation of a new policy that would take cognizance of the emerging macroeconomic environment. This paper presents the salient features of the new policy, paying special attention to the implementation mechanism, which is a major departure from the past.
2
The Sustainable Industrial Development Policy (SIDP)
In his foreword to the new policy document, the Minister for Industry and Trade writes: ‘Two major factors accounted for the need to prepare a new policy for the industrial sector. One is the expiry of the Basic Industry Strategy in 1995; the other is the government’s decision to phase itself out of investing directly in productive activities and let the private sector be the principle vehicle to the role’ (URT, 1996a). The second factor described by the Minister is in fact one of the implications of the wide-ranging reform programme that the country has been implementing since the mid-eighties. So far, Tanzania has successfully transformed its political system from a one-party system to a multiparty system. It has opened up its financial sector and implemented other 367
368 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
financial and monetary reforms, and the government is in the process of hiving off non-traditional functions of the state. The emerging sociopolitical and macroeconomic environment is different from that existing in the country when the BIS was designed in 1975. Not only did that strategy expire in 1995 but, as described in Chapter 1, its basic assumptions were no longer valid as early as the beginning of the eighties. Another major development worth noting is the formulation of a national vision, Development Vision 2025, that will generally guide socioeconomic development up to the year 2025. In Development Vision 2025, Tanzania has set itself the following socioeconomic targets: an increase in per capita income from the current US$200 to US$1200 a decline in infant mortality from the current 99 per 1000 inhabitants to 20 per 1000 inhabitants • an increase in life expectancy from the current 52 years to 70 years • an increase in the share of industry in GDP from 17 per cent to 40 per cent • a decline of the population growth rate from 2.8 per cent per year to 2.0 per cent. • •
2.1
The industrial sector mission and objectives
The mission of the industrial sector in the 1996–2020 period is two-fold: (i) to contribute towards the achievement of the overall national longterm development goals as contained in the Development Vision 2025 (ii) to enhance sustainability in the development of the sector. The objectives of the new industrial policy include: overall contributions towards human development and the creation of employment opportunities; economic transformation in order to achieve sustainable economic growth; external balance of payments; environmental sustainability; and equitable development. All of these objectives are consistent with the National Vision. The industrial sector’s role with regard to human development is twopronged. On the one hand, it is expected to produce goods fulfilling basic needs for the majority of the people. On the other hand, it is expected to create employment opportunities, directly and indirectly, through the expansion of the industrial sector and by stimulating informal sector development. The goal of economic transformation will benefit from the projected increasing share of industry in GDP. The development of intermediate and capital goods industries will enhance sustainable productivity increases, technological progress, structural change and inter-sectoral linkages.
Sustainable Industrial Development Policy 369
One of the major constraints to the implementation of the BIS was the lack of foreign exchange to finance imports of required machinery, spares and raw materials. Therefore, the SIDP calls for a balanced approach between import-substitution and export-oriented industrialization. Regional and rural–urban disparities will also be targeted so as to bring about equitable development. The current drive to develop physical and economic infrastructure across the country, the provision of incentive packages to large-scale industrial investors in less developed areas and the promotion of small and micro-enterprises are expected to contribute to such an equitable development. 2.2
Implementation strategy
The 25-year period to which the SIDP refers has been divided into three phases to enable specific quantitative targets to be set for indicators such as the rate of industrial growth, the structure of value added, exports and employment generation. For each phase, priority activities are identified. The three phases are short term (1996–2000) medium term (2000–2010) and long term (2010–20). Identification criteria in selecting specific priority activities are profitability and competitive advantage. The private sector will play a central role in the realisation of the new policy’s objectives and goals. Apart from creating and sustaining a conducive environment for the growth of the private sector, the government will have to pursue a vigorous vocational and technical educational training programme that will include entrepreneurship development. At the same time it will also have to provide assistance to informal-sector activities – a potential source of entrepreneurship – so that informal-sector entrepreneurs can progressively enter the formal sector. The priorities in the short, medium and long term are the following: Short-term priority programme (1996–2000) (i) Rehabilitation and consolidation of existing industrial capacities through financial, capital and management restructuring (ii) creating and sustaining an enabling environment (iii) development of agro-processing activities in which Tanzania has a comparative advantage. Medium-term priority programme (2000–2010) (i) Creation of new capacities in activities with clear competitive advantages for export (ii) promotion of intermediate goods industries, light capital goods and machine making
370 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
(iii) carrying out techno-economic preparations for exploitation of iron-ore deposits. Long-term priority programme (2010–20) Promoting full-fledged investments in basic capital goods industries.
3 The partnership between the government and the private sector In the SIDP the government role will change from that of being a direct and indirect investor, through the parastatal enterprises, to a ‘facilitating and supportive’ role by way of putting in place an enabling environment in the form of appropriate macroeconomic policies, legal frameworks and efficient infrastructures. On the other hand, the private sector will be expected to invest in a manner that will contribute to the realization of the objectives of the SIDP. This requires a very close working relationship or partnership between the government and the private sector, based on a convergence of purpose, interest, trust and transparency, all of which ultimately depend on each side playing its role effectively. On the one hand, government policies must be transparent, realistic, practical and predictable and sustainable, while on the other, the private sector must be capable of meeting the new challenges. There are three essential preconditions for this to happen: (i) the development of the private sector (ii) the creation and sustainability of an enabling environment (iii) the setting up of an effective consultative mechanism.
3.1
The development of the private sector
The emerging economic and business environment in Tanzania requires, among other things, greater dependence on market forces and private initiatives, hence the growing need for a stronger private sector. It also requires good governance, and transparency and accountability in administrative processes, which inspire current and future business confidence. The private sector in Tanzania is currently very small, and its institutional infrastructure is largely undeveloped, weak and uncoordinated. Efforts are under way to form a National Business Council. It is hoped this will function as a central coordinating, apex business body that will be an effective representative of private-sector interests. It is also expected to engage in an effective dialogue with the government and assume some of the responsibilities of the government in business and investment promotion.
Sustainable Industrial Development Policy 371
Private-sector development requires increased emphasis on vocational and technical training as a source of entrepreneurial skills. Informal-sector activities need to be assisted so that informal-sector firms can progressively enter the formal sector, and micro-enterprises can grow into larger enterprises. The introduction of the Dar es Salaam stock exchange and continuing financial sector reforms are expected to contribute to the creation and development of a much needed capital market. 3.2
Creation and sustainability of an enabling environment
The creation and sustainability of an enabling environment refer to an ever-changing economic situation. Therefore ongoing changes and adjustments in fiscal, monetary and trade policies are required to address specific situations as they arise. The following measures will be implemented within the SIDP framework. 3.2.1
Trade
(i) A new trade policy will be formulated to streamline export development, cross-border trade, import management and business licensing (ii) further measures will be undertaken to implement the 1994 Fair Trade Practices Act (iii) special export incentives will be provided under the export promotion strategy, which includes the establishment of export processing zones (EPZs). The new trade policy will chart Tanzania’s strategy in subregional economic groupings, and other international and global programmes in the context of the post-Uruguay Round agreements under the WTO. Measures geared towards opening up the economy to external competition will continue to be taken, but selective protection within the framework of WTO agreements will be applied. 3.2.2
Fiscal policies
Adjustments in the tax structure will continue to be made with the objective of ‘levelling the playing field’, improving tax compliance and reducing the inflow of inferior goods. 3.2.3
Monetary policy
Interest rates associated with the limited existing credit facilities are too high and unstable, and do not differentiate between trading and industrial operations. Further financial sector reforms are needed to ensure interest rate stability, encourage domestic savings and determine appropriate interest rates that will distinguish between purely trading and industrial operations. Long-term financial and working capital needs for industry require the development of a domestic capital and securities market.
372 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
3.2.4
Investment promotion
The old Investment Promotion Centre (IPC) was based on the Foreign Investment Protection Act, which has been repealed and replaced by a new law that provides for the establishment of a one-stop-centre, the Tanzania Investment Centre (TIC), which will design appropriate measures for both local and foreign investors. 3.2.5
Infrastructural development
The government will continue with efforts to expand and improve the provision of water, power, communication facilities and transport networks, which are essential for investment and trading. 3.2.6
Action on other related issues
Other measures include: a new land policy that, among other things, will give value to land; human resource development to improve skills and managerial capabilities; a review of labour laws; promoting product standards and quality assurance; development, consolidation and strengthening of technology and R&D institutions and activities; and the development of key complementary sectors of agriculture, livestock, mining and tourism.
4 The institutional framework and the consultative mechanism for policy implementation There are four key players in implementing the SIDP. First, the government will continue with the consolidation of the democratization process, the creation of a smaller, more streamlined and more efficient bureaucracy, and the protection of individual property rights. Second, the ministry responsible for industry will be in overall charge of the operationalization, monitoring and review of the SIDP at the national level, in collaboration with the ministries responsible for finance and planning. Third, the industrial support organizations, which offer essential services in the field of standardization, quality assurance and certification, research and development, and environmental management, will continue to play that role jointly with the government. The fourth and last key player is the private sector. In order to be able to play its role effectively, it will not only need to be developed (especially the local private sector), but will need to reorganize itself so that it develops a viable institutional network which can enter into dialogue with the government and engage in productive joint planning on a regular basis. The most important departure from the old plan implementation modality will be the partnership approach adopted in the SIDP. This approach is required for the full involvement of the private sector in the realisation of the objectives of industrial policy. Based on the fundamental assumption of a commitment by the partners to industrialization in
Sustainable Industrial Development Policy 373
particular and economic development in general, a legally binding institutional mechanism will be put in place to be known as the national consultative process for industrialization (NCPI). The framework will require the establishment of an apex umbrella organisation, which will bring together capable people conversant with the industrial sector, from both government and the private sector. The main functions of the apex body will be: (i) to recommend practical programmes of action to the government that will sustain developments in each industrial subsystem (ii) to provide strategic information to enterprises on technology, markets and competitive conditions (iii) to monitor tendencies towards excessive concentration of production and the emergence of other forms of monopolistic practices (iv) to participate in reviewing and monitoring the implementation of policies (v) to act as an intermediary between enterprises, working consultative groups and the government. At the apex level, the organisation will be assisted by a technical support group, which will conduct technical studies for working consultative groups (WCGs), one for each identified industrial subsystem. The term industrial subsystem (ISS), as used here, refers to a segment or branch of the industrial sector comprising core enterprises organised around a product or group of products, operating in the same markets for raw materials and consumers, and using more or less the same type of technology and skills. The critical requirement is for the enterprises to have a minimum level of common interests that will make them work together, collaborate to formulate development strategies, and design action plans and programmes to improve their operating environment for their mutual benefit. The bulk of the analytical work in terms of the problems, constraints, strengths, weaknesses, opportunities and threats facing each industrial subsystem will be done jointly by the technical support group and the working consultative groups. Another unit that will assist the apex organisation will be a management support group (MSG) which, apart from acting as a secretariat to the national body, will handle financial and administrative matters relating to the national consultative process. The working consultative group for each subsystem will carry out the following main functions: (i) to deliberate on the strengths, weaknesses, opportunities and threats in the subsystem (SWOT) (ii) to formulate strategies and policies in order to improve the subsystem’s overall operating environment
374 The Industrial Experience of Tanzania
(iii) to formulate action plans and programmes (iv) to formulate actions to be taken at the level of individual enterprises. The implementation of the national consultative process for industrialization involves the following phases: (i) A preparatory phase that will involve putting in place a legal framework within which the NCPI will operate; setting up the national coordinating body; organising and staffing the technical and management support groups; identifying industrial subsystems and setting up their corresponding WCGs. (ii) A study phase to establish base line data that will enable the new approach to take off and provide the basis for detailed future studies, including: • diagnostic studies of the identified industrial subsystems • analysis of the industrial structure with a view to establishing critical gaps that need to be filled • situation reports on the informal sector: micro- and small-scale enterprises • assessment of natural resource endowments for industrialization • assessment of the performance of industrial support organizations and the services they provide. (iii) A consultative phase that will include initiating the consultative process in the working groups of the industrial subsystems; the development of strategic action plans and programmes; and the formalization of the action plans and programmes. (iv) A take-off phase, during which programmes and plans are implemented. The implementation, monitoring, feedback and review of strategies, programmes and action plans are a continuous process during the whole period of the SIDP.
5
Concluding remarks
The implementation of the twenty-year (1975–95) basic industry strategy formally ended in 1995. A new 25-year policy, the Sustainable Industrial Development Policy (1996–2020), was designed and launched in 1996. The SIDP is expected to achieve the following: improvement of the quality of human life, creation of employment opportunities, economic transformation for achieving sustainable economic growth, external balance, environmental sustainability and equitable development. These objectives are consistent with the National Vision 2025. The success of the Sustainable Industrial Development Policy depends on the success of the economic
Sustainable Industrial Development Policy 375
reform programme in creating better prospects for the effective reversal of the declining performance of the industrial sector. The major departure of the new policy from the previous ones is with respect to the implementation modality. Under the liberalized economic system the private sector and market forces are increasingly replacing the government and its organs. The government is initiating a national consultative process for industrialization that will constitute an apex body, and working consultative groups for each main branch of industry to supervise and monitor policy implementation. For this to succeed, a government– private-sector partnership must be established and supported by a structured dialogue and continuous consultative process.
Note *
Ministry of Industry and Trade.
Bibliography Adam, C. (1994), ‘Privatization and Structural Adjustment in Africa’, in: W. van der Geest (ed.), Negotiating Structural Adjustment in Africa, London: James Curry. Agrawal, N., Z. Ahmed, M. Mered and R. Nord (1993), Structural Adjustment, Economic Performance, and Aid Dependency in Tanzania, Policy Research Working Paper WPS1204, Washington: World Bank. Alange, S. (1987), Acquisition of Capabilities through International Technology Transfer: The Case of Small Scale Industrialization in Tanzania, published PhD thesis, Sweden: Chalmers University of Technology. Alcorta, L. (1995), The Impact of Industrial Automation on Industrial Organisation: Implications for Developing Countries’ Competitiveness, submitted as Background Paper no. 7 to the UNIDO Global Forum on Industry. Appelbaum, R.P. and W.J. Chambliss (1995), Sociology, New York: Harper Collins. Ark, B. van (1993), ‘The ICOP Approach – Its Implications and Applicability’, in: A. Szirmai, D. Pilat and B. van Ark (eds), Explaining Economic Growth: Essays in Honour of Angus Maddison, North Holland: Elsevier, 375–98. Arkadic, B. van (1986) (ed.), External Finance and Policy Adjustment in Africa, London, Sage. Arrow, K. (1962), ‘Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Inventions’, in: R.R. Nelson (ed.), The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity, Princeton: Princeton University Press. Bagachwa, M.S.D. (1992), ‘Choice of Technology in Small and Large Firms: Grain Milling in Tanzania’, World Development, 20 (1), 97–107. Bagachwa, M.S.D. (1993a), ‘Impact of Structural Adjustment on the Small Enterprise Sector in Tanzania’, in: A.H.J. Helmsing and T. Kolstee (eds), Small Enterprises and Changing Policies, London: Intermediate Technology Publications, 91–113. Bagachwa, M.S.D. (1993b), Export Competitiveness and Firm Level Capabilities in Selected Tanzanian Industries, Economic Research Bureau, University of Dar es Salaam. Bagachwa, M.S.D. (1994), Export Competitiveness and Firm Level Capabilities in Selected Tanzanian Industries, Research Paper, ERB, University of Dar es Salaam. Bagachwa, M.S.D. and A.V.Y. Mbelle (eds) (1993), Economic Policy under a Multiparty System in Tanzania, University of Dar es Salaam, DUP. Bagachwa, M.S.D. and A.V.Y. Mbelle (1995), ‘Tanzania: Export Manufacturing’, in: S.M. Wangwe (ed.), Exporting Africa: Technology, Trade and Industrialization in subSaharan Africa, London Routledge. Bank of Tanzania (1970 [1973, 1977, 1978, 1981, 1982]), Economic and Operations Report June 1982 [1973, 1977, 1978, 1981, 1982], Dar es Salaam: Bank of Tanzania. Bank of Tanzania (1975), Economic Bulletin, 7, 1. Bank of Tanzania (1981), Tanzania: Twenty Years of Independence (1961–1981), A Review of Political and Economic Performance, Dar es Salaam: Bank of Tanzania. Bank of Tanzania (1984), Tanzania: Twenty Years of Independence (1961–1981): A Review of Political and Economic Performance, Dar es Salaam. Bank of Tanzania (1988), Economic and Operations Report 1988, Dar es Salaam: Bank of Tanzania.
376
Bibliography 377 Bank of Tanzania (1989), Economic and Operations Report for the Year ended 30th June 1989, Dar es Salaam: Bank of Tanzania. Bank of Tanzania (1992), Economic and Operations Report 1992, Dar es Salaam: Bank of Tanzania. Bank of Tanzania (1995), Economic and Operations Report 1995, Dar es Salaam: Bank of Tanzania. Bank of Tanzania (1996a), Economic Bulletin, 24 (4). Bank of Tanzania (1996b), Economic Trends in Figures, June 1966–June 1996. Bank of Tanzania (1997), Economic Bulletin, 30 Sept. Bank of Tanzania (1998a), Economic Bulletin, 27 (4). Bank of Tanzania (1998b), Monthly Economic Review, May 1998. Bank of Tanzania (various), Economic and Operations Report. Bank of Uganda (1995), Importation of Fertilizers in Uganda (1990–1994), Agricultural Secretariat. Barker, C.E., M.R. Baghavan, P.V. Mitschke-Collande and D.V. Wield (1986), African Industrialisation: Technology and Change in Tanzania, Vermont: Gower. Barro, R.J. and Jong-Wha Lee (1993), ‘Losers and Winners in Economic Growth’, Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics, 267–98. Washington DC: The World Bank. Barros, A.R. (1993), ‘Some implications of New Growth Theory for Economic Development’, Journal of International Development, 5 (5), 532–58. Bates, R. (1981), Markets and States in Tropical Africa, Berkeley: University of California Press. Beadle, L.C. and E.M. Lind (1960), ‘Research on the Swamps of Uganda’, Uganda Journal, 24, 84–98. Beaulac, M.N. and K.H. Reckhow (1982), ‘An Examination of Land Use – Nutrient Export Relationships’, Water Resources Bulletin, 18, 1013–24. Bell, M., B. Ross-Larsen and L.Westphal (1984), ‘Assessing the Performance of Infant Industries’, Journal of Development Economics, 16, 101–28. Benjamin, J.R. and C.A. Cornell (1970), Probability, Statistics and Decision for Civil Engineers, New York: McGraw-Hill. Bennett, J.T. and M.H. Johnson (1979), ‘Public versus Private Provision of Collective Goods and Services’, Public Choice, 34:55–64. Bertholet, C.J.L. and P.E. Lapperre (1991), The Development of Societies in Global Perspective, Eindhoven: lecture notes, Eindhoven University of Technology, Mimeo. Biersteker (1991), ‘Reducing the Role of the State in the Economy: A Conceptual Exploration of IMF and World Bank Prescription’, International Studies Quarterly, 34, 477–92. Board of External Trade (1989), Ten Years of the Board of External Trade: 1979–1989, Dar es Salaam: Tanzania Litho Ltd. Boardman, V.E. and Vining (1989), ‘Ownership and Performance in Competitive Environment: A Comparison of the Performance of Private, Mixed and State Owned Enterprises’, Journal of Law and Economics, 32 (April), 136. Bol, D. (1995), Employment and Equity Issues in Tanzania, A paper presented at an ERB workshop on Beyond SAP in Tanzania, Dar es Salaam. Bongenaar, B. (1997), ‘Analyzing Technology Development, Part I: Evaluating the Role of the Tanzania Research and Development Organization’, MSc thesis, Eindhoven: Technology and Development Studies, Eindhoven University of Technology. Bongenaar, B. and A. Szirmai (1998), The Role of a Research and Development Institute in the Development and Diffusion of Technology: the case of TIRDO, paper presented at
378 Bibliography the conference on The Industrial Performance of Tanzania, Eindhoven, 25–27 June 1998. Bongenaar, B. and A. Szirmai (1999), The Role of a Research and Development Institute in the Development and Diffusion of Technology, Working Paper 99.9, Eindhoven Centre of Innovation Studies, http://tm.tue.nl/ecis/pubs.html. Bootsma, H.A. and R.E. Hecky (1993), ‘Conservation of the African Great Lakes: A Limnological Perspective’, Conservation Biology, 7, 3, 644–55. Borcherding, T.E., W.W. Pommerchne and F. Schneider (1982), ‘Comparing the Efficiency of Private and Public Production: The Evidence from Five Countries,’ in: Zeitschrift für National-Ökonomie, 2. Bos, E. (1995), World Population Projections 1994–1995: Estimates and Projections with Related Demographic Statistics, London: Longman. Bos, O.F. (1997), Energy Conservation in Tanzanian Industry, Eindhoven: Technology and Development Studies, Eindhoven University of Technology. Boyco, M., A. Shleifer and R.W. Vishny (1993), A Theory of Privatization, Boston: Harvard University. Brabant, J.M. van (1994), ‘On the Economics of Property Rights and Privatisation in Transitional Economics’, in: P. Cook and C. Kirkpatrick (eds), Privatisation Policy and Performance – International Perspectives, New York: Prentice Hall. Braun, A. (1995), Nutrient Flows in Fallow Systems and Maize in Western Kenya, Wageningen, International Centre for Development Oriented Research in Agriculture: ICRA. Bromley, R.J. (1978), ‘Organization, Regulation and Exploitation in the So-Called Urban Informal Sector: The Street Traders of Cali Columbia’, World Development, 6 (9), Sept.–Oct., 1161–86. Bromley, R. and C. Birbeck (1984), ‘Researching Street Occupations of Cali: The Rationale and Methods of What Many Would Call an Informal Sector Study’, Regional Development Dialogue, 5 (2), 184–203. BRU (1974), Minimum Requirements for Permanent Single Storey Houses, Technical Pamphlet no. 2, Svare, TI, Dar es Salaam: Building Research Unit. BRU (1974–95), Various Reports and Technical Guidelines, Dar es Salaam: Building Research Unit. BRU (1985), The Tanzanian Building Regulations, 1985, Dar es Salaam: Building Research Unit of the Prime Minister’s Office. Bullock, A., S.O. Keya, F.M. Muthuri, T. Bailey-Watts, R. Williams and D. Waughray (1995), Lake Victoria Environmental Management Programme, Draft Final Report by the Regional Consultants. Bureau of Labour Statistics, USA (1998), Data Base Producer Price Indices, Internet: http:\\146142.424\CGI-BIN\DSRV, Version d.d. April 26, 1998. Bureau of Statistics (1970), Survey of Industrial Production, 1967 [1969–1974, 1979–1988, 1990], Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics, Ministry of Economic Affairs and Development Planning. Bureau of Statistics (1971), National Accounts of Tanzania, 1966 to 1968, Sources and Methods, Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics, Ministry of Economic Affairs and Development Planning. Bureau of Statistics (1972), The Economic Survey 1971–1972, Dar es Salaam, Government Printer. Bureau of Statistics (1977), The Economic Survey 1975–1976, Dar es Salaam, Government Printer. Bureau of Statistics (1981), National Accounts of Tanzania, 1966–1980, Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics, Ministry of Economic Affairs and Development Planning.
Bibliography 379 Bureau of Statistics (1982), The Economic Survey 1981, Dar es Salaam, Government Printer. Bureau of Statistics (1983), Statistical Abstract, 1982, Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics, Ministry of Economic Affairs and Development Planning. Bureau of Statistics (1985a), National Accounts of Tanzania, 1976–1984, Sources and Methods, May. Bureau of Statistics (1985b), Census of Industrial Production, vol. 3, Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics, Ministry of Planning and Economic Affairs, March. Bureau of Statistics (1986), Input–Output Table of Tanzania, 1976, a Background on Sources and Methods, Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics, Ministry of Finance, Economic Affairs and Planning. Bureau of Statistics (1988a), Industrial Commodities, Quarterly Report 87–1 [1985:4, 1986:1–4, 1987:1–4, 1988:1–2, 1989:1–4, 1990:1–2, 1990:1–4, 1992: 1–2, 1991:1–4, 1992:1–4, 1993:1, 1993:3, 1993:4, 1994:1, 1995:3], Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics, Ministry of Finance, Economic Affairs and Planning. Bureau of Statistics (1988b), Population Census: Preliminary Report of the Bureau of Statistics, Ministry of Finance, Economic Affairs and Planning, Dar es Salaam: Government Printer. Bureau of Statistics (1990), National Accounts of Tanzania, 1976–1989, Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics, President’s Office, Planning Commission. Bureau of Statistics (1992), National Accounts of Tanzania, 1976–1991, Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics, President’s Office, Planning Commission. Bureau of Statistics (1993a), Census of Industrial Production (1989), vol. V, Methodology Report, Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics, President’s Office, Planning Commission. Bureau of Statistics (1993b), National Accounts of Tanzania, Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics, President’s Office, Planning Commission. Bureau of Statistics (1994a), Census of Industrial Production (1989), vol. IV (Part 1), Comprehensive Report 10+, Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics, President’s Office, Planning Commission. Bureau of Statistics (1994b), Environment Statistics in Tanzania Mainland, Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics, President’s Office, Planning Commission. Bureau of Statistics (1994c), National Accounts of Tanzania, 1976–1993, Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics, President’s Office, Planning Commission, August. Bureau of Statistics (1994d), Statistical Abstract, 1992, Dar es Salaam: President’s Office, Planning Commission, Government Printer, February. Bureau of Statistics (1994e), Selected Statistical Series, 1951–1991, Dar es Salaam: President’s Office, Planning Commission. Bureau of Statistics (1995a), Revised National Accounts of Tanzania, 1976–1990, Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics, President’s Office, Planning Commission. Bureau of Statistics (1995b), National Accounts of Tanzania, 1976–1994, Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics, President’s Office, Planning Commission. Bureau of Statistics (1995c), Selected Statistical Series, 1951–1992, Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics, President’s Office, Planning Commission. Bureau of Statistics (1995d), Workshop on Consumer Price Index, 6 to 8 February 1995, Mkonge Hotel, Tanga. Bureau of Statistics (1995e), Selected Statistical Series, 1951–1994, Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics, President’s Office, Planning Commission. Bureau of Statistics (1996a), Producer Price Index (Manufacturing Sector), Quarterly Report 1995:3, Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics, President’s Office, Planning Commission.
380 Bibliography Bureau of Statistics (1996b), Industrial Commodities Quarterly Report, 1996:1, Dar es Salaam (and various issues). Bureau of Statistics (1999), Division of National Accounts, Printout 1987–1998, Dar es Salaam: National Bureau of Statistics, September. Calamari, D.A., M.O. Akech. and P.B.O. Ochumba (1994), Pollution of Winam Gulf, Lake Victoria, Kenya, CIFA Seminar on African Inland Fisheries, Aquaculture and Environment, Harare, Zimbabwe, 5–7 December. Callely, A.G., C.F. Forster and D.A. Stafford (1977), Treatment of Industrial Effluents, London: Hodder & Stoughton. Cameron, R. (1991), Economische Wereldgeschiedenis: van de Oude Steentijd tot Heden, Utrecht: Spectrum. Caniëls, M. (1999), Regional Growth Differentials: the Impact of Locally Bounded Knowledge Spillovers, thesis, University of Maastricht. Carlsson, B. (1987), ‘Reflections on “Industrial Dynamics”: The Challenges Ahead’, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 5 (2), 135–48. Castells, M. (1997), The Information Age: Economy, Society and Culture, vol. 1, Oxford: Blackwell Publishers. Caves, D.W. and L.R. Christensen (1980), ‘The Relative Efficiency of Public and Private Firms in a Competitive Environment: The Case of Canadian Railroads’, Journal of Political Economy, 98. Centraal Bureau voor de Statistiek (1995), Vijfennegentig Jaren Statistiek in Tijdreeksen 1899–1994, Den Haag: Staatsuitgeverij. Central Statistic Bureau (1964a), Census of Industrial Production in Tanganyika 1961, Dar es Salaam: Central Statistic Bureau. Central Statistic Bureau (1964b), The National Accounts of Tanganyika, 1960–1962, Dar es Salaam: Central Statistic Bureau. Central Statistic Bureau (1965), Survey of Industries, 1965, Memorandum on Definitions, Concepts and Procedures, Dar es Salaam: Central Statistic Bureau, Ministry of Economic Affairs and Development Planning. Central Statistic Bureau (1966), Survey of Industries, 1965, Dar es Salaam: Central Statistic Bureau, Ministry of Economic Affairs and Development Planning. Central Statistic Bureau (1969), Survey of Industries, 1967, Dar es Salaam: Central Statistic Bureau, Ministry of Economic Affairs and Development Planning. Central Statistical Office (1976), The Measurement of Changes in Production, Studies in Official Statistics, 25, London: Her Majesty’s Stationery Office. Centre for Development Research (1995), Structural Adjustment in Africa: A Survey of the Evidence. Chambua, S.E. (1990), Technology Assessment and Acquisition in Tanzania, Institute for Development Studies. Chazan, N., R. Mortimer, J. Ravenhill and D. Rothchild (eds) (1988), Politics and Society in Contemporary Africa, Boulder: Lynne Rienner. Chenery, H.B. (1958), ‘Development Policies and Programmes’, Economic Bulletin for Latin America, 3 (1). Chenery, H.B. (1979), Structural Change and Development Policy, Oxford: Oxford University Press. CHS (1995), Urban and Housing Indicators Study for Dar es Salaam, Dar es Salaam: Centre for Human Settlements Studies, ARDHI Institute. Chungu et al. (1994), Assessment and Choice of Technological Alternatives – The Case of Edible Oil Processing in Rural Tanzania, Dar es Salaam: Institute of Production Innovation.
Bibliography 381 Clark, W.E. (1978), Socialist Development and Public Investment in Tanzania, Toronto: University of Toronto Press. Clerides, S.K., S. Lachs, and J.R. Tybout (1998), ‘Is Learning by Exporting Important? Micro-Dynamic Evidence from Colombia, Mexico, and Morocco’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113, 903–48. Cody, J., H. Hughes and D. Wall (1980), Policies for Industrial Progress in Developing Countries, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Cody, J., R. Kitchen and J. Weiss (1990), Policy Design and Price Reform in Developing Countries: Guidelines with Special Reference to Industry, New York: Harvester Wheatsheaf. Collier, P. and J. Gunning (1999), ‘Explaining African Economic Performance’, Journal of Economic Literature, 37, 64–111. Cooper, C. (1991), Are Innovation Studies on Industrialized Economies Relevant to Technology Policy in Developing Countries?, UNU/INTECH, Working Paper no. 3, Maastricht. Cooper, C. (1995), Technology, Manufactured Exports and Competitiveness, UNU/INTECH Discussion Paper no. 9513, December. Cooper, C.M. (1993), Technology and Innovation in the International Economy, London: Edward Elgar. Cooper, C., et al. (1994), Import Liberalization, Industrialization and Technological Capability in Africa: An Outline of a Research Project, Oxford. COSTECH (1990), Tanzania Commission for Science and Technology, Dar Es Salaam. Coulson, A. (ed.) (1979), African Socialism in Practice, Nottingham: Spokesman. Coulson, A. (1982a), ‘The State and Industrialization in Tanzania’, in: M. Fransman (ed.), Industry and Accumulation in Africa, London: Heinemann, 60–76. Coulson, A. (1982b), Tanzania: A Political Economy, Oxford: Clarendon Press. Crul, R.C.M. (1993), Limnology and Hydrology of Lake Victoria, Monographs of the African Great Lakes, UNESCO/IHP. CS I (September 1982–February 1987), Caustic Soda Project File I, collection of approximately 150 notes, reports and documents, TIRDO. CS II (March 1987–July 1993), Caustic Soda Project File II, collection of approximately 180 notes, reports and documents, TIRDO. Dahlmann, C., B. Ross-Larsen and L.E. Westphal (1987), ‘Managing Technological Development: Lessons from Newly Industrialising Countries’, World Development, 15. DANIDA (1989), Country Strategy for Strengthening Environmental Considerations in Danish Development Assistance to Tanzania. Dao, G.C. (1989), ‘The Developing World and the Multi-Fibre Arrangement’, in: J. Whalley (ed.), Developing Countries and the Global Trading System, vol. 2, Basingstoke: Macmillan Press – now Palgrave. Dar, U. (1990), ‘Management of Technological Change: An Overview’, in: UNIDO, Management of Technological Change: Issues and Case Studies from India, chapter XIV, Vienna, UNIDO. Dar es Salaam Technical College (1995), unpublished internal documents. David, P. (1975), Technological Choice, Innovation and Economic Growth, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Davies, R. (1979), ‘Informal Sector Versus Subordinate Mode of Production: A Model’, in: R. Bromley and C. Gerry (eds), Casual Work and Poverty in Third World Cities, Chichester: Wiley, 87–109. DeBresson, C. (1989), ‘Breeding Innovation Clusters: A Source of Dynamic Development’, World Development, 17 (1), 1–16.
382 Bibliography DeBresson, C. (1994), Mapping the Sources and Application of Innovative Activities in Developing Countries, Research Development Project for a Comparative Study, University of Quebec at Montreal (UQAM). De Soto, H. (1989), The Other Path: The Invisible Revolution in the Third World, New York: Harper and Row. Dessing, M. (1990), Support for Microenterprises: Lessons for sub-Saharan Africa, World Bank Technical Paper Number 122, Washington DC: The World Bank. Dijk, M.P. van (1980), ‘De Informele Sector van Ouagadougou en Dakar’, dissertation, Amsterdam: Free University. Division of Environment (1995), National Environmental Policy (final draft), Ministry of Tourism, National Resources and Environment, Dar es Salaam. Diyamet, B.D., R.S. Mabala and R. Mandara, Poverty and Diffusion of Technological Innovations to Rural Women: The Role of Entrepreneurship, Research on Poverty Alleviation, Research Report no. 98.2, Dar es Salaam. Donges, J.B. (1976), ‘A Comparative Survey of Industrialisation Policies in Fifteen Semi-Industrial Countries’, Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 112, 4. Dore, R. (1984), ‘Technological Self Reliance’, in: M. Fransman and K. King (eds), Technological Capability in the Third World, London: Macmillan Press – now Palgrave, pp. 65–80. Dosi, G. (1984), Technical Change and Industrial Transformation, New York: St Martin’s Press – now Palgrave. Dosi, G. (1988), ‘Sources, Procedures and Microeconomic Effects of Innovation’ Journal of Economic Literature, 26, September. Downs, A. (1967), Inside Bureaucracy, Boston: Little Brown. Droruga, N. (1990), Report on the Purification of Industrial Waste Water in Uganda, Kampala: Ministry of Environmental Protection. Due, J.M. and A.E. Temu (1996), A Pilot Study of Privatised Agro-Industrial Parastatals in Tanzania, Morogoro: Urban. Duijsens, R.J.H. (1995), Education in Tanzania: A Sector Review, unpublished document, Eindhoven: Eindhoven University of Technology. Duijsens, R.J.H. (1996), Metal Industry and Technical Education in Tanzania: Model for Matching Demand and Supply of Knowledge and Skills, MSc thesis, Eindhoven: Technology and Development Studies, Eindhoven University of Technology. Duijsens, R.J.H. and P.E. Lapperre (1998), Education, Technical Education and the Nature and Causes of Shortcomings in Knowledge and Skills in the Metalworking Industry in Tanzania, paper presented at the conference The Industrial Performance of Tanzania, Eindhoven, 25–27 June 1998. Easterly, W. (1993), Is Africa Different? Evidence From Growth Regressions, Washington DC: World Bank Policy Research Department. Economopoulos, A.P. (1993), Assessment of Sources of Air, Water and Land Pollution, Part One: Rapid Inventory Techniques in Environmental Pollution, WHO/PEP/GETNET/93.1-A, Geneva: World Health Organization. Egmond-de Wilde de Ligny, E.L.C. van (1993), International Technology Transfer to Developing Countries, lecture notes no. 1649, Eindhoven: Eindhoven University of Technology. Egmond-de Wilde de Ligny, E.L.C. van (1995), International Technology Transfer to Developing Countries, Summary of ITT lectures, 1994–95, Eindhoven: TDS, Eindhoven University of Technology. Egmond-de Wilde de Ligny, E.L.C. van, (1996), ‘Summarized Findings of the Studies of the Housing Situation in Tanzania’, chapter 4 pp 29–35, in: Report of Baseline
Bibliography 383 Surveys on the National Opportunities for the Application of New Bamboo Construction Technologies in the Housing Sector in Tanzania, Egomond-de Wilde de Ligny, E.C.L. van, Gaillard, H. and Janssen, J.J.A. (ed.): Centre for International Co-Operation Activities, Eindhoven University of Technology, Eindhoven, The Netherlands and NCC, Dar es Salaam, Tanzania, February 1996. Egmond-de Wilde de Ligny, E.C.L. and Rijkenberg, S. (1998), The Construction Industry in Tanzania: Challenges to Contribute to Tanzanian Socioeconomic Development? Paper presented at the Conference on Industrial Performance of Tanzania, Eindhoven, The Netherlands, 25–27 June, 1998. Egmond-de Wilde de Ligny, E.L.C. van (2000), Technology Mapping for Technology Management, PhD Thesis, Delft University of Technology. Ehrhorn, T.H. (1982), Integrierte Energieversorgung im Brauereien, Berlin, Ehrhorn. Elbadawi, I. (1998), ‘Real Exchange Rate Policy and Export Competitiveness in subSaharan Africa’, paper presented at a UNU/WIDER Workshop on the Impact of Liberalization on Key Markets in sub-Saharan Africa, Addis Ababa, Ethiopia, March. Engblom, A.C. and V. Veres (1998), Capacity Utilization and the Impact of Structural Adjustment: The Case of the Tanzania Textile Industry unpublished MA thesis, Gothenburg University. Engelen, D.M. van (1996), Public Policy Making and the Rise and Fall of the Tanzanian Manufacturing Sector, MSc thesis, Eindhoven: Technology and Development Studies, Eindhoven University of Technology. ESCAP (1989), A Framework for Technology Based Development: An Overview of the Framework for Technology-Based Development, Bangalore: United Nations. ESRF (1997), Multi-Country Comparative Study of Private Enterprise Development (MCCPED): A Tanzania Country Report, (S.M. Wangwe, H.H. Semboja, J.P. Kweka and H.B.P. Moshi), Dar es Salaam, Tanzania. ESRF (1998), Labour Market Survey for VETA, Dar es Salaam, May. ESRF-PSRC (1996), The Impact of Divestiture and Privatization Process on Industrial Performance: The Case of Six Divested Companies, a report submitted to the Parastatal Sector Reform Commission (PSRC), Dar es Salaam. ESRF-VETA (1998), Labour Market Survey in the Dar es Salaam Region, final draft report. Evans, J. (1985), The Flowering of the Middle Ages, London: Thames and Hudson. Co-penhagen. Fei, J.C.H. and G. Ranis (1964), Development of the Labour Surplus Economy, Theory and Policy, Homewood, Ill: Richard D. Irwin. Fei, J.C.H. and G. Ranis (1976), ‘A Model of Growth in the Open Dualistic Economy: the Case of Korea and Taiwan’, Journal of Development Studies, May. Fereira, M.L. (1993), Tanzania: A Poverty Profile, Washington DC: World Bank. Fereira, M.L. and C.C. Griffin (1995), Human Resource Development Survey, Tanzania, Washington DC: World Bank, I, Annexes I & II. Fleisheuer, M. (1994), Road Construction in Tanzania: Problems, Constraints and Opportunities. A Case Study on the Execution of Road Construction in Tanzania, MSc thesis, Eindhoven: Technology and Development Studies, Eindhoven University of Technology. Foster, A.D. and M.R. Rosenzweig et al. (1995a), Learning by Doing and Learning From Others: Human Capital and Technical Change in Agriculture, University of Pennsylvania. Foster, A.D. and M.R. Rosenzweig et al. (1995b), Technical Change and Human Capital Returns and Investments: Evidence from the Green Revolution, University of Pennsylvania.
384 Bibliography Fransman, M. (1984), ‘Technological Capability in the Third World: An Overview and Introduction to Some of the Issues Raised in this Book’, in: M. Fransman and K. King (eds), Technological Capability in the Third World, London: Macmillan Press – now Palgrave. Fransman, M. (1986), Technology and Economic Development, Brighton: Wheatsheaf Books. Freeman, C. (1982), The Economics of Industrial Innovation, 2nd edn, London: Pinter. Gallagher, M. (1991), Rent Seeking and Economic Growth in Africa, Boulder: Westview. Galtung, J. (1968), Sociological Theory and Social Development, Kampala: Transition Books. Gerschenkron, A. (1962), Economic Development in Historical Perspective, Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Gnoth, M. (1994), Assessment of Condition of Trucks and Busses: Road Haulage Sector in Tanzania, MSc thesis, Eindhoven: Technology and Development Studies, Eindhoven University of Technology. Goodlad, J. (1979), What Schools Are for, Bloomington: Peacock. Gophen, M., P.B.O. Ochumba and L.S. Kaufman (1995), ‘Some aspects of perturbation in the structure and biodiversity of the ecosystem of Lake Victoria (East Africa)’, Aquatic Living Resources, 8, 27–41. Graham-Brown, S. (1991), Education in the Developing World, London: Longman. Green, R.H., D.G. Rwegasira and B. van Arkadie (1980), Economic Shocks and National Policy Making: Tanzania in the 1970s, The Hague: Institute of Social Studies. Greenaway, D. and C. Milner (1993), Trade and Industrial Policy in Developing Countries: A Manual of Policy Analysis, London: Macmillan Press – now Palgrave. Grigg, D. (1982), The Dynamics of Agricultural Change: the Historical Experience, London: Longman. Grossman, G.M. and E. Helpman (1995), Technology and Trade, National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper no. 4926. Guerguil, M. (1988), ‘Some Thoughts on the Definition of the Informal Sector’, CEPAL Review, 35, August. Gulhati, R. (1990), ‘Who Makes Economic Policy in Africa and How?’, World Development, 18, 8. Gulhati, R. and U. Sekhar (1982), ‘Industrial Strategy for Late Starters: The Experience of Kenya, Tanzania and Zambia’, World Development, 10, 11. Haggblade, S., C. Liedholm, and D.C. Mead (1990), ‘The Effect of Policy and Policy Reforms on Non-Agricultural Enterprises and Employment in Developing Countries: A Review of Past Experiences’, in: F. Stewart, H. Thomas and T. de Wilde (eds), The Other Policy, London: Intermediate Technology Publications. Hajjar, B.A. and J. Preskey (1993), ‘Privatization in an African Context: The Case of the United Republic of Tanzania’, Industry and Development, 32. Hammond, R.L. (1973), ‘Evaluation at the Logical Level’, in: B.R. Worthen and J.R. Sanders, Educational Evaluation: Theory and Practice, Belmont: Wadsworth. Hart, J. (1971), ‘Informal Income Opportunities and Urban Employment in Ghana’, Journal of Modern African Studies, 2, 61–89. Havnevik, K.J., R. Skarstein and S.M. Wangwe (1985), Small Scale Industrial Sector Study – Tanzania, Review of Experiences and Recommendations for the Future, a Report presented to the Ministry of Industries and Trade, October 1985. Hecky, R.E. (1993), ‘The Eutrophication of Lake Victoria’, Verhandlungen der Internationale Vereinigung für Limnologie, 25, 856–9. Helleiner, G.K. (1990), ‘Trade Strategy in Medium Term Adjustment’, World Development, 18, 6.
Bibliography 385 Helleiner, G.K. (ed.) (1992), Trade Policy, Industrialization and Development, Oxford: Clarendon Press. Helleiner, G.K. (1994), ‘From Adjustment to Development in sub-Saharan Africa: Consensus and Continuing Conflict’, in: G.A. Cornia and G.K. Helleiner, From Adjustment to Development in Africa: Conflict, Controversy, Convergence, Consensus, London: Macmillan Press – now Palgrave. Hemming, R. and K. Miranda (1991), ‘Privatization’, in: Ke-young Chu and R. Hemming (ed.) Public Expenditure Handbook, IMF, Washington, DC 139–45. Henley, J.S. and G.B. Assaf (1993), ‘Privatization in an African Context: The Case of the United Republic of Tanzania’, United Nations Industrial Development Organisation, Industry and Development, 32. HIID (1998), Africa Competitiveness Report, Boston: Harvard, Hillebrand, H. and H. Jansen (1991), ‘Voorwaarden voor industrialisering’, in: J.H. Righart (ed.), De Trage Revolutie: Over de Wording van Industriele Samenlevingen, Meppel: Boom. Husain (1993), ‘Comment on Barro and Wha’, Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics, 305–310, Washington DC: The World Bank. Hyden, G. (1982), Beyond Ujamaa in Tanzania: Underdevelopment and an Uncaptured Peasantry, London: Heinemann. ICRAF (International Centre for Research in Agroforestry) (1995), ‘Rain Sample Analysis’, in: A. Braun (ed.), Nutrient Flows in Fallow Systems and Maize in Western Kenya, 163. ILO (1972), Employment, Incomes and Equality: A Strategy for Increasing Productive Employment in Kenya, Geneva: International Labour Organization. ILO (1982), Basic Needs in Danger, Addis Ababa. ILO (1992), Increasing Productive Employment in East Africa, Geneva: ILO. Iwaarden, A. van (1997) Production and Application of Timber in the Construction Sector, Tanzania, MSc thesis, Eindhoven: Technology and Development Studies, Eindhoven University of Technology. Iwugo, K.O. (1990), Basic Concepts of Environmental Quality Control in Relation to Baseline Studies on Land-Based Sources of Pollution, lecture presented at the IOC–SAREC–UNEP–FAO–IAEA–WHO workshop on regional aspects of marine pollution, Mauritius, 20 October–9November, Mimeo. James, J. (1995), The State, Technology and Industrialization in Africa, Basingstoke: Macmillan Press – now Palgrave. James, J. (1998), Public Choice, Technology and Industrialization in Tanzania, paper presented at the conference on The Industrial Performance in Tanzania, Eindhoven, 25–27 June. Jansen, H. (1991), ‘De sterke en Flexibele Staat: Politiek-Institutionele Voorwaarden Voor Industrialisatie’, in: H. Righart, (ed.), De Trage Revolutie: Over de Wording van Industriële Samenlevingen, Meppel: Boom. Jedruszek, J. (1979), Development in Employment and Productivity in Tanzania, 1967–77, paper 78.5/78.6 Economic Research Bureau, University of Dar es Salaam. Jolliffe, D. (1995), Cognitive Skills, Schooling and Income: Evidence from Ghana, manuscript. Jørgensen, S.E. (1980), Lake Management, Oxford: Pergamon. Kahama C.G. (1982), Tanzania Professional Centre 2nd Inter Professional Conference on Priorities in National Development: Executive Summary, Dar Es Salaam. Kaplinsky, R. (1984), ‘Third World Industrialisation in the 1980s: Open Economies in a Closing World’, Journal of Development Studies, 21 (1). Kaplinsky, R. (1990), The Economies of Small, London: IT Publications.
386 Bibliography Katz, J.M. (1987) (ed.), Technology Generation in Latin American Manufacturing Industries, Basingstoke: Macmillan Press –. Kenya Grain Growers Cooperative Union (1991), ‘Government Fertilizer Distribution, 1990/1991’, unpublished, Nakuru, Kenya. Kers, D. (1997), Industrial Development and Electricity Supply: Mbagala, Tanzania, as a Case, MSc thesis, Eindhoven: Technology and Development Studies, Eindhoven University of Technology. Kessels, J.W.M. and C.A. Smit (1992), ‘Opleidingsnoodzaak en Evaluatie: op zoek naar Vaardigheden’, in: Opleiders in Organisaties Capita Selecta, Deventer: Kluwer Bedrijfswetenschappen. Killick, T. (1976), ‘The Possibilities of Development Planning’, Oxford Economic Papers, 41 (3). Killick, T. (1981), Policy Economics, London: Heinemann. Killick, T. (1989), Principles of Policy for the Adaptive Economy, Working Paper no. 32, London: Overseas Development Institute. Killick, T. (1990), Markets and Governments in Agricultural and Industrial Adjustment, Working Paper no. 34, London: Overseas Development Institute. Kimambo, R.H. (1984), Mining and Mineral Prospects in Tanzania, Arusha: Eastern Africa Publications Ltd. Kimambo, R.H. (1988), Development of the Non-Metallic Minerals and the Silicate Industry in Tanzania, a Profile of the Silicate Industry in Tanzania, Arusha, Tanzania. King, K. (1988), Aid and the Educational Research in Developing Countries: The Role of Donor Agencies in the Analysis of Education, Edinburgh: Edinburgh University, Centre of African Studies. Kiondo, A. (1991), ‘The Nature of Economic Reforms’, in: H. Campbell and H. Stein (eds), The IMF and Tanzania: The Dynamics of Liberalisation, Harare: Southern Africa Political Series Trusts. Kirkpatrick, C.H., N. Lee and F.I. Nixson (1984), Industrial Structure and Policy in Less Developed Countries, London: Allen and Unwin. Kirkpatrick, C. and J. Maharaja (1992), ‘The Effect of Trade Liberalization on Industrial-Sector Productivity Performance in Developing Countries’, in: J.M. Fontaine (ed.), Foreign Trade Reforms and Development Strategy, London: Routledge. Kirugara, D. and N. Nevejan (1996), Identification of Pollution Sources in the Kenyan Part of the Lake Victoria Catchment Area, Kisumu, Kenya, and Brussels, Belgium: Kenya–Belgium Joint Project in Freshwater Ecology. Kisanga, A.U. (1990), ‘The Challenge Faced by the Building Materials Industries in Developing Countries: with Special Reference to Tanzania’, Habitat International, 14 (4), 119–21. Kisimbo, A.T. (1994), Product Development and Commercialisation: TEMDO Experience, Fourth Annual Scientific Seminar, Dar es Salaam, COSTECH. Koenders, P. (1994), Development of a Travel Planning System at Tanzania Railways Corporation (TRC) and Effect of Liberalization on TRC, MSc thesis, Eindhoven: Technology and Development Studies, Eindhoven University of Technology. Komba (1999), Structural Change and Competitiveness in Tanzanian Manufacturing Sector. PhD thesis. (unpublished) Washington University. Kravis, I., A. Heston and R. Summers (1982), World Product and Income, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins. Krueger, A.O. (1992), Economic Policy Reform in Developing Countries, The Kuznets Memorial Lectures at the Economic Growth Center, Yale University, Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.
Bibliography 387 Krugman, P. (1987), ‘The Narrow Moving Band, the Dutch Disease, and the Competitive Consequences of Mrs. Thatcher – Notes on Trade in the presence of Dynamic Scale Economies’, Journal of Development Economics, 27, 41–55. Kulindwa, K.A. (1994), Energy Consumption Patterns in the Manufacturing Sector of Tanzania, PhD thesis, Dar es Salaam: University of Dar es Salaam. Kumar, N. and M. Saqib (1994), Firm Size, Opportunities for Adaptation, and In-House R&D Activity in Developing Countries: The Case of Indian Manufacturing, UNUINTECH Working Paper no. 13. Kyessi, A.G. (1995), Overview of the Human Settlements Development and Management in Tanzania, conference paper presented at the National Workshop on Launching Habitat II for NGOs, CBO and other actors, Dar es Salaam: CHS, ARDHI. Kyessi, A., A.A. Mwaiselage and B. Seleki (1995), Shelter Situation in Tanzania, a paper presented during the National Workshop on Prefabrication in Housing Construction, Dar es Salaam: CHS, ARDHI. Lake Basin Development Authority – Republic of Kenya (1984), Technical Course on Water Quality Monitoring and Analysis, Kakamega, January, Final Report. Lake Basin Development Authority – Republic of Kenya (1987), The Study of the Integrated Regional Development Master Plan for the Lake Basin Development Area, 7 vols. Lall, S. (1982), Developing Countries as Exporters of Technology: A First Look at the Indian Experience, London: Macmillan Press – now Palgrave. Lall, S. (1985), ‘Trade in Technology by a Slowly Industrializing Country: India’, in: N. Rosenberg and C. Frischtak (eds), International Technology Transfer: Concepts, Measures and Comparisons, New York: Praeger. Lall, S. (1987), Learning to Industrialize: The Acquisition of Technological Capability by India, London: Macmillan Press – now Palgrave. Lall, S. (1990), Building Industrial Competitiveness in Developing Countries, Paris: OECD. Lall, S. (1992a), ‘Technological Capabilities and Industrialization’, World Development, 20 (2). Lall, S. (1992b), Alternative Development Strategies in sub-Saharan Africa. New York: St. Martin’s Press – now Palgrave. Lall, S. (1995), ‘Structural Adjustment and African Industry’, World Development, 23, 2019–31. Lall, S. (1996), Opening Up, and Shutting Down?: Import Liberalization and Industrial Technology in sub-Saharan Africa, Study for the United Nations Institute for New Technologies (INTECH), QEH, Oxford. Lall, S. (1999), ‘Technological Change and Industrialization in the Asian NIEs: Achievements and Challenges’, in: A. Szirmai, J. Halman, and B. Verspagen (eds), Innovation in Theory and Practice, papers of the ECIS Opening Conference, Eindhoven: Eindhoven University of Technology. Lall, S. and S.M. Wangwe (1997), ‘Industrial Policy and Industrialization in subSaharan Africa’, A paper prepared for discussion at the AERC Research Workshop, 25 May. Lall, S. et al. (1997), Import Liberalisation and Technological Capabilities Building in Tanzania, Kenya and Zimbabwe, Research Report, n.p. Lapperre, P.E. (1992), Man, Technology, Society and Development, from the Hunters and Gatherers to the First Industrial Revolution, 3.5 Million Years Ago until AD 1760, Helmond: Wibro Press. Lapperre, P.E. (1993), Problems of Developing Countries in Institutional Perspective, lecture notes, Eindhoven: Eindhoven University of Technology.
388 Bibliography Lapperre, P.E. (1997), Sociologie en Techniek: Lange Termijn Wisselwerking Tussen Technologie en Maatschappij, lecture notes, Eindhoven: Eindhoven University of Technology. Lapperre, P.E. (1998), Industrialisation of Tanzania: Can Tanzania Learn from European History?, Paper for the Conference on the Industrial Development of Tanzania, Eindhoven. Lapperre, P.E. and J. van der Ploeg (1997a), Technology Audit Methodology for Medium and Small Scale Manufacturing Enterprises, Working Paper, Eindhoven: Eindhoven University of Technology. Lapperre, P.E. and J. van der Ploeg (1998), Assessment of Six Manufacturing Enterprises in Tanzania: Application of a Technology Audit Methodology for Medium and Small Scale Manufacturing Enterprises, paper presented at the conference on Industrial Performance in Tanzania, Eindhoven, 25–27 June. Laseur, W.J.J. (1989), Technologie Investeren Overzee, Groningen. Laseur, W.J.J. (1991), Managing Technology Transfer, Den Haag: Thieme. Lebrun, O. and C. Gerry (1975), ‘Petty Producers and Capatalism’, Review of African Economies, 1 (3), 20–33. Lee, Kyu Shik and A. Anas (1990), Manufacturers’ Response to Infrastructure Deficiencies in Nigeria: Private Alternatives and Policy Options, Policy Research and External Affairs Working Paper, no. 325, Washington, DC: The World Bank. Lehman, J.T and D.K. Branstrator (1994), ‘Nutrient Dynamics and Turnover Rate of Phosphate and Sulphate in Lake Victoria, East Africa’, Limnology and Oceanography, 39 (2), 223–7. Lemmens A.M.C. et al. (1996), Inventory of the Monitoring Activities, Needs and Possibilities for the Key Environmental Issues in Tanzania, consultancy report for the Royal Dutch Embassy in Dar es Salaam, Tanzania. Lemmens A.M.C., H.A. Zanting, J.H.Y. Katima, J.S. Balwira, F.W. Bugenyi and A.G.M. Scheren (1998a), A Rapid Assessment Methodology for Environmental Pollution Inventory in Tanzania, Lake Victoria Catchment Area as a Case Study, paper presented at the Engineering Research Partnership for Sustainable Development Symposium, Dar es Salaam, Tanzania, July 27–9. Lemmens A.M.C., H.A. Zanting, D.J.M. van Horen and A.G.M. Scheren (1998b), Industry and Environment: Methodologies for Environmental Assessment in Data Poor Situations, Paper presented at the International Conference on the Industrial Performance of Tanzania, Eindhoven, the Netherlands, June 25–7. Lensink, R. (1996), Structural Adjustment in sub-Saharan Africa, London: Longman. Lewis, W.A. (1954), ‘Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour’, The Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies, 22, 139–91. Lieberman, I. (1993), ‘Industrial Restructuring: Policy and Practice’, Policy and Research Series, 9, Washington: The World Bank. Liedholm, C. and D. Mead (1987), Small Scale Industries in Developing Countries: Empirical Evidence and Policy Implications, East Lansing, Michigan State University, Department of Agricultural Economics, MSU International Development Paper, no. 9. Likwelile, S.B. (1997), Private Investment, Macroeconomic Environment and Economic Growth in Tanzania, 1967–95, Dar es Salaam. Lipumba, N. (1991), ‘Exchange Rate Policy in Tanzania’, Tanzania Economic Trends, 3, 4. Lipumba, N.H.I. and A.V.Y. Mbelle (1993), ‘Policy Making for Economic Growth and Poverty Elimination in a Pluralistic Political System in Tanzania: An Overview’, in:
Bibliography 389 M.S.D. Bagachwa and A.V.Y. Mbelle, Economic Policy under a Multiparty System in Tanzania, Dar es Salaam: Dar es Salaam University Press. Little, I.M.D., R.N. Cooper, W.M. Corden and S. Rajapatirana (1993), Boom, Crisis and Adjustment: The Macroeconomic Experience of Developing Countries, Washington: World Bank. Lofchie, M. (1988), ‘Tanzania’s Economic Recovery’, Current History, May edition. Luvanga, N. (1994), Growth of Small and Medium Size Enterprises under Liberalized Markets: The Tanzania Experience, paper prepared for the ICGE, June 1994, Harare. Lynch, D. (1995), ‘Does Financial Sector Development Matter to Investment?’, Savings and Development, 1 (19). Maddison, A. (1995) Monitoring the World Economy, Paris: OECO Development Centre. Maddison, A. and B. van Ark (198), Comparisons of Real Output in Manufacturing, Washington: World Bank, Working Paper, no. 5. Maddison, A. and B. van Ark (1994), International Comparisons of Real Output and Productivity, Research Memorandum GD-b. Groningen Growth and Development Centre. Mageni, O.S. (1994), The Role of Government on Industrial Research and Development Institutions, TEMDO/ UNDP Regional Workshop on ‘Roles, Relevance, and Capabilities of Industrial Research and Development Institutes: Optimising for the 21st Century’, Arusha. Malecki, E.J. (1991), Technology and Economic Development – The Dynamics of Local, Regional and National Change, Harlow: Longman Science & Technical. Maliyamkono, T.L. and M.S.D. Bagachwa (1990), The Second Economy in Tanzania, London: James Curry. Maro, W.E. et al. (1991), Construction Cost Trends and Control Mechanisms in Tanzania, Economic Research Bureau/University of Dar es Salaam. Masuha, J., B. Mutagahywa and B. Nyichomba (1992), Phase I of Development of Improved Production Systems (DIPS): the TDP Project, Dar es Salaam: University of Dar es Salaam, Faculty of Engineering. Mattikalli, N.M. and K.S. Richards (1996), ‘Estimation of Surface Water Quality Changes in Response to Land Use Change: Application of the Export Coefficient Model Using Remote Sensing and Geographical Information System’, Journal of Environmental Management, 48, 263–82. Maxwell, P. (1977), Learning and Technical Change in the Steel Plant of Acindar S.A. in Rosario, Argentina, Research Program Working Paper no. 4, Buenos Aires: Economic Commission for Latin America. Mayer, A.F. (1992), ‘Richtzahlen und Ihr Sinnvoller Einsatz in der Brauerei’, II, Brauwelt, 46, 2427–9. Mbatia, K.S. (1993), ‘Constraints to the Growth of Non-Traditional Exports: Incentive Schemes’, Tanzania Economic Trends, 5, 3–4. Mbelle, A.V.Y. (1988), Foreign Exchange and Industrial Development: A Study of Tanzania, PhD thesis, Sweden: Gothenburg School of Economics and Commercial Law. Mbelle, A.V.Y. (1989), ‘Industrial Performance under the Economic Recovery Programme in Tanzania’, Tanzania Economic Trends, 2 (1), 7–10. Mbelle, A.V.Y. (1993), New Technologies and Export Orientation: The Case of Tanzanian Textile Industries, Department of Economics, University of Dar es Salaam.
390 Bibliography Mbelle, A.V.Y. (1994), ‘Sustainable Industrial Development in Tanzania: Can it be Achieved?’, in: Msambichaka et al. (eds), Development Challenges and Strategies for Tanzania: An Agenda for the 21st Century, Dar es Salaam University Press, 111–30. Mbelle, A.V.Y. (1998), Impact of Liberalization of the Foreign Exchange and Financial Markets in Tanzania, revised draft for the UNU/WIDER project ‘Impact of Liberalization on Key Markets in sub-Saharan Africa’, presented at the meeting in Addis Ababa, Ethiopia, 16–20 March. Mbelle, A.V.Y. and M.S.D. Bagachwa (1995), ‘Technology, Trade and Industrialization in sub-Saharan Africa: Tanzania Country Study’, in: S. Wangwe (ed.), Exporting Africa, London and New York: Routledge, 199–245. Mbelle, A.V.Y. and M.S.D. Semboja (1996), Exchange Rate Calculations, Economic Research Bureau, University of Dar es Salaam, Mimeo. Mbelle, A.V.Y. and J. Shitundu (1997), ‘The Management of Industrial Reforms in Tanzania: Perspectives and New Challenges’, in: D. Bol et al. (eds), Economic Management in Tanzania, Dar es Salaam: TEMA Publishers Co., 179–97. Mbelle, A.V.Y. and T. Sterner (1991), ‘Foreign Exchange and Industrial Development: A Frontier Production Function Analysis of Two Tanzanian Industries’, World Development, 19 (4), 341–7. Mbelle, A.V.Y., B.J. Ndulu and J.J. Semboja (1998a), ‘Trade Liberalization in Tanzania: Episodes and Impacts’ in: A. Oyejide, B.J. Ndulu and J. Gunning (eds), Integration and Trade Liberalization in sub-Saharan Africa, Vol. 2 Country Studies, London: MacMillan. Mbelle, A.V.Y., B.J. Ndulu and J.J. Semboja (1998b), Promoting Non-Traditional Exports in Tanzania, revised Draft for the UNU/WIDER project ‘Growth, External Sector and Role of Non-Traditional Exports in sub-Saharan Africa’ presented at the meeting in Addis Ababa, Ethiopia, 16–20 March. Meeus, M.T.H. and L.A.G. Oerlemans (1993), ‘Economic Network Research: A Methodological State of the Art’, in: P. Beije, J. Groenewegen and O. Nuys (eds.), Networking in Dutch Industries, Leuven: Garant. Meier, G.M. (1990), ‘Trade Policy and Development’, in: M. Scott and D. Lal (eds), Public Policy and Economic Development: Essays in Honour of Ian Little, Oxford: Clarendon Press. Meier, G.M. and W.F. Steel (1989), Industrial Adjustment in sub-Saharan Africa, New York: Oxford University Press. Metcalf and Eddy, Inc. (1991), Wastewater Engineering: Treatment, Disposal and Reuse, New York: McGraw-Hill. Mgana, S. and S. Mahongo (1997), Land-Based Sources and Activities Affecting the Quality and Uses of the Marine, Coastal and Associated Fresh Water Environment, workshop on the implementation of the Global Programme of Action Zanzibar, Tanzania, 6–9 Oct. Michalopoulus, C. (1987), ‘World Bank Programs for Adjustment and Growth’, in: V. Corbo, M. Goldstein and M. Khan (eds), Growth-Oriented Adjustment Programs, Washington: World Bank. Millward, R. and D.M. Parker (1983), ‘Public and Private Enterprise – Comparative Behaviour and Relative Efficiency’, in: R. Millward, D.M. Parker, et al. (eds), Public Sector Economics, London. Ministry of Agriculture, Animal Industry and Fisheries – Republic of Uganda (1992), Report on Uganda National Census of Agriculture and Livestock (1990–1991). Ministry of Agriculture, Animal Industry and Fisheries – Republic of Uganda (1995), Department of Veterinary Services. Annual Report, 1994.
Bibliography 391 Ministry of Education and Culture (1988), Educational Statistics, Dar es Salaam: Government Printer. Ministry of Education and Culture (1993), Tanzania’s Educational System, Dar es Salaam: Government Printer. Ministry of Education and Culture (1995), Wizara ya Elimu na Utamaduni Takwimu za Schule za Sekondari Tanzania, 1995, Dar es Salaam: Government Printer. Ministry of Finance and Economic Planning – Republic of Uganda (1992), The 1991 Population and Housing Census. Ministry of Finance and Economic Planning – Republic of Uganda (1993), Background to the Budget, 1993–1994, Kampala. Ministry of Health and Environmental Protection – Republic of Tanzania (1980), Handbook of Emission Factors I: Non-Industrial Sources, The Hague: Government Publishing Office. Ministry of Industries (1976), Tanzania Industrial Development Strategy, Dar es Salaam: National Printing Company Ltd. Ministry of Industries and Trade (1996), Sustainable Industrial Development Policy (SIDP), 1996–2020, Dar es Salaam: Printpak. Ministry of Industries and Trade (1999), Speech by the Minister of Industries and Trade, Hon. Iddi Simba, presenting budget estimates for the year 1999/2000 to Parliament, June. Ministry of Natural Resources – Republic of Uganda (1993), Rehabilitation of NWSC Jinja Water and Sewerage, Final Report Volume 1, Directorate of Water Development and International Development Association (IDA). Ministry of Natural Resources – Republic of Uganda (1995), Lake Victoria Environmental Management Program, Report of National Working Group No. 2 on Management of Water Quality and Land Use including Wetlands, Kampala. Ministry of Natural Resources – Republic of Uganda (1996), ‘Forestry Department: Remote Sensing Data from the National Biomass Study’ (unpublished), PO Box 7270, Kampala, Uganda. Ministry of Planning and National Development – Republic of Kenya (1993), Kisumu District Development Plan, 1994–1996. Ministry of Water Development – Republic of Kenya (1992), The Study on the National Water Master Plan. Sectoral Report 1: Socio Economy, Japan International Cooperation Agency (JICA). Misanga, M.K. (1993), ‘Training Needs for Science and Technology Up to the Year 2000 and Beyond’, Uhandisi Journal, December. Mitchell, B.R. (1995), International Historical Statistics: Africa, Asia and Oceania, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Mjema, G. and J. Shitundu (1995), ‘Performance of the Industrial Trade During the Economic Recovery Programme and Some Reflections on Future Prospects’, A paper presented at an ERB Workshop on Beyond SAP in Tanzania, Dar es Salaam. Mlawa, H.M. and M.S. Sheya (1990), Profiles of R&D Institutions in Tanzania, a study prepared for the Secretariat of the Future Actions Committee of Management of Science and Technology for Development, Dar es Salaam, Tanzania. MLYD (1991), Tanzania the Informal Sector, 1991, Ministry of Labor and Youth Development, prepared with assistance from UNDP/ILO, URT/91/028, Dar Es Salaam. Moavenzadeh, F. (1987), ‘The Construction Industry’, in: L. Rodwin (ed.), Shelter, Settlement and Development, Boston: Allen & Unwin.
392 Bibliography Mongi, J.F.K. (1980), ‘The Development of Price Control in Tanzania’, in: K.S.P. Rwegasira and L.A. Kanneworff (eds), Inflation in Tanzania, Dar es Salaam: Institute of Finance Management. More, C. (1997), The Industrial Age: Economy and Society in Britain, 1750–1995, London: Longman. Moshi, H.P.B. (1996), Fiscal Impact of Commercialization and Privatization of Public Enterprises, Dar es Salaam: Mimeo. Moshi, H.P.B. and A.A. Kilindo (1995), The Impact of Government Policy on Macroeconomic Variables: The Case of Private Investment in Tanzania, Nairobi. Mourik, C. van, E.M. van der Ouderaa and C.G. Hage (1991), Management van Research en Development, Deventer: Kluwer. Mukandala, R. (1985), ‘Trends in Civil Service Size and Income in Tanzania, 1967–1982’, Canadian Journal of African Studies, 2, 253–62. Mukandala, R. (1988), The Political Economy of Parastatal Enterprise in Tanzania and Botswana, unpublished doctoral dissertation, Berkeley: University of California. Mumburi, U.P. (1998), Manufacturing Output Growth in Tanzania: An Empirical Analysis, unpublished MA thesis, University of Dar es Salaam. Musonda, M. (1992), Development Strategy and Manufactured Exports in Tanzania, PhD thesis, Sweden: Department of Economics, University of Lund. Musonda, M. and J.P. Kweka (1998), The Dynamics and Potential of Cluster Firms in the Growth and Development of MSEs in Tanzania: The Case of Three Selected Clusters in Tanzania, Dar es Salaam ESRF, Mimeo. Mutagahywa, B. and P.N. Materu (1992), Academic–Industry Links, Development of a Vital Partnership, Faculty of Engineering, University of Dar es Salaam. Mwaiselage, A.A. (1992), Development of Local Construction Capacity in Building Works through Small Scale Contractors in Tanzania, Dar es Salaam: Centre for Housing Studies (CHS), Ardhi Institute. Mwandosya, M. and M. Luhanga (1993), ‘Energy and Development in Tanzania, Issues and Perspectives’, Energy Policy, May, 441–53. MWEM (1992), The Energy Policy of Tanzania, Dar es Salaam: Ministry of Water, Energy and Minerals. MWEM (1995), Energy Balance of Tanzania in 1992, print-out, Dar es Salaam: Ministry of Water, Energy and Minerals. Mwihava, N. and A. Towo (1994), A Study and Assessment of Energy Projects and their Effective Utilization in Tanzania, Dar es Salaam: COSTECH. National Water and Sewerage Corporation – Republic of Uganda (1995), Statistics on Sanitation in NWSC 9 Towns (unpublished), PO Box 7053, Kampala, Uganda. NBAQS and BC (1992), List of Registered Architects, Quantity Surveyors and Building Contractors Dec 1992, Dar Es Salaam. NBS (National Bureau of Statistics), Statistical Publications, various issues, Dar es Salaam. NCC, Komba, S.C. (1992a), Identification & Promotion of Utilisation of Local Resources and Locally Produced Materials for Construction Industry in Tanzania, Final report, phase I, Dar es Salaam: National Construction Council. NCC National Construction Council (1992b), Research and Development Issues in the Construction Industry in Tanzania, Dar Es Salaam. NCC National Construction Council (1995), Proposed National Construction Industry development Policy, Dar es Salaam: National Construction Council, Ministry of Works. ND I (July 1981–May 1984), Natural Dyes Project File I, collection of approximately 100 notes, reports and documents, TIRDO.
Bibliography 393 ND II (May 1984–November 1990), Natural dyes project file II, collection of approximately 70 notes, reports and documents, TIRDO. Ndulu, B.J. (1993), Tanzania’s Economic Development: Lessons from the Experience and Challenges for the Future, paper written for the International Conference on Development Challenges and Strategies for Tanzania: An Agenda for the 21st Century Dar es Salaam. Ndulu, B.J. and J.J. Semboja (1994), ‘Trade and Industrialization in Tanzania: A Review of Experiences and Issues’, in: G.K. Helleiner (ed.), Trade Policy and Industrialization in Turbulent Times, London: Routledge. Ndulu, B.J. and J.J. Semboja (1996), ‘The Development of Manufacturing for Export in Tanzania’ in: G. Helleiner (ed.), Manufacturing for Export in the Developing World: Problems and Possibilities, London and New York: Routledge. Ndulu, B.J., W. Lyakurw, J.J. Semboja and A. Chaligha (1987), Import Tariff Study – Tanzania, Dar es Salaam: unpublished report to the Ministry of Finance. Nelson, R.R. (1990), ‘On Technological Capabilities and Their Acquisition’, in: R.E. Evenson and G. Ranis, Science and Technology: Lessons for Development Policy, Boulder: Westview Press. Nelson, R.R. (1993), National Innovation Systems: A Comparative Analysis, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Nelson, R.R. and E. Phelps (1966), ‘Investment in Humans, Technological Diffusion, and Economic Growth’, American Economic Review, 56, May 69–75. Nelson, R.R. and S.C. Winter (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Cambridge MA Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. Newberry, D.P. and N. Stern (1987), The Theory of Taxation for Developing Countries, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Niosi, J. and J. Rivard (1988), ‘Canadian Technology Transfer to Developing Countries through Small and Medium-Size Enterprises’, World Development, 18, 11. Niskanen, W. (1973), Bureaucracy: Servant or Master?, London: Institute of Economic Affairs. Njau, G.J. et al. (1997), Environmental Impact Assessment on the Proposed Thermal Power Station in Tageta Area, Dar es Salaam, Prepared for Independent Power Tanzania (IPTL) Ltd, May. Nyerere, J. (1968a), Freedom and Socialism, London: Oxford University Press. Nyerere, J. (1968b), Ujamaa: Essays on Socialism, Dar es Salaam: Oxford University Press. Ochumba, P.B.O. (1993), Measurement of Water Currents, Temperature, Dissolved Oxygen and Winds in the Kenyan Lake Victoria, Contribution to the IDEAL Symposium on the Limnology, Climatology and Palaeoclimatology of the East African Lakes, Jinja, Uganda, 18–23 February. Ochumba, P.B.O. and D.I. Kibaara (1989), ‘Observations on Blue-green Algal Blooms in the Open Waters of Lake Victoria’, African Journal of Ecology, 27, 23–34. OECD (February 1971), Latest Information on National Accounts of Less Developed Countries, F/8, No. 5, Paris: OECD. Oerlemans, A.M.H.M. (1985), Research on the Production of Sugar Cane in Kenya, MSc thesis, Eindhoven: Technology and Development Studies, Eindhoven University of Technology. Ogaram, D.A. and W.S. Kalema (1995), Lake Victoria Environmental Management Program, Final report on regional task No. 15: Critical Sources of Industrial and Municipal Pollution.
394 Bibliography Orlova, A.P. and L.V. Yaroshenko (1976), ‘Contents of Pesticide and Mineral Fertilizers in Runoff Water of Uzbekistan Irrigation’, Formirovanie Kontrol Kachestva Poverkhnostnykh Vod, 3, 106–9. Pack, H. and L.E. Westphal (1986), ‘Industrial Strategy and Technological Change: Theory Versus Reality’, Journal of Development Economics, 22. Pack, H. (1987), Productivity, Technology, and Industrial Development, New York: Oxford University Press. Pack, H. (1993), ‘Productivity and Industrial Development in sub-Saharan Africa’, World Development, January, 21, 1–16. Pack, H. and C. Paxson (1998), Is African Manufacturing Skill Constrained?, paper presented at the conference on The Industrial Performance of Tanzania, Eindhoven, 25–27 June. Page Jr., J.M. (1990), ‘The Pursuit of Industrial Growth: Policy Initiatives and Economic Consequences’, in: M. Scott and D. Lal (eds), Public Policy and Economic Development: Essays in Honour of Ian Little, Oxford: Clarendon Press. Parker, R.L., R. Riopelle and W.F. Steel (1995), Small Enterprises Adjusting to Liberalization in Five Countries, World Bank Discussion Papers, no. 271, Washington, DC: The World Bank. Pasinetti, L.L. (1981), Structural Change and Economic Growth, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Pasinetti, L.L. and R.M. Solow (eds) (1994), Economic Growth and the Structure of Long Term Development, proceedings of the IEA Conference held in Varenna, Italy, Basingstoke and London: St Martin’s Press – now Palgrave – in association with the International Economic Association. Perkins, F. (1980), Technological Choice, Industrialization and Development: the Case of Tanzania, unpublished doctoral dissertation, University of Sussex, England. Perkins, F. (1983), ‘Technology Choice, Industrialization and Development Experiences in Tanzania’, Journal of Development Studies, 19 (2), 213–43. Pieper, U. (1998), Openness and Structural Dynamics of Productivity and Employment in Developing Countries: A Case of De-Industrialization?, Geneva: ILO. Pieterson, M. (1987), Het Technisch Labyrint: een Maatschappijgeschiedenis van drie Industriele Revoluties, Meppel: Boom. Planning Commission & Ministry of Labour and Youth Development (1991), National Informal Sector Survey, Dar es Salaam. Planning Commission & Ministry of Labour and Youth Development (1995), The Dar es Salaam Informal Sector Survey 1994/5 [only estimates for manufacturing (in Excel Worksheet format) at our disposal], Dar es Salaam. Porter, M.E. (1985), Competitive Advantage: Creating and Sustaining Superior Performance, London: Collier Macmillan. Porter, M.E. (1986), Competition in Global Industries, Boston: Harvard Business School Press. Porter, M.E. (1990), The Competitive Advantage of Nations, New York: Macmillan – now Palgrave. Prins, I.M. (1997), Manufacturing Statistics, Reconstructing Tanzanian Manufacturing Value Added, 1995–1995, MSc thesis, Eindhoven: Technology and Development Studies, Eindhoven University of Technology. Prins, I.M. and A. Szirmai (1998), A Reconstruction of GDP and Employment in Tanzanian Manufacturing, 1961–1995, Report to the Tanzanian Bureau of Statistics, Eindhoven, December. Psacharopoulos, G. (1991), ‘Vocational Education in Theory: Why Does Vocational Education Fail?’, International Journal of Educational Development, 11, 3.
Bibliography 395 Ranis, G. (1984), ‘Determinants and Consequences of Indigenous Technological Activity’, in: M. Fransman and K. King (eds), Technological Capability in the Third World, London Macmillan Press. Ranis, G. (1988), ‘Analytics of Development: Dualism’, in: H.Chenery and T.N. Srinivasan (eds), Handbook of Development Economics, Amsterdam North Holland Publishers. Reckhow, K.H. and J.T. Simpson (1980), ‘A Procedure Using Modelling and Error Analysis for Prediction of Lake Phosphorus Concentration from Land Use Information’, Canadian Journal of Fisheries and Aquatic Sciences, 37, 1439–48. Ren, R. (1997), China’s Economic Performance in an International Perspective, Paris: OECD. Richardson, C.J. and D.S. Nichols (1985), ‘Ecological Analysis of Wastewater Management Criteria in Wetland Ecosystems in the USA’, The Utrecht Plant Ecology News Report, Dec. 186–219. Riedijk, W. (ed.) (1987), Appropriate Technology for Developing Countries, Delft: Delft University Press. Righart, H. (1991), (ed.) De Trage Revolutie: over de Wording van Industriele Samenlevingen, Meppel: Boom. Ritter, W.F. (1988), ‘Reducing Impacts of Nonpoint Source Pollution from Agriculture: A Review’, Journal of Environmental Science and Health, A23 (7), 645–67. Rodriguez, E. (1998), Costa Rica: Policies and Conditions for Export Diversification, revised draft for the UNU/WIDER project ‘Growth, External Sector and Role of Non-Traditional Exports in sub-Saharan Africa’, presented at the meeting in Addis Ababa, Ethiopia, 16–20 March, Addis Ababa. Rogers, E.M. (1983), Diffusion of Innovations, 3rd edn, New York: The Free Press. Romano, C.A. (1990), ‘Identifying Factors which Influence Product Innovation: A Case Study Approach’, Journal of Management Studies, 27 (1), 75–95. Romein, J. (1954), Aera van Europa: De Europese Geschiedenis als Afwijking van het Algemeen Menselijk Patroon, Leiden: Brill. Romer, P. (1986), ‘Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth’, Journal of Political Economy, 94 (5), 1002–37. Romijn, H.A. (1996), Acquisition of Technological Capability in Small Firms in Developing Countries, Tilburg: Katholieke Universiteit Brabant. Romijn, H.A. (1999), Acquisition of Technological Capability in Small Firms in Developing Countries, Basingstoke: Macmillan Press – now Palgrave. Romiszowski, A.J. (1984), Designing Instructional Systems, London: Kogan Page. Rosberg, C. and T. Callaghy (1979), Socialism in sub-Saharan Africa, Berkeley: University of California, Institute of International Studies. Rosenberg, N. (1986), Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics, Cambridge, MA. Cambridge University Press. Rosenberg, N. (1990), ‘Science and Technology Policy for the Asian NIC’s: Lessons from Economic History’, in: R.E. Evenson and G. Ranis (eds), Science and Technology: Lessons for Development Policy, Boulder Westview. Rosenberg, N. and L.E. Birdzell (1986), How the West Grew Rich: the Economic Transformation of the Industrial World, New York: Basic Books, Inc., Publishers. Rosenzweig, M.R. (1995), ‘Why Are There Returns to Schooling?’, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, May. Rostow, W.W. (1960), The Stages of Economic Growth, Cambridge. Cambridge University Press. Rothwell (1977), ‘Characteristics of Successful Innovation and Technically Progressive Firms’, R & D Management, 7.
396 Bibliography Rothwell, R. (1992), ‘Successful Industrial Innovation: Critical Factors for the 1990s’, R & D Management, 22 (3), 221–31. Rothwell, R. and W. Zegveld (1982), Innovation and the Small and Medium Sized Firm, London: Frances Pinter. Rothwell, R. and W. Zegveld (1985), Re-industrialization and Technology, Longman: Harlow. RPED (1994), Development and Growth of Industrial Enterprise in Tanzania, Center for International Business Research, Helsinki School of Economics, Helsinki, Finland. RPED (1995), Dynamics of Enterprise Development in Tanzania, Final Report on Round II Survey Data, Helsinki School of Economics. Runciman, S. (1994), A History of the Crusades, London: The Folio Society. Ruttan, V.W. (1998), ‘The New Growth Theory and Development Economics: A Survey’, Journal of Development Studies, 35, (2), December. Rweyemamu, J.F. (1973), Underdevelopment and Industrialisation in Tanzania: A Study of Perverse Capitalist Industrial Development, London: Oxford University Press. Sagasti, F. (1979), ‘Towards Endogenous Science and Technology for another Development’, Development Dialogue, No 1. Samplonius, C. (1994), Energy Efficiency in the Tanzanian Industry: The Cement Industry as a Case Study, Eindhoven University of Technology, the Netherlands. Santschi, P.W. and P.W. Schindler (1977), ‘Chemical and Geochemical Studies of Lake Biel’, Schweizer Zeitschrift für Hydrologie, 39, (2), 182–200. Scheren, P.A.G.M. (1995), A Systematic Approach to Lake Water Pollution Assessment: Water Pollution in Lake Victoria, East Africa, Eindhoven University of Technology. Scheren, P.A.G.M., J.C. Bosboom, K. Njau and A.M.C. Lemmens (1995), ‘Assessment of Water Pollution in the Catchment Area of Lake Victoria, Tanzania’, Journal of Eastern African Research and Development, 25, 129–43. Schulte, W. (1996), Technology and Quality Care in Muhimbili Medical Center, Tanzania: Methodology to Study the Role of Technology from the View Point of Total Quality, MSc thesis, Eindhoven: Technology and Development Studies, Eindhoven University of Technology. Schultz, T.W. (1975), ‘The Value of the Ability to Deal with Disequilibria’, Journal of Economic Literature, Sept., 13, 827–46. Schumpeter, J. (1912), Theorie der Wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung, published in English as Theory of Economic Development (1961 edition by Redvers Opie), Oxford: Oxford University Press. Semboja, H.H. (1995), An Overview of the Industrial Sector and Selected Industries’ Performance During the 1980s–1990s, unpublished ESRF Technical Paper, Dar es Salaam: ESRF. Semboja, H.H. et al. (1996), Studies Comparing Small-Scale and Large-Scale Production in LDCs. Semboja, J.J. and I. Karamagi (1991), The Import Duty Tariff Study, a report prepared for the Presidential Commission of Enquiry into Public Revenue and Taxation, October 1991, Dar es Salaam. Semboja, H.H. and J.P.Kweka (1997), Garment Industry, Dar es Salaam: Economic and Social Research Foundation. Semboja, H.H. and J.P. Kweka (1998), An Analysis of the Garment Sector, paper presented at the conference on Industrial Performance in Tanzania, Eindhoven, 25–27 June. Semboja, H. and J. Kweka (forthcoming), Import Liberalization, Industrialization and Technological Capability in sub-Saharan Africa: The Case of the Garment Industry in Tanzania, ESRF Research Paper, Dar es Salaam.
Bibliography 397 Semboja, H.H., J. Kweka and G. Kahyarara (1997a), Firms’ Linkages in the Development of Industry: A Theoretical Note with Policy Perspectives, a paper presented at the International Conference on Entrepreneurship and Small Business Development in Tanzania, 21–22 October, White Sands, Dar es Salaam. Semboja, H., J.P. Kweka, S.M. Wangwe and H.B.P. Moshi (1997b), Multi-Country Comparative Study of Private Enterprise Development (MCC-PED): A Tanzania Country Report, Dar es Salaam: ESRF. Sen, A.K (1994). ‘Growth Economics: What and Why?’, in: L.L. Pasinetti and R.M. Solow (eds), op. cit. Sethuraman, S.V. (ed.) (1981), The Urban Informal Sector in Developing Countries: Employment, Poverty and Environment, Geneva: ILO. Shao, J.R. (1978), Some Features of Tanzanian Manufacturing Industry, MA thesis, University of Dar es Salaam. Shirley, M. (1989), ‘The Reform of State-Owned Enterprises: Lessons from World Bank Lending’, World Bank PPR Series, 4, Washington DC. Shitundu, J.L.M. and G.D. Mjema (1995), ‘Industrial Trade during the Economic Recovery Programme and Some Reflections on Future Prospects’, in: L.H.P.B. Msambichaka et al. (eds), Beyond Structural Adjustment Programmes in Tanzania: Success, Failures and New Perspectives, Dar es Salaam. Shivji, I.G. (1975), Class Struggles in Tanzania, Dar es Salaam: Tanzania Publishing House. Shu, G.F. (1990), ‘Betriebvergleich Energie 1990’, Brauwelt, nr. 9, 1992, p 361. SIDO (1984), Summary of the Fourth Five Year Plan for Development of SIDO 1983/84–1987/88, Dar-Es-Salaam: SIDO. Silver, M.S. (1984), The Growth of Manufacturing Industry in Tanzania, London: Westview Press. Sinda, S.H. (1991), Science and Technology Policies: Their Implementation with regard to Science and Technology Initiatives in Tanzania, in: Proceedings of the International Workshop on the South Commission Recommendations on S&T, COSTECH, Dares Salaam. Skarstein, R. and S.M. Wangwe (1986), Industrial Development in Tanzania: Some Critical Issues, Dar es Salaam: Tanzanian Publishing House. Sonali, D. and H.H. Semboja (1995), Import Liberalization, Industrialization and Technological Capability in Tanzania, Oxford UNU-INTECH Research Project. Souder, W.E. and A.K. Chakrabarti (1980), ‘Managing the Co-ordination of Marketing and R&D in the Innovation Process’, TIMS Studies in the Management Sciences, 15, 135–50. Souza, P.R. and V.E. Tokman (1976), ‘The Urban Informal Sector in Latin America’, International Labour Review, 114 (3), Nov.–Dec. Stein, H. (1991), ‘Economic Policy and the IMF in Tanzania: Conditionality, Conflict and Convergence’, in: H. Campbell and H. Stein (eds), The IMF and Tanzania: The Dynamics of Liberalisation, Harare: Southern Africa Political Economy Series Trusts. Steinmueller, E. and M-I. Bastos (1995), Information and Communication Technologies: Growth, Competitiveness, and Policy for Developing Nations, Background Paper no. 2, UNIDO Global Forum on Industry. Stewart, F. (1977), Technology and Underdevelopment, London: Macmillan Press – now Palgrave. Stewart, F. (1978), ‘Technological Self Reliance of the Developing Countries: Towards Operational Strategies’, in: UNIDO, Development and Transfer of Technology Series, New York: UNIDO.
398 Bibliography Stewart, F. (1984), ‘Facilitating Indigenous Technical Change in Third World Countries’, in: M. Fransman and K. King (eds), Technological Capability in the Third World, London: Macmillan Press – now Palgrave – 81–94. Stewart, F. and J. James (eds) (1982), The Economics of New Technology in Developing Countries, London: Frances Pinter. Stewart, F., S. Lall and S.M. Wangwe (eds) (1992), Alternative Development Strategies in African Development, Macmillan Press – now Palgrave. Straaten, J. van der, et al. (1992), Technology Transfer and Development: A Contribution to Policy Making, Amsterdam: Tool. Syrimis, S. (1988), Sector Review: The Financing of Education in Tanzania, Paris: UNESCO Educational Financing Commission. Szirmai, A. (1997a), Economic and Social Development: Trends, Problems and Policies, London: Prentice Hall. Szirmai, A. (1997b), Ontwikkelingslanden in de Industriële Wedloop [Developing Countries in the Industrial Race], inaugural lecture, Eindhoven University of Technology. Szirmai, A. and D. Pilat (1990), ‘Comparisons of Purchasing Power, Real Output and Labour Productivity in Manufacturing in Japan, South Korea and the USA, 1975–1985’, Review of Income and Wealth, 26 (1), March, 1–31. Szirmai, A. and R. Ren (1998), ‘Chinese Manufacturing in Comparative Perspective’, in: M. Fouquin and F. Lemoine (eds), The Chinese Economy, London: Economica, 49–64. Szirmai, A. and W. Schulte (1998), Comparative Analysis of Real Output and Labour Productivity in Tanzanian Manufacturing: A Level Comparison between Tanzania and the USA in 1989, paper presented at the conference on Industrial Performance in Tanzania, Eindhoven, 25–27 June. Tanzania Economic Trends (1990), ‘National Investment Promotion Policy’, Tanzania Economic Trends, 3, 1–2. Tanzania Economic Trends (1994). Statistical Appendix: Monthly Average Exchange Rates in Tanzania 1989–1993, in: Tanzania Economic Trends, 7, 1201–2. Tarimo, J. (1995), Experiences and Potential for Energy Conservation in Tanzania, a Case Study of TIRDO, paper presented at Demand Side Management Seminar, Dar es Salaam, 9 March. Teitel, S. (1981), ‘Toward an Understanding of Technical Change in SemiIndustrialized Countries’, in: J.M. Katz (ed.), Technology Generation in Latin American Manufacturing Industries, London: Macmillan Press – now Palgrave. TEXTMAT (1994a), The Impact of Practices of Fiscal Policies in Tanzania, Dar es Salaam: Mimeo. TEXTMAT (1994b), The Fiscal Impact of Trade Policy on Textile Industry in Tanzania, Dar es Salaam. Tezler, R. and Molenaar (1989), ‘In Search of New Approaches: Major Areas of Attention’, Operations Review Unit, Small Enterprises, New Approaches: Proceedings of the Workshop ‘Small Scale Enterprise Development, in Search of New Dutch Approaches’, The Hague: Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Directorate General for International Cooperation. Thirsk, J. (1982), ‘The Rural Economy: Markets, Trade and Transport’, in: J. Blum (ed.), Our Forgotten Past: Seven Centuries of Life on the Land, London: Thames and Hudson. Thomann, R.V. and J.A. Mueller (1987), Principles of Surface Water Quality Modelling and Control, New York: Harper & Row.
Bibliography 399 Thomas, C.Y. (1974), Dependence and Transformations, New York: Monthly Review Press. Timmer, M.P (1996), On the Reliability of Unit Value Ratios in International Comparisons, Groningen: Groningen Growth and Development Centre, Research Memorandum GD 31. Timmer, M.P. and A. Szirmai (1999), ‘Comparative Productivity Performance in Manufacturing in South and East Asia’, Oxford Development Studies, 27, (1), 57–79. TIRDO (1989), Ten Years of the Tanzania Industrial Research and Development Organisation (TIRDO) 1979–1989, TIRDO. TIRDO (1990), Semi-Detailed Energy Audit at Tanzania Breweries’ Dar es Salaam Plant, TIRDO and AF-Energi Konsult. TIRDO (1993a), Operational Guidelines and Procedures for the Extension Services – Manual, TIRDO. TIRDO (1993b), Draft TIRDO Five-Year Plan 1993/94–1997/98, TIRDO. TIRDO (1993c), Incentive Scheme Package – 1992/93, TIRDO. TIRDO (1995), Staff List as for 1-10-1995, TIRDO. Todaro, M.P. (1997), Economic Development in the Third World, New York: Longman. Toussaint, T.J.A. (1994), Energy Conservation in the Industry of Tanzania: Cost Reduction by Energy Conservation at Tanzania Breweries Ltd, Eindhoven University of Technology, the Netherlands. TPC, Meetings of the Technical Programme Committee, vols 1–22, TIRDO. TSG (1996), Roadmap Study of Four African Countries: Ghana, Namibia, Uganda and Tanzania, Washington, DC: The Service Group. UNESCO (1989), Statistical Yearbook 1989, Lanham: UNESCO Publishing & Bernan Press. UNESCO (1994), Statistical Yearbook 1994, Lanham: UNESCO Publishing & Bernan Press. UNESCO (1995), Statistical Yearbook 1995, Lanham: UNESCO Publishing & Bernan Press. UNIDO (1980), The Provision, Storage and Handling of Dyes and Chemicals for Textile Dyeing, Printing and Finishing, UNIDO. UNIDO (1982), Assistance to the Tanzania Industrial Research and Development Organisation, UNIDO. UNIDO (1988a), Industrial Restructuring Policies in Developing Asian Countries with Particular Attention to the Textile and Garment Industry, Vienna: UNIDO, Limited Distribution. UNIDO (1988b), Regenerating African Manufacturing Industry: Approach and Programme, Studies of the Rehabilitation of African Industry no. 1, PPD 101-29, December. UNIDO (1990), Rehabilitation of African Industry, no. 12, PPD 168, 10 July. UNIDO (1991), Manual for the Preparation of Industrial Feasibility Studies, Vienna: UNIDO. UNIDO (1993), Industry and Development Global Report, 1992/93, Vienna: UNIDO. UNIDO (1995), New Materials and the Challenge for Developing Countries, Background Paper no. 3, UNIDO Global Forum on Industry. UNIDO (various), Industry and Development Global Report, Geneva. United Nations (1961), Index Numbers of Industrial Production, Studies in Methods, series F, no. 1, New York: United Nations. United Nations (1968a), A System of National Accounts, Studies in Methods, series F, no. 2, rev. 3, New York: United Nations. United Nations (1968b), International Standard Industrial Classification of All Economic Activities, Statistical Papers, series M, no. 4, rev. 2, New York.
400 Bibliography United Nations (1979), National Accounting Practices in Seventy Countries, Studies in Methods, series F, no. 26, vol. 3, New York: United Nations. United Nations (1990), International Standard Industrial Classification of all Economic Activities, 3rd revision, Statistical Papers, series M, no. 4, rev. 3, New York: United Nations. United Nations (1993), System of National Accounts, Studies in Methods, series F, no. 2, rev. 4, Brussels/Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities. United Nations (1995), Statistical Yearbook,-40th issue, New York. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (1972), Guidelines for the Study of Transfer of Technology to Developing Countries, New York: United Nations. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (1978), Handbook on the Acquisition of Technology by Developing Countries, New York: United Nations. United Nations Department of Economic Affairs (1951), Measures for the Economic Development of Underdeveloped Countries, New York: United Nations Department of Economic Affairs. United Nations Development Programme, Development Cooperation Report Tanzania, various issues. United Republic of Tanzania (1969), Second Five Year Plan for Social and Economic Development (1969–1974): Volume I: General Analysis, Dar es Salaam: Government Printer. United Republic of Tanzania (1972), The Economic Survey, 1971–1972, Dar es Salaam: Government Printer. United Republic of Tanzania (1976), Third Five Year Plan for Economic and Social Development (1976–1981): Volume I: General Perspective, Dar es Salaam: Government Printer. United Republic of Tanzania (1977), The Economic Survey, 1975–1976, Dar es Salaam: Government Printer. United Republic of Tanzania (1980), The Regulation of Trade Act 1980: no. 18 of 1980, Dar es Salaam: Tanzanian Gazette Supplement. United Republic of Tanzania (1982a), Structural Adjustment Programme for Tanzania, Dar es Salaam: Government Printer. United Republic of Tanzania (1982b), The National Economic Survival Programme, Dar es Salaam: Government Printer. United Republic of Tanzania (1982c), The Economic Survey, 1981, Dar es Salaam: Government Printer. United Republic of Tanzania (1983), Speech by the Hon. Lt. Col. A.S. Muncho (MP): Minister for Trade, for the session of the national assembly for 1982/3, Dar es Salaam: Government Printer. United Republic of Tanzania (1985a), The National Science and Technology for Tanzania, Ministry of Planning and Economic Affairs, Dar es Salaam: United Republic of Tanzania. United Republic of Tanzania (1985b), Hali ya Uchumi wa Taifa katika Mwaka, 1984 [The Economic Survey 1984], Dar es Salaam: Government Printer. United Republic of Tanzania (1986a), Programme for Economic Recovery, Dar es Salaam: Government Printer. United Republic of Tanzania (1986b), Hali ya Uchumi wa Taifa katika Mwaka, 1985 [The Economic Survey 1985], Dar es Salaam: Government Printer. United Republic of Tanzania (1989), The Economic and Social Action Programme, Dar es Salaam: Government Printer.
Bibliography 401 United Republic of Tanzania (1990a), Industrial Rehabilitation Study of the Textile Subsector of Tanzania, Dar es Salaam: Ministry of Industries and Trade, Government Printers. United Republic of Tanzania (1990b), National Investment (Protection and Promotion) Act: No. 10 of 1990, Dar es Salaam: The President’s Office – Planning Commission. United Republic of Tanzania (1992a), National Investment (Protection and Promotion) (Amendment) Act: No. 10 of 1992, Dar es Salaam: Tanzanian Gazette Supplement. United Republic of Tanzania (1992b), Public Corporations Act: No. 2 of 1992, Dar es Salaam: Tanzanian Gazette Supplement. United Republic of Tanzania (1994), Fair Trade Practices Act: No. 4 of 1994, Dar es Salaam: Tanzanian Gazette Supplement. United Republic of Tanzania (1995a), Parastatal Sector Reform Commission: 1994 Review and Action Plan for 1995 and Beyond, Dar es Salaam: Parastatal Sector Reform Commission. United Republic of Tanzania (1995b), Economic Survey, 1994, Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics, Government Printer. United Republic of Tanzania (1995c). Revised National Accounts of Tanzania: 1976–1990, Dar es Salaam: Bureau of Statistics. United Republic of Tanzania (1996a), Sustainable Industrial Development Policy (SIDP) (1996–2020), Dar es Salaam: Ministry of Industries and Trade. United Republic of Tanzania (1996b), Industrial Development Policy (1995–2020): Revised Zero Draft, Dar es Salaam, Technical Committee on Formulation of Industrial Development Strategy and Policy United Republic of Tanzania (1997), Mkakati wa Taifa wa Kusimamia Utekelezaji wa Sera za Kuondoa Umaskini [National Strategy for Overseeing the Implementation of Poverty Eradication in Tanzania], Office of the Vice-President. United Republic of Tanzania (1998), The Development Vision 2025 for Tanzania, Planning Commission (Coordinating). United Republic of Tanzania (1999a), Economic Survey, 1998, Dar es Salaam: Planning Commission, June. United Republic of Tanzania (1999b), Speech by the Minister of Finance for the 1999/2000 Budget, Dar es Salaam. United Republic of Tanzania (1999c), Speech by the Minister of Industries and Trade, for 1999/2000 budget, Dar es Salaam, June. United Republic of Tanzania (Various), Economic Surveys, Dar es Salaam: Planning Commission and Bureau of Statistics. United Republic of Tanzania (Various), Analysis of Parastatal Accounts. UNU-INTECH, QEH-ESRF (1996), The Impact of Import Liberalisation on the Manufacturing Sector; see also Semboja and Kweka, forthcoming. US Department of Commerce (1986), National Income and Product Accounts of the United States, 1929–82, Washington, DC. US Department of Commerce (1990a), Bureau of the Census, 1989 Annual Survey of Manufactures, Statistics for Industry Groups and Industries, M90(AS)-1, Washington, DC. US Department of Commerce (1990b), Bureau of the Census, 1987 Census of Manufactures, General Summary and Industry Series. US Department of Commerce (1992), National Income and Product Accounts, 1959–88, vol. 2, Washington, DC, September. US Department of Commerce, (Various) Survey of Current Business. USAID/TANZANIA (1996), Environmental Threat Assessment, May.
402 Bibliography USAID-CTI (1994), Industrial Policy Proposal, a report based on Joint USAID and Confederation of Tanzania Industries Programme, Dar es Salaam. Valk, P. de (1992), A General Framework for Evaluating the Performance of Textile Enterprises in LDCs: With Application to Tanzania under Structural Adjustment, The Hague: Institute of Social Studies. Valk, P. de and A.V.Y. Mbelle (1990), Textile Industry under the Structural Adjustment Programme in Tanzania, 1980–1988, Dar es Salaam. Ven, Y. van der (1996), Privatization at Tanzania Harbors Authority, MSc thesis, Eindhoven: Technology and Development Studies, Eindhoven University of Technology. Verlinden, P. (1996), Rwanda & Burundi, Country Series Amsterdam, The Netherlands: Royal Tropical Institute (KIT). Vighi, M. and G. Chiaudani (1987), ‘Eutrophication in Europe: the Role of Agricultural Activities’, in: E. Hodgeson (ed.), Reviews in Environmental Toxicology, 3, 213–57. Vleuten, F. van der (1995), Energy and Environment in the Global Cement Industry: Strategies and Instruments to Promote Energy Efficiency in Developing Countries, Working Paper 4, Report ECN-C–94-035, Petten: ECN. Vleuten, F. van der and M. Yhdego (1996), Cleaner Production Technology for Greenhouse Gas Reduction in Tanzanian Private Industry, Preinvestment Study, Dar es Salaam: ERC. Vocational Education and Training Authority (1994), unpublished internal documents, Dar es Salaam: VETA. Vocational Education and Training Authority (1995), unpublished internal documents, Dar es Salaam: VETA. Vries, J. de (1984), European Urbanization, 1500–1800, London: Methuen and Co. Wangwe, S.M. (1979), Capacity Utilisation and Capacity Creation in Manufacturing in Tanzania with Special Reference to the Engineering Sector, unpublished PhD thesis, University of Dar es Salaam. Wangwe, S.M. (1986), Technology Imports, Technological Learning and Self-Reliance in Tanzania, Working Paper WEP 2–22/WP, Geneva: International Labor Office. Wangwe, S.M. (1990), Reflections on the Basic Industry Strategy, professorial inaugural lecture (unpublished), University of Dar es Salaam. Wangwe, S.M. (1992a), ‘Building Indigenous Technological Capacity: a Study of Selected Industries in Tanzania’, in: F. Stewart, S. Lall and S. Wangwe (eds), Alternative Development Strategies in sub-Saharan Africa, Basingstoke: Macmillan Press – now Palgrave – 265–93. Wangwe, S.M. (1992b), Rehabilitations in the Manufacturing Sector on Tanzania, Dar es Salaam. Wangwe, S.M. (1993), ‘Implications of Changing External and Internal Conditions for Industrial Restructuring in Tanzania’, in: M.S.D. Bagachwa and A.V.Y. Mbelle (eds), Economic Policy Under A Multiparty System in Tanzania, Dar es Salaam University Press. Wangwe, S.M. (1994), ‘Technology Development in Tanzania: Some Challenges for the 21st Century’, in: L.A. Msambichaka, H.P.B. Moshi and F.P. Mtatifikolo (eds) (1994), Development Challenges and Strategies for Tanzania: An Agenda for the 21st Century, Dar es Salaam: Economic Research Bureau/Department of Economic, University of Dar es Salaam. Wangwe, S.M. (ed.) (1995), Exporting Africa: Technology, Trade and Industrialization in sub-Saharan Africa, London: Routledge.
Bibliography 403 Wangwe, S.M. (1998), The Vision of Industrialization, paper submitted to the Team of Experts of the Development Vision, Dar es Salaam, ESRF. Wangwe, S.M. and M.S.D. Bagachwa (1990), ‘Impact of Policies on Technological Choice and Development in Tanzanian Industry’, in: F. Stewart, H. Thomas, and T. de Wilde (eds), The Other Policy, London: Intermediate Technology Publications. Wangwe, S.M. and N. Luvanga (1993), ‘Technological Transformation in the Third World: The case of Tanzania’, in: S.J. Patel (ed.), Technological Transformation in the Third World, vol. II, UNU/WIDER, Helsinki. Wangwe, S.M. and H. Semboja (1997), Industrialization in Africa, paper contributed to CODESRIA programme on Beyond Structural Adjustment, Dakar. Wangwe, S.M., F. Musonda and J. Kweka (1997a), Policies for Manufacturing Competitiveness: The Case of Tanzania, ESRF Discussion Paper, Dar es Salaam. Wangwe, S.M., H.H. Semboja and J.P. Kweka (1997b), Multi-Country Comparative Study of Private Enterprises Development in Africa (MCC-PED), A Draft Report for Tanzania, Dar es Salaam. Wangwe, S.M., H.H. Semboja, and H.B. Lecomte (1996), Exit Procedures and Economic Transformation: The case of Tanzania, ESRF Discussion Paper Series no. 010, Dar es Salaam. Watanabe, S. (1987), ‘Technological Capability and Industrialization: Effects of Aid and Sanctions in United Republic of Tanzania and Zimbabwe’, International Labor Review, 125 (5). Weaver, J.H. and A. Kronemer (1981), ‘Tanzanian and African Socialism’, World Development, 9 (9/10). Weiss, C., Jr. (1990), ‘Scientific and Technological Constraints to Economic Growth and Equity’, in: R.E. Evenson. and G. Ranis (eds), Science and Technology: Lessons for Development Policy, Boulder: Westview Press. Weiss, J. (1988), Industry in Developing Countries: Theory, Policy and Evidence, New York: Croon Helm. Welch, F. (1970). ‘Education in Production’, Journal of Political Economy, 38, 35–59. Wells, L. (1975), ‘Economic Man and Engineering Man: Choice of Technology in a Low-Wage Country’, in: C.P. Timmer et al. (eds), The Choice of Technology in Developing Countries, Cambridge: Harvard Studies in International Affairs, 69–74. Westphal, L.E. et al. (1990), ‘The Development of Technological Capability in Manufacturing: A Macroscopic Approach to Policy Research’, in: R.E. Evenson and G. Ranis (eds), Science and Technology: Lessons for Development Policy, Boulder: Westview Press. Westphal, L.E., L. Kim and C. Dahlman (1985), Reflections on the Republic of Korea’s Acquisition of Technological Capability, New York: Praeger. Westphal, L.E. and R.E. Evenson (1993), Technological Change and Technology Strategy, Development Economics Seminar, paper no. 93–1/4, Den Haag. White, G. (1984), ‘Developmental States and Socialist Industrialization in the Third World’, Journal of Development Studies, 21 (1). Williams, D. (1975), National Planning and the Choice of Technology: the Case of Textiles in Tanzania, Economic Research Bureau, paper no. 75.12, University of Dar Es Salaam. Williams, D. (1976), Choice of Technology and National Planning: the Case of Tanzania, unpublished doctoral dissertation, Harvard University. Winston, G. (1979), ‘The Appeal of Inappropriate Technologies: Self-Inflicted Wages, Ethnic Pride and Corruption’, World Development, 7 (8/9), 835–45. Wissema, J.G. and L. Euser (1988), Samenwerking bij Technologische Vernieuwing – De Nieuwe Dimensie van het Management van Innovatie [Cooperation in Technological
404 Bibliography Innovation – The New Dimension of Innovation Management], Deventer: Kluwer bedrijfswetenschappen. World Bank (1976), World Tables, 1976, Baltimore and London: Johns Hopkins University Press. World Bank (1980), World Tables, 1980, Baltimore and London: Johns Hopkins University Press. World Bank (1981), Accelerated Development in sub-Saharan Africa: An Agenda for Action, Washington, DC. World Bank (1984), Tanzania: Country Economic Memorandum, Report no. 5019-TA, Washington: World Bank. World Bank (1987a), Tanzania: An Agenda for Industrial Recovery, Report no. 6357-TA, vols I & II, Washington: World Bank. World Bank (1987b), World Development Report, 1987, Oxford: Oxford University Press. World Bank (1988), Parastatals in Tanzania: Towards a Reform Program, Report no. 7100-TA, Washington: World Bank. World Bank (1989), Industrial Development in Tanzania: An Agenda for Industrial Recovery, Washington DC: World Bank. World Bank (1991), Tanzania: Economic Report: Towards Sustainable Development in the 1990s, Report no. 9352-TA, vols I & II, Washington: World Bank. World Bank (1993a), Zimbabwe: A Policy Agenda for Private Sector Development, Washington, DC. World Bank (1993b), First Report on the Kenyan Survey, Regional Programme on Enterprise Development, Africa Technical Department. World Bank (1993c), Economic Reform in the Manufacturing Sector of Ghana, Africa Technical Department. World Bank (1993d), East Asian Economic Miracle, Washington. World Bank (1993e), Agricultural Sector Memorandum, Uganda, Report no. 10715-UG. World Bank (1994a), Adjustment in Africa: Reforms, Results and the Road Ahead, New York: Oxford University Press. World Bank (1994b), First Report on the Zimbabwe Survey, Regional Programme on Enterprise Development, Africa Technical Department. World Bank (1994c), The Road Ahead, Washington, DC. World Bank (1995a), Bureaucrats in Business: The Economics and Politics of Government Ownership, New York: Oxford University Press. World Bank (1995b), World Development Report, 1995, New York: Oxford University Press. World Bank (1995c), World Tables, 1995, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. World Bank, (various), World Tables, Washington, DC: World Bank. World Bank (1997), World Development Report, 1997, Oxford: Oxford University Press. World Health Organization (1976), Health and Environment, Geneva. Word Health Organisation (1982), Rapid Assessment of Sources of Air, Water and Land Pollution, WHO Offset Publication no. 62, Geneva. Wright, E. (ed.) (1984), History of the World: the Last Five Hundred Years, Feltham: Hanslyn Publishing Group. Zanting, H.A. (1996), A Systematic Assessment of Water Pollution in Lake Victoria, MSc thesis, Eindhoven, The Netherlands: Eindhoven University of Technology, Faculty of Technology Management. Zijl, G. and R. Lassche (1997), Testing a Technology Audit Methodology: Rapid Assessment of Six Small and Medium Scale Enterprises in Tanzania, MSc thesis, Eindhoven: Eindhoven University of Technology.
Index ABB National Transformers 157, 169 actor network 211–12 African Socialism 136, 295 African Tanneries Ltd (AT) 346 Afro-Cooling 160 agriculture 12, 245, 246 focus on SMEs 365 Ardhi Institute (University of Dar es Salaam) 210 Arrow, K. 127 Arusha declaration (1967) 17, 19, 30, 41, 45, 137, 145, 148, 151 Bagachwa, M.S.D. and Mbelle, A.V.Y. 360 Bank of Tanzania 147, 310 basic industry strategy (BIS) 351, 352, 358, 367 Bates, R. 135 beer industry 265–6, 267, 268–9, 270, 271 Bell, M.B. et al 196, 198 Bora Shoe Company 346 Bromley, R.J. 320 Building Contractors (BC) 206, 208 Building Research Unit (BRU) 210 bureaucracy foreign-exchange maximizing behaviour 144–9, 151 political/managerial aspects 145, 147–9 public choice approach 144 size of public sector under structural adjustment 149, 151 cement industry 271–7 Centre for Agricultural and Rural Mechanization and Appropriate Technology (CARMATEC) 169 Chazan, N. et al 145 Clark, W.E. 353 Clean Development Mechanism 263, 279
Cleaner Environment Production in Industry in Tanzania (CEPITA) 279 climate 245, 247 Commission for Science and Technology 164 Common Market for Eastern and Southern Africa (COMESA) 305 construction current social-economic performance/contribution to national development 200–1, 203, 206 dwelling subsector: human resources stock 208–10; natural resources stock 210–11; summary 212; technological capabilities 212; technology infrastructure (actor network) 211–12; technology stock 206, 208 David, P. 123, 127 DeBresson, C. 154 demographics 219, 220–1, 244–5 Development Vision 2025 368 Dosi, G. 127 Downs, A. 144 East African Community 32, 38 Economic Recovery Programme (ERP) 305–6, 342 economic and social action programme (ESAP) 342 Economic and Social Research Foundation (ESRF) 157, 160, 163, 168–9, 360 Multi-Country Comparative Study on Private Enterprise Development 161, 165 education 3–4, 6–7, 51, 291, 297–8 demand/supply of technical manpower 223–4 demographics 219, 221 financial sources 233, 234 405
406 Index education (cont.) firm owners/managers/employees 58–61 importance 218–19 metalworking industry example 224–34 post-primary 222 primary 221 role 52–4 secondary 222–3 structure/enrolment 221–3 teacher selection 233–4 technical 359–61 TIRDO staff 173 universities 221 use of English 233 Elbadawi, I. 310 energy conservation background 262 beer industry example 265–6, 267, 268–9, 270, 271 cement industry example 271–7 in industrial sector 262–3 in practice 263–5 summary 277–8 what industries can do 278–80 Energy Policy of Tanzania 262 Engblom, AC. and Veres, V. 306 environment 5–6, 12 background 237 industrial pollution in urban areas 252, 253, 255, 256; air 254, 257–9; mining activities 256, 259–60; water 254 Lake Victoria results; BOD loading estimates 247–8; TN/TP loading estimates 249–50 Lake Victoria statistics 243; agriculture 245, 246; industrial characteristics 244; population 244–5; rainfall 245, 247; wetlands 247 Environmental Resource Consultants in Dar es Salaam 263 ESCAP 175 ESRF-PSRC 157, 158, 159 exchange rates 19, 20, 21, 23, 26, 357–8 export credit guarantee scheme (ECGS) 30
exports background 114–16 dual economy model 116–22, 129–30 problems for new entrants 122–4; generic technological change 124–6; patterns of path dependency 126–9 Fei-Ranis dual economy model 117–22, 129–30 commercialization point 117 export substitution 117, 119, 129 labour-intensive export phase 117–19 technological predictions 119–22 weaknesses 129–30 Financial Act (1973) 21 firms descriptive information 58–61 estimates of cost functions 61, 63, 64, 65, 66–8, 69 planning in 50 selection for R&D 185–6 skills/production-level data 56–7 technology capability 69–71 Foreign Exchange Act (1992) 29 Foreign Investment Act (1963) 18 Framework Convention on Climate Change (FCCC) 263 Fransman, M. 155 Freeman, C. 124–5 G&T Company 159 Gallagher, M. 135 Galtung, J. 319 Ghana 57, 58–61, 70 Ghanaian Living Standards Measurement Study 59 government partnership with private sector 370 role/capacity 167, 365–6 Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. 126 human resources 199, 208–9 development 160–1, 359–61 educational backgrounds 209 occupational status 209–10 import substitution industrialization (ISI) 350–1 Indol International Holding 265
Index 407 industrial development 48–9 background 12–13 crisis in 44–5 1961–7 period 38–9 1967–73 period 39, 41 1973–80 period 41–3 1980–4 period 43–5 1984–90 period 45–7 1990–5 period 47–8 periods of analysis 35 poor infrastructure/shortage of skilled labour 13, 48 statistics concerning 36, 37, 41 trends/explanations 34, 37–8 industrial policy 3, 6, 7–8 background 11 classification of strategy 15–16 confinement 19, 22, 26 decontrol/shift from import substitution 25–8, 40 development plans 17 export incentives/promotion 23, 26–30 foreign aid 20–3, 25, 28–30 foreign exchange windows 46 import licensing 19, 21, 22, 25, 26 import substitution 17–18, 41, 43, 160 initial conditions 12–13 joint ventures 19, 39 liberalization 28–30 nationalization 18–19 policy periods 13–14, 17, 31 price control 21–2, 23, 26 private (foreign) entrepreneurship 28–30 private/public sector balance 23, 27–8, 41 rates of protection in manufacturing 24 regulatory control 18–23, 25 self-reliance 18–19 synthesis of external influences/policy periods 30, 32, 33, 34 tariff protection 17–18, 39 industrialization basic industry strategy 351 development of competitive industry 363–4; dynamic structure 364; enhance role/ capacity of
government support 365–6; focus on technological learning 364–5; priority of agro–based SMEs 365 failures: inadequate infrastructure 359; inadequate institutional capacity 358; low investment in technology/technological learning 362–3; low level of human resource development 359–61; policy 357–8; weak linkages between industry/related sectors 358–9 Great Depression 350 historical perspective 283 import substitution policies 350–1 planning models 350 post-independence period 349–50 prerequisites 285–6; economy 288–90, 293–6; education 291, 297–8; health care 291, 298; kinship 290, 296–7; politics 286–8, 291–3; religion 290–1, 297 present state 284 restructuring: economic reforms 354–5; insufficiency of macroeconomic reform 355–6; recovery 355; technological capabilities 356–7 strategy 366 innovation background 153–4 efforts/achievements in manufacturing sector 156–60 factors influencing productivity 160; access to technical information 165–6; competitive market turbulence 162–3; customer base 162–3; financial capabilities 163–4; human resource development 160–1; institutional framework 164–5; legal/regulatory framework 166; R&D efforts 161–2; role of government 167 forms/role from conceptual/general perspective 154–6 offensive/defensive strategies 156 policy recommendations 167–8 search capabilities 156
408 Index Institute for Production Innovation (IPI) 169 International Comparisons of Output and Productivity (ICOP) project 92 International Labour Organisation (ILO) 326 International Monetary Fund (IMF) 34 Jedruszek, J.
353
Kenya 57, 58–61, 70 Kimambo, R.H. 211 knowledge transfer 176–7 Krugman, P. 126 labour productivity 41–4, 45, 87 basic data 106–11 1989 benchmark 92; comparisons 98; data sources 95–6; methodology for comparison 92–5; unit value ratios 96–8, 97 comparative 104–5 Malaysian pattern 118 trends 104 Lake Victoria pollution 237, 239, 241–2, 247–50 statistics 243–7 Lall, S. 198 Lewis, A. 115, 116–17 Lewis dual economy model 116–17 macroeconomic policies empirical analysis: methodological issues 307–10; time series 310–14 impact on manufacturing sector 305–6 industrial development 303–5 insufficient reform 355–6 manufacturing performance 73–5 capacity utilization 302 data on 352–4 data sources for time series on 10+ 75 employment 302 exports 301–2 gross value added/employment 99 growth/share in GDP 301
labour productivity 87, 92–8, 104–5 new indices of production 81, 82–5, 87, 88–91 new insights 98; changes in structure 100, 102; level adjustments in nominal value added 100, 101; trends in real growth 102–4 post-independence 352–4 pre-independence 351–2 reconstruction of nominal 10+ GDP 76; conceptual errors 78–80; coverage 76–7; summary of adjustments 81; treatment of non-response in official statistics 77–8 manufacturing sector background 300–1 exports 315 investment 316 macroeconomic policies 303–6; analysis of effects 307–14 recent developments 301–2; dynamics 303; signs of recovery 302–3 Masuha 360 Mbelle, A.V.Y. 306 and Bagachwa, M.S.D. 303 metalwork industry research into education shortcomings: analysis 231, 233–4; background 224; facilities/ costs 230; family/community 228; finance 230–1; methodology 224–6; organization, contents, methods 230; results 226, 227, 228, 229, 230–1, 232; school management 230; students 228; teachers 228, 230 Ministry of Land and Urban Development 210 Ministry of Science and Technology and Higher Education 210 Ministry of Trade and Industries (MIT) 347, 348 Ministry of Works 210 Morogoro Canvas Mill 169 Morogoro Shoe Company 346 Moshi Leather Industries 159 Mukanda, R. 147
Index 409 National Board of Architects and the Quantity Surveyors (NBAQS) 206, 208 National Construction Council (NCC) 210, 211 national consultative process for industrialization (NCPI) 373 National Development Corporation (NDC) 18, 139, 145, 147 national economic survival programme (NESP) 17, 343 National Industries (Licensing and Registration) Act (1967) 19 National Investment (Promotion and Protection) Act (NIA) (1990) 28–9 National Price Commission 147 National Price Control Advisory Board 19 natural resources 199, 210–11 Ndulu, B.J. and Semboja, J.J. 312 Nelson, R.R. 198 newly industrialized countries (NICs) 54, 114–15 Niskanen, W. 144, 145 Nyerere, J. 136–7, 297 Pack, H. 176 and Paxson, C. 361 and Westphal, L.E. 128 Parastatal Sector Reform Commission (PSRC) 348 path dependencies and generic technological change 122–4 patterns 126–9 Pieper, U. 304 political system capacities distributive 287 extractive 286–7 internal/external 287 productive 287 regulating 287 symbolic 287 pollution see environment Portland Cement (Wazo) Ltd 302 Presidential Parastatal Sector Reform Commission 29 Prins, I.M. and Szirmai, A. 353 private sector balance with public 23, 27–8, 41
creation/sustainability of enabling environment 371; action on other related issues 372; fiscal policies 371; infrastructural development 372; investment promotion 372; monetary policy 371; trade 371 development 370–1 partnership with government 370 privatization conceptual framework 341–2 factors accounting for turnaround 346–7 reforms/industrial performance 342–4; insights 344–6; summary 347–8 production: aggregate evidence on technology 54, 55; background 50–1; determinants 51–4; economic environment 52; firm-level data 56–7; indices 81, 82–5, 86–7, 88–91; purchase of modern equipment 52; role of education/technology 52–4; technological ability 51 public choice approach 135, 144 Public Corporation Act (1992) 29 public sector: balance with private 23, 27–8, 41; political/managerial conflict 145, 147–9; size under structural adjustment 149, 151 rapid assessment evaluation 250, 251, 252, 260–1 rapid assessment methodology 238; penetration factors 240–2; reference nutrient load from modelling 242; waste loads 238–40; wet deposition 240 Regional Program on Enterprise Development (RPED) 56, 157, 158, 162 research and development (R&D) 154, 155, 160, 169 access to information 165 efforts in 161–2 institutions 169–70, 171–2 model 173–4 phases 174 selection of firms 176–7 Richardson, C.J. and Nichols, D.S. 241
410 Index Rodriguez, E. 303 Rogers, E.M. 176 Romano, C.A. 154 Romijn, H.A. 198 Rosenberg, N. 197 Rostow, W.W. 320 Rothwell, R. 163 Schumpeter, J. 155 science and technology (S&T) activities 164 Semboja, H.H. et al 157, 158, 161, 165 small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) 365 South African Breweries (SAB) 265 State Trading Corporation (STC) 19, 22 Steinmuller, E. and Bastos, M.-I. 125 structural adjustment plan (SAP) 17, 343 sustainable industrial development policy (SIDP) background 367 described 367–8 development of private sector 370–1; creation/sustainability of enabling environment 371–2 implementation strategy 369–70 industrial sector mission/objectives 368–9 institutional framework/consultative mechanism for policy implementation 372–4 partnership between government/private sector 370 success 374–5 Tanga Cement Company Ltd 302 Tanzania background 1–3 colonial period 12 economic policy 3 education 3–4, 6–7 environment 5–6 industrial policy 3, 6, 7–8 industrialization 284–5; lessons from European history 298–9; pre-requisites 291–8 technology 4–5 Tanzania Breweries Ltd 157, 160, 302, 347, 353
background 265, 344 energy; causes of inefficiency 269, 271; conservation opportunities 268–9, 270; costs 266, 268; efficiency 265–6; specific 267 performance 344–5 Tanzania Bureau of Standards (TBS) 169 Tanzania Cigarette Company (TCC) 302, 346 Tanzania Engineering and Manufacturing Design Organisation (TEMDO) 169 Tanzania Industrial Research and Development Organisation (TIRDO) 169, 171, 265, 358–9 acquisition of technology 181–3 adaptation of technology 183–5 educational levels of staff 173 field research 177–8 focus of 172–3 general characteristics of process 187, 189 projects: activated carbon 179; aluminium sulphate 178; caustic soda 178; dehydrated castor oil 178; natural dyes 178; pectin 179; satellite receivers 180; school chalk 179; solar thermal systems 179; Turkey red oil 180; variables 191–2; wood adhesive 179 selection of firms 185–6 summary 189–91 technology identification/selection 180–1 transfer/implementation of technology 186–7 Tanzania Industrial Studies and Consulting Organisation (TISCO) 355 Tanzania Oxygen Ltd 302 Tanzania Portland Cement Corporation Ltd 346 background 271–2 conservation opportunities: individual power station 275–6; long-term options 276; new measurement systems for kilns 276; reduction of radiation/
Index 411 convection losses 276; replace electrostatic filters 276 energy: causes of inefficiency 277; costs 274–5; efficiency 272–4 Tanzanian Electrical Goods Manufacturing Company (TANELEC) 346–7 background 345 performance 345–6 Tanzanian Investment Centre (TIC) 347, 348 technological behaviour public sector paradoxes 135–6; explanations/limitations 140–4; planned vs actual 136–9; project vs technological preferences 141–2; pronounced variations 139–40; two textile plant comparisons 142–4 technological capabilities 69–71 assessment 198 background 194 building 197–8, 213–16 construction industry example 200–1, 202, 203, 204–5, 206, 207, 208–12, 217 definitions 196–7, 199–200 levels 197 new theoretical views 194–6 restructuring 356–7 technological change 119–22 generic 124–6 and path dependencies 122–4 technology ability 51 acquisition 128, 175, 181–3 adaptation 176, 183–5 development 153 general characteristics of development process 187, 188, 189 identification/selection 174, 180–1 implementation/diffusion 177 investment in 362–3
and knowledge transfer 177 learning process 127–8, 196–7; focus on 364–5; low investment in 362–3 little change in 54, 55, 56 role 52–4 stock 199, 206, 208 transfer/implementation 186–7 upgrading 115 textile industry 139, 142–4, 356 Textile Manufacturing Association of Tanzania (TEXTMAT) 29 transnational corporations (TNCs) 38 urban informal sector background 318–19 current theoretical points of view/suggested research topics 320–1 empirical evidence 322; constraints for future growth 325–6; relations between formal/informal 323–4; relevance for socioeconomic development 324–5; support for formal/informal dichotomy 323 interest in 319–20 methodological problems 322 statistics 327–36 Vocational Educational Training Authority 161 Wangwe, S.M. 157, 163 et al 303, 306 Weiss, C. Jr 198 Wells, L. 140 Westphal, L.E. 198 Williams, D. 140–1, 143 World Bank 25, 39, 44, 46, 56, 149, 157 World Health Organisation (WHO) 252 Zimbabwe
57, 58–61, 70